Optimal Allocation of an Indivisible Good

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Optimal Allocation of an Indivisible Good"

Transcription

1 Optimal Allocation of an Indivisible Good Ran Shao y Yeshiva University Lin hou z Shanghai Jiao Tong University This Version: January Abstract In this paper we consider the problem of allocating an indivisible good between two agents under incomplete information. We provide a characterization of mechanisms that maximize the sum of the expected utilities of the agents among all deterministic feasible strategy-proof mechanisms: Any optimal mechanism must belong to either one of the two x price mechanisms or one of the two option mechanisms. Furthermore, when stochastic mechanisms are allowed and agents types are distributed uniformly, we show that any optimal mechanism must be a convex combination of two xed price mechanisms and two option mechanisms. Introduction In this paper we consider the problem of allocating an indivisible good between two agents when agents valuations of the good are private information. A typical problem of such is the bilateral bargaining model in which a seller and a buyer negotiate with each other as to if and how to trade a particular good. This problem has generated a large literature since the pioneering work of Myerson and Satterthwaite (983). Another more practical example is how to allocate a more desirable o ce between two interested employees. The The authors want to thank the the following scholars for their comments on the work reported in this paper: Hector Chade, Kim-Sau Chung, Jerry Green, Alejandro Manelli, Eric Maskin, David Miller, Benny Moldovanu, Stephen Morris, Ed Schlee, and participants at the 7 Far Eastern Meeting of the Econometric Society in Taipei and the 8 Southwest Economic Theory Conference at UC Santa Barbara. y Department of Economics, Yeshiva University, 5 Lexington Ave. Room 75, New York, NY 6. rshao@yu.edu. z Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, The People s Republic of China. zhoulin@sjtu.edu.cn

2 intense research interest in this type of problem is derived from a fundamental dilemma due to Green and La ont (977): when agents valuations are private information, it is impossible to nd a costless method that always gives the good to the agent with the higher valuation. Several methods are commonly used in practice to solve such allocation problems: Lotteries, seniority ranking or other type of queuing, or even auctions, are just few of the well-known examples. Many of such methods are quite e ective in soliciting agents revelation of true valuations. Yet some methods may often assign the good to the agent with the lower valuation (lotteries), others may incur negative cash out ows from the agents (auctions). At the more theoretical level, two particular classes of methods have received researchers attentions. The rst class consists of all Vickery-Clark-Groves pivotal mechanisms (Vickery, 96, Clarke, 97, Groves, 973) that extend the conventional English auction scheme. The second class consists of all xed-price mechanisms (Hagerty and Rogerson, 987), in which the good is assigned to one agent (the seller) unless both agents are willing to trade the good at a predetermined price. It is well-known that these two classes of methods have their own strength and weakness, yet no one has ever carried out any formal comparisons of these two methods, not to mention comparisons of more general methods. We shall conduct a systemic investigation of various allocation methods from the optimal mechanism design perspective. We focus on methods that are both robust and practical. Speci cally, we require that all methods be immune to individual manipulation so that it must be a dominant strategy for each agent to reveal his/her true valuation. We also require that all methods be feasible so that there would be no need of injection of money from outside. Our task is to nd among all such methods those that maximize the sum of the utilities of both agents. We show that xed price mechanisms are indeed optimal when primitives are well behaved. In addition, this exercise leads us to another class of mechanisms, called the option mechanisms. In an option mechanism, one agent is the temporary holder of the good and the other agent is the recipient of a call option that allows him to purchase the good from the rst agent at a predetermined price. The good changes hands as long as the option recipient is willing to buy the good from the temporary holder at the predetermined price. In comparison, under the xed price mechanism, the good changes hands only when both agents agree to the trade at a predetermined price. We can show that option mechanisms are also optimal. In fact, one of the main results of our paper is that any optimal mechanisms must be a lottery of xed price mechanisms and

3 option mechanisms. It is also interesting that we have found a new role for options. In the traditional nance literature options are either used as instruments for risk management for investors or as means to provide incentives for managers. In our model, however, they are used as a part of a mechanism to maximize the sum of agents utilities. Our results make a signi cant contribution to the literature of mechanism design. While the optimal mechanism design approach has been standard for the study of Bayesian mechanisms, it has rarely been applied by anyone to study strategy-proof mechanisms. Our paper is one of the very few that have identi ed the structure of optimal strategy-proof mechanisms in a canonical allocation model. The most closed related paper is Miller (). Miller considers a model that is similar to ours in a concurrently developed paper (Miller, ). The two- rm cartel with private information case subsumes the same math structure as our model. He shows that in general the mechanisms (V-C-G mechanisms) that guarantee the allocation e ciency cannot be optimal (Theorem of Miller ()). However, the paper s major focus is to identify the conditions under which the money burning (price war) is unavoidable. Moreover, there is no mentioning of the option mechanism and the characterization of all optimal mechanisms. The fundamental di culties of analyzing such kind of problem are underlying the problem of in nite dimension linear programming. In general, solving the optimal solution explicitly is extremely di cult. It is much easier to compute it numerically other than characterizing the properties the solution in general even after discretizing the problem into a nite problem. The Main Results Consider a model with two agents and one indivisible good. The good is a private good so that it can be consumed by one agent only. Each agent has a quasi-linear utility function The fact that there few known results with strategy-proof mechanisms is not the only motivation behind our work. The predicted outcomes of a strategy-proof mechanism are deemed reliable since all agents have unambiguous optimal actions regardless others actions. The predicted outcomes of a Bayesian mechanism are accepted only under strong informational and behavioral assumptions. For example, one must assume that the distribution of agents types is common knowledge among all agents and is also known to the designer of the mechanism. We will not debate on the relative merits of Bayesian mechanisms, strategyproof mechanisms and other alternatives here. Interested readers can nd them in other papers on this issue (Chung and Ely, 4, d Aspremont and Gerard-Varet (979), Bergemann and Morris, 5, Jehiel et al, 6). 3

4 for the good and the money transfer, v i (x i ; t i ; i ) = i x i t i : Here the parameter i [; ] is agent i s valuation of the good, or i s type and x i [; ] is the probability that agent i receives the good. The value of i is known to agent i only. When the values of and are commonly known, the e cient allocation is to give the good to the agent with the higher i. However, when and are privately known only, it is not always possible to identify and execute the e cient allocation. We consider here direct mechanisms that ask agents to report their types and use their reported types to determine the allocation as well as transfers to the agents. This attention on direct mechanisms is not excessively restrictive since, by the revelation principle, our analysis immediately extends to all direct mechanisms in which both agents have dominant strategies at every type pro le. Otherwise, we allow nearly all direct mechanisms. For the general setup, we allow all mechanisms that allocate the good to agents randomly. In fact, one of our main results is derived only allowing deterministic mechanisms without withholding by the designer. Formally, a direct mechanism M consists of four integrable functions on [; ] [; ]: x ( ; ); x ( ; ); t ( ; ); t ( ; ). Since x ( ; ) and x ( ; ) are respectively the probabilities agent and agent receive the good, they must satisfy x i ( ; ) [; ] ; and x ( ; ) x ( ; ) ; 8 ; : The functions t ( ; ) and t ( ; ) are transfers to the agents. To ensure that agents have incentives to report their true types, we require that all mechanisms under consideration be strategy-proof, i.e., (IC) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) x ( ~ ; ) t ( ~ ; ); 8 ; ~ ; x ( ; ) t ( ; ) x ( ; ~ ) t ( ; ~ ); 8 ; ; ~ : We also require that all mechanisms be feasible so that it does not need outside money, (F) t ( ; ) t ( ; ) ; 8 ; : We are still working on the more general result which uni es both Theorem and by allowing all stochastic mechanisms. 4

