Public Goods with Punishment and Abstaining in Finite and Infinite Populations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Public Goods with Punishment and Abstaining in Finite and Infinite Populations"

Transcription

1 Public Goods with Punishment and Abstaining in Finite and Infinite Populations The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Hauert, Christoph, Arne Traulsen, Hannelore Brandt, Martin A. Nowak, and Karl Sigmund Public goods with punishment and abstaining in finite and infinite populations. Biological Theory 3(2): Published Version doi: /biot Citable link Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:hul.instrepos:dash.current.terms-ofuse#oap

2 Public goods with punishment and abstaining in finite and infinite populations Christoph Hauert 1,2,, Arne Traulsen 1,3, Hannelore Brandt 4, Martin A. Nowak 1 & Karl Sigmund 5,6 1 Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Department of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology, Department of Mathematics, Harvard University, One Brattle Square, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA 2 Department of Mathematics, University of British Columbia, 1984 Mathematics Road, Vancouver B.C. Canada V6T 1Z2 3 Max-Planck-Institute for Evolutionary Biology, August-Thienemann-Str. 2, Plön, Germany 4 Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration, A-1090 Vienna, Austria 5 Faculty of Mathematics, University of Vienna, A-1090 Vienna, Austria 6 International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, A-2361 Laxenburg, Austria August 22, 2008 Running head: Punishing and abstaining for public goods Keywords: evolutionary game theory; cooperation; social dilemmas; public goods games; voluntary participation; punishment; Word count: abstract: 171; body: 4849 (including figure legends); 3 figures. Corresponding author: Christoph Hauert Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Harvard University One Brattle Square, Cambridge, MA 02138, USA phone: +(617) , fax: +(617) , christoph hauert@harvard.edu 1

3 Abstract The evolution and maintenance of cooperation in human and animal societies challenges various disciplines ranging from evolutionary biology, to anthropology, social sciences and economics. In social interactions, cooperators increase the welfare of the group at some cost to themselves whereas defectors attempt to free-ride and neither provide benefits nor incur costs. The problem of cooperation becomes even more pronounced when increasing the number of interacting individuals. Punishment and voluntary participation have been identified as possible factors to support cooperation and prevent cheating. Typically, punishment behavior is unable to gain a foothold in a population, while volunteering alone can efficiently prevent deadlocks in states of mutual defection but is unable to stabilize cooperation. The combined effects of the two mechanisms have surprisingly different consequences in finite and infinite populations. Here we provide a detailed comparison of the two scenarios and demonstrate that driven by the inherent stochasticity of finite populations, the possibility to abstain from social interactions plays a pivotal role, which paves the way for the establishment of cooperation and punishment. 2

4 1 Introduction Cooperation is a recurrent theme in nature ranging from microbial colonies to human societies (Axelrod & Hamilton, 1981, Colman, 1995, Dugatkin, 1997, Nowak, 2006b, Trivers, 1971). Yet, the evolution of cooperative behavior that produces benefits to others at some cost to self is far from obvious under Darwinian selection. In fact, defectors that avoid the costs and produce no benefits are better off, while cooperators are doomed and bound to disappear. In evolutionary game theory such scenarios are captured by public goods games (Hardin, 1968, Kagel & Roth, 1995) where cooperators invest into a common good while defectors attempt to exploit the resource without contributing to it. However, if everybody defects they forego the public good: everybody would be better off had they cooperated. This describes a classical conflict of interest between the individual and the community arising in social dilemmas (Dawes, 1980, Hauert et al., 2006). The evolution and maintenance of cooperation in large groups of interacting individuals poses a challenging problem in evolutionary biology as well as in studies of human interactions (Boyd & Richerson, 1988, Hauert & Schuster, 1997). It is well known that cooperation in public good situations requires positive or negative incentives discriminatingly directed at individual players (Olson, 1965). In particular, so called punishment directed by some of the players against cheaters in their group has proved to stabilise cooperation (Fehr & Fischbacher, 2004, Yamagishi, 1986). Such retaliatory peerpunishment can be viewed as a form of (direct or indirect) reciprocation. Clearly, defectors cannot invade a population of punishers (Boyd et al., 2003, Boyd & Richerson, 1992, Sigmund et al., 2001). But how can punishers establish themselves in a population of defectors? The emergence of punishing behaviour is viewed as a challenging problem. Interestingly, it can be resolved if participation in the public good interaction is optional rather than compulsory. Voluntary participation means the game is extended from cooperators and defectors to include a third strategic type, the loners (Hauert et al., 2002b). Participating in public enterprises bears considerable risks because whether and how many participants turn out to be defectors 3

5 is not known in advance. Loners are risk averse individuals that refuse to participate and, instead, rely on fixed autarkic resources. Recently, the combination of costly punishment and volunteering has led to some controversial results in infinite populations (Brandt et al., 2006, Fowler, 2005) but the issue has largely been resolved for the dynamics in finite populations and has revealed new insights relevant for real populations (Boyd & Mathew, 2007, Hauert et al., 2007). Here we provide a detailed analysis and comparison of the two different approaches. 2 Model & Methods In order to model punishing and abstaining in public goods games we follow Fowler (2005) and Brandt et al. (2006) and consider the dynamics of four strategic types: the cooperators x, the defectors y, the loners z and the punishers w. In infinite populations (see section 2.1) x, y, z, w refer to the fraction of the population adopting the respective strategy (x + y + z + w = 1), whereas in finite populations (see section 2.2) of size M the capital letters X, Y, Z, W refer to the number of individuals adopting the respective strategy (X + Y + Z + W = M). A group of N individuals is randomly sampled from the population: cooperators, defectors and punishers participate in the public goods interaction, whereas the loners rely on a small but fixed payoff σ. Loners are not secluded but, for example, collect mushrooms instead of joining a hunting party. Cooperators and punishers invest a fixed amount c into the common good. The total investments into the common pool are then multiplied by a factor r and equally divided among all participants, irrespective of their contributions but excluding the loners. Thus, the common resource yields a net benefit of B S = rc(n x + n w )/S to defectors as well as B S c to cooperators and punishers, where n i indicates the number of participants of type i in the sample and S = n x + n y + n w N denotes the effective number of participants, which varies based on the number of loners in the sample. If S = 1, the sole participant is forced to act as a loner and receives σ. Furthermore, punishers impose a fine β onto defectors at a cost γ with β > γ and, in addition, they also may punish cooperators because of their negligence and failure to punish 4

6 defectors (if there were any) but the fines and costs of punishment are reduced to αβ and αγ with 0 α 1. In this context, cooperators are often termed second order free-riders because they avoid the costs of punishment. The loners payoff is assumed to satisfy (r 1)c > σ > 0 such that loners are better off than groups of defectors (which score zero) but worse off than groups of contributors (mixtures of cooperators and punishers) obtaining (r 1)c. 2.1 The Replicator Equation The evolutionary process in infinite populations is traditionally studied using replicator dynamics (Hofbauer & Sigmund, 1998, Nowak & Sigmund, 2004, Taylor & Jonker, 1978). The state of the population is determined by the frequencies of the different types with x+y +z +w = 1, which confines the state space to the simplex S 4. Individuals interact in groups of size N that are randomly formed according to multinomial sampling. Under replicator dynamics, every strategy that performs better than the population on average increases in abundance: ẋ = x(p x P ) etc. where P i denotes the average payoff of strategy i and P = xp x + yp y + zp z + wp w represents the average population payoff. According to Brandt et al. (2006), which follows the approach in Hauert et al. (2002a), the average payoffs for each strategy are given by P x = z N 1 σ +B F (z)c w(n 1)G(y)αβ (1a) P y = z N 1 σ +B w(n 1)β (1b) P z = σ (1c) P w = z N 1 σ +B F (z)c y(n 1)γ x(n 1)G(y)αγ (1d) }{{}}{{}}{{} loner payoff public goods interaction punishment 5

7 with B = rc x + w 1 z (1 1 ) zn N(1 z) 1 z N 1 z F (z) = 1 + z N 1 (r 1) r N G(y) = 1 (1 y) N 2. Here B denotes the average benefit returned by the public good, F (z) indicates the effective costs of contributing to the public good and G(y) specifies the probability that the failure of cooperators to punish defectors is recognized by punishers. This occurs whenever a group consists of at least one cooperator, one defector and one punisher. Note that F (z) depends on the abundance of loners because they determine the number of participants in the public goods interaction and thus the effective group size S. The resulting effective costs of cooperation are given by (1 r/s)c because the fraction r/s of the investment is returned to the investor. Thus, if loners abound the typical group size is small and cooperation becomes dominant whenever r > S, i.e. if cooperative investments have a positive net return (Hauert et al., 2002a, 2006). However, if S = 1, which happens with probability z N 1, no interaction partners are found and the single participant gets the loner s payoff σ. We assume that r < N such that defection is the dominant solution in the absence of loners and punishers. The dynamics of this system is bi-stable and the evolutionary outcome depends on the initial configuration of the population: either punishers disappear, which gives rise to endless oscillations of cooperators, defectors and loners (Hauert et al., 2002b), or a neutral mixture of cooperators and punishers establishes. In addition, the dynamics is structurally unstable, and hence cannot be relied upon to yield robust predictions. Thus, the analysis of the replicator dynamics is insufficient to draw final conclusions about the relative merits of volunteering and punishment. For a full analysis, we refer to Brandt et al. (2006) and use this scenario as a reference point for the following discussion of the dynamics in finite populations. 6

