Key words. quasiconvex functions, dual representation, quasiconvex optimization, dynamic risk measures, conditional certainty equivalent.

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Key words. quasiconvex functions, dual representation, quasiconvex optimization, dynamic risk measures, conditional certainty equivalent."

Transcription

1 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS MARCO FRITTELLI AND MARCO MAGGIS Abstract. We provide a dual representation of quasiconvex maps π : L F L G, between two locally convex lattices of random variables, in terms of conditional expectations. This generalizes the dual representation of quasiconvex real valued functions π : L F R and the dual representation of conditional convex maps π : L F L G. These results were inspired by the theory of dynamic measurements of risk and are applied in this context. Key words. quasiconvex functions, dual representation, quasiconvex optimization, dynamic risk measures, conditional certainty equivalent. MSC (2010): primary 46N10, 91G99, 60H99; secondary 46A20, 46E Introduction 1. Quasiconvex analysis has important applications in several optimization problems in science, economics and in finance, where convexity may be lost due to absence of global risk aversion, as for example in Prospect Theory [KT92]. The first relevant mathematical findings on quasiconvex functions were provided by De Finetti [DF49] and since then many authors, as [Fe49], [Cr80], [PP84] and [PV90] - to mention just a few, contributed significantly to the subject. More recently, a Decision Theory complete duality involving quasiconvex real valued functions has been proposed by [CMM09b]. For a review of quasiconvex analysis and its applications and for an exhaustive list of references on this topic we refer to Penot [Pe07]. A function f : L R := R { } { } defined on a vector space L is quasiconvex if for all c R the lower level sets {X L f(x) c} are convex. In a general setting, the dual representation of such functions was shown by Penot and Volle [PV90]. The following theorem, reformulated in order to be compared to our results, was proved by Volle [Vo98], Th As shown in the Appendix 5.2, its proof relies on a straightforward application of Hahn Banach Theorem. Theorem 1.1 ([Vo98]). Let L be a locally convex topological vector space, L be its dual space and f : L R := R { } { } be quasiconvex and lower semicontinuous. Then where R : R L R is defined by f(x) = sup X L R(X (X), X ) (1.1) R(t, X ) := inf ξ L {f(ξ) X (ξ) t}. The generality of this theorem rests on the very weak assumptions made on the domain of the function f, i.e., on the space L. On the other hand, the fact that only real valued maps are admitted considerably limits its potential applications, especially in a dynamic framework. To the best of our knowledge, a conditional version of this representation is lacking in the literature. When (Ω, F, (F t ) t 0, P) is a filtered probability space, many Forthcoming on SIAM J. Financial Mathematics Dipartimento di Matematica, Università degli Studi di Milano. Dipartimento di Matematica Università degli Studi di Milano. 1 Acknowledgements We wish to thank Dott. G. Aletti for helpful discussion on this subject. 1

2 2 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS problems having dynamic features lead to the analysis of maps π : L t L s between the subspaces L t L 0 (Ω, F t, P) and L s L 0 (Ω, F s, P), 0 s < t (see Section 1.1 for some examples). In this paper we consider quasiconvex maps of this form and analyze their dual representation. We provide (see Theorem 2.9 and 2.10 for the exact statements) a conditional version of (1.1): where π(x) = ess sup R(E Q [X F s ], Q), (1.2) Q L t P R(Y, Q) := ess inf ξ L t {π(ξ) E Q [ξ F s ] Q Y }, L t L 1 t is the order continuous dual space of L t and { } dq P =: Q << P and Q probability = { ξ L 1 + E P [ξ ] = 1 }. dp With a slight abuse of notation, we write Q L t P instead of dq dp L t P. Furthermore, we prove in Proposition 2.13 that π is quasiconvex, monotone, continuous from below and regular if and only if (1.2) holds with R belonging to the class R of maps S : L 0 s L t L 0 s such that S(, ξ ) is quasiconvex, monotone, continuous from below and regular. If the map π is quasiconvex, monotone and cash additive then we derive from (1.2) the well known representation of a convex conditional risk measure, as in [DS05]. Of course, this is of no surprise since cash additivity and quasiconvexity imply convexity, but it supports the correctness of our dual representation. The formula (1.2) is obtained under quite weak assumptions on the space L t which allow us to consider maps π defined on the typical spaces used in the literature: L (Ω, F t, P), L p (Ω, F t, P), the Orlicz spaces L Ψ (Ω, F t, P). In Theorem 2.9 we assume that π is lower semicontinuous, with respect to the weak topology σ(l t, L t ). As shown in Proposition 2.5 this condition is equivalent to continuity from below, a natural requirement in this context. In Theorem 2.10 instead we provide the dual representation under a strong upper semicontinuity assumption. The proof of our main Theorems 2.9 and 2.10 is not based on techniques similar to those applied in the quasiconvex real valued case [Vo98], nor to those used for convex conditional maps [DS05]. Indeed, the so called scalarization of π via the real valued map X E P [π(x)] does not work, since this scalarization preserves convexity but not quasiconvexity. The idea of our proof is to apply (1.1) to the real valued quasiconvex map π A : L t R defined by π A (X) := ess sup ω A π(x)(ω), A F s, and to approximate π(x) with π Γ (X) := A Γ π A(X)1 A, where Γ is a finite partition of Ω of F s - measurable sets A Γ. As explained in Section 4.1, some delicate issues arise when one tries to apply this simple and natural idea to prove that: ess = ess inf Γ sup Q L t P ess inf ξ L t {π(ξ) E Q [ξ F s ] Q E Q [X F s ]} ess sup Q L t P ess inf ξ L t { π Γ (ξ) E Q [ξ F s ] Q E Q [X F s ] }. (1.3)

3 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 3 The uniform approximation result here needed is stated in the key Lemma 4.3 and the Appendix 5.1 is devoted to prove it. It has recently been shown 2 in [FM10] that results of the same nature, but technically quite different, of those of Theorems 2.9 and 2.10 hold for maps defined on Modules of the L p -type (see [FKV09] for details on this setting). The module approach used in [FM10] permits to prove that the maximum in (2.5) is attained, under the same assumptions of Theorem 2.10, when the maps are defined on Modules of the L p -type. In the present paper we limit ourselves to consider conditional maps π : L t L s and we defer to a forthcoming paper the study of the temporal consistency of the family of maps (π s ) s [0,t], π s : L t L s. The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we introduce the key definitions in order to have all the ingredients to state, in Section 2.1, our main results. Section 3 is a collection of a priori properties about the maps we use to obtain the dual representation. Theorems 2.9 and 2.10, are proved in Section 4 and a brief outline of the proof is there reported to facilitate its understanding. The technical important Lemmas are left to the Appendix, where we also report the proof of Theorem Applications to Finance. As a further motivation for our findings, we give some examples of quasiconvex (quasiconcave) conditional maps arising in economics and finance, which will also be analyzed in details in a future paper. Certainty Equivalent in dynamic settings. Consider a stochastic dynamic utility u : R [0, ) Ω R where: the function x u(x, t, ω) is strictly increasing and concave on R, for almost any ω Ω and for t [0, ); the function u(x, t, ) is F t - measurable for all (x, t) R [0, ). These functions have been recently considered in [MZ06] to develop the theory of forward utility. In [FM11] we defined the Conditional Certainty Equivalent (CCE) of a random variable X L t, as the random variable π(x) L s that is the solution of the equation: u(π(x), s) = E P [u(x, t) F s ]. Thus the CCE defines the valuation operator π : L t L s, π(x) = u 1 (E P [u(x, t) F s ]), s). We showed in [FM11] that the CCE, as a map π : L t L s is monotone, quasi concave, regular and that it admits the (concave version) representation as in (1.2). Static Risk Measures. Our interest in quasiconvex analysis was triggered by the recent paper [CMM09a] on quasiconvex risk measures, where the authors show that it is reasonable to weaken the convexity axiom in the theory of convex risk measures, introduced in [FS02] and [FR02]. In fact when one replaces cash additivity with cash subadditivity (as explained in [ER09]), quasiconvexity and convexity are not anymore equivalent. But the quasiconvexity property is the literal translation of the principle diversification should not increase the risk. The recent interest in quasiconvex static risk measures is also testified by a second paper [DK10] on this subject, that was inspired by [CMM09a] and disclosed after the first version of the present paper. 2 Added in the revision

4 4 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS Dynamic Risk Measures. As already mentioned the dual representation of a conditional convex risk measure can be found in [DS05]. The findings of the present paper show the dual representation of conditional quasiconvex risk measures when cash additivity does not hold true. For a better understanding we give a concrete example: consider a non empty convex set C L (Ω, F t, P) such that C + L + C. The set C represents the future positions considered acceptable by the supervising agency. Let s [0, t]. For all m R denote by v s (m, ω) the price at time s of m euros at time t. The function v s (m, ) will be in general F s measurable as in the case of stochastic discount factor where v s (m, ω) = D s (ω)m. By adapting the definitions in the static framework of [ADEH99] and [CMM09a] we set: ρ s,vs (X)(ω) = ess inf Y L 0 Fs {v s (Y, ω) X + Y C}. When v s is linear, then ρ s,vs is a convex monetary dynamic risk measure, but the linearity of v s may fail when zero coupon bonds with maturity t are illiquid. It seems reasonable to assume that v s (, ω) is increasing and upper semicontinuous and v s (0, ω) = 0, for P almost every ω Ω. In this case ρ s,vs (X)(ω) = v s (ess inf Y L 0 Fs {Y X + Y C}, ω) = v s (ρ s (X), ω), where ρ s (X) is the convex monetary dynamic risk measure induced by the set C. Thus in general ρ s,vs is neither convex nor cash additive, but it is quasiconvex and eventually cash subadditive (under further assumptions on v s ). Acceptability Indices. As studied in [CM09] the index of acceptability is a map α from a space of random variables L(Ω, F, P) to [0, + ) which measures the performance or quality of the random X which may be the terminal cash flow from a trading strategy. Associated with each level x of the index there is a collection of terminal cash flows A x = {X L α(x) x} that are acceptable at this level. The authors in [CM09] suggest four axioms as the stronghold for an acceptability index in the static case: quasiconcavity (i.e., the set A x is convex for every x [0, + )), monotonicity, scale invariance and the Fatou property. It appears natural (see also the recent paper [BCZ10]) 3 to generalize these kind of indices to the conditional case and to this aim we propose a couple of basic examples: i) Conditional Gain Loss Ratio: let F s F t and: CGLR(X F s ) = E P[X F s ] E P [X F s ] 1 {E P [X F s]>0}. This measure is clearly monotone, scale invariant and well defined on L 1 (Ω, F t, P). It can be proved that it is continuous from below and quasiconcave. ii) Conditional Coherent Risk-Adjusted Return on Capital: let F s F t and suppose a coherent conditional risk measure ρ : L(Ω, F t, P) L 0 (Ω, F s, P) is given, where L(Ω, F t, P) L 1 (Ω, F t, P) is any vector space. We define CRARoC(X F s ) = E P[X F s ] 1 {E[X Fs]>0}. ρ(x) 3 Added in the revision