5 The majority of work on bilateral bargaining further assumes budget-balanced-ness, i.e., (BB) t ( ; ) t ( ; ) = ; 8 ; : We don t want to impose budget-balanced-ness in our work. Although money burning seems ine cient ex post, it might conceivably increase the ex ante e ciency of a mechanism since it could provide incentives more e ectively. In fact, all Vickery-Groves-Clarke mechanisms that implement the e cient allocation of the good do not satisfy budgetbalanced-ness. If we were to impose budget-balanced-ness, we would have excluded a large class of mechanisms that are popular in the literature of mechanism design from consideration and the end result would be much weaker. So far the basic structure of our model looks virtually the same as the auction model with private values (Myerson, 98) and the bilateral bargaining model (Myerson and Satterthwaite, 983, Hagerty and Rogerson, 987). The main distinction between our model and the others is the di erence in objectives. In the auction literature the objective is maximal revenue extraction by an outsider from the agents, whereas in the bilateral bargaining model the objective is maximal revenue extraction by one agent (the seller) from the other (the buyer). In contrast, we adopt the utilitarian viewpoint here and our objective is to nd mechanisms that maximize the sum of ex-ante utilities of both agents. Given any feasible strategy-proof mechanism M = fx i ( ; ); t i ( )ji = ; g, the sum of agents utilities is at each ( ; ) is U ( ; ) U ( ; ) = x ( ; ) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; ): Since the mechanism M satis es feasibility, U ( ; ) U ( ; ) max f ; g ; 8 ; : If we could nd a feasible strategy-proof mechanism M for which U ( ; ) U ( ; ) = max f ; g ; 8 ; ; then M would be the optimal mechanism. However, this is impossible the classical result by Green and La ont (977) shows. On the other hand, for every ( ~ ; ~ ), it is easy to nd 5

6 a feasible strategy-proof mechanism M ( ~ ; ~ ) for which U ( ~ ; ~ ) U ( ~ ; ~ n ) = max ~ ; ~ o ; (just the trivial mechanism that always give the good to the agent with the higher ~ i ). Hence, we cannot nd a rst-best mechanism that (weakly) dominates all others at all type pro les. As a result, a meaningful criterion of optimality should be based on some average measurement. Throughout the paper, we assume that agents types are distributed symmetrically according to a nonatomic distribution function F with density f. Let F denote the class of all feasible strategy-proof mechanisms. For each M F, the total utilities of M is given by: T U(M) = ( x ( ; ) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; ))df ( ) df ( ) : Our goal is to characterize the mechanisms M F that yield the highest ex ante total utilities, that is, T U(M ) = max MF T U(M): To convey the intuition of our main theorems, let us calculate T U(M) for some wellknown mechanisms under uniform distribution. First, the canonical pivotal mechanism (or the second price auction mechanism) M SP has the total utility T U(M SP ) = 3, which is not very high. It is not even the best one among all V-C-G mechanisms. In a separate paper we nd the best V-C-G mechanism M BV CG with T U(M BV CG ) = 7 (Shao and hou, 7). Hagerty and Rogerson (987) consider xed price mechanisms: assuming that agent one is the seller and agent two the buyer, a trade will take place at some xed price p if and only both the seller and the buyer agree. Formally, the xed price mechanism with price p is de ned as follows (see Figure ): 8 >< >: x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = p; x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = p; when p and p; and 8 >< >: x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = ; x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = ; otherwise. 6

7 Figure Among all xed price mechanism, the mechanism with the price p = yields the highest total utility T U(M F ) = 5 8. (The same holds for the xed price mechanism in which agent two is the designated seller.) In this paper we also consider another mechanism, called the option mechanism, which is related to, but di erent from, the xed price mechanism. It gives the good to agent conditionally and, at the same time, issues a call option to agent that allows him to buy the good from agent one at a xed exercise price of p. Obviously, agent will exercise the option if and only if > p. Formally, it is de ned as follows (see Figure ): 8 >< >: x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = p; x ( ) = ; t ( ; ) = p; when p; and 8 >< >: x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = ; x ( ; ) = ; t ( ; ) = ; otherwise Among all option mechanisms, the mechanism with the option price p = yields the highest total utility T U(M O ) = 5 8. (The same holds for the option mechanism in which agent two is the conditional owner of the good and agent one is awarded the option.) It is interesting that the best xed price mechanism and the best option mechanism yield 7

8 Figure the same level of total utilities. These two mechanisms di er only in the region and where both agents types are greater than or equal to. The xed price mechanism favors agent by giving the whole region to agent, whereas the option mechanism favors agent. The total utilities are the same since agents types are distributed symmetrically. Our main ndings consists of two theorems. The rst theorem con rms that the aforementioned two types of budget-balance mechanisms x price mechanisms and option mechanisms are indeed the optimal mechanisms among all deterministic ones under a class of well-behaved distribution functions. By allowing stochastic mechanisms, the second theorem shows that both the xed price mechanisms and the option mechanisms are optimal when agents types distributed uniformly. Furthermore, all optimal mechanisms are convex combinations of these four mechanisms. Optimal Mechanisms under General Distributions As shown numerically by Example 4 of Miller (), under some distribution functions the optimal mechanisms could display both allocation ine ciency and money burning which is a compromise of both V-C-G mechanisms and budget-balance mechanisms. This implies that in general it is very di cult to solve for the optimal mechanisms analytically under arbitrary distributions. Hence, we restrict our attention to characterizing the optimal mechanisms 8

9 under a class of well-behaved distribution functions of agents types. In particular, we restrict the solution set to all the deterministic feasible mechanisms without withholding by the designer. Precisely, we requires that x ( ; ) ; x ( ; ) f; g and x ( ; ) x ( ; ) =. We rst derive some lemmas to help to prove the rst theorem. In fact, unlike the rst theorem, these lemmas also hold when stochastic mechanisms allowed. We begin with the structure of a generic mechanism M F. First, since M is strategyproof, x ( ; ) is non-decreasing in and x ( ; ) is non-decreasing in. For every pair of such x ( ; ) and x ( ; ), we can nd a continuum of pairs of t ( ; ) and t ( ; ) such that these four functions de ne a feasible strategy-proof mechanism. The canonical transfers are the generalized pivotal-taxes: t p ( ; ) = x ( ; ) t p ( ; ) = x ( ; ) x (; )d; and x ( ; )d: By de nition, the pivotal-taxes are non-positive so that they de ne a feasible mechanism. However, they represent out ows of money from agents so the resulting mechanism is not e cient. To improve the e ciency of the mechanism, we consider redistribution of the pivotal transfers between two agents while keeping the incentive property of the mechanism intact. To achieve this goal, we add some function of only h ( ) to t p ( ; ) and some function of only h ( ) to t p ( ; ): t ( ; ) = x ( ; ) t ( ; ) = x ( ; ) x (; )d h ( ) ; and x ( ; )d h ( ) : Obviously, the new mechanism is still strategy-proof. In fact, this is actually the only way to maintain the incentives. We may consider these functions h ( ) and h ( ) as rebates to the agents h ( ) is the amount of money agent receives when agent s type is and h ( ) is the amount of money agent receives when agent s type is. The total amounts of money that can be redistributed between the agents are limited from above by 9

10 the feasibility condition: (F) h ( ) h ( ) x ( ; ) x (; )d x ( ; )d: Based on the above discussion, the optimal mechanism problem can be written as the following programming problem: T U (M) = subject to max fx i ;t i ji=;g x ( ; ) x ( ; )t ( ; )t ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) : () () (F) h ( ) = x ( ; ) h ( ) = x ( ; ) x (; ) d t ( ; ) x ( ; ) d t ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; ) (a:e:) x ( ; ) is weakly increasing in x ( ; ) is weakly increasing in : (a:e:) (a:e:) A mechanism M is feasible if it satis es all the constraints above. To avoid unnecessary repetitions, we will drop the quali er (a.e.) from the proof whenever we invoke the (), () and (F) 3. Since x ( ; ) t ( ; ) = R x (a; )da h ( ), we have = = = ( x ( ; ) t ( ; ))df ( ) df ( ) x (; )d df ( ) df ( ) x (; )df ( ) ddf ( ) ( F ())x (; )ddf ( ) h ( )df ( ) h ( )df ( ) h ( )df ( ) 3 The proof remains valid if we have to be more rigorous. At some steps we need to use the Fubini theorem to justify our argument.