8 2.2 The Moran Process In finite populations, the Moran process (Moran, 1962) captures the evolutionary dynamics in three elementary steps: birth, death and replacement. An individual is randomly selected for reproduction with a probability proportional to its payoff or fitness and produces a clonal offspring. Then, a randomly chosen individual (independent of fitness) is eliminated and replaced by the offspring. Thus, individuals with a higher fitness have better chances to reproduce but they can still be eliminated due to random drift. The overall population size is kept constant. Based on this process, the fixation probability of a single mutant in a homogeneous resident population can be determined, i.e. the probability that eventually the entire population adopts the mutant strategy. Traditionally, the Moran process is considered for constant fitness values assigned to residents and mutants. Only recently this approach was extended to include frequency dependent fitness (Nowak, 2006a, Nowak et al., 2004). In this framework, the fitness of an individual consists of two components 1 s + sp : a static baseline fitness, which is normalized to one, and a dynamic component P, which depends on interactions with other members of the population. The selection strength s determines the relative contribution of the frequency dependent component to the overall fitness, i.e. s measures the importance of the game for overall success. In the present context, the Moran process can be equivalently interpreted as an imitation process where a randomly selected individual adopts the strategy of a random member of the population, which is chosen with a probability proportional its fitness. In this case mutations do not refer to genetic changes but rather to random experimenting with different behavioral patterns. Previous studies (Imhof et al., 2005, Nowak et al., 2004, Taylor et al., 2004, Traulsen et al., 2005) considered pairwise interactions among two or three strategic types. In the present case, new challenges arise because of the arbitrary interaction group size N: when sampling the interaction group, drawing one member affects the probabilities to select each strategic type in 7

9 subsequent draws of the remaining members. In a population of size M = X+Y +Z+W where X, Y, Z and W refer to the number of cooperators, defectors, loners and punishers, respectively, the group formation process is given by a multivariate hypergeometric distribution such that the probability to interact in a group of n x cooperators, n y defectors, n z loners and n w punishers with n x + n y + n z + n w = N (n x + n y + n w = S) becomes ( x )( y )( z )( w ) n H(X, n x, Y, n y, Z, n z, W, n w ) = x n y n z n ( w M ). (2) N Using Eq. (2) the average effective interaction group size S and its composition can be derived, to obtain the following average payoffs in finite populations: with N 1) ( M 1 N 1) N 1) ( M 1 P X = ( Z P Y = ( Z P Z = σ P W = ( Z W σ +B F (Z)c (N 1)G(Y )αβ (3a) M 1 M 1 N 1) σ +B W N 1) ( M 1 N 1) (N 1)β (3b) Y σ +B F (Z)c (N 1)γ X (N 1)G(Y )αγ (3d) M 1 M 1 }{{}}{{}}{{} loner payoff public goods interaction punishment ( ( X + W 1 B = rc 1 M (Z N + 1) M Z 1 N(M Z) F (Z) = 1 r ( Z ) ( M N N M Z 1 + N 1 r ( M 1 ) N N 1 G(Y ) = 1 M 1 ( M Y 1 ) N 1 ) M Y 1 ( M 1 N 1 ( Z N 1 ( M 1 N 1 ) )) Z + 1 M Z 1 + r M Z 2 M Z 1 1 ) ) (3c) In analogy to Eq. (1), B denotes the average return from the public good to defectors and F (Z) indicates the payoff difference between contributors (cooperators and punishers) and defectors before punishment. As before, G(Y ) is the probability that the second order free-riders (cooperators) are found out and punished for their negligence. If S = 1, which happens with probability ( ) ( Z N 1 / M 1 N 1), the single participant gets the loner payoff σ. In the limit M, Eq. (3) recovers Eq. (1) when converting strategy numbers into fractions using X xm, etc. 8

10 In order to study finite populations analytically, we consider the limit of rare mutations, µ 1/M 2 (Fudenberg et al., 2006, Imhof et al., 2005). In this limit, the population generally consists of a single type (in each generation µm mutants are produced and, typically, it takes less than M generations for a successful mutant to reach fixation). Occasionally a mutant appears and either disappears again or takes over the entire population before the next mutant appears. This restricts the evolutionary process to the edges of the simplex S 4 where at most two strategic types are present at any one point in time. For this setting we derive the probabilities to find the system in either one of the four homogenous states with all cooperators, defectors, loners or punishers. This determines the relative time the system spends in each of the four corners of S Dynamics along edges In order to analyze the dynamics along the edges of S 4, using Eq. (2) or Eq. (3) yields the payoffs in a population that consists of only two strategic types. For example, if the population consists of X cooperators and Y = M X defectors, then the average payoffs to cooperators P XY and defectors P YX are given by: P XY = P YX = N 1 k=0 = rc N ( N 1 k=0 = rc N ( k + 1 H(X 1, k, M X, N 1 k, 0, 0, 0, 0) 1 + X 1 ) (N 1) M 1 c H(X, k, M 1 X, N 1 k, 0, 0, 0, 0) X (N 1). M 1 ) N r 1 c ( ) k N rc Note that for the calculation of the payoff to cooperators, there are only X 1 cooperators left in the reservoir when sampling its N 1 co-players and the reservoir size is M 1. Similarly, the payoffs P ij of strategic type i competing against type j can be derived for all other possible 9

11 pairings: P XW = P W X = (r 1)c P ZX = P ZY = P ZW = σ P XZ = P W Z = (r 1)c P Y Z = P Y W = P W Y = rc N ( Z N 1 ( M 1 N 1 ) )σ ( Z N 1 ( M 1 N 1 W ( rc ) M 1 (N 1) N β ( 1 + W 1 ) (N 1) M 1 ) )((r 1)c σ) c M W M 1 (N 1)γ The above payoffs together with the selection strength s determine the transition probability that the number of individuals m i of type i increases by one, T + ij, or decreases by one, Tij, (and the corresponding change in the count m j = M m i of type j individuals): T + ij = m i (1 s + sp ij ) M(1 s) + s(m i P ij + (M m i )P ji ) T ij = (M m i )(1 s + sp ji ) m i M(1 s) + s(m i P ij + (M m i )P ji ) M M m i M (4a) (4b) Note that this requires that the overall fitness of all types is always positive (1 s + sp ij 0), which can be ensured by adding a suitable constant to all payoff values or by putting an upper limit on the selection strength s. The maximal selection strength is given by s max = 1/(1 min P ij ) for all strategic types i, j under consideration. The transition probabilities T + ij, T ij define a Master equation which describes the time evolution of the state of the system. From the Master equation, the fixation probability ρ ij of a single mutant strategy of type i in a resident population of type j can be derived (Karlin & Taylor, 1975, Nowak et al., 2004): ρ ij = 1 + M 1 1 k k=1 m i =1 T ij T + ij = 1 + M 1 k=1 m i =1 1 k 1 s + sp ji 1 s + sp ij (5) 10

12 Finally, the fixation probabilities ρ ij define the transition probabilities of a Markov process between the four different homogeneous states of the population. The transition matrix A is given by: 1 ρ yx ρ zx ρ wx ρ xy ρ xz ρ xw ρ yx 1 ρ xy ρ zy ρ wy ρ yz ρ yw A= ρ zx ρ zy 1 ρ xz ρ yz ρ wz ρ zw ρ wx ρ wy ρ wz 1 ρ xw ρ yw ρ zw (6) The stationary distribution is given by the normalized right eigenvector of A to the largest eigenvalue (which is one because A T is a stochastic matrix). This returns the probability to find the system in one of the four homogeneous states and concludes the analysis of the dynamics along the edges of S 4. 3 Results The analysis of the dynamics is restricted to the limiting cases of infinite populations (M ) or rare mutations (µ 0) but the general dynamics can be explored with simulations such as provided by the VirtualLabs (Hauert, 2007) or Brandt (2007). Before discussing the effects of finite population sizes on cooperation in voluntary public goods games with punishment, we analyze the effects and efficiency of the two mechanisms of volunteering and punishment separately. 3.1 Volunteering in public goods games In infinite populations, the dynamics in voluntary public goods interactions without punishment is characterized by a rock-scissors-paper-type dominance of the three strategic types to cooperate, to defect and to abstain (loners). This cyclic dominance is reflected in the heteroclinic cycle along the boundaries of the simplex S 3. For N > 2 the interior of S 3 contains a unique fixed 11

