Inert Consumers in Markets with Switching Costs and Price Discrimination

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Inert Consumers in Markets with Switching Costs and Price Discrimination"

Transcription

1 Inert Consumers in Markets with Switching Costs Price Discrimination Marielle C. Non March 15, 2011 Abstract This paper analyzes an infinite-period oligopoly model where consumers incur costs when switching supplier. Every period only a fraction α of consumers considers switching. Firms can price-discriminate between their current customers consumers who did not buy from the firm in the past period. In this setting, firms set relatively low introductory prices to attract new consumers. Contrary to previous findings in switching costs models, the full price can both increase decrease in switching costs, while the introductory price always decreases. Moreover, the introductory price increases in α while the full price again can both increase decrease. Keywords: switching costs, pricing, price discrimination, inert consumers JEL codes: C73, D43, L13 Contact:University of Groningen, DUI 314, P.O. Box 800, 9700 AV Groningen, The Netherls. M.C.Non@rug.nl. Phone: 0031 (0)

2 1 Introduction There exist quite some consumer markets where switching costs play an important role. Some examples that are often mentioned are telecom, insurance energy. Starting with Klemperer (1987), several researchers have investigated markets with switching costs, see Farrell Klemperer (2007) for an overview. One of the main themes in this previous research is the question whether switching costs will increase prices. There are however other interesting dimensions to switching, that have received less or no attention in previous research. In the current paper three of those elements are included in a switching model. First of all, in many markets with switching costs introductory offers are quite common. This can also be interpreted as price discrimination between current future customers. Most previous research on switching costs however assumes that firms can not discriminate between consumers. In the current paper it is shown that the introduction of introductory offers in a switching costs model has an important effect on the relation between switching costs prices. Second, previous research either assumes that consumers are perfectly rational in their switching behavior, or that consumers are completely inert in the sense that they always stay with their first choice (for a model with inert consumers see e.g Beggs Klemperer (1992) Padilla (1992)). This paper assumes that every period a fraction of consumers considers switching, but that the remaining consumers do not consider switching stay with their old firm. This is in line with observed behavior, see Wieringa Verhoef (2007). The common intuition is that an increase in the fraction of consumers who consider switching will increase competition lead to lower prices. The analysis in this paper shows that in a market with introductory offers this is not necessarily true. Third, most of the previous literature examines duopoly models, mainly because an extension to the oligopoly case is not computationally feasible. The only oligopoly model I am aware of is the one by Dube et al. (2009). The model in this paper also allows a general number of firms, which gives the possibility to examine the effect of an increase in the number of competitors on prices, switching behavior welfare. The model in this paper is an extension of the basic model of Cabral (2009). Cabral proposes a duopoly model with infinitely lived consumers firms. Each firm can price discriminate between consumers who have bought from the firm in the previous period, consumers who have not. Every period consumers assess whether they want to stay with their current firm, or switch to the competitor. Switching however comes at a cost. This model is extended by assuming that each period only a fraction α of the consumers considers switching. The parameter α can be a constant, but could also be a 1

3 function of the expected benefits of switching. Moreover, a general number of firms, n, is allowed. In equilibrium, the possibility of price discrimination indeed leads to introductory pricing. Consumers who return to their current firm pay the full price, while switching consumers pay a reduced price. This result is not very surprising. More interesting is the pricing behavior when the switching costs increase. The introductory price decreases in switching costs, for a relevant part of the parameter space the full price also decreases in switching costs. Although not mentioned by Cabral, this result also holds in the basic model with two firms α = 1. The reason why the introductory price decreases in switching costs is fairly simple. The introductory price is meant to attract switchers, when switching costs increase firms try to offset this by lowering the introductory price. For the full price, there are two effects. On the one h, an increase in the switching costs implies the firm has more monopoly power over its current customers. This should lead to an increase in prices. But on the other h the gap between the introductory full price becomes larger, which induces more consumers to switch. To prevent this, a firm should lower the full price as well. As a result of those two effects the full price can both increase decrease. As a total effect, the gap between the introductory full price always increases in the switching costs. This increase is however less than the increase in switching costs, implying that the net gains from switching decrease. Next to analyzing the effect of switching costs on prices, the model in this paper also allows to analyze the effect of an increase in the number of consumers who consider switching. The common idea is that an increase in the fraction of those consumers will lead to more competition lower prices. This issue is also interesting from a government perspective. In many recently liberalized markets only very few consumers switch supplier often the government sees it as its task to stimulate competition by raising awareness among consumers. The analysis in this paper shows that this might have an opposite effect. When the fraction of consumers who consider switching increases, the introductory prices tend to increase, while the full prices can both increase decrease. The intuition again is not very complicated. When setting the introductory price the firm weighs the price itself against the number of consumers it will attract. This number of consumers decreases in the introductory price, but increases in the fraction of consumers who consider switching. Therefore, when more consumers consider switching, it gets more attractive for firms to increase the introductory price. For the full price, on one h firms want to decrease it to keep aware customers in the firm. On the other h, the increase in the introductory price gives room to increase the full price as well. Firms balance those two effects, as shown by a full price that can both increase decrease. 2

4 The prices seem to increase in the number of firms... TO BE INVESTI- GATED FURTHER. The next section present the model that will be used. Section 3 will analyze the duopoly case of the model, presents some very clear results on the duopoly model. Section 4 will analyze the general oligopoly case. In section 5 an example will be investigated section 6 concludes. 2 Model Consider a market with n heterogenous firms, that each produce a single variety of the product. In the next section I will assume that n = 2. Later, I will generalize to any n 2. The firms have identical constant marginal costs of production, that will be normalized to 0. The firms choose their prices (or their price path) to maximize discounted profits with an infinite time horizon. The discount factor is δ. Firms are able to discriminate between consumers, based on whether the consumer has bought from the firm in the previous period or not. A consumer who has bought from firm j in period t 1, again buys from firm j in period t will have to pay the old consumer s price p oj,t. If the consumer would instead buy from firm k in period t (s)he will pay the new consumer s price p nk,t. Consumers have unit dem. They are infinitely lived buy in every period (alternatively, they have an infinite reservation price). If consumer i buys from firm j (s)he gets utility ɛ ij,t ˆp, where ˆp is either p oj,t or p nj,t, dependent on where the consumer bought in the previous period. ɛ ij,t is an iid rom variable drawn from F (ɛ) describes the match between consumer i firm j in period t. Note that every period ɛ ij,t is redrawn, this draw is independent from the draw in the previous period. When a consumer switches to another firm (s)he incurs switching costs s > 0. Consumers try to maximize their discounted utility, again with discount factor δ. At the same time, however, consumers are boundedly rational. With probability 0 < α < 1 a consumer considers switching to another firm, but with probability 1 α the consumer will not consider switching at all, will stay at his/her current firm. For a consumer who bought at firm j in period t 1 the probability α depends on P j will be denoted by α(p j ). In a duopoly market P j = p oj,t p nk,t s. In an oligopoly market with n firms P j = p oj,t 1 k j n 1 p nk,t s. That is, P j gives the expected first-period gain from switching to another firm. This gain increases in the old price, decreases in the new price switching costs. To ensure that the consumer more often considers switching when the expected gains from switching are higher, assume that α(p j) j = α (P j ) 0. Note that this allows α(p j ) to be a constant between

5 Whenever a consumer considers switching, (s)he compares utilities across firms, taking the switching costs into account. The consumer expects that in future periods (s)he will not switch anymore. Also, the consumer expects that in the future firms are symmetric, so that p oj,t+h = p ok,t+h p nj,t+h = p nk,t+h (which in equilibrium holds true). 3 Duopoly In this section I will analyze the model when there are two firms in the market. I will focus on a symmetric equilibrium. 3.1 Consumer behavior Consider a consumer at the start of period t who bought at firm j in period t 1. It is clear that with probability 1 α(p j ) the consumer does not consider switching will stay at firm j. With probability α(p j ) the consumer considers switching to firm k. In this case the consumer compares the utility of buying at j with the utility of buying at k. The (expected) utility of buying at j is ɛ ij,t p oj,t + E δ h (ɛ ij,t+h p oj,t+h ). h=1 Note that at the start of period t the consumers knows the realization of ɛ ij,t, but does not yet know the realization of ɛ ij,t+h with h 1. Also, the consumer expects that in future periods the old price is p oj,t+h. This could be the equilibrium old price, but this is not necessary as long as the consumer expects the same old price in firms j k. The old price in period t is observed at the start of period t. The (expected) utility of buying at k is ɛ ik,t p nk,t s + E δ h (ɛ ik,t+h p ok,t+h ). h=1 It is assumed that the consumer expects the firms to be symmetric, so expects p oj,t+h = p ok,t+h for h 1. Also, Eɛ ij,t+h = Eɛ ik,t+h. This implies that E h=1 δh (ɛ ij,t+h p oj,t+h ) = E h=1 δh (ɛ ik,t+h p ok,t+h ). Therefore, a consumer will decide to switch if only if ɛ ik,t p nk,t s > ɛ ij,t p oj,t, or ɛ ij,t ɛ ik,t < p oj,t p nk,t s = P j. In the remainder of this section, let G(x) be the CDF of ɛ ij,t ɛ ik,t, with g(x) the corresponding PDF. Then the probability that a consumer who considers switching indeed switches is G(P j ). 4