5 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 5 We use the convention that CRARoC(X F s ) = + on the F s -measurable set where ρ(x) 0. Again CRARoC( F s ) is well defined on the space L(Ω, F t, P) and takes values in the space of extended random variables; moreover is monotone, quasiconcave, scale invariant and continuous from below whenever ρ is continuous from above. 2. The dual representation. The probability space (Ω, F, P) is fixed throughout the paper and G F is any sigma algebra contained in F. As usual we denote with L 0 (Ω, F, P) the space of F measurable random variables that are P a.s. finite and by L 0 (Ω, F, P) the space of extended real-valued random variables. The L p (Ω, F, P) spaces, p [0, ], will simply be denoted by L p, unless it is necessary to specify the sigma algebra, in which case we write L p F. In presence of an arbitrary probability measure Q, if confusion may arise, we will explicitly write = Q (resp. Q ), meaning Q almost surely. Otherwise, all equalities/inequalities among random variables are meant to hold P-a.s. Moreover the essential (P almost surely) supremum ess sup λ (X λ ) of an arbitrary family of random variables X λ L 0 (Ω, F, P) will be simply denoted by sup λ (X λ ), and similarly for the essential infimum (see [FS04] Section A.5 for reference). Here we only notice that 1 A sup λ (X λ ) = sup λ (1 A X λ ) for any F measurable set A. Hereafter the symbol denotes inclusion and lattice embedding between two lattices; (resp. ) denotes the essential (P almost surely) maximum (resp. the essential minimum) between two random variables, which are the usual lattice operations. We consider a lattice L F := L(Ω, F, P) L 0 (Ω, F, P) and a lattice L G := L(Ω, G, P) L 0 (Ω, G, P) of F (resp. G) measurable random variables. Therefore, the range of a map π : L F L G includes extended real-valued random variables. Definition 2.1. A map π : L F L G is said to be (MON) monotone increasing if for every X, Y L F X Y π(x) π(y ) ; (QCO) quasiconvex if for every X, Y L F, Λ L 0 G and 0 Λ 1 π(λx + (1 Λ)Y ) π(x) π(y ) ; (LSC) τ lower semicontinuous if the set {X L F π(x) Y } is closed for every Y L G with respect to a topology τ on L F. (CFB) continuous from below if X n X P a.s. π(x n ) π(x) P a.s. (USC) τ strong upper semicontinuous if the set {X L F π(x) < Y } is open for every Y L G with respect to a topology τ on L F and there exists θ L F such that π(θ) < +. Remark 2.2. (On quasiconvexity) As it happens for real valued maps, the definition of (QCO) is equivalent to the fact that Y L G the lower level sets A(Y ) = {X L F π(x) Y } are conditionally convex, i.e., for all X 1, X 2 A(Y ) and for all G-measurable random variables Λ, 0 Λ 1, one has that ΛX 1 +(1 Λ)X 2 A(Y ). Remark 2.3. (On upper semicontinuity) When the map π is real valued then (USC) is equivalent to {X L F π(x) Y } is closed Y R. But when the range of π is L G (a space of random variables) this equivalence does not hold true. Our strong definition (USC) implies that if a net {X α } α L F satisfies

6 6 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS τ X α X then lim supα π(x α ) π(x). Furthermore, this last condition implies that the set {X L F π(x) Y } is closed, i.e., the usual upper semicontinuity (USC) condition, so that (USC) (USC). We are assuming that there exists at least one θ L F such π(θ) < + ; otherwise the set {X L F π(x) < Y } is always empty (and then open) and the condition (USC) looses any meaning. In [BF09] it is proved the equivalence between (CFB) and σ(l F, L F )-(LSC) for monotone convex real valued functions. In the next proposition, we state that this equivalence remains true for monotone quasiconvex conditional maps, under the same assumption on the topology adopted in [BF09]. Therefore, in Theorem 2.9 the σ(l F, L F )-(LSC) condition can be replaced by (CFB), which is often easy to check. Definition 2.4 ([BF09]). A linear topology τ on a Riesz space has the C-property τ if X α X implies the existence of of a sequence {Xαn } n and a convex combination o Z n conv(x αn,...) such that Z n X. As explained in [BF09], the assumption that σ(l F, L F ) has the C-property is very weak and is satisfied in all cases of interest. Proposition 2.5. Suppose that σ(l F, L F ) satisfies the C-property and L F is order complete. If π : L F L G is (MON) and (QCO) then: π is σ(l F, L F )-(LSC) if and only if π is (CFB). We omit the proof since it is a simple extension of the one written in the cited reference. Definition 2.6. A vector space L F L 0 F satisfies the property 1 F if X L F and A F = (X1 A ) L F. (1 F ) Suppose L F (resp. L G ) satisfies property (1 F ) (resp 1 G ). A map π : L F L G is: (REG) regular if for every X, Y L F and A G or equivalently if π(x1 A )1 A = π(x)1 A. π(x1 A + Y 1 A C ) = π(x)1 A + π(y )1 A C 2.1. The representation theorems and their consequences. Standing assumptions In the sequel of the paper it is assumed that: (a) G F and the lattice L F (resp. L G ) satisfies the property (1 F ) (resp 1 G ). Both L G and L F contains the constants as a vector subspace. (b) The order continuous dual of (L F, ), denoted by L F = (L F, ), is a lattice ([AB05], Th. 8.28) that satisfies L F L1 F and property (1 F). (c) The space L F endowed with the weak topology σ(l F, L F ) is a locally convex Riesz space. The condition (c) requires that the order continuous dual L F is rich enough to separate the points of L F, so that (L F,σ(L F, L F )) becomes a locally convex TVS and Proposition 5.5 can be applied. Remark 2.7. Many important classes of spaces satisfy these conditions, such as - The L p -spaces, p [1, ]: L F = L p F, L F = Lq F L1 F. - The Orlicz spaces L Ψ for any Young function Ψ: L F = L Ψ F, L F = LΨ F L1 F, where Ψ denotes the conjugate function of Ψ; - The Morse subspace M Ψ of the Orlicz space L Ψ, for any continuous Young function Ψ: L F = MF Ψ, L F = LΨ F L1 F.

7 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 7 Define K : L F (L F P) L 0 G and R : L0 G L F as K(X, Q) := inf {π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]}, (2.1) R(Y, ξ ) := inf {π(ξ) E P [ξ ξ G] Y }. (2.2) The function K is well defined on L F (L F P), while the actual domain of R is: Σ := {(Y, ξ ) L 0 G L F ξ L F s.t. E P [ξ ξ G] Y }. (2.3) Obviously (E P [ξ X G], ξ ) Σ for every X L F, ξ L F. Notice that K(X, Q) depends on X only through E Q [X G]. Moreover, for every λ > 0, R(E P [ξ X G], ξ ) = R(E P [λξ X G], λξ ). Thus we can consider R(E P [ξ X G], ξ ), ξ 0, ξ 0, always defined on the normalized elements Q L F P. It is easy to check that [ ] dq E P dp ξ G and for Q L F P we deduce E P [ dq dp X G K(X, Q) = R ] E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G], ( [ ] ) dq E P dp X G, Q. Remark 2.8. Since the order continuous functional on L F are contained in L 1, then Q(ξ) := E Q [ξ] is well defined and finite for every ξ L F and Q L F P. In particular this and property (1 F ) imply that E Q [ξ G] is well defined. Moreover, (1 F ) guarantees that dq dp 1 A L F whenever Q L F and A F. Theorem 2.9. Suppose that σ(l F, L F ) has the C-property and L F is order complete. If π : L F L G is (MON), (QCO), (REG) and σ(l F, L F )-(LSC) then π(x) = sup K(X, Q). (2.4) Theorem If π : L F L G is (MON), (QCO), (REG) and τ-(usc) then π(x) = sup K(X, Q). (2.5) Notice that in (2.4) and (2.5) the supremum is taken over the set L F P. In the next corollary, proved in Section 4.2, we show that we match the conditional convex dual representation, by restricting our optimization problem on the set { } dq P G =: Q P and Q = P on G. dp Clearly, when Q P G then L 0 (Ω, G, P) = L 0 (Ω, G, Q) and comparison of G measurable random variables is understood to hold indifferently for P or Q. Corollary Under the same hypothesis of Theorem 2.9 or Theorem 2.10, suppose that for X L F there exists η L F and δ > 0 such that P(π(η) + δ < π(x)) = 1. Then π(x) = sup K(X, Q). (2.6) G

8 8 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS If S : Σ L 0 G then: S(, ξ ) is (REG) if S(Y 1 A, Q)1 A = S(Y, Q)1 A A G; S(, ξ ) is (CFB) if Y n Y, P a.s., and (Y n, ξ ) Σ, (Y, ξ ) Σ imply S(Y n, ξ ) S(Y, ξ ). As shown in the next Proposition, the dual characterization of maps π : L F L G that are (MON), (REG), (QCO) and (CFB) is obtained throught the class: R := { S : Σ L 0 G such that S(, ξ ) is (MON), (REG) and (CFB) }. Remark Any map S : Σ L 0 G such that S(, ξ ) is (MON) and (REG) is automatically (QCO) in the first component. Indeed, let Y 1, Y 2, Λ L 0 G, 0 Λ 1 and define B = {Y 1 Y 2 }, S(, Q) = S( ). Then S(Y 1 1 B ) S(Y 2 1 B ) and S(Y 2 1 B C ) S(Y 1 1 B C ) so that from (MON) and (REG) S(ΛY 1 + (1 Λ)Y 2 ) S(Y 2 1 B + Y 1 1 B C ) = S(Y 2 )1 B + S(Y 1 )1 B C S(Y 1 ) S(Y 2 ). Proposition Suppose that σ(l F, L F ) satisfies the C-property and L F is order complete. The map π : L F L G is (MON), (QCO), (REG) and (CFB) if and only if there exists S R such that π(x) = sup S ( [ ] ) dq E dp X G, Q. (2.7) The proof is based on Theorem 2.9 and is postponed to Section 4.2. In [CMM09b] the authors provide a complete duality for real valued quasiconvex (either USC or LSC) functionals when the space L F is an M-space (such as L ): the idea is to prove a one to one relationship between quasiconvex monotone functionals π and the function R in the dual representation. Obviously R will be unique only in an opportune class of maps satisfying certain properties. A similar result has been recently obtained in [DK10] for general TVS in the LSC real valued case. In the conditional case, uniqueness is a very delicate issue which has only recently been addressed (see [FM10]) 4, but only in the module framework developed in [FKV09]. In the setting of the present paper, a partial result can be easily derived, from the static case, when G is countably generated by a partition {A n } n N and thus the map π is constant on each atom A n. In the following Corollary (proved in Section 4.2) we show that the (MON) property implies that the constraint E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G], in the definition of K(X, Q), may be restricted to E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]. We also show that we may recover, in agreement with [DS05], the dual representation of a dynamic risk measure when π also satisfies the following property: A map π : L F L G is said to be (CAS) cash additive if for all X L F and Λ L G L F π(x + Λ) = π(x) + Λ. Corollary Suppose that E Q [ξ G] L F Q L F P G and ξ L F. (i) If Q L F P G and if π : L F L G is (MON) and (REG), then 4 Added in the revision K(X, Q) = inf {π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] = E Q [X G]} ; (2.8)