13 point Q, which is surrounded by closed periodic orbits (see Fig. 1a and Hauert et al. (2002a) for a detailed analysis). For our purposes it is important to note that only the homogeneous states Fig. 1 with all cooperators and all defectors are hyperbolic saddle points but the loner s corner e z is not and is neutrally stable to first order. The intuitive reason is that a single cooperator does near here not affect the payoffs in the population (nor does a single defector) because this cooperator will never find an interaction partner. It takes at least two cooperators to invade the loner population. As a consequence, the motion along the trajectory slows down in the vicinity of e z, which can be easily verified (Brandt, 2007, Hauert, 2007). In finite populations it seems natural to assume that the system is most likely found in a state with all loners. Interestingly, however, this is not the case (see Fig. 1b, c). Instead, in the limit of rare mutations, the system spends significantly less time in the defector corner and similar times in the cooperator and loner corners. Intuitively this can be understood by noting that the average population payoff is at its maximum if everybody cooperates and at its minimum if everybody defects. The fitness difference between a mutant defector and a resident cooperator tends to be much smaller than the fitness difference between a mutant loner and a resident defector. Hence, the mutant defector is more likely to be eliminated by random drift than the mutant loner and consequentially the system spends more time in the cooperator state than in the defector state. Under weak selection, the population may even cooperate most of the time. Simulations confirm this result even for higher mutation rates. 3.2 Punishment in public goods games In infinite populations, punishment in compulsory public goods interactions (in the absence of loners) produces a bi-stable situation: depending on the initial configuration, the system either evolves to an asocial state where everybody defects or into a state where cooperation is enforced by punishment (see Fig. 2a). Along the boundary of the simplex S 3 the bi-stability Fig. 2 is reflected by an unstable fixed point P on the edge between punishers and defectors. The 12 near here

14 edge between cooperators and punishers consists of fixed points and those with w > w c = (N r)/(βn(n 1)) are stable Nash equilibria. In this case, changes that arise due to stochasticity in finite populations are equally surprising (see Fig. 2b, c). In the limit of rare mutations (Fig. 2c), the system spends most of the time in states where everybody defects. Only for very weak selection or efficient punishment (γ β), punishers manage to enforce cooperation. This outcome changes when increasing the mutation rate (Fig. 2b). For mutation rates of the order of 1/M, punishers prevail. The intuitive reason for these differences is the slow drift dynamics along the neutral cooperator-punisher-edge. This leaves ample time for defectors to appear through mutation. As long as w > w c, mutant defectors actually promote punishment and push the system closer towards the punisher state. Thus, punishment can be stable provided that the punishers are challenged sufficiently often. 3.3 Volunteering and punishment in public goods games In infinite populations, the combined effects of voluntary participation and punishment opportunities in public goods interactions lead to different conclusions based on different modeling techniques. Fowler (2005) reports that loners pave the way for punishers to establish cooperation, whereas Brandt et al. (2006) demonstrate that bi-stable situations arise, in which the initial configuration determines whether the evolutionary end state corresponds to endless cycles of cooperators, defectors and loners or whether a neutral mixture of cooperators and punishers evolves (everybody cooperates, no punishment). Moreover, the dynamics is structurally unstable, because neither the periodic orbits nor the fixed points are isolated. These differences arise because the former approach favors punishers in a twofold way. First, a single punisher (or cooperator), being the only participant in the public goods game, can profit from the public good instead of being reduced to the loner s payoff and second, punishers punish cooperators even if there were no defectors in the interaction group. It seems that the latter approach presents a more convincing analysis. 13

15 Interestingly, however, finite population sizes change the odds in favor of punishers. In the limit of rare mutations, the system spends most of the time in the homogeneous state with all punishers (see Fig. 3). This effect becomes more pronounced for larger population sizes such Fig. 3 that for M = 1000 the system typically spends > 80% of the time in the punisher state. These results are supported by simulation data for small mutation rates. Thus, the original intuition near here of Fowler (2005) is vindicated in finite populations. However, in contrast to Fowler (2005), punishing second order free-riders (α > 0) turns out to have only marginal effects (Hauert et al., 2007). In larger populations, the effects of random fluctuations become weaker and deterministic drift becomes increasingly important (Traulsen et al., 2005). Therefore, strong selection has much stronger effects in large populations. In tiny populations with M = 10 individuals, strong selection leads to approximately the same result as ten times weaker selection for M = 100 and a hundred times weaker selection for M = 1000 (see Fig. 3), which suggests that the relevant quantity characterizing the evolutionary process is given by sm. This is in agreement with other results for frequency dependent selection (Traulsen et al., 2006). Similarly, the product of population size and difference in fitness of two genotypes denotes the relevant evolutionary parameter in population genetics (Crow & Kimura, 1970). 4 Conclusions In Nowak (2006b), five mechanisms have been proposed for the evolution of cooperation: direct reciprocity (Axelrod, 1984, Lindgren, 1991, Nowak & Sigmund, 1993, Trivers, 1971), indirect reciprocity (Nowak & Sigmund, 1998, 2005), kin selection (Grafen, 1985, Hamilton, 1964, Queller, 1985), group selection (Fletcher & Zwick, 2004, Maynard Smith, 1964, Traulsen & Nowak, 2006) and graph selection (Hauert, 2001, Nowak & May, 1992, Ohtsuki et al., 2006). Costly punishment (Clutton-Brock & Parker, 1995, Fehr & Gächter, 2002, Fehr & Rockenbach, 2003, Rockenbach & Milinski, 2006, Yamagishi, 1986) can be viewed as a special form 14

16 of direct or indirect reciprocity. If you punish a person who has defected against you, then direct reciprocity is at work. If you punish a person who has defected against others (Fehr & Fischbacher, 2004) then indirect reciprocity is used. Voluntary participation and the opportunity to punish defectors have been identified as potent mechanisms to promote and stabilize cooperation in public goods interactions in sizeable groups. The dynamics of model systems that combine both mechanisms have recently been analyzed for infinite populations (Brandt et al., 2006, Fowler, 2005) as well as in finite populations (Hauert et al., 2007). This approach does not require group selection (Boyd et al., 2003) or spatial structure (Brandt et al., 2003, Nakamaru & Iwasa, 2006) to establish cooperation and punishment. In agreement with earlier results (Imhof et al., 2005, Nowak et al., 2004, Traulsen et al., 2005), the stochastic components of the dynamics in finite populations produces qualitatively different results and requires to modify intuitions, which are based on infinite dynamics. In voluntary public goods interactions, i.e. in the absence of punishers, mutation and selection in finite populations supports cooperation such that the system spends most of the time either in the state with all cooperators or all loners. This contrasts with expectations from infinite populations where loners should dominate because the dynamics slows down near the loner s corner. Instead, in the limit of rare mutations, the systems spends roughly 40% of the time in the cooperator state as compared to 50% in the loner state and only 10% in states with all defectors. Conversely, in compulsory public goods games with punishment, i.e. in the absence of loners, finite populations tend to reduce cooperation such that the system spends little time in the cooperator or punisher states but most of the time in the state with all defectors (typically more than 80%). Only if fines are very high or punishment very cheap, punishers can rule the world. In that case, individuals will do whatever it takes to avoid punishment and just as Boyd & Richerson (1992) have put it: punishment can stabilize cooperation - or anything else. However, this does not explain the evolution of punishment behavior itself. The dynamics changes considerably when considering the joint effects of voluntary partic- 15

17 ipation and punishment opportunities. In infinite populations this leads to bi-stable dynamics where the evolutionary outcome depends on the initial configuration. However, in finite populations, volunteering creates an evolutionary pathway for establishing punishment behavior. The state with all loners acts as a junction where the system switches to the cooperative state or the punishing state with equal probabilities (Boyd & Mathew, 2007, Hauert et al., 2007). In both cases, cooperative behavior emerges because whenever the groups of participants are small, there is some probability that they consist, through sheer chance, mostly of cooperators or punishers. In each case, the group is highly successful, and will find many imitators. The difference is that in a population consisting of mostly cooperators, defectors will thrive, and the rock-scissors-paper-cycle will repeat itself. If the population consists mostly of punishers, it is much more stable, and can only get undermined by the slow process of non-punishing cooperators invading through random drift. Thus, finite populations promote the establishment of punishment. This emphasizes the pivotal role of loners in the evolutionary process. The possibility to abstain from public enterprises not only prevents economic stalemate by providing an escape hatch out of states of mutual defection but it also paves the way for establishing punishment mechanisms that are capable of largely stabilizing cooperation in sizeable groups. Cooperation (and punishment) is more likely to occur and persist if interactions are voluntary rather than compulsory. Acknowledgments Support from the John Templeton Foundation and the NSF/NIH joint program in mathematical biology (NIH grant R01GM078986) is gratefully acknowledged. A.T. is supported by the Deutsche Akademie der Naturforscher Leopoldina (Grant No. BMBF-LPD 9901/8134). K.S. and H.B. are supported by I-104-G15 (EUROCORES TECT). The Program for Evolutionary Dynamics (PED) at Harvard University is sponsored by Jeffrey Epstein. 16