6 3.2 Pricing decision In each period each firm has to set two prices: p o.,t p n.,t. I will focus on a symmetric equilibrium where prices are constant over time, so p o.,t = p o, p n.,t = p n P = p o p n s. To derive the equilibrium prices, consider the pricing decision of firm j in period t. Let π o denote the (expected) discounted profits a firm can make on a single consumer who bought from the firm in period t 1 let π n denote the (expected) discounted profits a firm can make on a single consumer who did not buy from the firm in period t 1. Then π o = max p oj,t α(p j )G(P j )δπ n + (1 α(p j )G(P j ))(p oj,t + δπ o ) (1) π n = max p nj,t α(p k )G(P k )(p nj,t + δπ o ) + (1 α(p k )G(P k ))δπ n. (2) Note that π o depends only on p oj,t p nk,t π n depends only on p nj,t p ok,t. When setting its old price, firm j therefore only has to consider its old consumers when setting its new price firm j only has to consider its new consumers. Furthermore, the optimal prices do not depend on market share. This is a general feature of duopoly switching costs models with price discrimination, see also... The first-order conditions give the following equilibrium condition. Proposition 3.1 Let Q 1 (x) be defined by Q 1 (x) = (α(x)g(x)) = α(x)g(x)+ α (x)g(x). In any symmetric equilibrium, P is implicitly defined by P Equilibrium prices are given by 1 2α(P )G(P ) = s. (3) p o = (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) + δα(p )G(P ) p n = Equilibrium profits are given by δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ). π n = α(p )2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ) 5

7 π o = δα(p )2 G(P ) 2 + (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) 2. (1 δ) The proof of this proposition is in the Appendix. The first order conditions alone do not guarantee existence or uniqueness of the equilibrium. For this, the following assumption is needed. Assumption A1 with 2Q 1 (x) 1 α(x)g(x) < Q 2(x) Q 1 (x) < 2Q 1(x) α(x)g(x) Q 1 (x) = (α(x)g(x)) = α(x)g(x) + α (x)g(x) Q 2 (x) = (α(x)g(x)) = α (x)g(x) + 2α (x)g(x) + α(x)g (x). When assumption A1 holds, the second-order conditions are satisfied. Moreover, it can be shown that under this assumption (3) has a unique solution. This gives the following Proposition. Proposition 3.2 When A1 holds, the equilibrium defined by proposition 3.1 exists is the unique symmetric equilibrium. Whether assumption A1 holds depends strongly on α(x). Assume for the moment that α(x) is constant. If α(x) = 1, using that g(x) is symmetric around 0, assumption A1 simplifies to g (x) g(x) < 2g(x) G(x). This holds for every log-concave density. If on the other h α(x) = 0 assumption A1 simplifies to 0 < g (x) g(x) < 2g(x) G(x). Since g(x) is symmetric around 0, g (x) g(x) > 0 can never hold for all x in the support. More general, if α(x) is a constant, assumption A1 will hold for large values of α(x), while assumptions A1 will not hold for small values of α(x). Intuitively, this is clear from the profit functions. When only a few fixed number of consumers consider switching, a firm that has to set a price for its current customers wants to focus on the part that is loyal by definition, since those consumers have no maximum willingness to pay, the firm wants to set an infinite price. When α(x) is not constant, this reasoning will not hold anymore. Increasing the price will then lead to an increase in α(p ) a decrease in customers. this will give a moderate price, even when α(p ) is relatively small. It is fairly easy to find combinations of α(x) G(x) for which assumption A1 holds. One example with α(x) logistic will be discussed later. 6

8 3.3 Equilibrium properties In this section we will assume A1 holds. The proof of proposition 3.2 shows that the unique symmetric solution has P > s. Since P = p o p n s, P > s implies p o > p n. This is a quite intuitive result that mirrors the classic bargain-then-ripoff result of the switching literature. Firms compete fiercely for new consumers, trying to persuade them to switch by setting a low introductory price. But once a consumer is in the firm, the firm tries to rip him off by setting a higher price. At the same time, the proof of proposition 3.2 shows that in equilibrium firms make sure that less than 50% of their old customers switch: α(p )G(P ) < 1 2. If α(p ) is high enough, α(p )G(P ) < 1 2 implies that p o p n is bounded above. Even though firms have some power over old consumers, they do not have monopoly power. The higher the price for old consumers, the more those consumers consider switching (α(p ) does not decrease in P ), the more those consumers indeed switch (G(P ) increases in P ). This makes firms cautious not to raise their old price too much lose most of their customer base. Proposition 3.1 gives expressions for p o p n in terms of P. The price for old customers, p o, is always above marginal costs. To see this, note that both the numerator the denominator are strictly positive. The price for new customers can be below marginal costs. Again, the denominator of the expression for p n is always strictly positive, but the numerator can be both positive negative. For example, suppose δ = 1, α(p ) = ep 1+e P F (P ) Exp(1). Then for s = 1 2 the numerator ( consequently p n) is positive, but for s = 1 the numerator ( consequently p n ) is negative. The expected profits π o π n are both strictly positive, even though p n can be negative. A switching consumer can give a short term loss, but once this customer is old, the firm expects to make a profit on him/her. Note that because α(p )G(P ) < 1 2, π o > π n. So, as expected, a customer who bought from the firm in period t 1 is more profitable than a customer who did not buy from the firm in t 1. The next proposition summarizes the discussion above. Proposition 3.3 In equilibrium, the following properties hold p o > p n p o > 0 p n can be both positive negative π o > π n > 0 α(p )G(P ) < 1 2 7

9 An interesting issue is how the equilibrium changes when the switching costs increase. Intuitively, when the switching costs increase, consumers switch less. This increases the power firms have over their old consumers. At the same time, firms need to put in more effort to attract new consumers, which lowers the prices for new consumers. The next proposition formally states the effects of a change in switching costs s. Proposition 3.4 A change in s has the following effects 1. 1 < < 0 0 < po pn < 1 2. α(p ) 0, G(P ) < 0 3. po 4. For δ πo 6. πn < 0 α(p )G(P ) < 0 can be both positive negative. p n < 0 can be both positive negative. The proof of this proposition is in the Appendix. Proposition 3.4 confirms part of the intuition above. First, 2. shows that indeed consumers switch less when the switching costs increase. This is not surprising, given that the expected gains from switching, P, decrease in the switching costs. Part 1. also claims that the difference between the old new price increases in s. This reflects that indeed firms have more power over their old consumers compete more for new consumers. The competition for new consumers is also reflected in 4. The price for new consumers decreases when the switching costs increase, at least for δ 1 2. For δ < 1 2 it is not clear what happens to p n. Theoretically, the derivative could be positive, but I have not been able to find an example where this indeed happens. Perhaps a bit surprising is that the price for old consumers can both increase decrease in s. Intuitively, the firm should have more power over its old consumers, allowing it to increase prices. Still, p o can also decrease the key to understing this result is that the switching probability, α(p )G(P ), not only decreases in s but also increases in p o decreases in p n. If the decrease in p n is strong, many consumers will consider switching, which lowers π o. A firm might therefore want to counter the effect of p n on α(p )G(P ) by decreasing p o. If the decrease in p n is low (or if p n increases), the change in p n will be offset by the change in s a firm might want to increase p o. The increase in p o will however always be limited, since a too large increase will induce too much switching. This is also visible in 1. The 8