9 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 9 if in addition π is (CAS), then: K(X, Q) = E Q [X G] π (Q), (2.9) where π (Q) := sup ξ LF {E Q [ξ G] π(ξ)}. (ii) Under the same hypotheses of Theorem 2.9 or Theorem 2.10 and if π is also (CAS), then: π(x) = sup {E Q [X G] π (Q)}. (2.10) G 3. Preliminary results. In the sequel of the paper π :L F L G is assumed(reg) Properties of R(Y, ξ ). We remind that Σ is the actual domain of R as given in (2.3). For any (Y, ξ ) Σ, we have R(Y, ξ ) = inf A(Y, ξ ) where A(Y, ξ ) := {π(ξ) ξ L F, E P [ξ ξ G] Y }. By convention R(Y, ξ ) = + for every (Y, ξ ) (L 0 G L F ) \ Σ Lemma 3.1. For every (Y, ξ ) Σ the set A(Y, ξ ) is downward directed and therefore there exists a sequence {η m } m=1 L F such that E P [ξ η m G] Y and as m, π(η m ) R(Y, ξ ). Proof. We have to prove that for every π(ξ 1 ), π(ξ 2 ) A(Y, ξ ) there exists π(ξ ) A(Y, ξ ) such that π(ξ ) min{π(ξ 1 ), π(ξ 2 )}. Consider the G-measurable set G = {π(ξ 1 ) π(ξ 2 )} then min{π(ξ 1 ), π(ξ 2 )} = π(ξ 1 )1 G + π(ξ 2 )1 G C = π(ξ 1 1 G + ξ 2 1 G C ) = π(ξ ), where ξ = ξ 1 1 G + ξ 2 1 G C. Hence E P [ξ ξ G] = E P [ξ ξ 1 G]1 G + E P [ξ ξ 2 G]1 G C that we can deduce π(ξ ) A(Y, ξ ). Lemma 3.2. Properties of R(Y, ξ ). i) R(, ξ ) is monotone, for every ξ L F. ii) R(λY, λξ ) = R(Y, ξ ) for any λ > 0, Y L 0 G and ξ L F. iii) For every A G, (Y, ξ ) Σ Y so R(Y, ξ )1 A = inf {π(ξ)1 A E P [ξ ξ G] Y } (3.1) = inf {π(ξ)1 A E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A } = R(Y 1 A, ξ )1 A. (3.2) iv) For every Y 1, Y 2 L 0 G (a) R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) = R(Y 1 Y 2, ξ ) (b) R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) = R(Y 1 Y 2, ξ ) v) The map R(, ξ ) is quasi-affine, i.e., for every Y 1, Y 2, Λ L G and 0 Λ 1, R(ΛY 1 + (1 Λ)Y 2, ξ ) R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) (quasiconcavity) R(ΛY 1 + (1 Λ)Y 2, ξ ) R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) (quasiconvexity). vi) inf Y L 0 G R(Y, ξ 1) = inf Y L 0 G R(Y, ξ 2) for every ξ 1, ξ 2 L F. Proof. (i) and (ii) are trivial. (iii) By definition of the essential infimum one easily deduce (3.1). To prove (3.2), for every ξ L F such that E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A we define the random variable η = ξ1 A + ζ1 A C where E P [ξ ζ G] Y. Then E P [ξ η G] Y and we can conclude {η1 A η L F, E P [ξ η G] Y } = {ξ1 A ξ L F, E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A }.

10 10 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS Hence from (3.1) and (REG): 1 A R(Y, ξ ) = inf η L F {π(η1 A )1 A E P [ξ η G] Y } = inf {π(ξ1 A )1 A E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A } = inf {π(ξ)1 A E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A }. The second equality in (3.2) follows in a similar way. (iv) a): Since R(, ξ ) is monotone, the inequality R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) R(Y 1 Y 2, ξ ) holds true. To show the opposite inequality, define the G-measurable sets: B := {R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ )} and A := {Y 1 Y 2 } so that R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) = R(Y 1, ξ )1 B +R(Y 2, ξ )1 B C R(Y 1, ξ )1 A +R(Y 2, ξ )1 A C (3.3) Set: D(A, Y ) = {ξ1 A ξ L F, E P [ξ ξ1 A G] Y 1 A } and check that D(A, Y 1 ) + D(A C, Y 2 ) = {ξ L F E P [ξ ξ G] Y 1 1 A + Y 2 1 A C } := D From (3.3) and using (3.2) we get: R(Y 1, ξ ) R(Y 2, ξ ) R(Y 1, ξ )1 A + R(Y 2, ξ )1 A C = inf {π(ξ1 A)1 A } + ξ1 A D(A,Y 1) inf η1 A C D(A C,Y 2) = inf ξ1 A D(A,Y 1) {π(ξ1 A )1 A + π(η1 A C )1 A C } η1 A C D(A C,Y 2) = inf {π(ξ1 A + η1 A C )} (ξ1 A +η1 A C ) D(A,Y 1)+D(A C,Y 2) {π(η1 A C )1 A C } = inf ξ D {π(ξ)} = R(Y 11 A + Y 2 1 A C, ξ ) = R(Y 1 Y 2, ξ ). Simile modo: iv) b). (v) Follows from item (iv) and Remark (vi) Trivial generalization of Theorem 2 (H2) in [CMM09b]. Consider the map R + : Σ L 0 G defined by R + (Y, ξ ) = ess sup R(Y, ξ ). (3.4) Y <Y Lemma 3.3. If π : L F L G is (REG) and (MON) then R + R. Proof. Clearly R + (, Q) inherits from R(, Q) the properties (REG) and (MON). From Remark 2.12 we then know that R + (, Q) is (QCO). We show that it is also (CFB). Let Y n Y. It is easy to check that (MON) of R(, ξ ) implies that the set {R(η, ξ ) η < Y } is upward directed. Then for any ε, δ > 0 we can find η ε < Y s.t. P(R + (Y, ξ ) R(η ε, ξ ) < ε) > 1 δ (3.5) There exists an n ε such that P(Y n > η ε ) > 1 δ for every n > n ε. Denote by A n = {Y n > η ε } so that from (REG) we have R + (Y n, ξ )1 An R(η ε, ξ )1 An. This last inequality together with equation (3.5) implies P(R + (Y, ξ ) R + (Y n, ξ ) < ε) > 1 2δ n > n ε, i.e., R + (Y n, Q) P R + (Y, Q). From (MON), R + (Y n, Q) R + (Y, Q) P-a.s.

11 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 11 Proposition 3.4 is in the spirit of [CMM09b]: as a consequence of the dual representation the map π induces on R (resp. R + ) its characteristic properties and so does R (resp. R + ) on π. Recall that (E P [ξ X G], ξ ) Σ for every X L F, ξ L F. Proposition 3.4. Consider a map S : Σ L G. (a) Let χ L F, X L F and π(x) = sup S(E P [Xξ G], ξ ). ξ χ Then for every (Y, ξ ) Σ, A G, λ R +, Λ L G L F i) S(Y 1 A, ξ )1 A = S(Y, ξ )1 A = π (REG); ii) Y S(Y, ξ ) (MON) = π (MON); iii) Y S(Y, ξ ) (QCO) = π (QCO); iv) Y S(Y, ξ ) (CFB) = π (CFB); v) S(λY, ξ ) = S(Y, ξ ) = π(λx) = π(x); vi) S(λY, ξ ) = λs(y, ξ ) = π(λx) = λπ(x); vii) S(E P [(X + Λ)ξ G], ξ ) = S(E P [Xξ G], ξ ) + Λ = π(x + Λ) = π(x) + Λ; viii) S(E P [(X + Λ)ξ G], ξ ) S(E P [Xξ G], ξ ) + Λ = π(x + Λ) π(x) + Λ. (b) When the map S is replaced by R defined in (2.2), all the above items - except (iv) - hold true replacing = by. (c) When the map S is replaced by R + defined in (3.4), all the above items (i)-(viii) hold true replacing = by. Proof. The proofs of all items in (a) are trivial. (b): The implication = in (i) and (ii) follow from Lemma 3.2. We omit the remaining elementary proofs. (c) the implications = in (i) (ii) (iii) and (iv) are proved in Lemma 3.3. The remaining items are easily proved from the corresponding properties of R Properties of K(X, Q) and H(X).. Lemma 3.5. Properties of K(X, Q). Let Q L F P and X L F. i) K(, Q) is monotone and quasi affine. ii) K(X, ) is scaling invariant: K(X, λq) = K(X, Q) for every λ > 0. iii) K(X, Q)1 A = inf ξ LF {π(ξ)1 A E Q [ξ1 A G] Q E Q [X1 A G]} for all A G. iv) There exists a sequence { ξ Q m} m=1 L F such that E Q [ξ Q m G] Q E Q [X G] m 1, π(ξ Q m) K(X, Q) as m. v) The set K = {K(X, Q) Q L F P} is upward directed, i.e., for every K(X, Q 1), K(X, Q 2 ) K there exists K(X, Q) K such that K(X, Q) K(X, Q 1 ) K(X, Q 2 ). vi) Let Q 1 and Q 2 be elements of L dq1 F P and B G. If dp 1 B = dq2 dp 1 B then K(X, Q 1 )1 B = K(X, Q 2 )1 B. Proof. The monotonicity property in (i), (ii) and (iii) are trivial; from Lemma 3.2 v) it follows that K(, Q) is quasi affine; (iv) is a consequence of Lemma 3.1. (v) Define F = {K(X, Q 1 ) K(X, Q 2 )} and let Q given by d Q dp := 1 F dq1 dp + 1 F C dq2 dp ; up to a normalization factor (from property (ii)) we may suppose Q L F P. We need to show that K(X, Q) = K(X, Q 1 ) K(X, Q 2 ) = K(X, Q 1 )1 F + K(X, Q 2 )1 F C. From E Q[ξ G] = Q E Q1 [ξ G]1 F + E Q2 [ξ G]1 F C we get E Q[ξ G]1 F = Q1 E Q1 [ξ G]1 F and E Q[ξ G]1 F C = Q2 E Q2 [ξ G]1 F C. For i = 1, 2, consider the sets  = {ξ L F E Q[ξ G] Q E Q[X G]} A i = {ξ L F E Qi [ξ G] Qi E Qi [X G]}.