18 References Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. Basic Books, New York. Axelrod, R. & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 211, Boyd, R., Gintis, H., Bowles, S. & Richerson, P. (2003). The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA, 100, Boyd, R. & Mathew, S. (2007). A narrow road to cooperation. Science, 316, Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1988). The evolution of reciprocity in sizeable groups. J. theor. Biol. 132, Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1992). Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13, Brandt, H. (2007). Interactive simulations, Brandt, H., Hauert, C. & Sigmund, K. (2003). Cooperation, punishment and reputation in spatial games. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B, 270, Brandt, H., Hauert, C. & Sigmund, K. (2006). Punishing and abstaining for public goods. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA, 103 (2), Clutton-Brock, T. H. & Parker, G. A. (1995). Punishment in animal societies. Nature, 373, Colman, A. M. (1995). Game Theory and its Applications in the Social and Biological Sciences. Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford. Crow, J. F. & Kimura, M. (1970). An Introduction to Population Genetics Theory. Harper and Row, New York. 17

19 Dawes, R. M. (1980). Social dilemmas. Ann. Rev. Psychol. 31, Dugatkin, L. A. (1997). Cooperation among animals: an evolutionary perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Fehr, E. & Fischbacher, U. (2004). Third-party punishment and social norms. Evol. Hum. Behav. 25, Fehr, E. & Gächter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature, 415, Fehr, E. & Rockenbach, B. (2003). Detrimental effects of sanctions on human altruism. Nature, 422, Fletcher, J. & Zwick, M. (2004). Strong altruism can evolve in randomly formed groups. J. theor. Biol. 228, Fowler, J. H. (2005). Altruistic punishment and the origin of cooperation. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA, 102 (19), Fudenberg, D., Nowak, M. A., Taylor, C. & Imhof, L. A. (2006). Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations with strong selection and weak mutation. Theor. Pop. Biol. 70, Grafen, A. (1985). A geometric view of relatedness. In Oxford Surveys in Evolutionary Biology vol. 2, pp Oxford University Press Oxford. Hamilton, W. D. (1964). The genetical evolution of social behaviour I. J. theor. Biol. 7, Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, Hauert, C. (2001). Fundamental clusters in spatial 2 2 games. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B, 268, Hauert, C. (2007). Virtuallabs: interactive tutorials on evolutionary game theory, 18

20 Hauert, C., De Monte, S., Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. (2002a). Replicator dynamics in optional public goods games. J. theor. Biol, 218, Hauert, C., De Monte, S., Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. (2002b). Volunteering as red queen mechanism for cooperation in public goods games. Science, 296, Hauert, C., Michor, F., Nowak, M. & Doebeli, M. (2006). Synergy and discounting of cooperation in social dilemmas. J. theor. Biol. 239, Hauert, C. & Schuster, H. G. (1997). Effects of increasing the number of players and memory size in the iterated prisoner s dilemma: a numerical approach. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B, 264, Hauert, C., Traulsen, A., Brandt, H., Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. (2007). Via freedom to coercion: the emergence of costly punishment. Science, 316, Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Imhof, L. A., Fudenberg, D. & Nowak, M. A. (2005). Evolutionary cycles of cooperation and defection. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA, 102 (31), Kagel, J. H. & Roth, A. E., eds (1995). The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Karlin, S. & Taylor, H. M. (1975). First Course in Stochastic Processes. 2nd edition, Academic Press, London. Lindgren, K. (1991). Evolutionary phenomena in simple dynamics. In Artificial Life II, (Langton, C. G., Farmer, J. D., Rasmussen, S. & Taylor, C., eds), vol. X, of Proc. of the Santa Fe Institue Studies in the Sciences of Complexity pp Addison-Wesley Redwood City, CA. 19

21 Maynard Smith, J. (1964). Group selection and kin selection. Nature, 201 (4942), Moran, P. A. P. (1962). The Statistical Processes of Evolutionary Theory. Clarendon, Oxford, UK. Nakamaru, M. & Iwasa, Y. (2006). The coevolution of altruism and punishment: role of the selfish punisher. J. theor. Biol. 240 (3), Nowak, M. A. (2006a). Evolutionary Dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA. Nowak, M. A. (2006b). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314, Nowak, M. A. & May, R. M. (1992). Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature, 359, Nowak, M. A., Sasaki, A., Taylor, C. & Fudenberg, D. (2004). Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations. Nature, 428, Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. (1993). A strategy of win-stay, lose-shift that outperforms titfor-tat in the prisoner s dilemma game. Nature, 364, Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. (1998). Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature, 393, Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. (2004). Evolutionary dynamics of biological games. Science, 303, Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, Ohtsuki, H., Hauert, C., Lieberman, E. & Nowak, M. A. (2006). A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature, 441, Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA. 20

22 Queller, D. C. (1985). Kinship, reciprocity and synergism in the evolution of social behavior. Nature, 318, Rockenbach, B. & Milinski, M. (2006). Indirect reciprocity resolves the efficiency dilemma of costly punishment. Nature, 444, Sigmund, K., Hauert, C. & Nowak, M. A. (2001). Reward and punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 98, Taylor, C., Fudenberg, D., Sasaki, A. & Nowak, M. A. (2004). Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations. Bull. Math. Biol. 66, Taylor, P. & Jonker, L. (1978). Game dynamics and evolutionarily stable strategies. Math. Bio. Sci. 40, Traulsen, A., Claussen, J. C. & Hauert, C. (2005). Coevolutionary dynamics: from finite to infinite populations. Phys. Rev. Lett. 95, Traulsen, A. & Nowak, M. A. (2006). Evolution of cooperation by multilevel selection. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA, 103 (29), Traulsen, A., Nowak, M. A. & Pacheco, J. M. (2006). Stochastic dynamics of invasion and fixation. Phys. Rev. E, 74, Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q. Rev. Biol. 46, Yamagishi, T. (1986). The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 51,

23 Figure legends Hauert et al. - Figure 1 a e z b e z c 1 Q relative time in homogeneous states e x e y e x e y selection strength s Figure 1: Voluntary participation in public goods games as a mechanisms to promote cooperation in infinite and finite populations. a Evolutionary dynamics in infinite populations. The cyclic dominance of the strategies cooperate, defect and loner leads to a heteroclynic cycle along the boundaries of S 3 and an interior fixed point Q that is surrounded by closed periodic orbits (N > 2). b In finite populations the population spends most of the time in the cooperator (28.3%), defector (12.7%) and loner (22.9%) corners, as compared to < 10 3 % in states in the center of S 3. The densities are color coded on a logarithmic scale with black indicating low, red intermediate and yellow high densities. c In the limit of rare mutations the dynamics is restricted to the boundary of S 3. The probabilities to find the system in homogeneous states with all cooperators (blue), defectors (red) or loners (yellow) are shown as a function of the selection strength s. The dashed vertical line indicates the selection strength used in panel b. In the limit of neutral evolution (s 0) the strategic differences disappear and all three states are equally likely. For s > 0 the system spends the least time in the defector state and significantly more time in the cooperator or loner states. Under weak selection the system even spends most of its time in the cooperative state. Simulation results of the average fraction of each strategic type confirm the analysis (colored dots). Parameters: N = 5, r = 3, c = 1, σ = 1; b M = 100, mutation rate µ = 10 3, s = 0.05; c M = 100, µ = 10 3, s max =

24 Hauert et al. - Figure 2 a e w b e w c 1 P relative time in homogeneous states e x e y e x e y selection strength s Figure 2: Punishment opportunities in public goods games as a mechanism to promote cooperation in infinite and finite populations. a In infinite populations the dynamics is bi-stable and, depending on the initial configuration, the evolutionary end state is either a homogeneous population with all defectors or a neutral mixture of cooperators and punishers. The size of the basins of attraction are essentially determined by the location of the fixed point P along the punisher-defector-edge. b In finite populations the population spends slightly more time in the punisher corner (29.7%) than in the defector corner (28.4%) and significantly less in the cooperator corner (11.9%), as compared to < 10 4 % in states in the center of S 3. The densities are color coded on a logarithmic scale with black indicating low, red intermediate and yellow high densities. c In the limit of rare mutations the dynamics is restricted to the boundary of S 3. The probability to find the system in homogeneous states with all cooperators (blue), defectors (red) or punishers (green) is shown as a function of the selection strength s. The analysis is confirmed by simulation results of the average fraction of each strategic type (colored dots) and the dashed vertical line indicates the selection strength used in panel b. The population is usually found in a state with all defectors except for weak selection where punishers manage to get the upper hand (c.f. panel b). Increasing the efficacy of punishment, i.e. increasing β, supports punishment directly by increasing the time spent in the punisher state as well as indirectly by reducing the maximal selection strength. Parameters: N = 5, r = 3, c = 1, γ = 0.3, β = 1, α = 0.1; b M = 100, mutation rate µ = 10 3, s = 0.05; c M = 100, µ = 10 3, s max =