10 difference between p o p n will increase, but the derivative is bounded above. Given that the probability a consumer switches is decreasing in s, given that p n also tends to decrease in s, it is intuitive that the expected profits from new consumers decrease in s. After all, profits on those consumers can only be made when the consumer switches, those profits depend on p n. The profits on old consumers, π o can both increase decrease in s, reflecting that p o can both increase decrease in s. Next, consider the effect of a change in the discount factor δ. From (3) it is clear that P does not depend on δ. This greatly simplifies the analysis. The next proposition summarizes the effect of δ. Proposition 3.5 A change in δ has the following effects 1. δ 2. po δ = 0, po pn δ = 0, α(p ) δ = 0 G(P ) δ = 0 = pn δ = 1 2α(P )G(P ) < 0 3. (1 δ)πo 1 2α(P )G(P ) δ = < 0 4. (1 δ)πn δ = 0 This proposition can easily be derived from proposition 3.1 therefore the proof is omitted. The effect of δ on the prices is fairly intuitive. When the discount factor increases, the future gets more weight. Since the largest part of the profits that are made on switching consumers (π n ) are made in future periods, the future gets more weight, firms lower p n in order to induce more switching. More switching decreases the profits on old consumers. Therefore, firms lower p o to match the decrease in p n, thereby make sure that the switching rate α(p )G(P ) does not change. The analysis of profits needs some care. The profits do not only depend on prices market shares, but also on the level of δ. When δ increases, profits tend to increase as well, just because all future periods get more weight. Therefore, proposition 3.5 corrects the profits by dividing them by 1 1 δ = 1 + δ + δ Once the profits are corrected, the expected profits on old consumers decrease in δ. This can be explained by the decrease in prices. Surprisingly, the (corrected) profits on switching consumers do not change in δ. The reason for this is that firms make more profits on switching consumers in future periods. Even with the proposed correction, the future periods get more weight compared to the current period, which tends to increase total expected profits. On the other h, the decreasing prices tend to decrease profits. These two effects cancel out, leading to no net change in profits. 9

11 4 Oligopoly In this section I will analyze the model when there are n 2 firms in the market. I will again focus on a symmetric equilibrium. 4.1 Consumer behavior Consider a consumer at the start of period t who bought at firm j in period t 1. Recall that in an oligopoly P j = p oj,t 1 k j n 1 p nk,t s. With probability 1 α(p j ) the consumer does not consider switching will stay at firm j. With probability α(p j ) the consumer considers switching to some other firm. In this case the consumer compares the utility of buying at j with the utility of buying at some other firm k. The (expected) utility of buying at j is ɛ ij,t p oj,t + E δ h (ɛ ij,t+h p oj,t+h ). h=1 The (expected) utility of buying at k j is ɛ ik,t p nk,t s + E δ h (ɛ ik,t+h p ok,t+h ). h=1 Recall that it is assumed that the consumer expects the firms to be symmetric. Therefore, a consumer will decide to stay at firm j if only if for all k j ɛ ij,t p oj,t ɛ ik,t p nk,t s. Since ɛ i.,t is iid with cdf F, the probability that the consumer stays at firm j can be written as ( F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) f(ɛ)dɛ. (4) k j Now consider the probability that a consumer switches to firm l. A consumer will switch to l if only if ɛ il,t p nl,t s ɛ ij,t p oj,t, for all k j, l, ɛ il,t p nl,t ɛ ik,t p nk,t. The probability that this occurs equals F (ɛ + p oj,t p nl,t s) ( k j,l F (ɛ p nl,t + p nk,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ. (5) As in the previous section, I will focus on a symmetric equilibrium where prices are constant over time. This implies that in equilibrium p o.,t = p o, p n.,t = p n P = p o 1 k j n 1 p n s = p o p n s. In such an equilibrium, the probability that a consumer stays at firm j can be written as F (ɛ P ) n 1 f(ɛ)dɛ 10

12 the probability that a consumer switches from firm j to firm l can be written as Note that by definition F (ɛ + P )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ. (n 1) F (ɛ + P )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ = 1 F (ɛ P ) n 1 f(ɛ)dɛ. (6) In this section, define G(P ) by G(P ) = (n 1) F (ɛ + P )F (ɛ)n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ. Note that G(P ) is a different expression than in the previous section, but the interpretation is the same. G(P ) denotes the probability that a consumer who considers switching indeed switches. Also define g(p ) = (n 1) f(ɛ + P )F (ɛ)n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ, the derivative of G(P ) w.r.t. P. Note that because of (6) g(p ) can also be written as g(p ) = (n 1) f(ɛ P )F (ɛ P ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ. 4.2 Pricing decision To derive the optimal pricing decision of firm j, consider π o π n. As before, π o gives the expected current discounted future profits from a single consumer who has bought from firm j in the previous period, π n gives the expected current discounted future profits from a single consumer who has not bought from firm j in the previous period. The expression for π o is a simple generalization of (1). ( π o = max 1 α(p j )+α(p j ) p oj,t ( α(p j ) 1 ( k j ( k j F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ (p oj,t +δπ o )+ F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n. The expression for π n is a bit more complicated, since the probability that a consumer who is currently in firm k considers switching, α(p k ) depends on k. Therefore, the expected profits that firm j makes on a consumer who is not currently in j depend on the firm where the consumer currently is. Define ρ k as the current market share of firm k define π nk by π nk = α(p k ) F (ɛ+p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ+p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ(p nj,t +δπ o )+ l j,k 11

13 ( 1 α(p k ) F (ɛ + p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ + p nl,t p nj,t ) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n. l j,k Then ρ k π n = max π nk. p nj,t 1 ρ j k j Note that as before π o depends only on p oj,t p nk,t with k j. Also, π n depends only on p nj,t p ok,t p nk,t with k j. Therefore, when setting its old price, firm j therefore only has to consider its old consumers when setting its new price firm j only has to consider its new consumers. It is immediately clear that the optimal p oj,t does not depend on market shares. From the expression for π n it seems that the optimal p nj,t does depend on market shares, but in a symmetric equilibrium π nk = π nl for k l. Therefore in a symmetric equilibrium for π n. ρ k 1 ρ j will drop out of the expression The first-order conditions give the following equilibrium condition. Proposition 4.1 Let Q 1 (x) R 1 (x) be defined as Q 1 (x) = α(x)g(x) + α (x)g(x) R 1 (x) = 1 n 1 α (x)g(x)+α(x)g(x)+(n 1)α(x) In any symmetric equilibrium, P is implicitly defined by (n 2)F (ɛ+x)f (ɛ) n 3 f(ɛ) 2 dɛ. P 1 α(p )G(P ) Equilibrium prices are given by + α(p )G(P ) R 1 (P ) = s. (7) p o = δ α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ(1 α(p )G(P )))(1 α(p )G(P )) + n 1 R 1 (P ) p n = α(p )G(P ) (1 + δ (1 α(p )G(P ))2 α(p )G(P )) δ. R 1 (P ) n 1 Equilibrium profits are given by 12

14 π n = α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ)(n 1)R 1 (P ) π o = δα(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ)(n 1)R 1 (P ) (1 α(p )G(P ))2 +. The proof of this proposition is in the appendix. Note that when R 1 (x) = Q 1 (x) (which holds for n = 2) the equilibrium in Proposition 4.1 is equal to the equilibrium in Proposition 3.1. In general, however, R 1 (x) Q 1 (x). To underst why this is the case, first consider the interpretation of Q 1 (x) R 1 (x). Q 1 (x) can be interpreted as the derivative w.r.t. p oj,t of the probability that a consumer who is currently at firm j stays at firm j. R 1 (x) can be interpreted as the derivative w.r.t. p nj,t of the probability that a consumer who is currently at firm k switches to firm j. These derivatives differ for two reasons. First, the effect of p oj,t on P j differs from the effect of p nj,t on P k : j p oj,t = 1 k p nj,t = 1 n 1. This explains the 1 n 1 in the first term of R 1 (x). Second, a consumer who decides to stay at firm j compares p oj,t p nk,t +s for all k j. For every one of those comparisons the effect of a change in p oj,t is the same. But a consumer who switches from k to j compares p ok,t with p nj,t + s compares p nj,t with p nl,t for all l j, k. The effect of a change in p nj,t on the first comparison is different from the effect on the second set of comparisons. This is reflected in R 1 (x) by the last term. The second-order conditions can be derived by twice differentiating the profit functions. For p o this gives the condition Q 2(x) Q 1 (x) > 2Q 1(x) 1 α(x)g(x), with Q 2(x) = α (x)g(x) + 2α (x)g(x) + α(x)g (x). For p n, deriving the second derivative gives a lengthy expression that cannot be expressed in terms of α(x), G(x) /or R 1 (x). For sake of brevity, this expression is left out of the paper, but there are combinations of α(x) F (x) for which both second order conditions hold, for which the lhs of (7) is increasing in P. 4.3 Equilibrium properties Assuming that the second-order conditions are satisfied, the equilibrium defined in Proposition 4.1 has some properties that are easy to derive. First note that Q 1 (x) > 0 R 1 (x) > 0 for any x. Also using that by definition 0 < α(x) < 1 0 < G(x) < 1 it is easy to see that p o > 0, π o > 0 π n > 0. Moreover, p n can be both positive negative. For example, suppose F (x) Exp(1), α(p ) = ep, δ = 1 n = 5. Then for s = 1 p 1+e P n is negative, but for s = 0, 5 p n is positive. The next proposition summarizes. Proposition 4.2 Assume the second-order conditions are satisfied. In equilibrium, the following properties hold 13