12 12 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS For every ξ A 1 define η = ξ1 F + X1 F C Q 1 << P η1 F = Q1 ξ1 F E Q[η G]1 F Q E Q[X G]1 F Q 2 << P η1 F C = Q2 X1 F C E Q[η G]1 F C = Q E Q[X G]1 F C Then η Â and π(ξ)1 F = π(ξ1 F )1 F = π(η1 F )1 F = π(η)1 F. Viceversa, for every η Â define ξ = η1 F + X1 F C. Then ξ A 1 and again π(ξ)1 F = π(η)1 F. Hence inf π(ξ)1 F = inf π(η)1 F. ξ A 1 η Â In a similar way: inf ξ A2 π(ξ)1 F C = inf η Â π(η)1 F C and we can finally deduce K(X, Q 1 ) K(X, Q 2 ) = K(X, Q). (vi). By the same argument used in (v), it can be shown that inf ξ A1 π(ξ)1 B = inf ξ A2 π(ξ)1 B and the thesis. For X L F we define H(X) := sup K(X, Q) = and notice that for all A G H(X)1 A = sup sup inf {π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]} inf {π(ξ)1 A E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]}. Applying Proposition 3.4 we already know the one to one correspondence between the properties of π and those of H. In particular, H is (MON) and the regularity of π implies that H is (REG) (i.e., H(X1 A )1 A = H(X)1 A for any A G). As an immediate consequence of Lemma 3.5 iv) and v) we deduce the next result. Lemma 3.6. Let X L F. There exist a sequence { Q k} k 1 L F P and, { k 1, a sequence ξ Qk m } m 1 L F satisfying E Q k[ξ Qk m G] Q k E Q k[x G] and π(ξ Qk m ) K(X, Q k ) as m, K(X, Q k ) H(X) as k, (3.6) H(X) = lim k lim m π(ξqk m ). (3.7) 3.3. On the map π A. Given π : L F L G we define for every A G, the map π A : L F R by π A (X) := ess sup π(x)(ω). ω A Proposition 3.7. Under the assumptions of Theorem 2.9 or of Theorem 2.10 and for any A G π A (X) = sup inf {π A (ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]}. (3.8) Proof. Notice that the map π A inherits from π the properties (MON) and (QCO). Under the assumptions of Th. 2.9 we get, from Proposition 2.5, that π is (CFB) and this obviously implies that π A is (CFB). Applying to π A Proposition 2.5, which holds also for real valued maps, we deduce that π A is σ(l F, L F )-(LSC).

13 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 13 Under the assumptions of Th we prove that π A is τ-(usc) by showing that c R the set B c := {ξ L F π A (ξ) < c} is τ open. W.l.o.g. B c. If we fix an arbitrary η B c, we may find δ > 0 s.t. π A (η) < c δ. Define B := {ξ L F π(ξ) < (c δ)1 A + (π(η) + δ)1 A C }. Since (c δ)1 A + (π(η) + δ)1 A C L G and π is (USC) we deduce that B is τ open. Moreover π A (ξ) c δ for every ξ B, i.e., B B c, and η B since π(η) < c δ on A and π(η) < π(η) + δ on A C. Applying Theorem 1.1 in the (LSC) case and Theorem 5.4 in the (USC) one then deduce the representation of π A : π A (X) = sup sup inf {π A (ξ) E Q [ξ] E Q [X]} inf {π A (ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]} π A (X). Notice that in case π A is (USC) the sup can be replaced by a max. 4. Proofs of the main results. Notations: In the following, we will only consider finite partitions Γ = { A Γ} of G measurable sets A Γ Γ and we set π Γ (X) : = A Γ Γ π A Γ(X)1 A Γ, K Γ (X, Q) : = inf { π Γ (ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G] } H Γ (X) : = sup K Γ (X, Q) 4.1. Outline of the proof. We anticipate an heuristic sketch of the proof of Theorem 2.9 and Theorem 2.10, pointing out the essential arguments involved in it and we defer to the following section the details and the rigorous statements. Unfortunately, we cannot prove directly that ε > 0, Q ε L F P s.t. {ξ L F E Qε [ξ G] Qε E Qε [X G]} {ξ L F π(ξ) > π(x) ε} (4.1) relying on Hahn-Banach Theorem, as it happened in the real case (see the proof of Theorem 1.1, equation (5.26), in Appendix). Indeed, the complement of the set in the right hand side of (4.1) is not any more a convex set - unless π is real valued - regardless of the continuity assumption made on π. Also the idea applied in the conditional convex case [DS05] can not be used here, since the map X E P [π(x)] there adopted preserves convexity but not quasiconvexity. Then our method is to apply an approximation argument and the choice of approximating π( ) by π Γ ( ), is forced by the need to preserve quasiconvexity. I The first step is to prove (see Proposition 4.4) that: H Γ (X) = π Γ (X). This is based on the representation of the real valued quasiconvex map π A in Proposition 3.7. Therefore, the assumptions (MON), (REG), (QCO) and (LSC) or (USC) on π are here all needed. II Then it is a simple matter to deduce π(x) = inf Γ π Γ (X) = inf Γ H Γ (X), where the inf is taken with respect to all finite partitions. III As anticipated in (1.3), the last step, i.e., proving that inf Γ H Γ (X) = H(X), is more delicate. It can be shown easily that is possible to approximate H(X)

14 14 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS with K(X, Q ε ) on a set A ε of probability arbitrarily close to 1. However, we need the following uniform approximation: For any ε > 0 there exists Q ε L F P such that for any finite partition Γ we have HΓ (X) K Γ (X, Q ε ) < ε on the same set A ε. This key approximation result, based on Lemma 4.3, shows that the element Q ε does not depend on the partition and allows us (see equation (4.7)) to conclude the proof Details. The following two lemmas are straightforward applications of measure theory; the third is the already mentioned key result and it is proved in the Appendix, for it needs a pretty long argument. Lemma 4.1. For every Y L 0 G there exists a sequence Γ(n) of finite partitions such that Γ(n) (sup A Y ) 1 Γ(n) A converges in probability, and P-a.s., to Y, so that Γ(n) for any ε, δ > 0 we may find N such that for Γ = Γ(N) we have: P { ω Ω A Γ Γ ( sup Y A Γ ) 1 A Γ(ω) Y (ω) < δ Lemma 4.2. For each X L F and Q L F P inf Γ KΓ (X, Q) = K(X, Q) } > 1 ε. (4.2) where the infimum is taken with respect to all finite partitions Γ. Lemma 4.3. Let X L F and let P and Q be arbitrary elements of L F P. Suppose there exists ε 0 and B G s.t.: K(X, P )1 B >, π B (X) < + and K(X, Q)1 B K(X, P )1 B + ε1 B. Then for every partition Γ = {B C, Γ}, where Γ is a partition of B, we have K Γ (X, Q)1 B K Γ (X, P )1 B + ε1 B. Since π Γ assumes only a finite number of values, we may apply Proposition 3.7 and deduce the dual representation of π Γ. Proposition 4.4. Suppose that the assumptions of Theorem 2.9 or of Theorem 2.10 hold true and Γ is a finite partition. If for every X L F, π(x) < c with c [0, + ), then: H Γ (X) = π Γ (X) π(x) (4.3) and therefore inf Γ H Γ (X) = π(x). Proof. First notice that K Γ (X, Q) H Γ (X) π Γ (X) < + for all Q L F P. Consider the sigma algebra G Γ := σ(γ) G, generated by the finite partition Γ. From Proposition 3.7 we then have for every A Γ Γ π A Γ(X) = sup inf {π A Γ(ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]}. (4.4) Moreover H Γ (X) is constant on A Γ since it is G Γ -measurable as well. Using the fact that π Γ ( ) is constant on each A Γ, for every A Γ Γ we then have: H Γ { (X)1 A Γ = sup inf π Γ (ξ)1 A Γ E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G] } = sup inf {π A Γ(ξ)1 A Γ E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]} = π A Γ(X)1 A Γ = π Γ (X)1 A Γ (4.5)

15 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 15 where the first equality in (4.5) follows from (4.4). consequence of (4.3) and Lemma 4.1 The remaining statement is a Proof. [of Theorems 2.9 and 2.10] Obviously π(x) H(X), since X satisfies the constraints in the definition of H(X). Step 1. First we assume that π is uniformly bounded, i.e., there exists c > 0 such that for all X L F π(x) c. Then H(X) >. From Lemma 3.6, eq. (3.6), there exists a sequence Q k L F P s.t. K(X, Q k ) H(X), as k. Therefore, for any ε > 0 we may find Q ε L F P and A ε G, P(A ε ) > 1 ε s.t. Since H(X) K(X, Q) Q L F P, H(X)1 Aε K(X, Q ε )1 Aε ε1 Aε. (K(X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε K(X, Q)1 Aε Q L F P. This is the basic inequality that enable us to apply Lemma 4.3, replacing there P with Q ε and B with A ε. Only notice that sup Ω π(x) c and K(X, Q) > for every Q L F P. This Lemma assures that for every partition Γ of Ω (K Γ (X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε K Γ (X, Q)1 Aε Q L F P. (4.6) From the definition of essential supremum of a class of random variables equation (4.6) implies that for every Γ (K Γ (X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε sup K Γ (X, Q)1 Aε = H Γ (X)1 Aε. (4.7) Since π Γ c, applying Proposition 4.4, equation (4.3), we get (K Γ (X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε π(x)1 Aε. Taking the infimum over all possible partitions, as in Lemma 4.2, we deduce: Hence, for any ε > 0 (K(X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε π(x)1 Aε. (4.8) (K(X, Q ε ) + ε)1 Aε π(x)1 Aε H(X)1 Aε K(X, Q ε )1 Aε which implies π(x) = H(X), since P(A ε ) 1 as ε 0. Step 2. Now we consider the case when π is not necessarily bounded. We define the new map ψ( ) := arctan(π( )) and notice that ψ(x) is a G-measurable r.v. satisfying ψ(x) Π 2 for every X L F. Moreover ψ is (MON), (QCO) and ψ(x1 G ) = ψ(x)1 G for every G G. In addition, ψ inherits the (LSC) (resp. the (USC) ) property from π. The first is a simple consequence of (CFB) of π. For the second we may apply Lemma 4.5 below. The map ψ is uniformly bounded and by step 1 we may conclude ψ(x) = H ψ (X) := sup K ψ (X, Q), where