25 Hauert et al. - Figure 3 1 M = 10 M = M = 1000 relative time in homogeneous states selection strength s selection strength s a b c selection strength s Figure 3: Punishment and abstaining in public goods games in finite populations. In the limit of rare mutations, the dynamics is restricted to the boundary of S 4. The average fractions of cooperators (blue), defectors (red), loners (yellow) or punishers (green) are shown as a function of the selection strength for different population sizes M. Simulations where the fitness is determined through a single random interaction confirm the results (colored dots). The mutation rate µ is the same for all M and thus effects of mutations increases and deviations become larger when increasing the population size. The analytical approximations are expected to hold for µ < 1/M 2 but the qualitative predictions remain valid for larger mutation rates (µ = 1/M in c). Parameters: N = 5, r = 3, c = 1, σ = 1, γ = 0.3, β = 1, α = 0.1, s max = 0.385; Simulations: µ = 10 3, a sampling times, T > 10 8, b, c T >

Emergence of Cooperation and Evolutionary Stability in Finite Populations

Emergence of Cooperation and Evolutionary Stability in Finite Populations Emergence of Cooperation and Evolutionary Stability in Finite Populations The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation

More information

Darwinian Evolution of Cooperation via Punishment in the Public Goods Game

Darwinian Evolution of Cooperation via Punishment in the Public Goods Game Darwinian Evolution of Cooperation via Punishment in the Public Goods Game Arend Hintze, Christoph Adami Keck Graduate Institute, 535 Watson Dr., Claremont CA 97 adami@kgi.edu Abstract The evolution of

More information

THE DYNAMICS OF PUBLIC GOODS. Christoph Hauert. Nina Haiden. Karl Sigmund

THE DYNAMICS OF PUBLIC GOODS. Christoph Hauert. Nina Haiden. Karl Sigmund DISCRETE AND CONTINUOUS Website: http://aimsciences.org DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS SERIES B Volume 4, Number 3, August 2004 pp. 575 587 THE DYNAMICS OF PUBLIC GOODS Christoph Hauert Departments of Zoology and Mathematics

More information

On the evolution of reciprocal cooperation

On the evolution of reciprocal cooperation On the evolution of reciprocal cooperation Jean-Baptiste André Ecologie & Evolution - CNRS - ENS, Paris, France Biodiversity and Environment: Viability and Dynamic Games Perspectives Montreal, November

More information

The One-Third Law of Evolutionary Dynamics

The One-Third Law of Evolutionary Dynamics The One-Third Law of Evolutionary Dynamics The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Ohtsuki Hisashi, Pedro Bordalo,

More information

Tit-for-Tat or Win-Stay, Lose-Shift?

Tit-for-Tat or Win-Stay, Lose-Shift? Tit-for-Tat or Win-Stay, Lose-Shift? The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed Citable

More information

arxiv:math/ v1 [math.oc] 29 Jun 2004

arxiv:math/ v1 [math.oc] 29 Jun 2004 Putting the Prisoner s Dilemma in Context L. A. Khodarinova and J. N. Webb Magnetic Resonance Centre, School of Physics and Astronomy, University of Nottingham, Nottingham, England NG7 RD, e-mail: LarisaKhodarinova@hotmail.com

More information

Kalle Parvinen. Department of Mathematics FIN University of Turku, Finland

Kalle Parvinen. Department of Mathematics FIN University of Turku, Finland Adaptive dynamics: on the origin of species by sympatric speciation, and species extinction by evolutionary suicide. With an application to the evolution of public goods cooperation. Department of Mathematics

More information

Repeated Games and Direct Reciprocity Under Active Linking

Repeated Games and Direct Reciprocity Under Active Linking Repeated Games and Direct Reciprocity Under Active Linking The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Pacheco,

More information

The Replicator Equation on Graphs

The Replicator Equation on Graphs The Replicator Equation on Graphs The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters. Citation Published Version Accessed Citable

More information

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 18 Dec 2007

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 18 Dec 2007 The Effect of a Random Drift on Mixed and Pure Strategies in the Snowdrift Game arxiv:0711.3249v2 [q-bio.pe] 18 Dec 2007 André C. R. Martins and Renato Vicente GRIFE, Escola de Artes, Ciências e Humanidades,

More information

Evolution of Cooperation in Evolutionary Games for Heterogeneous Interactions

Evolution of Cooperation in Evolutionary Games for Heterogeneous Interactions Commun. Theor. Phys. 57 (2012) 547 552 Vol. 57, No. 4, April 15, 2012 Evolution of Cooperation in Evolutionary Games for Heterogeneous Interactions QIAN Xiao-Lan ( ) 1, and YANG Jun-Zhong ( ) 2 1 School

More information

The Paradox of Cooperation Benets

The Paradox of Cooperation Benets The Paradox of Cooperation Benets 2009 Abstract It seems natural that when benets of cooperation are increasing, the share of cooperators (if there are any) in the population also increases. It is well

More information

Evolution of cooperation. Martin Nowak, Harvard University

Evolution of cooperation. Martin Nowak, Harvard University Evolution of cooperation Martin Nowak, Harvard University As the Fukushima power plant was melting down, a worker in his 20s was among those who volunteered to reenter. In an interview he said: There are

More information

Policing and group cohesion when resources vary

Policing and group cohesion when resources vary Anim. Behav., 996, 52, 63 69 Policing and group cohesion when resources vary STEVEN A. FRANK Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology, University of California at Irvine (Received 5 January 996;

More information

arxiv: v4 [q-bio.pe] 16 Feb 2011

arxiv: v4 [q-bio.pe] 16 Feb 2011 Sanctioning by Institution, Skepticism of Punisher and the Evolution of Cooperation Huhh, Jun-Sok November 3, 208 arxiv:0.702v4 [q-bio.pe] 6 Feb 20 Abstract This article aims to clarify the case and the

More information

Stability in negotiation games and the emergence of cooperation

Stability in negotiation games and the emergence of cooperation Received 3 September 23 Accepted 4 November 23 Published online 3 January 24 Stability in negotiation games and the emergence of cooperation Peter D. Taylor * and Troy Day Department of Mathematics and

More information

Evolutionary Dynamics in Structured Populations

Evolutionary Dynamics in Structured Populations Evolutionary Dynamics in Structured Populations The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Nowak, Martin A., Corina

More information

N-Player Prisoner s Dilemma

N-Player Prisoner s Dilemma ALTRUISM, THE PRISONER S DILEMMA, AND THE COMPONENTS OF SELECTION Abstract The n-player prisoner s dilemma (PD) is a useful model of multilevel selection for altruistic traits. It highlights the non zero-sum

More information

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 17 Aug 2016

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 17 Aug 2016 Simulation of an Optional Strategy in the Prisoner s Dilemma in Spatial and Non-spatial Environments Marcos Cardinot, Maud Gibbons, Colm O Riordan, and Josephine Griffith arxiv:1608.05044v1 [cs.gt] 17

More information

Competition between groups can lead to selection of cooperative

Competition between groups can lead to selection of cooperative Evolution of cooperation y multilevel selection Arne Traulsen and Martin A. Nowak* Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Departments of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology and Mathematics, Harvard University,

More information

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Journal of Theoretical Biology

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Journal of Theoretical Biology Journal of Theoretical Biology 256 (29) 45 57 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Theoretical Biology journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/yjtbi Direct reciprocity with costly punishment:

More information

Topology-independent impact of noise on cooperation in spatial public goods games

Topology-independent impact of noise on cooperation in spatial public goods games PHYSIAL REVIEW E 80, 056109 2009 Topology-independent impact of noise on cooperation in spatial public goods games Attila Szolnoki, 1 Matjaž Perc, 2 and György Szabó 1 1 Research Institute for Technical

More information

Evolutionary Dynamics of Lewis Signaling Games: Signaling Systems vs. Partial Pooling

Evolutionary Dynamics of Lewis Signaling Games: Signaling Systems vs. Partial Pooling This version: October 8, 2006. Introduction Evolutionary Dynamics of Lewis Signaling Games: Signaling Systems vs. Partial Pooling Simon Huttegger Brian Skyrms Rory Smead Kevin Zollman In Lewis signaling