11 = F ( ) x ( ; )df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) Thus, we can rewrite the objective function T U (M) as T U (M) = h ( ) df ( ) F ( ) f ( ) h ( )df ( ) : x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) h ( ) df ( ) : Claim: x ( ; ) R x (; ) d is increasing in ; and x ( ; ) R x ( ; ) d is increasing in. To see this, x, assume <, x ; = = x ; x ; x ( ; ) d x ( ; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d x ; x ( ; ) d (x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d x ( ; ) d The last step holds because x ( ; ) is increasing in : Hence, t ( ; ) is decreasing. R Similarly, x ( ; ) x (; ) d is increasing in and t ( ; ) is decreasing in. Lemma Given any M ~ F, there exists a symmetric M = fx i ( ; ) ; h i () ji = ; g F with T U ~M = T U (M), such that x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) ; t ( ; ) = t ( ; ) and h () = h (). The idea of this lemma is that the two agents are ex-ante the same. If any optimal mechanism is in favor of one of the two agents, there must exist another optimal mechanism which is in favor of the other agent. Then, based on these two mechanisms, one can derive a "fair" mechanism which treat them equally. Hence, given a arbitrary mechanism, one can always nd a symmetric mechanism which is feasible and yields the same total utility as the given one. Technically, such symmetric mechanisms have more structure and therefore

12 easy to work with. Without loss of generality, we only need to focus on such symmetric mechanisms to nd the optimal mechanisms. Proof: Given ~ M = Obviously, the mechanism utility. Now, let n ~x ( ; ) ; ~x ( ; ) ; h ~ ( ) ; h ~ o ( ), if it is not symmetric, let ~x ( ; ) = ~x ( ; ) ; ~x ( ; ) = ~x ( ; ) and ~h () = ~ h () ; ~ h () = ~ h () : n ~x ( ; ) ; ~x ( ; ) ; h ~ ( ) ; h ~ o ( ) gives the same total x ( ; ) = ~x ( ; ) ~x ( ; ) x ( ; ) = ~x ( ; ) ~x ( ; ) h () = h ~ () h ~ () h () = h ~ () h ~ () : It is immediate to see that the mechanism fx ( ; ) ; x ( ; ) ; h ( ) ; h ( )g is symmetric and also yields the same total utility. We only need to verify it is feasible. By letting t ( ; ) = ~ t ( ; ) ~ t ( ; ) and t ( ; ) = ~ t ( ; ) ~ t ( ; ), it is straightforward to verify the feasibility. Q.E.D. Note that under the symmetric mechanism along the diagonal = of the type space, x (; ) = x (; ) = and h () = R x (; ) d t (; ). Furthermore, t (; ). When <, t ( ; ). Otherwise, t ( ; ) >, x and decrease, since t ( ; ) is decreasing in we have t ( ; ) > contradiction. Similarly, h () = R x (; ) d t (; ), t (; ) and t ( ; ) when >. Due to x ( ; ) is weakly increasing in and x (; ) =, x ( ; ) when <. Similarly, x ( ; ) when >. Lemma If A () is decreasing, R b R b a a A ( ) x ( ; )A ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) is maximized by letting x ( ; ) and x ( ; ) be constant with x ( ; )x ( ; ) =. Proof: Since x ( ; ) is increasing in and A ( ) is decreasing in, x, by

13 Chebyshev inequality 4, b a Similarly, b a A ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) A ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) Hence, F (b) F (b) F (a) F (a) b a b a A ( ) df ( ) A ( ) df ( ) b a b a x ( ; ) df ( ) : x ( ; ) df ( ) : b b a a F (b) F (a) A ( ) x ( ; ) A ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) b F (b) F (a) = F (b) F (a) = (F (b) F (a)) a b a b a b a A ( ) df ( ) A ( ) df ( ) A ( ) df ( ) A ( ) df ( ). b b a a b b a a b b a a x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) x ( ; ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) It is easy to verify that any constant x and x with x x = can yield the derived upper bound. Q.E.D. REMARK: This lemma indicates that how to allocate the indivisible good with agents types belong to any block along the diagonal doesn t change the overall welfare as long as the probability remain constant within such blocks. Later, when dealing with symmetric mechanisms, we only need to set x = x = for such blocks. REMARK: The above lemmas hold for not just deterministic mechanisms but also stochastic ones. Theorem If ( F ) =f is decreasing and F=f is increasing, the optimal deterministic mechanisms must be x price mechanisms or option mechanisms with p = where = E (). 4 The conditions required by Chebyshev inequality can be further relaxed by using Ste ensen inequality (see also Shao ) 3

14 To prove this theorem: ) we restrict the solution set to these symmetric mechanisms corresponding to all deterministic mechanisms; ) we show that there is a unique optimal mechanism among the symmetric mechanisms; 3) we then derive the corresponding deterministic mechanisms which are optimal among all deterministic mechanisms automatically. Proof: Since M is strategy-proof, x ( ; ) is (weakly) increasing in and x ( ; ) is (weakly) increasing in. As we de ne ' ( ) = inf fbjx (b; ) = g ; and ' ( ) = inf fajx ( ; a) = g ; both ' ( ) and ' ( ) are (weakly) increasing functions from [; ] to [; ]. Since they are increasing, they are almost continuous everywhere on [; ]. They are virtually inverse functions to each other since = ' ( ) if and only if = ' ( ) at every pro le ( ; ) where both ' ( ) and ' ( ) are continuous. For simplicity, WLOG, we denote ' () as ' () and denote ' () as ' (). That is x ( ; ) = if ' ( ) and x ( ; ) = if < ' ( ). When we plot the graphs of these two functions on the unit square [; ] [; ], they separate the region in which agent gets the good from the region in which agent gets the good (see Figure 3). STEP : By the rst lemma, given any deterministic mechanism, there exists a symmetric mechanism which provides the same total utility. The corresponding symmetric allocation rule has x i ; ;. Moreover, x i = happens only within the area bounded by ' ( ) and ' ( ) as illustrated in the Figure 3. Next, we show that each corresponding symmetric mechanism is dominated by a unique symmetric mechanism meanwhile it is budget-balance. STEP : Denote ; as the point where h i achieves the maximum value. Also h () = R x (; ) d t (; ) together with t i (; ) imply that. By () and (); h ( ) h = x ; x ; x (; ) d x ( ; ) d t ; t ; 4

15 Figure 3 and h ( ) h = x ( ; ) x ; Due to (F), we have x (; ) d x ; d t ; t ; : h ( ) x ; x ; x ; d x ( ; ) d and h ( ) x ; x ; x (; ) d x ; d : As shown in Figure 3, ' (a) =. When i a, we know that, x ( ; ) = over 5

16 [; a] ; and x ( ; ) = over ; [; a]. Hence, h ( ) x ; x ; x x ( ; ) d for [; a] ; d x ( ; ) d and h ( ) For [a; ] and =, x ( ; ) =. Hence, x (; ) d for [; a] : h ( ) = x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d t ( ; ) x ( ; ) d for [a; ] : Similarly, h ( ) x (; ) d for [a; ] : To derive the symmetric optimal mechanism, we derive an upper bound for the symmetric M F. Then show that such upper bound can be achieved by a unique feasible symmetric mechanism. The upper bound is derived by dividing the objective functions into two parts and deriving the upper bound of each parts respectively. S-I: We derive the upper bound for the rst part of the objective function below: F ( ) f ( ) h ( ) df ( ) F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) h ( ) df ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) 6