15 p o > 0 p n can be both positive negative π o > 0 π n > 0 In the duopoly case it was also derived that p o > p n, π o > π n α(p )G(P ) < 1 2. These properties do not necessarily generalize to the case n > 2. The problem here is that Q 1 (x) R 1 (x), assumptions on Q 1 (x) R 1 (x) are necessary to evaluate the prices profits. For example, it can be shown that when Q 1 (x) > R 1 (x) α(0) 1 2 all the properties mentioned above hold. The condition Q 1 (x) > R 1 (x) is however quite restrictive. Assuming that (n 1)Q 1 (x) > R 1 (x), which is a less restrictive condition, it can be shown that α(p )G(P ) < n 1 n. The restriction (n 1)Q 1(x) > R 1 (x) is however not sufficient to show that p o > p n or π o > π n. The fact that the equilibrium depends on both Q 1 (x) R 1 (x) also complicates the derivation of the effects of a change in s or δ. In the next section some results will be derived for one specific example. 5 Results for a specific example In this section it will be assumed that α(p ) follows a logistic distribution that F (x) follows an exponential distribution. That is, α(x) = Then it can be derived that ex+a 1 + e x+a F (x) = 1 e x. Also, G(x) = { 1 1 n e x + 1 n e x (1 e x ) n if x < n e x if x 0 { 1 g(x) = n e x 1 n e x (1 e x ) n (1 e x ) n 1 if x < 0 1 n e x if x 0 α (x) = e x+a (1 + e x+a = α(x)(1 α(x)), ) 2 Q 1 (x) = α(x)g(x) + α(x)(1 α(x))g(x) for n > 2 14

16 For n = 2 P is defined by R 1 (x) = 1 α(x)(1 α(x))g(x) + α(x)g(x). n 1 P P 1+eP +a 1+e P +a e2p +a e P +a e 2P +a ( ep +a ) 1+eP +a 1+e a e P +a e P +a e P +a ( ea ) = s if P < 0 = s if P 0 For n = 2 it can be checked that assumption A1 holds, therefore all the results in Section?? hold. For n > 2 P is defined by h(p ) = s with h(p ) defined by h(p ) = P 1 e P +a 1 (n 1)(1+e P +a )+1 (1 e P ) n 1 (1+e P +a ) 2 e P +a (1+ 1 n ea 1 n ea (1 e P ) n ) e P +a (1+e P +a )(1 e P ) n 1 if P < 0 P 1 e P +a 1 (n 1)(1+e P +a )+1 if P 0 Note that the denominator of the last term of h(p ) for P < 0 can be written as e P +a (1 + 1 n ea 1 n ea (1 e P ) n (1 + e P +a )(1 e P ) n 1 ) = e P +a (1 + e P +a f(p ) (1 e P ) n 1 ) > 0. For P 0 it is clear that h(p ) is increasing in P. For P < 0 it is shown in the appendix that when a ln 75 7 h(p ) is also increasing in P.1 Note that for P h(p ) that for P h(p ). Therefore, for a ln 75 7 there is a unique solution to h(p ) = s. The second order conditions can be checked, show that this solution indeed defines a maximum. In the duopoly case, Proposition 3.3 gives some properties of the equilibrium. Except for the last property, all properties also hold in the oligopoly case of the example in the current section. Proposition 5.1 Assume that α(x) = ex+a, F (x) = 1 e x a 1+e x+a. Then in equilibrium, the following properties hold ln 75 7 p o > p n p o > 0 1 a ln 75 is a sufficient condition for 7 h (P ) to be positive. It is likely that h(p ) is also increasing in P for a > ln 75 75, but this is hard to prove. a ln is not a very restrictive 7 7 assumption. For a = ln 75 consumers who expect no gain from switching (P = 0) will 7 consider switching with probability

17 p n can be both positive negative π o > π n > 0 The proof of this proposition is in the appendix. The interpretation of the results is the same as before. Most of the effects of a change in s that were specified in Proposition 3.4 also generalize to the oligopoly case of the example of the current section. Proposition 5.2 Assume that α(x) = ex+a, F (x) = 1 e x a 1+e x+a. Then in equilibrium, a change in s has the following effects ln < 0 2. α(p ) < 0, G(P ) < 0 3. po 4. pn < 0 5. πo 6. πn < 0 α(p )G(P ) < 0 can be both positive negative. can be both positive negative. The next table gives some simulation results for different value of n. TO BE CONTINUED 6 Conclusion TO BE WRITTEN References [1] Beggs, A. P. Klemperer, Multi-period competition with switching costs, Econometrica, [2] Cabral, L., Small switching costs lead to lower prices, Journal of Marketing Research, [3] Dube, J., G.J. Hitsch P.E. Rossi, Do switching costs make markets less competitive?, Journal of Marketing, [4] Farrell, J. P. Klemperer, Coordination lock-in: competition with swiching costs network effects, Hbook of Industrial Organization, North Holl Publishing,

18 α(p ) G(P ) α(p )G(P ) po pn πo πn

19 [5] Klemperer, P., The competitiveness of markets with switching costs, The RAND Journal of Economics, [6] Padilla, A.J., Mixed pricing in oligopoly with consumer switching costs, International Journal of Industrial Organization, [7] Wieringa, J.E. P.C. Verhoef, Understing customer switching behavior in a liberalizing service market: an exploratory study, Journal of Service Research,

20 A Proof of Proposition 3.1 First, it can be derived that α(p j ) = α(p j) j = α (P j ) p oj,t j p oj,t α(p k ) = α(p k) k = α (P k ). p nj,t k p nj,t This gives first order conditions (α (P j )G(P j )+α(p j )g(p j ))δπ n (α (P j )G(P j )+α(p j )g(p j ))(p oj,t +δπ o )+1 α(p j )G(P j ) = 0 (α (P k )G(P k )+α(p k )g(p k ))(p nj,t +δπ o )+α(p k )G(P k )+(α (P k )G(P k )+α(p k )g(p k ))δπ n = 0. In a symmetric equilibrium with p o.,t = p o, p n.,t = p n P = p o p n s this translates to (α (P )G(P )+α(p )g(p ))δπ n (α (P )G(P )+α(p )g(p ))(p o +δπ o )+1 α(p )G(P ) = 0 (α (P )G(P )+α(p )g(p ))(p n +δπ o )+α(p )G(P )+(α (P )G(P )+α(p )g(p ))δπ n = 0. Rewriting gives p o = δ(π n π o ) + 1 α(p )G(P ) p n = δ(π n π o ) + α(p )G(P ). Plugging this back into the profit functions gives π o = α(p )G(P )δπ n + (1 α(p )G(P )) ( δπ n + ) 1 α(p )G(P ) 19

21 This gives ( π n = α(p )G(P ) δπ n + ) α(p )G(P ) + (1 α(p )G(P ))δπ n. π n = α(p )2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ) π o = δα(p )2 G(P ) 2 + (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) 2. (1 δ) Finally, plugging those expressions for π o π n back into the expressions for p o p n gives p o = 1 δ + (2δ 1)α(P )G(P ) p n = δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ). Note that all prices profits depend on P, which is defined as P = p o p n s. P is therefore implicitly defined by or P = 1 2α(P )G(P ) s P 1 2α(P )G(P ) = s B Proof of Proposition 3.2 To show that under A1 (3) has a unique solution, first note that any solution should have 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0. Suppose to the contrary that 1 2α(P )G(P ) 0. Then it should be that G(P ) > 0.5, since g(x) is symmetric around 0, 2 P > 0. But if P > 0 1 2α(P )G(P ) 0, then the lhs of (3) is strictly positive, which can never hold. Therefore, any solution should have 1 2α(P )G(P ) > α(P )G(P ) Next, for 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0 under A1, α(p )g(p )+α (P )G(P ) is decreasing in P. To show this, it is sufficient to show that the derivative of is negative: 1 2α(P )G(P ) α(p )g(p )+α (P )G(P ) 2 Recall the G(x) is the CDF of ε ij,t ε ik,t, with g(x) the corresponding CDF. Since ε ij,t ε ik,t are iid, g(x) should be symmetric around 0. 20