More information

MATCHING STRUCTURE AND THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION IN THE PRISONER S DILEMMA

MATCHING STRUCTURE AND THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION IN THE PRISONER S DILEMMA MATCHING STRUCTURE AN THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION IN THE PRISONER S ILEMMA Noureddine Bouhmala 1 and Jon Reiersen 2 1 epartment of Technology, Vestfold University College, Norway noureddine.bouhmala@hive.no

More information

Alana Schick , ISCI 330 Apr. 12, The Evolution of Cooperation: Putting gtheory to the Test

Alana Schick , ISCI 330 Apr. 12, The Evolution of Cooperation: Putting gtheory to the Test Alana Schick 43320027, ISCI 330 Apr. 12, 2007 The Evolution of Cooperation: Putting gtheory to the Test Evolution by natural selection implies that individuals with a better chance of surviving and reproducing

More information

Reputation-based mutual selection rule promotes cooperation in spatial threshold public goods games

Reputation-based mutual selection rule promotes cooperation in spatial threshold public goods games International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis Schlossplatz 1 A-2361 Laxenburg, Austria Tel: +43 2236 807 342 Fax: +43 2236 71313 E-mail: publications@iiasa.ac.at Web: www.iiasa.ac.at Interim Report

More information

Understanding and Solving Societal Problems with Modeling and Simulation

Understanding and Solving Societal Problems with Modeling and Simulation Understanding and Solving Societal Problems with Modeling and Simulation Lecture 8: The Breakdown of Cooperation ETH Zurich April 15, 2013 Dr. Thomas Chadefaux Why Cooperation is Hard The Tragedy of the

More information

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games International Journal of Mathematics and Soft Computing Vol.5, No.2 (2015), 197-212. ISSN Print : 2249-3328 ISSN Online: 2319-5215 Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

More information

ALTRUISM OR JUST SHOWING OFF?

ALTRUISM OR JUST SHOWING OFF? ALTRUISM OR JUST SHOWING OFF? Soha Sabeti ISCI 330 April 12/07 Altruism or Just Showing Off? Among the many debates regarding the evolution of altruism are suggested theories such as group selection, kin

More information

Hamilton s Rule Applied to Reciprocal Altruism

Hamilton s Rule Applied to Reciprocal Altruism Hamilton s Rule pplied to Reciprocal ltruism Jeffrey. Fletcher Systems Science Ph.D. Program Portland State University Portland, OR 9727 Email: jeff@pdx.edu bstract Reciprocal altruism and inclusive fitness

More information

Spatial three-player prisoners dilemma

Spatial three-player prisoners dilemma Spatial three-player prisoners dilemma Rui Jiang, 1 Hui Deng, 1 Mao-Bin Hu, 1,2 Yong-Hong Wu, 2 and Qing-Song Wu 1 1 School of Engineering Science, University of Science and Technology of China, Hefei

More information

Evolutionary Game Theory

Evolutionary Game Theory Evolutionary Game Theory ISI 330 Lecture 18 1 ISI 330 Lecture 18 Outline A bit about historical origins of Evolutionary Game Theory Main (competing) theories about how cooperation evolves P and other social

More information

stochastic, evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations

stochastic, evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations PHYSICAL REVIEW E 80, 011909 2009 Deterministic evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations Philipp M. Altrock* and Arne Traulsen Emmy-Noether Group of Evolutionary Dynamics, Department of Evolutionary

More information

Behavior of Collective Cooperation Yielded by Two Update Rules in Social Dilemmas: Combining Fermi and Moran Rules

Behavior of Collective Cooperation Yielded by Two Update Rules in Social Dilemmas: Combining Fermi and Moran Rules Commun. Theor. Phys. 58 (2012) 343 348 Vol. 58, No. 3, September 15, 2012 Behavior of Collective Cooperation Yielded by Two Update Rules in Social Dilemmas: Combining Fermi and Moran Rules XIA Cheng-Yi

More information

Cooperation Achieved by Migration and Evolution in a Multilevel Selection Context

Cooperation Achieved by Migration and Evolution in a Multilevel Selection Context Proceedings of the 27 IEEE Symposium on Artificial Life (CI-ALife 27) Cooperation Achieved by Migration and Evolution in a Multilevel Selection Context Genki Ichinose Graduate School of Information Science

More information

Dynamic-persistence of cooperation in public good games when group size is dynamic

Dynamic-persistence of cooperation in public good games when group size is dynamic Journal of Theoretical Biology 243 (26) 34 42 www.elsevier.com/locate/yjtbi Dynamic-persistence of cooperation in public good games when group size is dynamic Marco A. Janssen a,, Robert L. Goldstone b

More information

EVOLUTIONARY GAMES WITH GROUP SELECTION

EVOLUTIONARY GAMES WITH GROUP SELECTION EVOLUTIONARY GAMES WITH GROUP SELECTION Martin Kaae Jensen Alexandros Rigos Department of Economics University of Leicester Controversies in Game Theory: Homo Oeconomicus vs. Homo Socialis ETH Zurich 12/09/2014

More information

The Stability for Tit-for-Tat

The Stability for Tit-for-Tat e-issn:31-6190 p-issn:347-94 The Stability for Tit-for-Tat Shun Kurokawa 1,* 1 Kyoto University, Oiwake-cho, Kitashirakawa, Sakyo-ku, Kyoto, Japan Key Lab of Animal Ecology and Conservation Biology, Institute

More information

Human society is organized into sets. We participate in

Human society is organized into sets. We participate in Evolutionary dynamics in set structured populations Corina E. Tarnita a, Tibor Antal a, Hisashi Ohtsuki b, and Martin A. Nowak a,1 a Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Department of Mathematics, Department

More information

Evolution of Cooperation in Continuous Prisoner s Dilemma Games on Barabasi Albert Networks with Degree-Dependent Guilt Mechanism

Evolution of Cooperation in Continuous Prisoner s Dilemma Games on Barabasi Albert Networks with Degree-Dependent Guilt Mechanism Commun. Theor. Phys. 57 (2012) 897 903 Vol. 57, No. 5, May 15, 2012 Evolution of Cooperation in Continuous Prisoner s Dilemma Games on Barabasi Albert Networks with Degree-Dependent Guilt Mechanism WANG

More information

Reward from Punishment Does Not Emerge at All Costs

Reward from Punishment Does Not Emerge at All Costs Jeromos Vukov 1 *, Flávio L. Pinheiro 1,2, Francisco C. Santos 1,3, Jorge M. Pacheco 1,4 1 ATP-group, Centro de Matemática e Aplicações Fundamentais, Instituto para a Investigação Interdisciplinar da Universidade

More information

Complexity in social dynamics : from the. micro to the macro. Lecture 4. Franco Bagnoli. Lecture 4. Namur 7-18/4/2008

Complexity in social dynamics : from the. micro to the macro. Lecture 4. Franco Bagnoli. Lecture 4. Namur 7-18/4/2008 Complexity in Namur 7-18/4/2008 Outline 1 Evolutionary models. 2 Fitness landscapes. 3 Game theory. 4 Iterated games. Prisoner dilemma. 5 Finite populations. Evolutionary dynamics The word evolution is

More information

Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics

Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics ARTICLE I PRESS Journal of Theoretical Biology 246 (2007) 522 529 www.elsevier.com/locate/yjtbi Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics Arne Traulsen a,, Jorge M. Pacheco

More information

Complex networks and evolutionary games

Complex networks and evolutionary games Volume 2 Complex networks and evolutionary games Michael Kirley Department of Computer Science and Software Engineering The University of Melbourne, Victoria, Australia Email: mkirley@cs.mu.oz.au Abstract

More information

Replicator Dynamics for Optional Public Good Games

Replicator Dynamics for Optional Public Good Games J. theor. Biol. (2002) 218, 187 194 doi:10.1006/yjtbi.3067, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on Replicator Dynamics for Optional Public Good Games Christoph Hauertwz, SilviaDeMontewy, Josef

More information

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 19 Mar 2009

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 19 Mar 2009 Mutation selection equilibrium in games with multiple strategies arxiv:0811.2009v2 [q-bio.pe] 19 Mar 2009 Tibor Antal a, Arne Traulsen b, Hisashi Ohtsuki c, Corina E. Tarnita a, Martin A. Nowak a a Program

More information

Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations

Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations Martin A. Nowak, Corina E. Tarnita and Tibor Antal Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 2010 365, 19-30 doi: 10.1098/rstb.2009.0215 References Rapid response Subject collections

More information

Analytical Results for Individual and Group Selection of Any Intensity

Analytical Results for Individual and Group Selection of Any Intensity Bulletin of Mathematical Biology (2008) DOI 10.1007/s11538-008-9305-6 ORIGINAL ARTICLE Analytical Results for Individual and Group Selection of Any Intensity Arne Traulsen a,b,, Noam Shoresh c, Martin

More information

ABSTRACT: Dissolving the evolutionary puzzle of human cooperation.