16 16 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS K ψ (X, Q) := inf {ψ(ξ) E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]}. Applying again Lemma 3.6, equation (3.6), there exists Q k L F such that H ψ (X) = lim k K ψ (X, Q k ). We will show below that Admitting this, we have for P-almost every ω Ω K ψ (X, Q k ) = arctan K(X, Q k ). (4.9) arctan(π(x)(ω)) = ψ(x)(ω) = H ψ (X)(ω) = lim k K ψ (X, Q k )(ω) = lim k arctan K(X, Q k )(ω)) = arctan(lim k K(X, Q k )(ω)), where we used the continuity of the function arctan. This implies π(x) = lim k K(X, Q k ) and we conclude: π(x) = lim k K(X, Q k ) H(X) π(x). It only remains to show (4.9). We prove that for every fixed Q L F P K ψ (X, Q) = arctan (K(X, Q)). Since π and ψ are regular, from Lemma 3.5 iv), there exist ξ Q h L F and η Q h L F such that E Q [ξ Q h G] Q E Q [X G], E Q [η Q h G] Q E Q [X G], h 1, (4.10) ψ(ξ Q h ) K ψ(x, Q) and π(η Q h ) K(X, Q), as h. From (4.10) and the definitions of K(X, Q), K ψ (X, Q) and by the continuity and monotonicity of arctan we get: K ψ (X, Q) lim h ψ(η Q h ) = lim h arctan π(ηq h ) = arctan lim h π(ηq h ) = arctan K(X, Q) arctan lim h π(ξ Q h ) = lim h ψ(ξq h ) = K ψ(x, Q). Let Y be G-measurable and define: A := {ξ L F π(ξ) < tan(y )} B := {ξ L F arctan(π(ξ)) < Y }, where tan(y ) = + on { } { } Y π 2 and tan(y ) = on Y π 2. Notice that A = { ξ B π(ξ) < on { }} Y > π 2. Lemma 4.5. Suppose that π is regular and there exists θ L F such that π(θ) < +. For any G-measurable random variable Y, if A is open then also B is open. Proof. We may assume Y π 2, otherwise B =. Let ξ B, θ L F such that π(θ) < +. Define ξ 0 := ξ1 {Y π 2 } + θ1 {Y > π 2 }. Then ξ 0 A. Since A is open, we may find a neighborhood U of 0 such that: ξ 0 + U A. Define: V := (ξ 0 + U)1 {Y π 2 } + (ξ + U)1 {Y > π 2 } = ξ + U1 {Y π 2 } + U1 {Y > π 2 }.

17 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 17 It is easy to show that ξ V and V B. Finally V is a neighborhood of ξ, since the set U1 {Y π 2 } + U1 {Y > π 2 } contains U and therefore is a neighborhood of 0. Proof. [of Proposition 2.13] The if part is trivial, as the various properties are easy to check. For the only if part we already know from Theorem 2.9 that ( [ ] ) dq π(x) = sup R E dp X G, Q, where R is defined in [ (2.2). For every Q L F P we consider R+ (, Q) R(, Q) and denote X Q = E dq dp ]. X G We observe that π(x) δ>0 sup R + (X Q, Q) = sup sup sup R(X Q δ, Q) X Q δ<x Q sup R(Y, Q) Y <X Q = sup sup R(E P [(X δ) dq/dp G], Q) = sup π(x δ) δ>0 and so we have the representation π(x) = δ>0 sup R + (E Q [X G], Q) (CF B) = π(x) and we already know from Lemma 3.3 that R + R. Remark 4.6. Take Q P such that Q P on G and define the probability [ dp Q(F ) := E Q dq G 1 F ] where G dp dq [ dp =: E Q G dq ], F F. Then Q(G) = P(G) for all G G, and so Q P G. Moreover, it is easy to check that for all X L F and Q L F P such that Q P on G we have: E Q[X G] = E Q [X G] which implies K(X, Q) = K(X, Q). Proof. [of Corollary 2.11] Consider the probability Q ε L F P built up in Theorem 2.9, satisfying equation (4.8). We claim that Q ε is equivalent to P on A ε. By contradiction there exists B G, B A ε, such that P(B) > 0 but Q ε (B) = 0. Consider η L F, δ > 0 such that P(π(η)+δ < π(x)) = 1 and define ξ = X1 B C +η1 B so that E Qε [ξ G] Qε E Qε [X G]. By regularity π(ξ) = π(x)1 B C + π(η)1 B which implies for P-a.e. ω B π(ξ)(ω) + δ = π(η)(ω) + δ < π(x)(ω) K(X, Q ε )(ω) + ε π(ξ)(ω) + ε which is impossible for ε δ. So Q ε P on A ε for all small ε δ. Consider Q ε such that d Q ε dp = dqε dp 1 A ε + dp dp 1 (A ε) C. Up to a normalization factor Q ε L F P and is equivalent to P. Moreover from Lemma 3.5 (vi), K(X, Q ε )1 Aε = K(X, Q ε )1 Aε and from Remark 4.6 we may define Q ε P G such that K(X, Q ε )1 Aε =

18 18 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS K(X, Q ε )1 Aε = K(X, Q ε )1 Aε. From (4.8) we finally deduce: K(X, Q ε )1 Aε + ε1 Aε π(x)1 Aε, and the thesis then follows from Q ε P G. Proof. [of Corollary 2.14] First we prove equation (2.8): let us denote with k(x, Q) the right hand side of equation (2.8) and notice that K(X, Q) k(x, Q). By contradiction, suppose that P(A) > 0 where A =: {K(X, Q) < k(x, Q)}. As shown in Lemma 3.5 iv), there exists a random variable ξ L F s.t.: E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G] and Q(E Q [ξ G] > E Q [X G]) > 0. K(X, Q)(ω) π(ξ)(ω) < k(x, Q)(ω) for P-a.e. ω B A and P(B) > 0. Set Z = Q E Q [ξ X G]. By assumption, Z L F and it satisfies Z Q 0 and, since Q P G, Z 0. Then, thanks to (MON), π(ξ) π(ξ Z). From E Q [ξ Z G] = Q E Q [X G] we deduce the contradiction: K(X, Q)(ω) π(ξ)(ω) < k(x, Q)(ω) π(ξ Z)(ω) for P-a.e. ω B. Second we show (2.9). From (2.8) we deduce: K(X, Q) = inf {π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]} = E Q [X G] + inf {π(ξ) E Q [X G] E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]} = E Q [X G] + inf {π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]} = E Q [X G] sup {E Q [ξ G] π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]} = E Q [X G] π (Q), where the last equality follows from Q P G and π (Q) = sup {E Q [ξ + E Q [X ξ G] G] π(ξ + E Q [X ξ G])} = sup η L F {E Q [η G] π(η) η = ξ + E Q [X ξ G]} sup {E Q [ξ G] π(ξ) E Q [ξ G] = Q E Q [X G]} π (Q). (ii) The (CAS) property implies that for every X L F and δ > 0, P(π(X 2δ) + δ < π(x)) = 1. So the hypothesis of Corollary 2.11 holds true and (2.10) is a consequence of (2.9) and (2.6). As noticed in [DS05] and in [CDK06] when L F = L F, the assumption that π is (REG) is not necessary, as (CAS) and (MON) or (CAS) and convexity already imply regularity. 5. Appendix Proof of the key approximation Lemma 4.3. We will adopt the following notations: If Γ 1 and Γ 2 are two finite partitions of G-measurable sets then Γ 1 Γ 2 := {A 1 A 2 A i Γ i, i = 1, 2} is a finite partition finer than each Γ i. Lemma 5.1 is the generalization of Lemma 3.1 to the approximated problem. Lemma 5.1. For every partition Γ, X L F and Q L F P, the set A Γ Q(X) {π Γ (ξ) ξ L F and E Q [ξ G] Q E Q [X G]} is downward directed. This implies that there exists exists a sequence { η Q m} m=1 L F, depending also on Γ, such that E Q [η Q m G] Q E Q [X G] m 1, π Γ (η Q m) K Γ (X, Q) as m.

19 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 19 Proof. To show that the set A Γ Q (X) is downward directed we use the notations and the results in the proof of Lemma 3.1 and check that π Γ (ξ ) = π Γ (ξ 1 1 G + ξ 2 1 G C ) min { π Γ (ξ 1 ), π Γ (ξ 2 ) }. For any given sequence of partition there exists one sequence that works for all: Lemma 5.2. For any fixed, at most countable, family of partitions {Γ(h)} h 1 and Q L F P, there exists a sequence { ξ Q m} m=1 L F such that E Q [ξ Q m G] Q E Q [X G] for all m 1 π(ξ Q m) K(X, Q) as m and for all h π Γ(h) (ξ Q m) K Γ(h) (X, Q) as m. Proof. Apply Lemma 3.1 and Lemma 5.1 and find {ϕ 0 m} m, {ϕ 1 m} m,..., {ϕ h m} m,... such that for every i and m we have E Q [ϕ i m G] Q E Q [X G] and π(ϕ 0 m) K(X, Q) as m and for all h π Γ(h) (ϕ h m) K Γ(h) (X, Q) as m. For each m 1 consider m i=0 π(ϕi m): then there will exists a (non unique) finite partition of Ω, {Fm} i m i=1 such that m m π(ϕ i m) = π(ϕ i m)1 F i m. i=0 i=0 Denote ξm Q m =: i=0 ϕi m1 F i and notice that m m i=0 π(ϕi (REG) m)1 F i m = π ( ξm) Q and E Q [ξm G] Q Q E Q [X G] for every m. Moreover π(ξm) Q is decreasing and π(ξm) Q π(ϕ 0 m) implies π(ξm) Q K(X, Q). For any fixed h, π(ξm) Q π(ϕ h m) for all h m and: π Γ(h) (ξ Q m) π Γ(h) (ϕ h m) implies π Γ(h) (ξ Q m) K Γ(h) (X, Q) as m. Finally, we state the basic step used in the proof of Lemma 4.3. Lemma 5.3. Let X L F and let P and Q be arbitrary elements of L F P. Suppose there exists ε 0 and B G s.t.: K(X, P )1 B >, π B (X) < + and K(X, Q)1 B K(X, P )1 B + ε1 B. Then for any δ > 0 and any partition Γ 0 there exists Γ Γ 0 for which K Γ (X, Q)1 B K Γ (X, P )1 B + ε1 B + δ1 B Proof. By our assumptions we have: < K(X, P )1 B π B (X) < + and K(X, Q)1 B π B (X) < +. Fix δ > 0 and the partition Γ 0. Suppose by contradiction that for any Γ Γ 0 we have P(C) > 0 where C = {ω B K Γ (X, Q)(ω) > K Γ (X, P )(ω) + ε + δ}. (5.1)