17 = F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) df ( ) The inequality is due to above disscussion. obtained when x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) = over [; ] [; ]. Due to Lemma, the maximum value is Notice that the allocation rule we determined depends on the value of x i over [; a] ; and ; [; a]. It is possible that to maximize the upper bound of the remaining part of the objective function, such values may need to be changed which makes the above argument invalid. However, in the following, we rule out such possibility. Hence, the validity of the above argument guaranteed. S-II: We determine the upper bound for the remaining part of the objective function: F ( ) f ( ) F ( ) f ( ) F ( ) f ( ) h ( ) df ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) By symmetry, h i should also satisfy: h ( ) df ( ) : h () = h () = x (; ) d t (; ) x (; ) d t (; ) : Let g ( ) = g ( ) = x ( ; ) d x (; ) d: n o n o Hence, h ( ) min g ( ) ; and h ( ) min g ( ) ; for i [ ; ]. This 7

18 yields an upper bound for the above remaining term, F ( ) f ( ) F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) F ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) f ( ) min g ( ) ; df ( ) min g ( ) ; df ( ). Before we choose x i to maximize the upper bound. We rst compare the upper bounds using either g i () or alone. If g ( ) ; g ( ) >, the upper bound becomes (T) (T) (T3) F ( ) f ( ) F ( ) f ( ) F ( ) f ( ) df ( ). x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) Given Lemma, term (T3) is maximized at x i =. x i = too. To see it, over area [ ; ] [; ], >, F ( ) f( ) < F ( ) f( ) And term (T) is maximized by F ( ) f( ) is decreasing, then. To maximize this term, we should let x be as large as possible. But from previous discussion we also know that within the area > the largest value can be assigned to x is. Similar argument can also be applied to term (T). To sum up, if g ( ) ; g ( ) >, the upper bound is maximized by having x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) =. If g ( ) ; g ( ) <, the upper bound becomes 8

19 F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) F ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) f ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) F ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) f ( ) F ( ) x ( ; ) F ( ) f ( ) f ( ) x ( ; ) df ( ) df ( ) df ( ). It is maximized by having x = if > and x = if > : Compare the above two upper bounds using either g i () or alone; x, when >, using g ( ) and as an upper bound requires to assign x i with di erent values. Meanwhile, the the choice of x i ( ; ) also a ects the choice of g ( ) and as minimum value used. If x ( ; ) = for <, g ( ) = R o x ( ; ) d is less than. Then, ng can not be used as min ( ) ;. If x ( ; ) = for <, g ( ) is greater than. Then g ( ) cannot be used as g ( ). o WLOG, we start with the upper bound using ng as min ( ) ;. Fix, that means we need to increase the value of x ( ; ) = to for some when > to prevent g ( ) <. To do that, one can only increase x ( ; ) to from the smallest due to monotonicity and up to the point ( ; ) ; otherwise g ( ) becomes greater than which means increasing x ( ; ) = to will decrease the the value of the upper bound. As a result the upper bound is maximized by having x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) = over [ ; ][ ; ], x ( ; ) = over [; ][ ; ] and x ( ; ) = over [ ; ][; ]. To put the two parts of the maximized value of the upper bound together, we have F ( ) F ( ) d ( F ( )) where = E (). Now, we optimize the upper bound over. Take derivative of we have f ( ) ( F ( )) ( F ( )) f ( ) = 9

20 It is easy to see that the upper bound is optimized when =. Moreover, such upper bound is obtainable by using allocation rule: x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) (; ) (; ) [ (; ) (; ), x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) [ ; ] [; ] and x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) [; ] [ ; ]. STEP 3: The corresponding deterministic allocation rule is x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) [ ; ] [; ] and x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) [; ] [ ; ] and either x or x equals to over (; ) (; ) [ (; ) (; ). Depends on the value of x i chosen over (; ) (; ) [ (; ) (; ), the mechanisms are corresponding to the two x price mechanisms and two option mechanisms. Q.E.D.. Optimal Mechanisms when Stochastic Mechanisms Allowed Next, we further enlarge admissible mechanisms by allowing stochastic mechanisms as well as withholding by the designer. The stochastic mechanisms allows the designer to allocate the good with certain probability at some pro les ( ; ). Intuitively, withholding the good by not giving out to any agent at some realized pro les ( ; ) may hurt the total utility. However, by doing so, the bene t from improved incentives may be able to compensate the loss. As shown in Theorem, we fully characterize the structure of all optimal mechanisms with fx i ( ; ) ; i = ; jx () x () and x i () [; ]g. As a trade-o, we cannot do that under a class of distributions as in Theorem. Hence, we only restrict to uniform distribution. The fundamental di culty remains the same as in Theorem. But the speci c property of uniform distribution allows us to say more in this situation. Theorem If agents types are distributed uniformly, every optimal mechanism is a convex combination of the two xed-price mechanisms and the two option mechanisms with p = =. Proof We will divide the proof into two parts. In Part I we show max MF T U(M) = 5 8. In Part II we demonstrate that any mechanism that satis es T U(M) = 5 8 must be a convex combination of the four mechanisms. Part I First us estimate the upper-bound of T U (M) = ( x ( ; ) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; ))d d :

21 That is T U(M) = = = = ( x ( ; ) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; ))d d (( )x ( ; ) ( )x ( ; )) d d h ( )d h ( )d (x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d d ( x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d d (x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d d h ( )d h ( )d h ( )d h ( )d ( x ( ; ) x ( ; ) t ( ; ) t ( ; )) d d (x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d d h ( )d T U(M): h ( )d Hence, (E) T U(M) (x ( ; ) x ( ; )) d h ( )d h ( )d A : The equation holds in (E) if and only if R R (t ( ; ) t ( ; )) d d =. The next Lemma gives us an estimate of the second term on the right hand side of (E): Lemma 3 Let A be the area in that is below the minor diagonal = : h ( ) d h ( ) d 3 4 A (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d : Proof of Lemma 3: Let us consider the feasibility inequality on the minor diagonal

22 = ; and = : h ()h ( ) x (; ) x (; ) d( ) x (; ) x (; ) d: We integrate the above inequality over [; ], = h () d x (; )d h ( ) d ( )x (; )d x (; (x (; ) ( )x (; )) d x (; ) dd ) dd x (; ) dd x (; ) dd: The rst term is easy to estimate: Since we have max fx (; ) ( )x (; )g = x x ( ; ; ; (x (; ) ( )x (; )) d ( )d d = 3 4 : Through the change of variables, we can express the double integrals in the second and the third term as integrals over the area A, = = A x (; ) dd ~ x ; ~ dd ~ (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d : x (; ) dd x (; ) dd

23 Putting these two inequalities together, we prove the lemma. Finally, we can apply the lemma to (E) to obtain the desired estimate T U(M) = [;][;]na 3 8 = 5 8 : (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d! (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d h ( )d A h ( )d (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d Since T U(M) = 5 8 for both the xed price mechanisms and the option mechanisms, these mechanisms are all optimal. Part II We now show that any mechanism that satis es T U(M) = 5 8 must be a convex combination of the xed price mechanisms and the option mechanisms. We can see from the proof above that any mechanism M satis es T U(M) = 5 8 must also satisfy (B) (B) h ( ) h ( ) = x ( ; ) R x (; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) x ( ; ) = on [; ] [; ]na: R x ( ; ) d; We now divide [; ] [; ] into four small squares of equal size and study M on each of them separately. Part II- Consider rst the upper-left square (; ] ( ; ]. On this area, agent s type is always higher than agent s type. It is intuitive that the good should and could be given to agent, i.e., x ( ; ) = on ; ;. Let us present a formal proof. We begin with the upper half of ; ; and prove x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) with < and > : Suppose, on the contrary, x ( ; ) with > for some ( ; ) with < and >. Since x ( ; ) is non-decreasing in and x ( ; ) is non-increasing in 3

24 Figure 4 (since x ( ; ) = x ( ; ) on this region), we must have x ( ; ) for all ( ; ) with and (see Figure 4): In particular, this inequality holds on the minor diagonal = ; and =. Repeating a part of the proof of Lemma 3, we have when = h () d x (; )d h ( ) d x (; ) dd x (; ) dd (x (; ) ( )x (; )) d (x (; ) ( )x (; )) d A ( )x (; )d (x (; ) ( )x (; )) d (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d 4