ABSTRACT: Dissolving the evolutionary puzzle of human cooperation. ABSTRACT: Dissolving the evolutionary puzzle of human cooperation. Researchers of human behaviour often approach cooperation as an evolutionary puzzle, viewing it as analogous or even equivalent to the

More information

Evolution of Diversity and Cooperation 2 / 3. Jorge M. Pacheco. Departamento de Matemática & Aplicações Universidade do Minho Portugal

Evolution of Diversity and Cooperation 2 / 3. Jorge M. Pacheco. Departamento de Matemática & Aplicações Universidade do Minho Portugal Evolution of Diversity and Cooperation 2 / 3 Jorge M. Pacheco Departamento de Matemática & Aplicações Universidade do Minho Portugal Luis Santaló School, 18 th of July, 2013 prisoner s dilemma C D C (

More information

How altruism evolves: assortment and synergy

How altruism evolves: assortment and synergy doi:10.1111/j.1420-9101.2006.01146.x COMMENTARY How altruism evolves: assortment and synergy J. A. FLETCHER* & M. DOEBELI *Department of Zoology, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC, Canada Departments

More information

Physica A. Promoting cooperation by local contribution under stochastic win-stay-lose-shift mechanism

Physica A. Promoting cooperation by local contribution under stochastic win-stay-lose-shift mechanism Physica A 387 (2008) 5609 5615 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Physica A journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/physa Promoting cooperation by local contribution under stochastic win-stay-lose-shift

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.ds] 27 Jan 2015

arxiv: v2 [math.ds] 27 Jan 2015 LIMIT CYCLES SPARKED BY MUTATION IN THE REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA DANIELLE F. P. TOUPO Center for Applied Mathematics, Cornell University Ithaca, NY 14853, USA dpt35@cornell.edu arxiv:1501.05715v2 [math.ds]

More information

Application of Evolutionary Game theory to Social Networks: A Survey

Application of Evolutionary Game theory to Social Networks: A Survey Application of Evolutionary Game theory to Social Networks: A Survey Pooya Esfandiar April 22, 2009 Abstract Evolutionary game theory has been expanded to many other areas than mere biological concept

More information

Evolutionary Games and Computer Simulations

Evolutionary Games and Computer Simulations Evolutionary Games and Computer Simulations Bernardo A. Huberman and Natalie S. Glance Dynamics of Computation Group Xerox Palo Alto Research Center Palo Alto, CA 94304 Abstract The prisoner s dilemma

More information

The Fastest Evolutionary Trajectory

The Fastest Evolutionary Trajectory The Fastest Evolutionary Trajectory The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Traulsen, Arne, Yoh Iwasa, and Martin

More information

An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory: Lecture 2

An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory: Lecture 2 An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory: Lecture 2 Mauro Mobilia Lectures delivered at the Graduate School on Nonlinear and Stochastic Systems in Biology held in the Department of Applied Mathematics,

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-bio.pe] 22 Sep 2016

arxiv: v1 [q-bio.pe] 22 Sep 2016 Cooperation in the two-population snowdrift game with punishment enforced through different mechanisms André Barreira da Silva Rocha a, a Department of Industrial Engineering, Pontifical Catholic University

More information

Revisiting The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups : Continuous reciprocity in the repeated -person prisoner s dilemma

Revisiting The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups : Continuous reciprocity in the repeated -person prisoner s dilemma Revisiting The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups : Continuous reciprocity in the repeated -person prisoner s dilemma Masanori Takezawa, Michael E. Price To cite this version: Masanori Takezawa,

More information

Shared rewarding overcomes defection traps in generalized volunteer's dilemmas

Shared rewarding overcomes defection traps in generalized volunteer's dilemmas International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis Schlossplatz 1 A-2361 Laxenburg, Austria Tel: +43 2236 807 342 Fax: +43 2236 71313 E-mail: publications@iiasa.ac.at Web: www.iiasa.ac.at Interim Report

More information

Distributional stability and equilibrium selection Evolutionary dynamics under payoff heterogeneity (II) Dai Zusai

Distributional stability and equilibrium selection Evolutionary dynamics under payoff heterogeneity (II) Dai Zusai Distributional stability Dai Zusai 1 Distributional stability and equilibrium selection Evolutionary dynamics under payoff heterogeneity (II) Dai Zusai Tohoku University (Economics) August 2017 Outline

More information

Evolutionary Games and Periodic Fitness

Evolutionary Games and Periodic Fitness Evolutionary Games and Periodic Fitness Philippe Uyttendaele Frank Thuijsman Pieter Collins Ralf Peeters Gijs Schoenmakers Ronald Westra March 16, 2012 Abstract One thing that nearly all stability concepts

More information

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 13 Feb 2017

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 13 Feb 2017 Evolutionary dynamics of N-person Hawk-Dove games Wei Chen 1, Carlos Gracia-Lázaro 2, Zhiwu Li 3,1, Long Wang 4, and Yamir Moreno 2,5,6 arxiv:1702.03969v1 [physics.soc-ph] 13 Feb 2017 1 School of Electro-Mechanical

More information

Costly Signals and Cooperation

Costly Signals and Cooperation Costly Signals and Cooperation Károly Takács and András Németh MTA TK Lendület Research Center for Educational and Network Studies (RECENS) and Corvinus University of Budapest New Developments in Signaling

More information

Evolution of Cooperation in the Snowdrift Game with Incomplete Information and Heterogeneous Population

Evolution of Cooperation in the Snowdrift Game with Incomplete Information and Heterogeneous Population DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Evolution of Cooperation in the Snowdrift Game with Incomplete Information and Heterogeneous Population André Barreira da Silva Rocha, University of Leicester, UK Annick Laruelle,

More information

Genetic stability and territorial structure facilitate the evolution of. tag-mediated altruism. Lee Spector a and Jon Klein a,b

Genetic stability and territorial structure facilitate the evolution of. tag-mediated altruism. Lee Spector a and Jon Klein a,b 1 To appear as: Spector, L., and J. Klein. 2006. Genetic Stability and Territorial Structure Facilitate the Evolution of Tag-mediated Altruism. In Artificial Life, Vol. 12, No. 4. Published by MIT Press

More information

arxiv:q-bio/ v1 [q-bio.pe] 24 May 2004

arxiv:q-bio/ v1 [q-bio.pe] 24 May 2004 Effects of neighbourhood size and connectivity on the spatial Continuous Prisoner s Dilemma arxiv:q-bio/0405018v1 [q-bio.pe] 24 May 2004 Margarita Ifti a,d Timothy Killingback b Michael Doebeli c a Department

More information

Evolutionary prisoner s dilemma game on hierarchical lattices

Evolutionary prisoner s dilemma game on hierarchical lattices PHYSICAL REVIEW E 71, 036133 2005 Evolutionary prisoner s dilemma game on hierarchical lattices Jeromos Vukov Department of Biological Physics, Eötvös University, H-1117 Budapest, Pázmány Péter sétány

More information

Oscillatory dynamics in evolutionary games are suppressed by heterogeneous adaptation rates of players

Oscillatory dynamics in evolutionary games are suppressed by heterogeneous adaptation rates of players Oscillatory dynamics in evolutionary games are suppressed by heterogeneous adaptation rates of players arxiv:0803.1023v1 [q-bio.pe] 7 Mar 2008 Naoki Masuda 1 Graduate School of Information Science and

More information

Dynamic Properties of Evolutionary Multi-player Games in Finite Populations

Dynamic Properties of Evolutionary Multi-player Games in Finite Populations Games 2013, 4, 182-199; doi:10.3390/g4020182 OPEN ACCESS games ISSN 2073-4336 www.mdpi.com/journal/games Article Dynamic Properties of Evolutionary Multi-player Games in Finite Populations Bin Wu, Arne

More information

Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics

Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics Arne Traulsen and Christoph Hauert. Game theory and evolution Modern game theory goes bac to a series of papers by the mathematician John von Neumann in the 920s.

More information

Imitation Processes with Small Mutations

Imitation Processes with Small Mutations Imitation Processes with Small Mutations The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Fudenberg, Drew, and Lorens

More information

Evolutionary dynamics on graphs: Efficient method for weak selection

Evolutionary dynamics on graphs: Efficient method for weak selection Evolutionary dynamics on graphs: Efficient method for weak selection Feng Fu, 1,2 Long Wang, 2 Martin A. owak, 1,3 and Christoph Hauert 1,4, * 1 Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Harvard University, Cambridge,

More information

Evolutionary Game Theory and Frequency Dependent Selection

Evolutionary Game Theory and Frequency Dependent Selection Evolutionary Game Theory and Frequency Dependent Selection 1 Game Theory A major component of economics Given a set of rules, predict how would rational beings behave in an interaction Who is in the game?