20 20 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS Notice that C is the union of a finite number { of} elements in the partition Γ. Lemma 3.5 guarantees the existence of ξ Q h L F satisfying: π(ξ Q h ) K(X, Q), as h,, E Q[ξ Q h G] Q E Q [X G] h 1. (5.2) Moreover, for each partition Γ and h 1 define: { Dh Γ := ω Ω π Γ (ξ Q h )(ω) π(ξq h )(ω) < δ } G, 4 h=1 and observe that π Γ (ξ Q h ) decreases if we pass to finer partitions. From Lemma 4.1 equation (4.2), we deduce that for each h 1 there exists a partition( Γ(h) such ) that ( ) h P D Γ(h) h 1 1. For every h 1 define the new partition Γ(h) = Γ(h) Γ 2 h 0 j=1 ( ) so that for all h 1 we have: Γ(h + 1) Γ(h) Γ 0, P D Γ(h) h 1 1 and 2 h ( π(ξ Q h ) + δ ) ) 1 Γ(h) 4 D (π Γ(h) (ξ Qh ) 1 Γ(h) h D, h 1. (5.3) h Lemma 5.2 guarantees that for the fixed sequence of partitions {Γ(h)} h 1, there exists a sequence { ξ P m} m=1 L F, which does not depend on h, satisfying For each m 1 and Γ(h) define: C Γ(h) m := E P [ξ P m G] P E P [X G] m 1, (5.4) π Γ(h) (ξ P m) K Γ(h) (X, P ), as m, h 1. (5.5) { ω C π Γ(h) (ξ P m)(ω) K Γ(h) (X, P )(ω) δ 4 } G. Since the expressions in the definition of Cm Γ(h) assume only a finite number of values, from (5.5) and from our assumptions, which imply that K Γ(h) (X, P ) K(X, P ) > ( on B, we deduce ) that for each Γ(h) there exists an index m(γ(h)) such that: P C \ C Γ(h) m(γ(h)) = 0 and Set E h = D Γ(h) h ( K Γ(h) (X, P )1 Γ(h) C π Γ(h) (ξm(γ(h)) P ) δ ) 1 Γ(h) m(γ(h)) 4 C, h 1. (5.6) m(γ(h)) C Γ(h) m(γ(h)) G and observe that From (5.3) and (5.6) we then deduce: ( π(ξ Q h ) + δ 4 K Γ(h) (X, P )1 Eh 1 Eh 1 C P a.s. (5.7) ) ) 1 Eh (π Γ(h) (ξ Qh ) ( π Γ(h) (ξ P m(γ(h)) ) δ 4 1 Eh, h 1, (5.8) ) 1 Eh, h 1. (5.9)

21 DUAL REPRESENTATION OF QUASICONVEX CONDITIONAL MAPS 21 We then have for any h 1 π(ξ Q h )1 E h + δ 4 1 E h (π Γ(h) (ξ Qh ) ) 1 Eh (5.10) K Γ(h) (X, Q)1 Eh (5.11) ( ) K Γ(h) (X, P ) + ε + δ 1 Eh (5.12) (π Γ(h) (ξ Pm(Γ(h)) ) δ4 ) + ε + δ 1 Eh (5.13) (π(ξ Pm(Γ(h)) ) + ε + 34 ) δ 1 Eh. (5.14) (in the above chain of inequalities, (5.10) follows from (5.8); (5.11) follows from (5.2) and the definition of K Γ(h) (X, Q); (5.12) follows from (5.1); (5.13) follows from (5.9); (5.14) follows from the definition of the maps π A Γ(h)). Recalling (5.4) we then get, for each h 1, π(ξ Q h )1 E h ( π(ξm(γ(h)) P ) + ε + δ ) ( 1 Eh K(X, P ) + ε + δ ) 1 Eh >. (5.15) 2 2 From equation (5.2) and (5.7) we have π(ξ Q h )1 E h K(X, Q)1 C P-a.s. as h and so from (5.15) ( 1 C K(X, Q) = lim π(ξ Q h )1 E h lim 1 Eh K(X, P ) + ε + δ ) ( = 1 C K(X, P ) + ε + δ ) h h 2 2 which contradicts the assumption of the Lemma, since C B and P(C) > 0. Proof. [of Lemma 4.3] First notice that the assumptions of this Lemma are those of Lemma 5.3. Assume by contradiction that there exists Γ 0 = {B C, Γ 0 }, where Γ 0 is a partition of B, such that P(ω B K Γ0 (X, Q)(ω) > K Γ0 (X, P )(ω) + ε) > 0. (5.16) By our assumptions we have K Γ0 (X, P )1 B K(X, P )1 B > and K Γ0 (X, Q)1 B π B (X)1 B < +. Since K Γ0 is constant on every element A Γ0 Γ 0, we denote with K AΓ 0 (X, Q) the value that the random variable K Γ0 (X, Q) assumes on A Γ0. From (5.16) we deduce that there exists ÂΓ0 B, Â Γ0 Γ 0, such that Let then d > 0 be defined by + > KÂΓ 0 (X, Q) > KÂΓ 0 (X, P ) + ε >. d =: KÂΓ 0 (X, Q) KÂΓ 0 (X, P ) ε. (5.17) Apply Lemma 5.3 with δ = d 3 : then there exists Γ Γ 0 (w.l.o.g. Γ = {B C, Γ} where Γ Γ 0 ) such that K Γ (X, Q)1 B ( K Γ (X, P ) + ε + δ ) 1 B. (5.18)

22 22 M. FRITTELLI AND M. MAGGIS Considering only the two partitions Γ and Γ 0, we may apply Lemma 5.2 and conclude that there exist two sequences {ξ P h } h=1 L F and {ξ Q h } h=1 L F satisfying as h : E P [ξ P h G] P E P [X G], π Γ0 (ξ P h ) K Γ0 (X, P ), π Γ (ξ P h ) K Γ (X, P ) (5.19) E Q [ξ Q h G] Q E Q [X G], π Γ0 (ξ Q h ) KΓ0 (X, Q), π Γ (ξ Q h ) KΓ (X, Q) (5.20) Since K Γ0 (X, P ) is constant and finite on ÂΓ0, from (5.19) we find h 1 1 s.t. πâγ 0 (ξ P h ) KÂΓ 0 (X, P ) < d 2, h h 1. (5.21) From equation (5.17) and (5.21) we deduce that πâγ 0 (ξh P ) < KÂΓ 0 (X, P ) + d 2 = KÂΓ 0 (X, Q) ε d + d 2, h h 1, and therefore, knowing from (5.20) that KÂΓ 0 (X, Q) πâγ 0 (ξ Q h ), πâγ 0 (ξ P h ) + d 2 < π Â Γ 0 (ξq h ) ε h h 1. (5.22) We now take into account all the sets A Γ ÂΓ0 B. For the convergence of π A Γ(ξ Q h ) we distinguish two cases. On those sets A Γ for which K AΓ (X, Q) > we may find, from (5.20), h 1 such that Then using (5.18) and (5.19) we have π A Γ(ξ Q h ) KAΓ (X, Q) < δ 2 h h. so that π A Γ(ξ Q h ) < KAΓ (X, Q) + δ 2 KAΓ (X, P ) + ε + δ + δ 2 π A Γ(ξP h ) + ε + δ + δ 2 π A Γ(ξ Q h ) < π A Γ(ξP h ) + ε + 3δ 2 h h. On the other hand, on those sets A Γ for which K AΓ (X, Q) = the convergence (5.20) guarantees the existence of ĥ 1 for which we obtain again: π A Γ(ξ Q h ) < π A Γ(ξP h ) + ε + 3δ 2 h ĥ (5.23) (notice that K Γ (X, P ) K(X, P )1 B > and (5.19) imply that π A Γ(ξh P ) converges to a finite value, for A Γ B). Since the partition Γ is finite there exists h 2 1 such that equation (5.23) stands for every A Γ ÂΓ0 and for every h h 2 and for our choice of δ = d 3 (5.23) becomes π A Γ(ξ Q h ) < π A Γ(ξP h ) + ε + d 2 h h 2 A Γ ÂΓ0. (5.24) Fix h > max{h 1, h 2 } and consider the value πâγ 0 (ξ Q h ). Then among all A Γ ÂΓ0 we may find B Γ ÂΓ0 such that π B Γ(ξ Q h ) = πâγ 0 (ξ Q h ). Thus: πâγ 0 (ξ Q h ) = π B Γ(ξ Q h ) (5.24) < π B Γ(ξh P ) + ε + d 2 π Â Γ 0 (ξp h ) + ε + d (5.22) < πâγ 2 0 (ξ Q h ). which is a contradiction.

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance Definitions and properties of Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance First Part: Convex Marco Frittelli Milano University The Fields Institute, Toronto, April 2010 Definitions and

More information

On Quasi-convex Risk Measures

On Quasi-convex Risk Measures On Quasi-convex Risk Measures Marco Frittelli based on joint papers with Marco Maggis Perspectives in Analysis and Probability Conference in Honor of Freddy Delbaen ETH Zurich September 24-28, 2012 Marco

More information

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions Samuel Drapeau Michael Kupper Ranja Reda October 6, 21 We give robust representations of law-invariant monotone quasiconvex functions.

More information

B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces

B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces B.1 B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces B.1. Fréchet spaces. In this appendix we go through the definition of Fréchet spaces and their inductive limits, such as they are used for definitions of function

More information

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation 4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation We consider a discrete-time information structure given by a filtration (F t ) t=0,...,t on our probability space (Ω, F, P ). The time horizon

More information

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q)

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) Andreas Löhne May 2, 2005 (last update: November 22, 2005) Abstract We investigate two types of semicontinuity for set-valued

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples

Dynamic risk measures. Robust representation and examples VU University Amsterdam Faculty of Sciences Jagiellonian University Faculty of Mathematics and Computer Science Joint Master of Science Programme Dorota Kopycka Student no. 1824821 VU, WMiI/69/04/05 UJ

More information

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory Part V 7 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets Lebesgue Integration Theory Definition 7. (Preliminary). A measure on a set is a function :2 [ ] such that. () = 2. If { } = is a finite

More information

Pareto optimal allocations and optimal risk sharing for quasiconvex risk measures

Pareto optimal allocations and optimal risk sharing for quasiconvex risk measures Pareto optimal allocations and optimal risk sharing for quasiconvex risk measures Elisa Mastrogiacomo University of Milano-Bicocca, Italy (joint work with Prof. Emanuela Rosazza Gianin) Second Young researchers

More information

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Stochastic Processes and their Applications 121 (2011) 185 211 www.elsevier.com/locate/spa Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I Erhan Bayraktar, Song Yao Department of Mathematics, University

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

Strongly Consistent Multivariate Conditional Risk Measures

Strongly Consistent Multivariate Conditional Risk Measures Strongly Consistent Multivariate Conditional Risk Measures annes offmann Thilo Meyer-Brandis regor Svindland January 11, 2016 Abstract We consider families of strongly consistent multivariate conditional

More information

2) Let X be a compact space. Prove that the space C(X) of continuous real-valued functions is a complete metric space.