22 2 2 (1 2α(P )G(P ))Q 2 (P ) < 0 Note that the denominator of the derivative is left out, since the denominator is strictly positive. Since 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0, one can use A1 to show that the derivative is indeed negative. This implies that for 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0 the lhs of (3) is strictly increasing in P. Note that 1 2α(P )G(P ) is decreasing in P approaches 1 when p. Therefore, there does exist a region where 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0, this region has the form (, P ), with P > 0 with P = if lim P 1 2α(P ) > 0. In this region the lhs of (3) is strictly increasing in P. For P = s, 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0, the lhs of (3) is strictly below s. For P = P, the lhs of (3) is strictly positive. This implies that there is a unique solution to (3), this unique solution has s < P < P. To show that the unique solution to (3) defines a maximum, consider the second derivatives δπ n [ α (P )G(P ) + 2α (P )g(p ) + α(p )g (P ) ] + (p o + δπ o ) [ α (P )G(P ) 2α (P )g(p ) α(p )g (P ) ] 2α(P )g(p ) 2α (P )G(P ) (p n + δπ o ) [ α (P )G(P ) + 2α (P )g(p ) + α(p )g (P ) ] + δπ n [ α (P )G(P ) 2α (P )g(p ) α(p )g (P ) ] 2α(P )g(p ) 2α (P )G(P ) To ensure that the first order conditions maximize profits, both second derivatives should be negative at the value of P defined by (3). Using the values of p o, p n, π o π n defined by Proposition 3.1 the second derivatives can be written as 1 α(p )G(P ) Q 2 (P ) 2 (8) α(p )G(P ) Q 2 (P ) 2. (9) Under assumption A1 both second derivatives are negative. 21

23 C Proof of Proposition 3.4 First note that p o, p n, π o π n only depend on s via P. Therefore, it is sufficient to know the derivatives of prices profits w.r.t. P to know the derivative of P w.r.t. s. 1. Using (3), it can be derived that 2Q 1(P ) 2 (1 2α(P )G(P ))Q 2 (P ) 2 with Q 2 (P ) as defined in A1. Rewriting gives = 1 or (3 + (1 2α(P )G(P ))Q 2(P ) 2 ) = 1 = (1 2α(P )G(P ))Q 2 (P ). Using A1, using that 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0 gives 1 α(p )G(P ) 1 < 1 + α(p )G(P ) < Since = po pn 1, 1 < 2. Since α(p ) G(P ) 0, α(p ) G(P ) 0 = α(p ) G(P ) > 0, < α(p )G(P ) 2 α(p )G(P ) < 0. < 0 implies 0 < po pn < 1. > 0 = G(P ) < 0 it is immediately clear that α(p )G(P ) = α(p ) G(P ) + α(p ) G(P ) < 0. < 0. Also, since α(p ) > 0 3. First note that the derivative of (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) + δα(p )G(P ) w.r.t. P is (2δ 1). This gives p o = (2δ 1)Q 1(P ) 2 ((1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) + δα(p )G(P ))Q 2 (P ) 2. Rewriting gives p o = 2δ 1 ((1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) + δα(p )G(P ))Q 2(P ) 2. Since po = po po po < 0, the sign of is -1 times the sign of. Now suppose that f(x) Exp(1), α(p ) = ep, δ = 0.95 s = 2. Then 1+e P it can be shown that po < 0. But when G(x) Exp(1), α(p ) = ep, 1+e P δ = 0.95 s = 1, po po > 0. This shows that can be both positive 22

24 negative. 4. First note that the derivative of δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ) w.r.t. P is (2δ + 1). This gives or p n = (2δ + 1)Q 1(P ) 2 ( δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ))Q 2 (P ) 2 p n = 2δ + 1 ( δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ))Q 2(P ) 2. Now suppose δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ) > 0. Using A1 gives 2δ(1 α(p )G(P )) α(p )G(P ) α(p )G(P ) < p n 1 + α(p )G(P ) + 2δα(P )G(P ) <. 1 α(p )G(P ) When δ 1 2, 2δ(1 α(p )G(P )) α(p )G(P ) 1 2α(P )G(P ) > 0, so p n pn > 0 < 0. Now suppose δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ) < 0. Again using A1 gives 1 + α(p )G(P ) + 2δα(P )G(P ) 1 α(p )G(P ) < p n 2δ(1 α(p )G(P )) α(p )G(P ) <. α(p )G(P ) Since 1+α(P )G(P )+2δα(P )G(P ) 1 α(p )G(P ) is clearly positive, pn pn > 0 < First note that the derivative of δα(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 + (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 w.r.t. P equals 2δα(P )G(P ) 2(1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )), or 2(δ + α(p )G(P ) 1). This gives π o = 1 ( 2(δ + α(p )G(P ) 1) 1 δ (δα(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 + (1 δ)(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 )Q 2 (P ) 2 When f(x) Exp(1), α(p ) = ep, s = 1 δ = 0.95 πo 1+e P ). > 0, since πo < 0, < 0. But when f(x) Exp(1), α(p ) = ep, s = 2, 5 1+e P πo πo < 0, since < 0, > 0. This shows that can be δ = 0.95 πo both positive negative. 6. First note that the derivative of α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 w.r.t. P equals 2α(P )G(P ). This gives 23

25 or Using A1 gives Since π n = 1 2α(P )G(P ) 2 α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 Q 2 (P ) 1 δ 2 π n = 1 ( 2α(P )G(P ) α(p )2 G(P ) 2 ) Q 2 (P ) 1 δ 2. 0 < π n < 1 2α(P )G(P ) 1 δ 1 α(p )G(P ). < 0 this gives πn < 0. D Proof of Proposition 7 First, it can be derived that α(p j ) = α(p j) j = α (P j ) p oj,t j p oj,t α(p k ) = α(p k) k = 1 p nj,t k p nj,t n 1 α (P k ). This gives first order conditions ( α (P j ) + α ( (P j ) F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) f(ɛ)dɛ α(p j ) α(p j ) k j f(ɛ (p oj,t p nl,t s)) ( l j k j,l F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ (p oj,t +δπ o )+ ( 1 α(p j ) + α(p j ) F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) f(ɛ)dɛ+ k j ( α (P j )(1 ( F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)))f(ɛ)dɛ)+ k j f(ɛ (p oj,t p nl,t s)) ( l j k j,l F (ɛ (p oj,t p nk,t s)) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n = 0 24

26 k j ρ k 1 ρ j (( 1 n 1 α (P k ) F (ɛ+p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ+p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ+ l j,k α(p k ) f(ɛ + p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ + p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ+ l j,k α(p k ) F (ɛ+p ok,t p nj,t s) h j,k f(ɛ+p nh,t p nj,t ) ( l j,k,h F (ɛ+p nl,t p nj,t ) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ (p nj,t +δπ o )+ α(p k ) F (ɛ + p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ + p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ+ l j,k ( 1 n 1 α (P k ) F (ɛ + p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ + p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ l j,k α(p k ) f(ɛ + p ok,t p nj,t s) ( F (ɛ + p nl,t p nj,t ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ l j,k α(p k ) F (ɛ+p ok,t p nj,t s) h j,k f(ɛ+p nh,t p nj,t ) ( l j,k,h In a symmetric equilibrium with p o.,t = p o, p n.,t = p n P = p o p n s this translates to ( α (P )+α (P ) F (ɛ P ) n 1 f(ɛ)dɛ α(p ) 1 α(p ) + α(p ) F (ɛ P ) n 1 f(ɛ)dɛ+ ( α (P )(1 F (ɛ P ) n 1 f(ɛ)dɛ)+α(p ) F (ɛ+p nl,t p nj,t ) ) ) f(ɛ)dɛ )δπ n = 0. ) (n 1)f(ɛ P )F (ɛ P ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ (p o +δπ o )+ ) (n 1)f(ɛ P )F (ɛ P ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n = 0 25

27 ( 1 n 1 α (P ) F (ɛ+p )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ+α(p ) f(ɛ+p )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ+ ) α(p ) F (ɛ+p )(n 2)F (ɛ) n 3 f(ɛ) 2 dɛ (p n +δπ o )+α(p ) F (ɛ+p )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ+ ( 1 n 1 α (P ) F (ɛ+p )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ α(p ) f(ɛ+p )F (ɛ) n 2 f(ɛ)dɛ ) α(p ) F (ɛ + P )(n 2)f(ɛ)F (ɛ) n 3 f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n = 0. Using the definition of G(x), this can be written as ( α (P )G(P ) α(p )g(p ))(p o +δπ o )+1 α(p )G(P )+(α (P )G(P )+α(p )g(p ))δπ n = 0 ( (p n + δπ o ) 1 1 n 1 α (P ) n 1 G(P ) α(p ) 1 g(p )+ n 1 ) α(p ) F (ɛ+p )(n 2)F (ɛ) n 3 f(ɛ) 2 dɛ +α(p ) 1 n 1 ( 1 G(P )+ 1 ) α(p ) g(p ) + α(p ) F (ɛ + P )(n 2)f(ɛ)F (ɛ) n 3 f(ɛ)dɛ δπ n = 0. n 1 Isolating p o p n gives 1 n 1 α (P ) G(P )+ n 1 p o = δ(π n π o ) + 1 α(p )G(P ) p n = δ(π n π o ) + α(p )G(P ). R 1 (P ) Plugging this back into the profit functions gives π o = α(p )G(P )δπ n + (1 α(p )G(P )) 26 ( δπ n + ) 1 α(p )G(P )