More information

Unifying the Theories of Inclusive Fitness and Reciprocal Altruism

Unifying the Theories of Inclusive Fitness and Reciprocal Altruism Portland State University PDXScholar Systems Science Faculty Publications and Presentations Systems Science 7-14-2006 Unifying the Theories of Inclusive Fitness and Reciprocal Altruism Jeffrey Alan Fletcher

More information

EVOLUTIONARILY STABLE STRATEGIES AND GROUP VERSUS INDIVIDUAL SELECTION

EVOLUTIONARILY STABLE STRATEGIES AND GROUP VERSUS INDIVIDUAL SELECTION 39 EVOLUTIONARILY STABLE STRATEGIES AND GROUP VERSUS INDIVIDUAL SELECTION Objectives Understand the concept of game theory. Set up a spreadsheet model of simple game theory interactions. Explore the effects

More information

Irrational behavior in the Brown von Neumann Nash dynamics

Irrational behavior in the Brown von Neumann Nash dynamics Irrational behavior in the Brown von Neumann Nash dynamics Ulrich Berger a and Josef Hofbauer b a Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration, Department VW 5, Augasse 2-6, A-1090 Wien,

More information

Play Locally, Learn Globally: The Structural Basis of Cooperation

Play Locally, Learn Globally: The Structural Basis of Cooperation Play Locally, Learn Globally: The Structural Basis of Cooperation Jung-Kyoo Choi 1 University of Massachusetts, Amherst, MA 01003 November 2002 1 I would like to thank the Santa Fe Institute for the Computational

More information

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 7 Aug 2012

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 7 Aug 2012 Building Cooperative Networks Ignacio Gomez Portillo Grup de Física Estadística, Departament de Física, Universitat Autónoma de Barcelona, 08193 Barcelona, Spain. Abstract We study the cooperation problem

More information

Game interactions and dynamics on networked populations

Game interactions and dynamics on networked populations Game interactions and dynamics on networked populations Chiara Mocenni & Dario Madeo Department of Information Engineering and Mathematics University of Siena (Italy) ({mocenni, madeo}@dii.unisi.it) Siena,

More information

evolutionary dynamics of collective action

evolutionary dynamics of collective action evolutionary dynamics of collective action Jorge M. Pacheco CFTC & Dep. Física da Universidade de Lisboa PORTUGAL http://jorgem.pacheco.googlepages.com/ warwick - UK, 27-apr-2009 the challenge of minimizing

More information

arxiv: v1 [q-bio.pe] 20 Feb 2008

arxiv: v1 [q-bio.pe] 20 Feb 2008 EPJ manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Diversity of reproduction rate supports cooperation in the arxiv:0802.2807v1 [q-bio.pe] 20 Feb 2008 prisoner s dilemma game on complex networks Attila

More information

arxiv: v2 [physics.soc-ph] 1 Sep 2013

arxiv: v2 [physics.soc-ph] 1 Sep 2013 Corruption Drives the Emergence of Civil Society Sherief Abdallah,2,3,, Rasha Sayed, Iyad Rahwan 4,2, Brad LeVeck 5, Manuel Cebrian 6,7, Alex Rutherford 4, James H. Fowler 5 arxiv:37.6646v2 [physics.soc-ph]

More information

Social Control and the Social Contract: The Emergence of Sanctioning Systems for Collective Action

Social Control and the Social Contract: The Emergence of Sanctioning Systems for Collective Action Dyn Games Appl () : 49 7 DOI.7/s5---4 Social Control and the Social Contract: The Emergence of Sanctioning Systems for Collective Action Karl Sigmund Christoph Hauert Arne Traulsen Hannelore De Silva Published

More information

Selfishness is rarely described as a group-beneficial strategy.

Selfishness is rarely described as a group-beneficial strategy. Selfishness as second-order altruism Omar Tonsi Eldakar* and David Sloan Wilson* Departments of *Biological Sciences and Anthropology, Binghamton University, Binghamton, NY 13902-6000 Edited by Brian Skyrms,

More information

THE EMERGENCE AND EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS

THE EMERGENCE AND EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION ON COMPLEX NETWORKS International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos, Vol. 22, No. 9 (2012) 1250228 (8 pages) c World Scientific Publishing Company DOI: 10.1142/S0218127412502288 THE EMERGENCE AND EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION ON

More information

Some Analytical Properties of the Model for Stochastic Evolutionary Games in Finite Populations with Non-uniform Interaction Rate

Some Analytical Properties of the Model for Stochastic Evolutionary Games in Finite Populations with Non-uniform Interaction Rate Commun Theor Phys 60 (03) 37 47 Vol 60 No July 5 03 Some Analytical Properties of the Model for Stochastic Evolutionary Games in Finite Populations Non-uniform Interaction Rate QUAN Ji ( ) 3 and WANG Xian-Jia

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT November 4, 2009 1 Introduction Outline The role of networks in cooperation A model of social norms

More information

FirstCite. e-publishing

FirstCite. e-publishing 45 456789 4 5 Received September FirstCite Accepted 4 November e-publishing Published online 7 45 46 47 48 49 Stability in negotiation games and the emergence 5 of cooperation 5 Peter D. Taylor * and Troy

More information

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 13 Apr 2016

arxiv: v2 [q-bio.pe] 13 Apr 2016 Assortment and the evolution of cooperation in a Moran process with exponential fitness * aniel ooney 1 Benjamin Allen 2,4 arl Veller 3,4,5 arxiv:1509.05757v2 [q-bio.pe] 13 Apr 2016 Abstract: We study

More information

ALTRUISM AND REPUTATION cooperation within groups

ALTRUISM AND REPUTATION cooperation within groups ALTRUISM AND REPUTATION cooperation within groups Krzysztof Kułakowski Małgorzata Krawczyk Przemysław Gawroński Kraków, Poland 21-25 September, University of Warwick, UK Complex are: text, mind, community,

More information

EVOLUTIONARY STABILITY FOR TWO-STAGE HAWK-DOVE GAMES

EVOLUTIONARY STABILITY FOR TWO-STAGE HAWK-DOVE GAMES ROCKY MOUNTAIN JOURNAL OF MATHEMATICS olume 25, Number 1, Winter 1995 EOLUTIONARY STABILITY FOR TWO-STAGE HAWK-DOE GAMES R. CRESSMAN ABSTRACT. Although two individuals in a biological species often interact

More information

The Evolution of Cooperation under Cheap Pseudonyms

The Evolution of Cooperation under Cheap Pseudonyms The Evolution of Cooperation under Cheap Pseudonyms Michal Feldman John Chuang School of Information Management and Systems University of California, Berkeley Abstract A wide variety of interactions on

More information

Brief history of The Prisoner s Dilemma (From Harman s The Price of Altruism)

Brief history of The Prisoner s Dilemma (From Harman s The Price of Altruism) Brief history of The Prisoner s Dilemma (From Harman s The Price of Altruism) 1948 The RAND Corporation. a civilian nonprofit think tank of an elite cadre of physicists, mathematicians, economists, and

More information

Diversity-optimized cooperation on complex networks

Diversity-optimized cooperation on complex networks Diversity-optimized cooperation on complex networks Han-Xin Yang, 1 Wen-Xu Wang, 2 Zhi-Xi Wu, 3 Ying-Cheng Lai, 2,4 and Bing-Hong Wang 1,5 1 Department of Modern Physics, University of Science and Technology

More information

Emergence of Cooperation in Heterogeneous Structured Populations

Emergence of Cooperation in Heterogeneous Structured Populations Emergence of Cooperation in Heterogeneous Structured Populations F. C. Santos 1, J. M. Pacheco 2,3 and Tom Lenaerts 1 1 IRIDIA, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Avenue Franklin Roosevelt 5, Bruxelles, Belgium

More information

An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory

An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory An Introduction to Evolutionary Game Theory Lectures delivered at the Graduate School on Nonlinear and Stochastic Systems in Biology held in the Department of Applied Mathematics, School of Mathematics

More information

Excessive abundance of common resources deters social responsibility

Excessive abundance of common resources deters social responsibility Excessive abundance of common resources deters social responsibility Xiaojie Chen 1, and Matjaž Perc 2, 1 Evolution and Ecology Program, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Schlossplatz

More information

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 3 Feb 2011

arxiv: v1 [physics.soc-ph] 3 Feb 2011 Phase diagrams for the spatial public goods game with pool-punishment Attila Szolnoki, 1 György Szabó, 1 and Matjaž Perc, 2 1 Research Institute for Technical Physics and Materials Science, P.O. Box 49,

More information