2) Let X be a compact space. Prove that the space C(X) of continuous real-valued functions is a complete metric space. University of Bergen General Functional Analysis Problems with solutions 6 ) Prove that is unique in any normed space. Solution of ) Let us suppose that there are 2 zeros and 2. Then = + 2 = 2 + = 2. 2)

More information

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces Part III 10 Topological Space Basics Topological Spaces Using the metric space results above as motivation we will axiomatize the notion of being an open set to more general settings. Definition 10.1.

More information

Dynamic Assessment Indices

Dynamic Assessment Indices Dynamic Assessment Indices Tomasz R. Bielecki Department of Applied Mathematics, Illinois Institute of Technology, Chicago, 60616 IL, USA bielecki@iit.edu Samuel Drapeau Humboldt-Universität Berlin, Unter

More information

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 8, 2014, no. 109, 5439-5447 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2014.43176 Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued

More information

ON THE EQUIVALENCE OF CONGLOMERABILITY AND DISINTEGRABILITY FOR UNBOUNDED RANDOM VARIABLES

ON THE EQUIVALENCE OF CONGLOMERABILITY AND DISINTEGRABILITY FOR UNBOUNDED RANDOM VARIABLES Submitted to the Annals of Probability ON THE EQUIVALENCE OF CONGLOMERABILITY AND DISINTEGRABILITY FOR UNBOUNDED RANDOM VARIABLES By Mark J. Schervish, Teddy Seidenfeld, and Joseph B. Kadane, Carnegie

More information

2 Lebesgue integration

2 Lebesgue integration 2 Lebesgue integration 1. Let (, A, µ) be a measure space. We will always assume that µ is complete, otherwise we first take its completion. The example to have in mind is the Lebesgue measure on R n,

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

Introduction and Preliminaries

Introduction and Preliminaries Chapter 1 Introduction and Preliminaries This chapter serves two purposes. The first purpose is to prepare the readers for the more systematic development in later chapters of methods of real analysis

More information

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS

CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS CONDITIONAL ACCEPTABILITY MAPPINGS AS BANACH-LATTICE VALUED MAPPINGS RAIMUND KOVACEVIC Department of Statistics and Decision Support Systems, University of Vienna, Vienna, Austria Abstract. Conditional

More information

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Andreas H. Hamel Abstract Recently defined concepts such as nonlinear separation functionals due to

More information

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces Course 212: Academic Year 1991-2 Section 1: Metric Spaces D. R. Wilkins Contents 1 Metric Spaces 3 1.1 Distance Functions and Metric Spaces............. 3 1.2 Convergence and Continuity in Metric Spaces.........

More information

2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets

2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets 2. The Concept of Convergence: Ultrafilters and Nets NOTE: AS OF 2008, SOME OF THIS STUFF IS A BIT OUT- DATED AND HAS A FEW TYPOS. I WILL REVISE THIS MATE- RIAL SOMETIME. In this lecture we discuss two

More information

Coherent risk measures

Coherent risk measures Coherent risk measures Foivos Xanthos Ryerson University, Department of Mathematics Toµɛας Mαθηµατ ικὼν, E.M.Π, 11 Noɛµβρὶoυ 2015 Research interests Financial Mathematics, Mathematical Economics, Functional

More information

Convex Optimization Notes

Convex Optimization Notes Convex Optimization Notes Jonathan Siegel January 2017 1 Convex Analysis This section is devoted to the study of convex functions f : B R {+ } and convex sets U B, for B a Banach space. The case of B =

More information

Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function

Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function Marco Frittelli Milano University, email: marco.frittelli@unimi.it Marco Maggis Milano University, email: marco.maggis@unimi.it Ilaria

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Topic 7: Quasiconvex Functions I 7.1 Level sets of functions For an extended real-valued

More information

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA address:

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA  address: Topology Xiaolong Han Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA E-mail address: Xiaolong.Han@csun.edu Remark. You are entitled to a reward of 1 point toward a homework

More information

Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction. What is wrong with Riemann integration?

Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction. What is wrong with Riemann integration? Lebesgue Integration: A non-rigorous introduction What is wrong with Riemann integration? xample. Let f(x) = { 0 for x Q 1 for x / Q. The upper integral is 1, while the lower integral is 0. Yet, the function

More information

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Main Definitions We start with providing the central definitions of convex functions and convex sets. Definition 1. A function f : R n R + } is called convex,

More information

Recall that if X is a compact metric space, C(X), the space of continuous (real-valued) functions on X, is a Banach space with the norm

Recall that if X is a compact metric space, C(X), the space of continuous (real-valued) functions on X, is a Banach space with the norm Chapter 13 Radon Measures Recall that if X is a compact metric space, C(X), the space of continuous (real-valued) functions on X, is a Banach space with the norm (13.1) f = sup x X f(x). We want to identify

More information

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions

The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions The Subdifferential of Convex Deviation Measures and Risk Functions Nicole Lorenz Gert Wanka In this paper we give subdifferential formulas of some convex deviation measures using their conjugate functions

More information

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND CHAPTER A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND POSITIVE OPERATORS In tis capter we give a brief introduction to Banac lattices and positive operators. Most results of tis capter can be found, e.g.,

More information

LECTURE 3 Functional spaces on manifolds

LECTURE 3 Functional spaces on manifolds LECTURE 3 Functional spaces on manifolds The aim of this section is to introduce Sobolev spaces on manifolds (or on vector bundles over manifolds). These will be the Banach spaces of sections we were after

More information

Probability and Measure

Probability and Measure Part II Year 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2018 84 Paper 4, Section II 26J Let (X, A) be a measurable space. Let T : X X be a measurable map, and µ a probability

More information

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Prakash Balachandran Department of Mathematics Duke University April 2, 2008 1 Review of Discrete-Time

More information

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ.

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ. Convexity in R n Let E be a convex subset of R n. A function f : E (, ] is convex iff f(tx + (1 t)y) (1 t)f(x) + tf(y) x, y E, t [0, 1]. A similar definition holds in any vector space. A topology is needed

More information

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University February 7, 2007 2 Contents 1 Metric Spaces 1 1.1 Basic definitions...........................

More information

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due ). Show that the open disk x 2 + y 2 < 1 is a countable union of planar elementary sets. Show that the closed disk x 2 + y 2 1 is a countable

More information

Rapporto n Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function. Marco Fritelli, Marco Maggis, Ilaria Peri.

Rapporto n Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function. Marco Fritelli, Marco Maggis, Ilaria Peri. Rapporto n. 225 Risk Measures on P(R) and Value At Risk with Probability/Loss function Marco Fritelli, Marco Maggis, Ilaria Peri Marzo 2012 Dipartimento di Metodi Quantitativi per le Scienze Economiche

More information

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. Minimization Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. 1 Minimization A Topological Result. Let S be a topological

More information

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond Measure Theory on Topological Spaces Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond May 22, 2011 Contents 1 Introduction 2 1.1 The Riemann Integral........................................ 2 1.2 Measurable..............................................

More information

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε 1. Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem

E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem E. The Hahn-Banach Theorem This Appendix contains several technical results, that are extremely useful in Functional Analysis. The following terminology is useful in formulating the statements. Definitions.

More information

6 Classical dualities and reflexivity

6 Classical dualities and reflexivity 6 Classical dualities and reflexivity 1. Classical dualities. Let (Ω, A, µ) be a measure space. We will describe the duals for the Banach spaces L p (Ω). First, notice that any f L p, 1 p, generates the

More information

A NICE PROOF OF FARKAS LEMMA

A NICE PROOF OF FARKAS LEMMA A NICE PROOF OF FARKAS LEMMA DANIEL VICTOR TAUSK Abstract. The goal of this short note is to present a nice proof of Farkas Lemma which states that if C is the convex cone spanned by a finite set and if

More information

Set theory and topology

Set theory and topology arxiv:1306.6926v1 [math.ho] 28 Jun 2013 Set theory and topology An introduction to the foundations of analysis 1 Part II: Topology Fundamental Felix Nagel Abstract We provide a formal introduction into

More information

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming 1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming Formally, a stochastic dynamic program has the same components as a deterministic one; the only modification is to the state transition equation. When events in the future

More information

Journal of Mathematical Economics. Coherent risk measures in general economic models and price bubbles

Journal of Mathematical Economics. Coherent risk measures in general economic models and price bubbles Journal of Mathematical Economics ( ) Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of Mathematical Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jmateco Coherent risk measures in general

More information

Math 350 Fall 2011 Notes about inner product spaces. In this notes we state and prove some important properties of inner product spaces.

Math 350 Fall 2011 Notes about inner product spaces. In this notes we state and prove some important properties of inner product spaces. Math 350 Fall 2011 Notes about inner product spaces In this notes we state and prove some important properties of inner product spaces. First, recall the dot product on R n : if x, y R n, say x = (x 1,...,

More information

Weak Topologies, Reflexivity, Adjoint operators

Weak Topologies, Reflexivity, Adjoint operators Chapter 2 Weak Topologies, Reflexivity, Adjoint operators 2.1 Topological vector spaces and locally convex spaces Definition 2.1.1. [Topological Vector Spaces and Locally convex Spaces] Let E be a vector

More information

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries Chapter 1 Measure Spaces 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets 1.1.1 Notation and preliminaries We shall denote by X a nonempty set, by P(X) the set of all parts (i.e., subsets) of X, and by the empty set.