25 < 3 4 A ( )d ( ( )( )) d (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d (x ( ; ) x ( ; ))d d : A When we plug this into the estimation of T U(M), we have d T U(M) < 5 8 : This contradicts the assumption that M is optimal. Thus x ( ; ) = for ( ; ) with < and > : Now we show that x ( ; ) = also holds for the other half of [; ] ( ; ] in which > and. First, for any > >, we can nd some with < and >. Then h ( ) h ( ) = x ( ; ) d and h h ( ) = Taking the di erence of the two, we have x ( ; ) d: h h ( ) = x ( ; ) d = : Hence, h ( ) is a constant h on ;. A similar argument also shows that h ( ) is a constant h on ;. Consider any ( ; ) with > and. Since x is zero to the right of the diagonal, x is also zero on this area for x is non-increasing in. Hence h ( ) h ( ) = x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d: 5

26 Choosing any >, we have h h ( ) = x ( ; ) d: Subtracting one from the other yields x ( ; ) = x ( ; )d x ( ; )d = x ( ; )d : This shows x ( ; ) =. Hence, (II-) x ( ; ) = on ; ; : Part II- When we work with the lower-right square ; ;, we can show that h ( ) is a constant h on ; and that h ( ) is a constant h on ;, and (II-) x ( ; ) = on ; ; : Part II-3 Now consider the upper-right square ; ;. (B) implies h h = x ( ; ) x (; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d: Since x (; ) = for <, and x ( ; ) = for <, h h = x ( ; ) x (; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d: If we let both! and!, we obtain h h =. Now plug it back into the equation above, = x ( ; ) x (; ) d x (; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d = x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d; or x ( ; ): 6

27 Since x ( ; ) is non-decreasing in and x ( ; ) is non-decreasing in, the equation above implies x (; ) = x ( ; ); for all ; ; and x ( ; ) = x ( ; ); for all ; : It is easy to verify that this holds for all ( ; ) ; ; if and only if there are two constants c and c with c c = such that (II-3) x ( ; ) = c and x ( ; ) = c on ; ; : Part II-4 Lastly, we consider the lower-left square ; ;. We know h h = x ( ; ) x (; ) d x ( ; ) x ( ; ) d: When let both! and!, we obtain h h =. Hence, x ( ; ) x ( ; ) = x (; ) d x ( ; ) d: So we can conclude that there are two constants d and d such that (II-4) x ( ; ) = d and x ( ; ) = d on ; ; : To nd out more about d and d, we put together we have shown about h s and x s. First, on the upper-left square, we have h h = x ( ; ) Similarly, on the lower-right square x ( ; ) d = d d = ( d ) : h h = ( d ) : 7

28 Figure 5 On the other hand, we already know h h = and h h = : These four equations together lead to d d =. Hence, any optimal mechanism can be characterized by two parameters c [; ] and d [; ] with the allocation probabilities given by the table in Figure 5: There are four di erent combinations of extreme values of c and d: (i) c = and d = : this corresponds to the xed price mechanism M in which agent two is the seller; (ii) c = and d = : this corresponds to the xed price mechanism M in which agent one is the seller; (iii) c = and d = : this corresponds to the option mechanism M in which agent one is given the good and agent two is given the option; and (iv) c = and d = : this corresponds to the option mechanism M in which agent two is given the good and agent one is given the option. 8

29 Any other optimal mechanism M is just a convex combination of these four mechanisms: M = c M (d c) M ( c d) M ; for c d; or M = d M (c d) M ( c d) M ; for c > d: This provides the characterization optimal mechanisms among all feasible strategy-proof mechanisms. Q.E.D. 3 Discussions Before closing, we discuss more about our result in comparison with other known results in the literature and explore some possible extensions of our result for future research. Every feasible strategy-proof mechanism consists of two parts: the rst part is the rule of assigning the good to the agents, and the second part transfers that are necessary to force the agents to report their types truthfully. The loss of e ciency may come from both sources: either the good is not assigned to the agent with the higher valuation, or the total transfer leads to a money out ow. A very natural and important question is: What is the optimal trade-o between these two types of ine ciency? However, this issue has never been addressed formally by others in the previous literature. Most papers in the literature either focus on V-C-G mechanisms or on trading mechanisms in which money changes hands between two agents. These two classes of mechanisms are mutually exclusive by de nition: all V-C-G mechanisms are immune from the rst type of ine ciency, and most trading mechanisms including the xed-price mechanisms are immune from the second type of ine ciency. Hence, it is impossible to discuss the potential trade-o within between the two types of ine ciency in either model. In order to address this issue, we must adopt a more general setting that includes both V-C-G mechanisms and trading mechanisms as subclasses of admissible mechanisms. We have done it successfully in this paper. The nding is somewhat surprising: although it might be expected that an optimal mechanism entails a compromise of both types of ine ciency, our result indicates the second type of ine ciency seems more damaging. Furthermore, it must be completely absent at any optimal mechanism for a class of well-behaved environments. Our model also di ers from the model of Hagerty and Rogerson, and other models in bilateral bargaining, in another dimension for we do not impose individual rationality on mechanisms under consideration in our model. Since this enlarges the class of admissible 9

30 mechanisms, this makes our result even stronger. In addition, we are able to discover the two optimal option mechanisms, which have never been studied before largely because they do not satisfy individual rationality when one agent the designated seller and the other agent the designated buyer 5. In many allocation problems where neither agent originally owns the good, such as the o ce assignment problem, the option mechanisms are better alternatives than the xed-price mechanisms as they are more equitable ex ante. advantage is not huge as it disappears once lotteries are admissible. This Once we break away from the bilateral bargaining model, it is then natural to consider a model in which an indivisible good (or even multiple units of the good) are allocated among more than two agents. We still do not have any formal results in such a model yet. Admittedly, it will be quite di cult to obtain a complete characterization of all optimal mechanisms. However, it is reasonable to believe that we can still derive some partial results. While we are unsure how to extend the xed-price mechanism, we have found a generalization of the option mechanism. We assign the good to an agent, say agent one, conditionally and direct him to run a second-price auction of the good with the other n agents with a reservation price. This mechanism always balances the budget since money just changes hands from one agent to another. It should also be reasonably e cient, depending on the value of. The best value of can be found by maximizing the sum of the expected utilities of all agents (the transfers are absent since the budget is always balanced): = arg n yd(y n ) A : Hence, =. Note that this optimal reservation value is the same as that in Myerson s mechanism in which the expected revenue of the seller is maximized. It would be remarkable that the maximum e ciency in allocating an indivisible good among n agents can be achieved when we give the good to one of the agents and direct him to conduct a revenue maximizing auction with the other n agents as buyers. Of course, this is just a conjecture at this point, and further research is needed to yield a formal answer. Finally, we return to an issue we already mentioned when we set up the basic model. Although we have derived the optimal mechanisms under a class of distributions, one may still ask what will happen to our main nding if di erent distributions are used. Although 5 Nevertheless, that the option mechanisms do satisfy the weak individual rationality condition that no agent has negative utility at any pro le. 3