28 1 π n = α(p )G(P ) n 1 This gives ( δπ n + ) α(p )G(P ) R 1 (P ) 1 + (1 α(p )G(P ) n 1 )δπ n. π n = α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ)(n 1)R 1 (P ) π o = δα(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 (1 δ)(n 1)R 1 (P ) (1 α(p )G(P ))2 +. Finally, plugging those expressions for π o π n back into the expressions for p o p n gives p o = δα(p )2 G(P ) 2 (1 α(p )G(P ))(1 δ(1 α(p )G(P ))) + (n 1)R 1 (P ) p n = α(p )G(P ) (1 + R 1 (P ) δα(p )G(P ) ) n 1 δ(1 α(p )G(P ))2. All prices profits depend on P, which is defined as P = p o p n s. P is therefore implicitly defined by or P = 1 α(p )G(P ) α(p )G(P ) R 1 (P ) s P 1 α(p )G(P ) + α(p )G(P ) R 1 (P ) = s. E Proof that the example has a unique solution Derivative wrt P P 1 α(p )G(P ) Q(P ) + n 1 n α 1+1+ (1 α(p )G(P ))(2α(P )(1 α(p ))g(p ) + α(p )g(p ) + α(p )(1 α(p ))(1 2α(P ))G(P )) (α(p )g(p ) + α(p )(1 α(p ))G(P )) 2 + (n P < 0 27

29 2+ (1 α(p )G(P ))(2(1 α(p ))g(p ) g(p ) + (n 1)(1 ep ) n 2 e P + (1 3α(P ) + 2α(P ) 2 )G(P )) α(p )(g(p ) + (1 α(p ))G(P )) 2 + Define X = 1 α(p )+α(p )g(p )+α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 = g +(1 α(p ))G(P )+ (1 e P ) n 1 2α(X (1 e P ) n 1 ) 2 +X((X (1 e P ) n 1 )(1 2α(P ))+(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P X) (X (1 e P ) n 1 )(X 2α(P )(1 e P ) n 1 ) + (n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P X 2 X (1 e P ) n 1 = (1 α(p ))(1 (1 e P ) n 1 ) + α(p )g(p ) > 0 X 2α(P )(1 e P ) n 1 = 1 α(p ) + α(p )g(p ) α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 1 2e P e a (1 e P ) n n ea 1 n ea (1 e p ) n First deceasing then increasing in P. Minimum at e P = 1 minimum is n ea (1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 ) 2n 1. Value at For n = 3 1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 = n ea (1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 ) > 0 for e a < n 2 2n 1 )n 1 is decreasing in n. For n > 3 but 1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 < n ea (1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 ) is increasing in n so > 0. When 1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 > n ea (1 2( 2n 2 2n 1 )n 1 ) > 0 by definition. So minimum is always positive. F Proof of Proposition When P = s, h(p ) < s. Since h(p ) is increasing in P this implies that P should be larger than s, or p o p n > It is immediately clear from the expression for p o in Proposition 4.1 that p o > Suppose δ = 1, a = 0 n = 5. Then for s = 1 p n < 0 for s = 0.5 p n > 0. 28

30 4. It is immediately clear from the expressions for π o π n in Proposition 4.1 that π o > 0 π n > 0. Also, it has already been shown that π o π n > 0 for n = 2. Therefore, in this proof it will be assumed that n 3. α(p )G(P ) Using that R 1 (P ) = n 1 n α(p ), note that π o π n > 0 if only if α(p )G(P ) + (1 α(p )G(P )) 2 (n α(p )) > 0. This can be rewritten as α(p ) 2 G(P )g(p ) α(p ) 2 G(P ) 2 +n(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 α(p )+2α(P ) 2 G(P ) > 0. When P < 0, g(p ) = 1 G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1. Then π o π n > 0 if only if α(p ) 2 G(P )(1 e P ) n 1 + n(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 α(p )(1 α(p )G(P )) > 0. It is clear that for P < 0 α(p ) 2 G(P )(1 e P ) n 1 > 0. It will be shown now that n nα(p )G(P ) α(p ) > 0, which implies that n(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 α(p )(1 α(p )G(P )) > 0. Plugging α(p ) = ep +a 1+e P +a G(P ) = 1 1 n e P + 1 n e P (1 e P ) n in n nα(p )G(P ) α(p ) multiplying by 1 + e P +a leaves to show that n + e a e a (1 e p ) n P +a > 0. This expression is increasing in n, so n 3 gives n+e a e a (1 e p ) n P +a 3+2e P +a 3e P e P +a +e P +a e 2P. This expression in turn is increasing in a, so 3 + 2e P +a 3e P e P +a + e P +a e 2P lim a 3 + 2e P +a 3e P e P +a +e P +a e 2P = 3. Therefore n+e a e a (1 e p ) n P +a 3 > 0. Now assume P 0 Then g(p ) = 1 G(P ) π o π n > 0 if only if n(1 α(p )G(P )) 2 α(p )(1 α(p )G(P )) > 0, or, equivalently, n ep +a nα(p )G(P )) α(p ) > 0. Plugging in α(p ) = G(P ) = e P +a n e P, multiplying by 1 + e P +a leaves to show that n + e a e P +a > 0. Suppose that this is not true, that is, suppose that e P +a n+e a. Then the definition of P gives P 1 e P +a 1 (n 1)(1 + e P +a ) + 1 ln(n+ea ) a 1 n + e a 1 (n 1)(n e a ) + 1. The rhs of this expression is increasing in n, so because n 3 ln(n+e a ) a 1 n + e a 1 (n 1)(n e a ) + 1 ln(3+ea ) a e a e a. The rhs of this expression is decreasing in a, so since a ln

31 ln(3 + e a ) a e a 1 96 ln 9 + 2ea 7 ln > 0. Therefore, if e P +a n + e a P 1 e P +a 1 (n 1)(1 + e P +a ) + 1 > 0 which can never hold for s 0. So, in equilibrium e P +a < n + e a, or π o π n > 0. G Proof of Proposition 5.2 For n = 2 all statements have been proved in Proposition 3.4, except for < 0. To prove this, it has to be shown that p n p n = 2δ+1 ( δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )G(P ))(2(1 α(p ))g(p ) + g (P ) + (1 α(p ))(1 2α(P ))G(P )) > g(p ) + (1 α(p ))G(P ) When P < 0 g (P ) = g(p ) = G(P ), so it it left to show that (2δ + 1)(2 α) ( δ + (2δ + 1)α(P )g(p ))(4 5α(P ) + 2α(P ) 2 ) > 0. The derivative of this expression wrt δ is 8 8α(P )g(p ) 7α(P ) + 10α(P ) 2 g(p ) + 2α(P ) 2 4α(P ) 3 g(p ). This expression in turn is decreasing in g(p ), since P < 0 gives G(P ) < 1 2 the derivative wrt δ is larger than 8 11α(P ) + 7α(P )2 2α(P ) 3 > 0. Since the derivative wrt δ is positive, (2δ+1)(2 α) ( δ+(2δ+1)α(p )g(p ))(4 5α(P )+2α(P ) 2 ) > 2 α α(p )g(p )(4 5α(P )+2α(P ) 2 ). The rhs of this expression is again decreasing in g(p ), so (2δ+1)(2 α) ( δ+(2δ+1)α(p )g(p ))(4 5α(P )+2α(P ) 2 ) > 2 α α(p )(2 5 2 α(p )+α(p )2 ) > 0. When P 0 g (P ) = g(p ) G(P ) = 1 g(p ), so it it left to show that 2δ (1 2α(P ))(δ 2δα α + (2δ + 1)α(P )g(p )) > 0. The derivative of this expression wrt δ equals 30