More information

Problem List MATH 5143 Fall, 2013

Problem List MATH 5143 Fall, 2013 Problem List MATH 5143 Fall, 2013 On any problem you may use the result of any previous problem (even if you were not able to do it) and any information given in class up to the moment the problem was

More information

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities

Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lecture 4: Lebesgue spaces and inequalities 1 of 10 Course: Theory of Probability I Term: Fall 2013 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 4 Lebesgue spaces and inequalities Lebesgue spaces We have seen how

More information

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann

HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS. Josef Teichmann HOPF S DECOMPOSITION AND RECURRENT SEMIGROUPS Josef Teichmann Abstract. Some results of ergodic theory are generalized in the setting of Banach lattices, namely Hopf s maximal ergodic inequality and the

More information

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Moulinath Banerjee May 18, 2010 1 Extended Weak Convergence The lack of measurability of the empirical process with respect to the sigma-field generated

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces. 1. Boundedness, continuity, operator norms

08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces. 1. Boundedness, continuity, operator norms (February 24, 2017) 08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/real/notes 2016-17/08a-ops

More information

at time t, in dimension d. The index i varies in a countable set I. We call configuration the family, denoted generically by Φ: U (x i (t) x j (t))

at time t, in dimension d. The index i varies in a countable set I. We call configuration the family, denoted generically by Φ: U (x i (t) x j (t)) Notations In this chapter we investigate infinite systems of interacting particles subject to Newtonian dynamics Each particle is characterized by its position an velocity x i t, v i t R d R d at time

More information

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION HALUK ERGIN AND TODD SARVER Abstract. Suppose (i) X is a separable Banach space, (ii) C is a convex subset of X that is a Baire space (when endowed

More information

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s.

If Y and Y 0 satisfy (1-2), then Y = Y 0 a.s. 20 6. CONDITIONAL EXPECTATION Having discussed at length the limit theory for sums of independent random variables we will now move on to deal with dependent random variables. An important tool in this

More information

REAL RENORMINGS ON COMPLEX BANACH SPACES

REAL RENORMINGS ON COMPLEX BANACH SPACES REAL RENORMINGS ON COMPLEX BANACH SPACES F. J. GARCÍA PACHECO AND A. MIRALLES Abstract. In this paper we provide two ways of obtaining real Banach spaces that cannot come from complex spaces. In concrete

More information

Semicontinuous functions and convexity

Semicontinuous functions and convexity Semicontinuous functions and convexity Jordan Bell jordan.bell@gmail.com Department of Mathematics, University of Toronto April 3, 2014 1 Lattices If (A, ) is a partially ordered set and S is a subset

More information

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor)

Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Dynkin (λ-) and π-systems; monotone classes of sets, and of functions with some examples of application (mainly of a probabilistic flavor) Matija Vidmar February 7, 2018 1 Dynkin and π-systems Some basic

More information

Contents. Index... 15

Contents. Index... 15 Contents Filter Bases and Nets................................................................................ 5 Filter Bases and Ultrafilters: A Brief Overview.........................................................

More information

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM We begin our study by identifying certain special kinds of linear functionals on certain special vector spaces of functions. We describe these linear functionals

More information

= ϕ r cos θ. 0 cos ξ sin ξ and sin ξ cos ξ. sin ξ 0 cos ξ

= ϕ r cos θ. 0 cos ξ sin ξ and sin ξ cos ξ. sin ξ 0 cos ξ 8. The Banach-Tarski paradox May, 2012 The Banach-Tarski paradox is that a unit ball in Euclidean -space can be decomposed into finitely many parts which can then be reassembled to form two unit balls

More information

Lyapunov Stability Theory

Lyapunov Stability Theory Lyapunov Stability Theory Peter Al Hokayem and Eduardo Gallestey March 16, 2015 1 Introduction In this lecture we consider the stability of equilibrium points of autonomous nonlinear systems, both in continuous

More information

Integration on Measure Spaces

Integration on Measure Spaces Chapter 3 Integration on Measure Spaces In this chapter we introduce the general notion of a measure on a space X, define the class of measurable functions, and define the integral, first on a class of

More information

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 The Annals of Applied Probability 1999, Vol. 9, No. 3, 94 95 THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1 By D. Kramkov 2 and W. Schachermayer Steklov Mathematical

More information

Optimization Theory. A Concise Introduction. Jiongmin Yong

Optimization Theory. A Concise Introduction. Jiongmin Yong October 11, 017 16:5 ws-book9x6 Book Title Optimization Theory 017-08-Lecture Notes page 1 1 Optimization Theory A Concise Introduction Jiongmin Yong Optimization Theory 017-08-Lecture Notes page Optimization

More information

6 Lecture 6: More constructions with Huber rings

6 Lecture 6: More constructions with Huber rings 6 Lecture 6: More constructions with Huber rings 6.1 Introduction Recall from Definition 5.2.4 that a Huber ring is a commutative topological ring A equipped with an open subring A 0, such that the subspace

More information

The Lebesgue Integral

The Lebesgue Integral The Lebesgue Integral Brent Nelson In these notes we give an introduction to the Lebesgue integral, assuming only a knowledge of metric spaces and the iemann integral. For more details see [1, Chapters

More information

Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory

Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory Lecture Notes Introduction to Ergodic Theory Tiago Pereira Department of Mathematics Imperial College London Our course consists of five introductory lectures on probabilistic aspects of dynamical systems,

More information

s P = f(ξ n )(x i x i 1 ). i=1

s P = f(ξ n )(x i x i 1 ). i=1 Compactness and total boundedness via nets The aim of this chapter is to define the notion of a net (generalized sequence) and to characterize compactness and total boundedness by this important topological

More information

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han Set, functions and Euclidean space Seungjin Han September, 2018 1 Some Basics LOGIC A is necessary for B : If B holds, then A holds. B A A B is the contraposition of B A. A is sufficient for B: If A holds,

More information

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 CHRISTIAN LÉONARD Contents Preliminaries 1 1. Convexity without topology 1 2. Convexity

More information

Document downloaded from: This paper must be cited as:

Document downloaded from:  This paper must be cited as: Document downloaded from: http://hdl.handle.net/10251/50602 This paper must be cited as: Pedraza Aguilera, T.; Rodríguez López, J.; Romaguera Bonilla, S. (2014). Convergence of fuzzy sets with respect

More information

Ergodic Theorems. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539. Taken from Probability: Theory and examples by R.

Ergodic Theorems. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539. Taken from Probability: Theory and examples by R. Ergodic Theorems Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Taken from Probability: Theory and examples by R. Durrett Samy T. Ergodic theorems Probability Theory 1 / 92 Outline 1 Definitions

More information

EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR QUASILINEAR HEMIVARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES AT RESONANCE. Leszek Gasiński

EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR QUASILINEAR HEMIVARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES AT RESONANCE. Leszek Gasiński DISCRETE AND CONTINUOUS Website: www.aimsciences.org DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS SUPPLEMENT 2007 pp. 409 418 EXISTENCE RESULTS FOR QUASILINEAR HEMIVARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES AT RESONANCE Leszek Gasiński Jagiellonian

More information

Lebesgue Measure on R n

Lebesgue Measure on R n CHAPTER 2 Lebesgue Measure on R n Our goal is to construct a notion of the volume, or Lebesgue measure, of rather general subsets of R n that reduces to the usual volume of elementary geometrical sets

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Chapter 4 GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION Alberto Cambini Department of Statistics and Applied Mathematics University of Pisa, Via Cosmo Ridolfi 10 56124

More information

Topologies, ring norms and algebra norms on some algebras of continuous functions.

Topologies, ring norms and algebra norms on some algebras of continuous functions. Topologies, ring norms and algebra norms on some algebras of continuous functions. Javier Gómez-Pérez Javier Gómez-Pérez, Departamento de Matemáticas, Universidad de León, 24071 León, Spain. Corresponding

More information

On duality theory of conic linear problems

On duality theory of conic linear problems On duality theory of conic linear problems Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 3332-25, USA e-mail: ashapiro@isye.gatech.edu

More information

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures

CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures CVaR and Examples of Deviation Risk Measures Jakub Černý Department of Probability and Mathematical Statistics Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance November 10, 2014 1 / 25 Contents CVaR - Dual

More information

CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS

CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS CHAPTER II THE HAHN-BANACH EXTENSION THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE OF LINEAR FUNCTIONALS In this chapter we deal with the problem of extending a linear functional on a subspace Y to a linear functional on the

More information

Discrete-Time Market Models

Discrete-Time Market Models Discrete-Time Market Models 80-646-08 Stochastic Calculus I Geneviève Gauthier HEC Montréal I We will study in depth Section 2: The Finite Theory in the article Martingales, Stochastic Integrals and Continuous

More information

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide

Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide aliprantis.tex May 10, 2011 Aliprantis, Border: Infinite-dimensional Analysis A Hitchhiker s Guide Notes from [AB2]. 1 Odds and Ends 2 Topology 2.1 Topological spaces Example. (2.2) A semimetric = triangle

More information

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1)

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1) 1.4. CONSTRUCTION OF LEBESGUE-STIELTJES MEASURES In this section we shall put to use the Carathéodory-Hahn theory, in order to construct measures with certain desirable properties first on the real line

More information

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded

Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded Coherent and convex monetary risk measures for unbounded càdlàg processes Patrick Cheridito ORFE Princeton University Princeton, NJ, USA dito@princeton.edu Freddy Delbaen Departement für Mathematik ETH

More information

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers.

2. Dual space is essential for the concept of gradient which, in turn, leads to the variational analysis of Lagrange multipliers. Chapter 3 Duality in Banach Space Modern optimization theory largely centers around the interplay of a normed vector space and its corresponding dual. The notion of duality is important for the following

More information

Notes on Ordered Sets

Notes on Ordered Sets Notes on Ordered Sets Mariusz Wodzicki September 10, 2013 1 Vocabulary 1.1 Definitions Definition 1.1 A binary relation on a set S is said to be a partial order if it is reflexive, x x, weakly antisymmetric,

More information

The optimal partial transport problem

The optimal partial transport problem The optimal partial transport problem Alessio Figalli Abstract Given two densities f and g, we consider the problem of transporting a fraction m [0, min{ f L 1, g L 1}] of the mass of f onto g minimizing

More information

and BV loc R N ; R d)

and BV loc R N ; R d) Necessary and sufficient conditions for the chain rule in W 1,1 loc R N ; R d) and BV loc R N ; R d) Giovanni Leoni Massimiliano Morini July 25, 2005 Abstract In this paper we prove necessary and sufficient

More information

Lipschitz p-convex and q-concave maps

Lipschitz p-convex and q-concave maps Lipschitz p-convex and q-concave maps J. Alejandro Chávez-Domínguez Instituto de Ciencias Matemáticas, CSIC-UAM-UCM-UC3M, Madrid and Department of Mathematics, University of Texas at Austin Conference

More information

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS REAL AND COMPLE ANALYSIS Third Edition Walter Rudin Professor of Mathematics University of Wisconsin, Madison Version 1.1 No rights reserved. Any part of this work can be reproduced or transmitted in any

More information