31 it is clear that optimal mechanisms will change, we have not been able to derive a full characterization of all optimal mechanisms for a general distribution function of agents types. The distributions used in Theorem are only su cient to guarantee the budget balance mechanisms are optimal. In a separate paper (Shao and hou, 8), we undertake a more modest task. Instead of including all feasible strategy-proof mechanisms, we consider only the V-C-G mechanisms and the xed-price mechanisms (or the option mechanisms), two classes of mechanisms that are most prominent in the literature. Assuming that the distributions of agents types are independent and symmetric, we manage to nd separately the best mechanism among all V-C-G mechanisms and the best mechanism among all xed-priced mechanisms. Then we compare these two mechanisms to see which one is better. For some distributions, the best V-C-G mechanism actually outperforms the best xed-price mechanism. However, in two important cases when the distribution function of types is either concave or convex, we show that the best xed-price mechanism beats the best V-C-G mechanism. We should point out that the model of quasi-linear preferences with a general distribution of types is mathematically equivalent to the model of more general preferences with a uniform distribution of types. Copic and Ponsati (8) have reported some results for the latter model in the bilateral trade framework. While their work has made some progresses in dealing with non-linearity of preferences, it still shares the similar weakness that Hagerty and Rogerson s work exhibits. For instance, it assumes budget-balanced-ness so it excludes the V-C-G mechanisms as well as many other potentially mechanisms from consideration. Hence, it cannot even compare the e ciency of the xed-priced mechanisms and the V-C-G mechanisms. This being said, their work is already a rather complicated mathematical exercise. We certainly cannot underestimate the di culty we shall face when we try to nd optimal feasible strategy-proof mechanisms when we assume a much more general distribution of agents types. References [] S. Athey and D. Miller. E ciency in repeated trade with hidden valuations. Theoretical Economics (3), (7). [] D. Bergemann and S. Morris. Robust Mechanism Design. Econometrica 73(6), (5). 3

32 [3] K.-S. CHUNG and J. C. ELY. Foundations of Dominant-Strategy Mechanisms. Review of Economic Studies 74(), (Apr. 7). [4] E. H. Clarke. Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice (), 7 33 (Sept. 97). [5] C. D Aspremont. Incentives and incomplete information. Journal of Public Economics (), 5 45 (Feb. 979). [6] J. Green and J. Laffont. Characterization of satisfactory mechanisms for the revelation of preferences for public goods. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society pp (977). [7] T. Groves. Incentives in Teams. Econometrica 4(4), (July 973). [8] K. Hagerty. Robust trading mechanisms. Journal of Economic Theory 4(), 94 7 (June 987). [9] J. C. Harsanyi. Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics, and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility. The Journal of Political Economy 63(4), 39 3 (Aug. 955). [] P. Jehiel, M. Meyer-ter Vehn, B. Moldovanu, and W. R. ame. The Limits of ex post Implementation. Econometrica 74(3), (May 6). [] D. Miller. Robust Collusion with Private Information. The Review of Economic Studies pp. 34 (Sept. ). [] R. B. Myerson. Optimal Auction Design. Mathematics of Operations Research 6(), (Feb. 98). [3] R. B. Myerson and M. Satterthwaite. E cient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory 9(), 65 8 (Apr. 983). [4] C. Ponsat and J. Copic. Ex post Constrained E cient Bilateral Trade with Risk Averse Traders. Working Paper, (8). [5] R. Shao. Generalized Coarse Matching. Working Paper,(). [6] R. Shao and L. hou. Comparison between Groves Mechanisms and Fixed-Price Mechanisms. Working Paper,(7). 3

33 [7] W. Vickrey. Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders. The Journal of Finance 6(), 8 37 (Mar. 96). 33

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1846 EFFICIENT AUCTIONS AND INTERDEPENDENT TYPES Dirk Bergemann, Stephen Morris, and Satoru Takahashi

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

Redistribution Mechanisms for Assignment of Heterogeneous Objects

Redistribution Mechanisms for Assignment of Heterogeneous Objects Redistribution Mechanisms for Assignment of Heterogeneous Objects Sujit Gujar Dept of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India sujit@csa.iisc.ernet.in Y Narahari Dept

More information

Game Theory: Spring 2017

Game Theory: Spring 2017 Game Theory: Spring 2017 Ulle Endriss Institute for Logic, Language and Computation University of Amsterdam Ulle Endriss 1 Plan for Today In this second lecture on mechanism design we are going to generalise

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility May 30, 2013 Setup X : finite set of public alternatives X = {x 1,..., x K } Θ i : the set of possible types for player i, F i is the marginal distribution of θ i. We assume types are independently distributed.

More information

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 John Nachbar Washington University May 2, 2017 The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1 1 Introduction. The Revenue Equivalence Theorem gives conditions under which some very different auctions generate the same

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen Strategic Form Games In this part we will analyze games in which the players choose their actions simultaneously (or without the knowledge of other players

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 The Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Note: This is a only a

More information

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts Advanced Microeconomic Theory: Economics 521b Spring 2011 Juuso Välimäki Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts The setup is similar to that of a Bayesian game. The ingredients are: 1. Set of players, i {1,

More information

CPS 173 Mechanism design. Vincent Conitzer

CPS 173 Mechanism design. Vincent Conitzer CPS 173 Mechanism design Vincent Conitzer conitzer@cs.duke.edu edu Mechanism design: setting The center has a set of outcomes O that she can choose from Allocations of tasks/resources, joint plans, Each

More information

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems CSCI699: Topics in Learning and Game Theory Lecture 4 Lecturer: Shaddin Dughmi Scribes: Haifeng Xu,Reem Alfayez 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems Example 1: Single Item Auctions. There is a single

More information

Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design

Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design Makis Arsenis National Technical University of Athens April 216 Makis Arsenis (NTUA) AGT April 216 1 / 41 Outline 1 Social Choice Social Choice

More information

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Jonathan Levin 1 Economics 285 Market Design Winter 2009 1 These slides are based on Paul Milgrom s. onathan Levin VCG Mechanisms Winter 2009 1 / 23 Motivation We consider

More information

Constrained-optimal strategy-proof assignment: beyond the Groves mechanisms

Constrained-optimal strategy-proof assignment: beyond the Groves mechanisms Constrained-optimal strategy-proof assignment: beyond the Groves mechanisms Yves Sprumont Département de Sciences Économiques and CIREQ Université de Montréal December 19, 2011 Abstract A single object

More information

Vickrey Auction VCG Characterization. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

Vickrey Auction VCG Characterization. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design Algorithmic Game Theory Vickrey Auction Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Characterization of IC Mechanisms Mechanisms with Money Player preferences are quantifiable. Common currency enables utility transfer

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Tighter Bounds for Facility Games

Tighter Bounds for Facility Games Tighter Bounds for Facility Games Pinyan Lu 1, Yajun Wang 1, and Yuan Zhou 1 Microsoft Research Asia {pinyanl, yajunw}@microsoft.com Carnegie Mellon University yuanzhou@cs.cmu.edu Abstract. In one dimensional

More information

Lecture 10: Mechanism Design

Lecture 10: Mechanism Design Computational Game Theory Spring Semester, 2009/10 Lecture 10: Mechanism Design Lecturer: Yishay Mansour Scribe: Vera Vsevolozhsky, Nadav Wexler 10.1 Mechanisms with money 10.1.1 Introduction As we have

More information

Vickrey Auction. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

Vickrey Auction. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design Algorithmic Game Theory Vickrey Auction Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Mechanisms with Money Player preferences are quantifiable. Common currency enables utility transfer between players. Preference

More information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Alain Delacroix (UQAM) and Etienne Wasmer (Sciences-Po) September 4, 2009 Abstract Wage determination under asymmetric information generates ine ciencies

More information

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation joint work with Stephen Morris August 2009 Barcelona Introduction mechanism design and implementation literatures are theoretical successes mechanisms

More information

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Game Theory Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012 Myerson Optimal Auction Note: This is a only a draft version,

More information

Robust Mechanism Design: An Introduction

Robust Mechanism Design: An Introduction Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics Discussion Paper No. 88 Princeton University Economic Theory Center Working Paper No. 020-20 Robust Mechanism Design: An Introduction Dirk Bergemann

More information

Veto Constraint in Mechanism Design: Ine ciency with Correlated Types

Veto Constraint in Mechanism Design: Ine ciency with Correlated Types Veto Constraint in Mechanism Design: Ine ciency with Correlated Types Olivier Compte and Philippe Jehiel y Revised, November 2006 Abstract We consider bargaining problems in which parties have access to