32 3 4α(P ) + 2α(P )g(p ) + 4α(P ) 2 4α(P ) 2 g(p ). Since P 0 g(p ) 1 2, for any possible value of 0 < g(p ) 1 2 the derivative wrt δ is positive. This gives 2δ+1+(1 2α(P ))(δ 2δα α+(2δ+1)α(p )g(p )) > 1 (1 2α(P ))(α α(p )g(p )) > 0. in the remainder of this proof consider the case n The definition of P gives h (P ) = 1. Since h (P ) > 0, < Using that α(p ) < 0 that > 0, G(P ) > 0 is immediately clear. 3. First note that α(p )G(P ) > 0 this so p n = n 1 α(p )G(P ) (1 α(p )G(P ))2 + δ δ n α(p ) n α(p ) p n = (n 1)α(P )(1 α(p )) (n α(p )) 2 +δ Q 1(P ) n α(p ) +δ α(p )2 G(P )(1 α(p )) (n α(p )) 2 +2δ(1 α(p )G(P ))+δ(1 α(p )G where Q 1 (P ) is the derivative of Q 1(P ) wrt P. When P < 0, g(p ) = 1 G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 g (P ) = 1 + G(P ) + (1 e P ) n 1 + (n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P. This gives = α(p )(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n ) Q 1 (P ) = α(p )(1 2α(P ))(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 ep ) n 1 ) + α(p )(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P. This in turn gives p n (n 1)α(P )(1 α(p )) = (n α(p )) 2 +δ α(p )(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 ep ) n ) +δ α(p )2 G(P )(1 α(p )) n α(p ) (n α(p )) 2 +2δ(1 It is clear that the first three terms are positive. The last two terms together give δ(1 α(p )G(P )) 2α(P )(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 ep ) n ) 2 + (1 α(p )G(P ))((1 2α(P ))(1 α(p )G(P ) α(p )(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n I will show that these two terms together also are positive, so consequently pn > 0. The sign of the last two terms is determined by 2α(P )(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n ) 2 +(1 α(p )G(P ))(1 2α(P ))(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 )+(1 α(p )G 31

33 Rewriting gives that it has to be shown that (1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 )α(p )(1 G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 )+(1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 )(1 α(p ) α(p ) Since 1 G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 = g(p ) > 0 consequently 1 α(p )G(P ) (1 e P ) n 1 > 0, the first term of this expression is positive. Suppose 1 α(p ) α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 0, then the second term is positive, the third term is positive the total expression is positive. QED When 1 α(p ) α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 < 0 the second third term together are larger than (1 α(p )G(P ))(1 α(p ) α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 + (n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P ). Plugging in α(p ) = ep +a 1+e P +a gives 1 α(p ) α(p )(1 e P ) n 1 +(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P = e P +a (1 ep +a (1 e P ) n 1 +(1+e P +a )(n 1)(1 e When e P > 1 n, 1 ep +a (1 e P ) n 1 + (1 + e P +a )(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P is increasing in a, so 1 e P +a (1 e P ) n 1 + (1 + e P +a )(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P > 1 + (n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P > 0. QED When e P < 1 n, 1 ep +a (1 e P ) n 1 + (1 + e P +a )(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P is decreasing in a, so 1 e P +a (1 e P ) n 1 + (1 + e P +a )(n 1)(1 e P ) n 2 e P > 1 e P 75 7 (1 ep ) n 1 + (1 + e P 75 7 )(n 1)(1 ep ) n 2 e P When P 0, g(p ) = 1 G(P ), g (P ) = g(p ), = α(p )(1 α(p )G(P )) Q 1 (P ) = α(p )(1 2α(P ))(1 α(p )G(P )). Plugging this rewriting gives in pn p n (n 1)α(P )(1 α(p )) α(p )(1 α(p )G(P )) = (n α(p )) 2 +δ +δ α(p )2 G(P )(1 α(p )) n α(p ) (n α(p )) 2 +2δ(1 α(p )G(P ))+ The first three terms of this expression are positive. The remaining two expressions can be written as δ(1 α(p )G(P ))frac1α(p ) > 0 so pn > 0 pn < < α(p ) < 0, G(P ) < 0 p o α(p )G(P ) < 0 can be both positive negative. 32

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

A theory of recommended price dispersion

A theory of recommended price dispersion A theory of recommended price dispersion Marco Haan Pim Heijnen Martin Obradovits January 3, 017 WORK IN PROGRESS DO NOT CITE Abstract This paper contributes to the theory of recommended retail prices

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005 Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price

More information

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395 ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 95 PROFESSOR A. JOSEPH GUSE (1) (Gibbons 1.6) Consider again the Cournot duopoly model with demand given by the marginal willingness to pay function: P(Q) = a Q, but this time

More information

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix 087/msom070057 Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix Wedad Elmaghraby Altan Gülcü Pınar Keskinocak RH mith chool of Business,

More information

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė 27 May A Early returns Suppose that a consumer must return one product before buying another one. This may happen due to

More information

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs

Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs Supplementary Appendix to Prices and Heterogeneous Search Costs José Luis Moraga-González Zsolt Sándor Matthijs R. Wildenbeest June 216 Introduction In this supplementary appendix we present two extensions

More information

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing

Mathematical Appendix. Ramsey Pricing Mathematical Appendix Ramsey Pricing PROOF OF THEOREM : I maximize social welfare V subject to π > K. The Lagrangian is V + κπ K the associated first-order conditions are that for each I + κ P I C I cn

More information

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Effects Adriana Gama Mario Samano September 7, 218 Abstract We establish an important difference between Cournot oligopolies with and without positive

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Answer Key: Problem Set 1 Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a The profit function (revenue minus total cost) is π(q) = P (q)q cq The first order condition with respect to (henceforth wrt) q is P (q )q + P (q

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Gabriel Y. Weintraub, Lanier Benkard, and Benjamin Van Roy Stanford University {gweintra,lanierb,bvr}@stanford.edu Abstract

More information

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1 Ralph s Strategic Disclosure Ralph manages a firm that operates in a duopoly Both Ralph s (privatevalue) production cost and (common-value) inverse demand are uncertain Ralph s (constant marginal) production

More information

1 Basic Game Modelling

1 Basic Game Modelling Max-Planck-Institut für Informatik, Winter 2017 Advanced Topic Course Algorithmic Game Theory, Mechanism Design & Computational Economics Lecturer: CHEUNG, Yun Kuen (Marco) Lecture 1: Basic Game Modelling,

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice Economics 101 Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice 1 Uncle Léon The canonical model of exchange in economics is sometimes referred to as the Walrasian Model, after the early economist Léon

More information

Online Supplement for Bounded Rationality in Service Systems

Online Supplement for Bounded Rationality in Service Systems Online Supplement for Bounded ationality in Service Systems Tingliang Huang Department of Management Science and Innovation, University ollege London, London W1E 6BT, United Kingdom, t.huang@ucl.ac.uk

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT Strategic Incentives for Managers in Contests Matthias Kräkel Discussion Paper No. 01-08 GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION - GEABA

More information

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions Songzi Du Haoxiang Zhu September 2013 This document supplements Du and Zhu (2013. All results

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix 1 The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias Esther Gal-Or, Tansev Geylani, Tuba Pinar Yildirim Web Appendix DERIVATIONS OF EQUATIONS 16-17 AND PROOF OF LEMMA 1 (i) Single-Homing: Second stage prices are

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

competition: the choice of scope

competition: the choice of scope Multi-product firms under monopolistic competition: the choice of scope SKokovin, PhUshchev, EZhelobodko 7 April 2012 Stylized facts about multi-product firms Multi-product firms account for the most part

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

Durable goods monopolist

Durable goods monopolist Durable goods monopolist Coase conjecture: A monopolist selling durable good has no monopoly power. Reason: A P 1 P 2 B MC MC D MR Q 1 Q 2 C Q Although Q 1 is optimal output of the monopolist, it faces

More information

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Jianqing Chen Andrew Whinston Web Appendix A Heterogeneous Consumer Valuation In the baseline model, we assumed that consumers

More information

SOLUTIONS Problem Set 2: Static Entry Games

SOLUTIONS Problem Set 2: Static Entry Games SOLUTIONS Problem Set 2: Static Entry Games Matt Grennan January 29, 2008 These are my attempt at the second problem set for the second year Ph.D. IO course at NYU with Heski Bar-Isaac and Allan Collard-Wexler

More information

Problem Set #06- Answer key First CompStat Problem Set

Problem Set #06- Answer key First CompStat Problem Set Fall 2015 Problem Set #06- Answer key First CompStat Problem Set ARE211 (1) Inproblem 3 on your last problem set, you foundthemaximum and minimumdistance from the origin to the ellipse x 2 1 +x 1x 2 +x

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

Finite Brand Loyalty and Equilibrium Price Promotions

Finite Brand Loyalty and Equilibrium Price Promotions Finite Brand Loyalty and Equilibrium Price Promotions Bing Jing and Zhong Wen Stern School of Business, New York University June 26, 2005 Abstract The extant literature on price promotions typically assumes

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018 EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 018 Show all your work clearly and make sure you justify all your answers. NAME 1. Consider the market for smart pencil in which only one firm (Superapiz) enjoys a