More information

Mechanism Design: Dominant Strategies

Mechanism Design: Dominant Strategies May 20, 2014 Some Motivation Previously we considered the problem of matching workers with firms We considered some different institutions for tackling the incentive problem arising from asymmetric information

More information

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts Contents 1 Motivating Examples 1 1.1 Instrumental variable estimator....................... 1 1.2 Estimating parameters in monetary policy rules.............. 2 1.3 Estimating

More information

Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers

Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers Huiyi Guo Texas A&M University December 31, 2018 1 / 27 Motivation In practice, some mechanism designers introduce uncertain rules to the mechanisms, e.g., Priceline

More information

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Katharina Huesmann February 13, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the problem of assigning an indivisible good of limited availability

More information

Intro to Economic analysis

Intro to Economic analysis Intro to Economic analysis Alberto Bisin - NYU 1 Rational Choice The central gure of economics theory is the individual decision-maker (DM). The typical example of a DM is the consumer. We shall assume

More information

A Preliminary Introduction to Mechanism Design. Theory

A Preliminary Introduction to Mechanism Design. Theory A Preliminary Introduction to Mechanism Design Theory Hongbin Cai and Xi Weng Department of Applied Economics, Guanghua School of Management Peking University October 2014 Contents 1 Introduction 3 2 A

More information

Property Rights and the E ciency of Bargaining

Property Rights and the E ciency of Bargaining Property Rights and the E ciency of Bargaining Ilya Segal and Michael Whinston y April 7, 2014 1 Introduction Property rights specify an initial default position from which agents may subsequently bargain

More information

On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors

On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors Nicole Immorlica Brendan Lucier Abstract We consider the problem of converting an arbitrary approximation algorithm for a singleparameter social

More information

Graph Theoretic Characterization of Revenue Equivalence

Graph Theoretic Characterization of Revenue Equivalence Graph Theoretic Characterization of University of Twente joint work with Birgit Heydenreich Rudolf Müller Rakesh Vohra Optimization and Capitalism Kantorovich [... ] problems of which I shall speak, relating

More information

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form) A Game in Normal (strategic) Form consists of three components. A set of players. For each player, a set of strategies (called actions in textbook). The interpretation

More information

Motivation. Game Theory 24. Mechanism Design. Setting. Preference relations contain no information about by how much one candidate is preferred.

Motivation. Game Theory 24. Mechanism Design. Setting. Preference relations contain no information about by how much one candidate is preferred. Motivation Game Theory 24. Mechanism Design Preference relations contain no information about by how much one candidate is preferred. Idea: Use money to measure this. Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg

More information

Lecture Notes in Information Economics

Lecture Notes in Information Economics Lecture Notes in Information Economics Juuso Valimaki February, 2014 Abstract These lecture notes are written for a rst-year Ph.D. course in Microeconomic Theory. They are based on teaching material from

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Problem Set 0. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann 4/5/4 This problem set is due on Tuesday, 4//4..

More information

Revenue Maximization in Multi-Object Auctions

Revenue Maximization in Multi-Object Auctions Revenue Maximization in Multi-Object Auctions Benny Moldovanu April 25, 2017 Revenue Maximization in Multi-Object Auctions April 25, 2017 1 / 1 Literature Myerson R. (1981): Optimal Auction Design, Mathematics

More information

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is.

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is. Problem 1: Choice models and assortment optimization Consider a MNL choice model over five products with prices (p1,..., p5) = (7, 6, 4, 3, 2) and preference weights (i.e., MNL parameters) (v1,..., v5)

More information

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model Yu (Larry) Chen School of Economics, Nanjing University Fall 2015 Principal-Agent Relationship Principal-agent relationship

More information

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Joosung Lee Daniel Z. Li University of Edinburgh Durham University January, 2018 1 / 48 A Motivational Example A puzzling observation in mergers and acquisitions

More information

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction. 2. The preliminaries

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 1 pp Introduction. 2. The preliminaries 1. Introduction In this paper we reconsider the problem of axiomatizing scoring rules. Early results on this problem are due to Smith (1973) and Young (1975). They characterized social welfare and social

More information

Mechanism Design. Christoph Schottmüller / 27

Mechanism Design. Christoph Schottmüller / 27 Mechanism Design Christoph Schottmüller 2015-02-25 1 / 27 Outline 1 Bayesian implementation and revelation principle 2 Expected externality mechanism 3 Review questions and exercises 2 / 27 Bayesian implementation

More information

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Lecture Notes on Game Theory Lecture Notes on Game Theory Levent Koçkesen 1 Bayesian Games So far we have assumed that all players had perfect information regarding the elements of a game. These are called games with complete information.

More information

Full Surplus Extraction and Costless Information Revelation in Dynamic Environments. Shunya NODA (University of Tokyo)

Full Surplus Extraction and Costless Information Revelation in Dynamic Environments. Shunya NODA (University of Tokyo) Full Surplus Extraction and Costless Information Revelation in Dynamic Environments Shunya NODA (University of Tokyo) Outline 1. Introduction. Two-Period Example 3. Three-Period Example 4. Model 5. Main

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) April 2001 Abstract

More information

Classic Mechanism Design (III)

Classic Mechanism Design (III) Parkes Mechanism Design 1 Classic Mechanism Design (III) David C. Parkes Division of Engineering and Applied Science, Harvard University CS 286r Spring 2002 Parkes Mechanism Design 2 Vickrey-Clarke-Groves

More information

Discussion Paper #1541

Discussion Paper #1541 CMS-EMS Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics And Management Science Discussion Paper #1541 Common Agency with Informed Principals: Menus and Signals Simone Galperti Northwestern University June

More information

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis 1 Convex sets Both convex sets and functions have general importance in economic theory, not only in optimization. Given two points x; y 2 R n and 2 [0; 1]; the weighted

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

Adding an Apple to an Orange: A General Equilibrium Approach to Aggregation of Beliefs

Adding an Apple to an Orange: A General Equilibrium Approach to Aggregation of Beliefs Adding an Apple to an Orange: A General Equilibrium Approach to Aggregation of Beliefs Yi Jin y, Jianbo Zhang z, Wei Zhou x Department of Economics, The University of Kansas August 2006 Abstract This paper

More information

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB)

Game Theory. Bargaining Theory. ordi Massó. International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB) Game Theory Bargaining Theory J International Doctorate in Economic Analysis (IDEA) Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB) (International Game Theory: Doctorate Bargainingin Theory Economic Analysis (IDEA)

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete

Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete Implementation with Interdependent Valuations Preliminary and Incomplete Richard P. McLean Rutgers University Andrew Postlewaite University of Pennsylvania April 1, 004 1. Introduction There is a large

More information

Northwestern University

Northwestern University Northwestern University 2001 Sheridan Road 580 Leverone Hall Evanston, IL 60208-2014 USA Discussion Paper #1487 March 2010 Common Knowledge of Rationality and Market Clearing in Economies with Asymmetric

More information

Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers

Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers Mechanism Design with Ambiguous Transfers Huiyi Guo Department of Economics, University of Iowa huiyi-guo@uiowa.edu First draft: November 4, 2016 Current draft: September 15, 2017 Abstract This paper introduces

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory Dirk Bergemann and Johannes Hoerner Department of Economics Yale Uniersity Final Exam (Solution) Economics 5b Microeconomic Theory May This is a closed-book exam. The exam lasts for 8 minutes. Please write

More information

Ex-Post Constrained-Efficient Bilateral Trade with Risk-Averse Traders

Ex-Post Constrained-Efficient Bilateral Trade with Risk-Averse Traders Ex-Post Constrained-Efficient Bilateral Trade with Risk-Averse Traders Jernej Čopič and Clara Ponsatí October 2, 2006 Abstract We address robust mechanism design for bilateral trade of an indivisible commodity,

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Dynamic Mechanism Design:

Dynamic Mechanism Design: Dynamic Mechanism Design: Revenue Equivalence, Pro t Maximization, and Information Disclosure Alessandro Pavan, Ilya Segal, Juuso Toikka May 2008 Motivation Mechanism Design: auctions, taxation, etc...

More information

NTU IO (I) : Auction Theory and Mechanism Design II Groves Mechanism and AGV Mechansim. u i (x, t i, θ i ) = V i (x, θ i ) + t i,

NTU IO (I) : Auction Theory and Mechanism Design II Groves Mechanism and AGV Mechansim. u i (x, t i, θ i ) = V i (x, θ i ) + t i, Meng-Yu Liang NTU O : Auction Theory and Mechanism Design Groves Mechanism and AGV Mechansim + 1 players. Types are drawn from independent distribution P i on [θ i, θ i ] with strictly positive and differentiable

More information

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Ilan Guttman, Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz Stanford Graduate School of Business November 2011 1 Introduction

More information

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Volume 30, Issue 3 Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich Abstract The Milgrom-Shannon single crossing property is essential for monotone

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Optimal Search, Learning and Implementation

Optimal Search, Learning and Implementation Optimal Search, Learning and Implementation Alex Gershkov and Benny Moldovanu January 4, 2 Abstract We characterize the incentive compatible, constrained e cient policy ("second-best") in a dynamic matching

More information

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11 Externalities and PG MWG- Chapter 11 Simple Bilateral Externality When external e ects are present, CE are not PO. Assume: 1 Two consumers i = 1, 2 2 The actions of these consumers do not a ect prices

More information

Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information

Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information Zhuozheng Li, Huanxing Yang, and Lan Zhang y JEL Classi cation: D3, D74, D8 Keywords: Cheap talk, Coordination game, Centralization,

More information

Introduction to Mechanism Design

Introduction to Mechanism Design Introduction to Mechanism Design Xianwen Shi University of Toronto Minischool on Variational Problems in Economics September 2014 Introduction to Mechanism Design September 2014 1 / 75 Mechanism Design

More information

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University

Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1561RR ROBUST IMPLEMENTATION IN DIRECT MECHANISMS Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris March 2006 Revised

More information

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) October 2000 An E cient Auction Motty Perry The Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Penn State University and Philip J. Reny Department of Economics University of Chicago (First version: October 1998) October 2000 Abstract

More information

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Daron Acemoglu y Kostas Bimpikis z Asuman Ozdaglar x October 2008. Abstract This paper studies a simple model of experimentation and innovation. Our analysis suggests

More information

Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments

Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments Thierry Marchant and Debasis Mishra July 7, 2014 Abstract We study mechanism design in quasi-linear private values environments when

More information

Comment on The Veil of Public Ignorance

Comment on The Veil of Public Ignorance Comment on The Veil of Public Ignorance Geoffroy de Clippel February 2010 Nehring (2004) proposes an interesting methodology to extend the utilitarian criterion defined under complete information to an

More information

Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good

Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 29/12 Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good Martin Hellwig M A X P L A N C K S O C I E T Y Preprints of

More information

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics

On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics On the level of public good provision in games of redistributive politics Benoit S Y Crutzen and Nicolas Sahuguet y September 20 Abstract This paper studies an electoral competition game between two candidates,

More information

Envy-Freeness and Implementation in Large Economies

Envy-Freeness and Implementation in Large Economies Envy-Freeness and Implementation in Large Economies Matthew O. Jackson y and Ilan Kremer z February 5, 2003 revised August 3, 2005 forthcoming: The Review of Economic Design Abstract We show that an asymptotic

More information

Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments

Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments Mechanism Design with Two Alternatives in Quasi-Linear Environments Thierry Marchant and Debasis Mishra June 25, 2013 Abstract We study mechanism design in quasi-linear private values environments when

More information

Dynamic Markets for Lemons: Performance, Liquidity, and Policy Intervention

Dynamic Markets for Lemons: Performance, Liquidity, and Policy Intervention Dynamic Markets for Lemons: Performance, Liquidity, and Policy Intervention Diego Moreno y John Wooders z August 2013 Abstract We study non-stationary dynamic decentralized markets with adverse selection

More information

Strategy-proof divisible public goods. for quasi-linear preferences.

Strategy-proof divisible public goods. for quasi-linear preferences. Strategy-proof divisible public goods for quasi-linear preferences. Pasha Andreyanov et al. (Preliminary Draft) October 27, 2016 Abstract When agents are risk-neutral and costs are linear, allocating a

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Cooperative game theory Harald Wiese University of Leipzig Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 1 / 45 Part D. Bargaining theory and Pareto optimality 1

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information

Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information Common-Value All-Pay Auctions with Asymmetric Information Ezra Einy, Ori Haimanko, Ram Orzach, Aner Sela July 14, 014 Abstract We study two-player common-value all-pay auctions in which the players have

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions

Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions Matthew O. Jackson September 21, 2005 Forthcoming: Review of Economic Design Abstract A simple example shows that equilibria

More information

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Natalia Lazzati y November 09, 2013 Abstract We study collective choice models from a revealed preference approach given limited

More information

Advanced Economic Theory Lecture 9. Bilateral Asymmetric Information. Double Auction (Chatterjee and Samuelson, 1983).

Advanced Economic Theory Lecture 9. Bilateral Asymmetric Information. Double Auction (Chatterjee and Samuelson, 1983). Leonardo Felli 6 December, 2002 Advanced Economic Theory Lecture 9 Bilateral Asymmetric Information Double Auction (Chatterjee and Samuelson, 1983). Two players, a buyer and a seller: N = {b, s}. The seller

More information

Efficiency and strategy-proofness in object assignment problems with multi-demand preferences

Efficiency and strategy-proofness in object assignment problems with multi-demand preferences Efficiency and strategy-proofness in object assignment problems with multi-demand preferences Tomoya Kazumura and Shigehiro Serizawa February 23, 2016 Abstract We consider the problem of allocating sets

More information

Ordered Value Restriction

Ordered Value Restriction Ordered Value Restriction Salvador Barberà Bernardo Moreno Univ. Autònoma de Barcelona and Univ. de Málaga and centra March 1, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we restrict the pro les of preferences to be

More information

Strategy-Proof and Fair Wages

Strategy-Proof and Fair Wages Strategy-Proof and Fair Wages Svensson, Lars-Gunnar 2004 Link to publication Citation for published version (APA): Svensson, L-G. (2004). Strategy-Proof and Fair Wages. (Working Papers. Department of Economics,

More information

BAYESIAN AND DOMINANT STRATEGY IMPLEMENTATION IN THE INDEPENDENT PRIVATE VALUES MODEL. 1. Introduction

BAYESIAN AND DOMINANT STRATEGY IMPLEMENTATION IN THE INDEPENDENT PRIVATE VALUES MODEL. 1. Introduction BAYESIAN AND DOMINANT STRATEGY IMPLEMENTATION IN THE INDEPENDENT PRIVATE VALUES MODEL ALEJANDRO M. MANELLI AND DANIEL R. VINCENT Abstract. We prove in the standard independent private-values model that

More information

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics.

Puri cation 1. Stephen Morris Princeton University. July Economics. Puri cation 1 Stephen Morris Princeton University July 2006 1 This survey was prepared as an entry for the second edition of the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. In a mixed strategy equilibrium of

More information

Strategy-proof allocation of indivisible goods

Strategy-proof allocation of indivisible goods Soc Choice Welfare (1999) 16: 557±567 Strategy-proof allocation of indivisible goods Lars-Gunnar Svensson Department of Economics, Lund University, P.O. Box 7082, SE-220 07 of Lund, Sweden (e-mail: lars-gunnar.svensson@nek.lu.se)

More information

Taking Turns. Gregory C. Leo. November 15, 2014

Taking Turns. Gregory C. Leo. November 15, 2014 Gregory C. November 5, 204 Two individuals have a regular task to complete that requires the effort of only one. Some days it is less costly for one of the individuals to complete the task, and some days

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information