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information) Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan 200 Good luck!!! Question (duopoly games with imperfect information) Consider a duopoly game in which the inverse demand function is linear where it is positive

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction. Introduction. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6 3. General results on maximizing with two variables 8 4. Model of a private ownership economy 5. Consumer

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Jianwei Huang & Lin Gao Network Communications and Economics Lab (NCEL) Information Engineering Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong Huang

More information

Industrial Organization

Industrial Organization Industrial Organization Lecture Notes Sérgio O. Parreiras Fall, 2017 Outline Mathematical Toolbox Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Revision Perfect Competition Monopoly Oligopoly Mathematical Toolbox

More information

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Tilburg University On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Publication date: 1997 Link to publication General rights Copyright and

More information

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION John Riley 8 February 7 CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION 3. TWO VARIABLES 8 Second Order Conditions Implicit Function Theorem 3. UNCONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION 4 Necessary and Sufficient Conditions 3.3 CONSTRAINED

More information

Math Spring 2017 Mathematical Models in Economics

Math Spring 2017 Mathematical Models in Economics 2017 - Steven Tschantz Math 3660 - Spring 2017 Mathematical Models in Economics Steven Tschantz 2/7/17 Profit maximizing firms Logit demand model Problem Determine the impact of a merger between two of

More information

The Harris-Todaro model

The Harris-Todaro model Yves Zenou Research Institute of Industrial Economics July 3, 2006 The Harris-Todaro model In two seminal papers, Todaro (1969) and Harris and Todaro (1970) have developed a canonical model of rural-urban

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) - What is the old empirical IO? The old empirical IO refers to studies that tried to draw inferences about the relationship

More information

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary July 29, 2005. Appeared in the International Journal

More information

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12 Aggregate Supply Econ 208 Lecture 16 April 3, 2007 Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, 2007 1 / 12 Introduction rices might be xed for a brief period, but we need to look beyond this The di

More information

Approximately Optimal Auctions

Approximately Optimal Auctions Approximately Optimal Auctions Professor Greenwald 17--1 We show that simple auctions can generate near-optimal revenue by using non-optimal reserve prices. 1 Simple vs. Optimal Auctions While Myerson

More information

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Luís Cabral IESE Business School and CEPR September 009 Abstract I revisit the issue of aftermarkets by developing an infinite period model with overlapping

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter Victor Aguirregabiria. Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013

Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter Victor Aguirregabiria. Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013 Industrial Organization II (ECO 2901) Winter 2013. Victor Aguirregabiria Problem Set #1 Due of Friday, March 22, 2013 TOTAL NUMBER OF POINTS: 200 PROBLEM 1 [30 points]. Considertheestimationofamodelofdemandofdifferentiated

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Competition with Reference Price Effect

Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Competition with Reference Price Effect Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 8, 204, no. 74, 3693-3708 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/0.2988/ams.204.44242 Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Competition with Reference Price Effect

More information

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

( )! ± and g( x)! ± ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±. If f!(x) g!(x) !, IV. MORE CALCULUS There are some miscellaneous calculus topics to cover today. Though limits have come up a couple of times, I assumed prior knowledge, or at least that the idea makes sense. Limits are

More information

A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets

A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets Thomas D. Jeitschko Soo Jin Kim Aleksandr Yankelevich April 12, 2018 Abstract We study a Hotelling framework in which customers first pay

More information

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana Oligopoly Notes Simona Montagnana Question 1. Write down a homogeneous good duopoly model of quantity competition. Using your model, explain the following: (a) the reaction function of the Stackelberg

More information

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model Andres Carvajal, Rahul Deb, James Fenske, and John K.-H. Quah Department of Economics University of Toronto Introduction Cournot oligopoly is a canonical noncooperative model of firm competition. In this

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider

Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider November 2004 Flow Control, Routing, and Performance with a For-profit Service Provider by Daron Acemoglu 1 and Asuman Ozdaglar 2 Abstract We consider a game theoretic framework to analyze traffic in a

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

On production costs in vertical differentiation models

On production costs in vertical differentiation models On production costs in vertical differentiation models Dorothée Brécard To cite this version: Dorothée Brécard. On production costs in vertical differentiation models. 2009. HAL Id: hal-00421171

More information

Paul Schrimpf. November 25, UBC Economics 565. Price dispersion and search. Paul Schrimpf. Introduction. Models of price dispersion

Paul Schrimpf. November 25, UBC Economics 565. Price dispersion and search. Paul Schrimpf. Introduction. Models of price dispersion Fixed Sequential UBC Economics 565 November 25, 2015 Fixed Sequential Theory and overview of reduced form : Baye, Morgan, and Scholten (2006) Structural papers:, Moraga-González and Wildenbeest (2008),

More information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Introduction to Games Normal (or Strategic) Form Representation Teoria dos Jogos - Filomena Garcia 1 Outline of Static Games of Complete Information

More information

Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War

Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War Bresnahan, JIE 87: Competition and Collusion in the American Automobile Industry: 1955 Price War Spring 009 Main question: In 1955 quantities of autos sold were higher while prices were lower, relative

More information

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: Practice Questions for Mid-Term I Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form: y f(k) = k α ; α (0, 1) (1) where y and k are output per worker and capital per worker respectively.

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

Online Supplement to

Online Supplement to Online Supplement to Pricing Decisions in a Strategic Single Retailer/Dual Suppliers Setting under Order Size Constraints Ali Ekici Department of Industrial Engineering, Ozyegin University, Istanbul, Turkey,

More information

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012 The time limit for this exam is 4 hours. It has four sections. Each section includes two questions. You are

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly Economic Theory 22, 227 232 (2003) On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly Rabah Amir 1 and Isabel Grilo 2 1 CORE and Department of Economics, Université Catholique de Louvain, 34

More information

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry! Econ 0A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sry! This Problem set tests the knowledge that you accumulated mainly in lectures 2 to 26. The problem set is focused

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition

Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Aftermarket Power and Basic Market Competition Luís Cabral New York University and CEPR April 008 Abstract I revisit the relation between aftermarket power and basic market competition. I consider an infinite

More information

Lecture 3 Unobserved choice sets

Lecture 3 Unobserved choice sets Lecture 3 Unobserved choice sets Rachel Griffith CES Lectures, April 2017 Introduction Unobserved choice sets Goeree (2008) GPS (2016) Final comments 1 / 32 1. The general problem of unobserved choice

More information

Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms

Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms Price Competition when Not All Customers Know of All Firms B. Curtis Eaton Department of Economics University of Calgary Ian MacDonald Commerce Division Lincoln University Laura Meriluoto Department of

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Katz and Shapiro (1985) Katz and Shapiro (1985) 1 The paper studies the compatibility choice of competing firms in industries with network externalities. Also investigated are the social vs. private incentives of compatibility

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

Feedback D. Incorrect! Exponential functions are continuous everywhere. Look for features like square roots or denominators that could be made 0.

Feedback D. Incorrect! Exponential functions are continuous everywhere. Look for features like square roots or denominators that could be made 0. Calculus Problem Solving Drill 07: Trigonometric Limits and Continuity No. of 0 Instruction: () Read the problem statement and answer choices carefully. () Do your work on a separate sheet of paper. (3)

More information

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 22, 2015 First Last (shortinst) Short title November 22, 2015 1

More information

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index. , see Q.E.D. ln, see natural logarithmic function e, see Euler s e i, see imaginary number log 10, see common logarithm ceteris paribus, 4 quod erat demonstrandum, see Q.E.D. reductio ad absurdum, see

More information

Basic Concepts. 1.0 renewable, nonrenewable, and environmental resources

Basic Concepts. 1.0 renewable, nonrenewable, and environmental resources 1 Basic Concepts 1.0 renewable, nonrenewable, and environmental resources Economics might be defined as the study of how society allocates scarce resources. The field of resource economics, would then

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

Market Failure: Externalities

Market Failure: Externalities Market Failure: Externalities Ram Singh Lecture 21 November 10, 2015 Ram Singh: (DSE) Externality November 10, 2015 1 / 18 Questions What is externality? What is implication of externality for efficiency

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly Yasuo Sanjo Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University Abstract We investigate a mixed duopoly market by introducing quality choice

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation Robert Somogyi Preliminary version August 21, 2013 Abstract Since Kreps and Scheinkman's seminal article (1983) a large number of papers

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

CLASS NOTES: BUSINESS CALCULUS

CLASS NOTES: BUSINESS CALCULUS CLASS NOTES: BUSINESS CALCULUS These notes can be thought of as the logical skeleton of my lectures, although they will generally contain a fuller exposition of concepts but fewer examples than my lectures.

More information