Strategic trading and return predictability PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Strategic trading and return predictability PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE"

Transcription

1 Strategic trading and return predictability PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Bradyn Breon-Drish Stanford Graduate School of Business October 8, 25 Abstract This paper studies a dynamic economy in which a risk-averse strategic investor trades with a continuum of competitive risk-averse uninformed investors. The strategic investor receives a random endowment of a nontradeable with payoffs correlated with the dividend on the traded stock. She trades with the uninformed to share the endowment risk. Due to her concern with price impact, the strategic investor responds sluggishly to shocks and her risky asset holdings exhibit inertia. This inertia effectively modifies the net supply of the asset, changing the amount of risk borne by the uninformed and feeding into the conditional risk premium. Gradual and predictable flows of capital as the strategic trader adjusts her portfolio therefore lead to predictable changes in the risk premium. In the short run, this generates momentum since the strategic investor s trades are positively autocorrelated. In the long run reversals materialize as the nontradeable endowment of the informed reverts to its unconditional mean and there is less aggregate risk to be borne by the uninformed. The above results are first illustrated in a model with symmetric information, and they are later shown to hold when the strategic trader also has private information about the dividends on the stock. Because she has a larger concern for price impact in this setting, momentum effects are even more extreme in magnitude. Keywords: return predictability, price drift, momentum, reversals Thanks to Anat Admati, Bruno Biais, Philip Bond, Peter DeMarzo, and David Hirshleifer for helpful comments. Assistant Professor of Finance, Stanford Graduate School of Business. breon@stanford.edu, website:

2 Introduction There is now substantial evidence that stock returns are predictable using past returns. There is remarkable consistency that returns tend to exhibit momentum at short horizons Jegadeesh and Titman 993 but reversals at longer horizons Fama and French 988; Poterba and Summers 988. These effects appear across many different asset classes Moskowitz, Ooi, and Pedersen 22 and persist despite wide knowledge of their existence. In this paper, I show that short-run momentum and long-run reversals arise naturally when some investors are strategic and trade slowly to mitigate price impact. At first this may seem unsurprising. A trader who slows her trading would seem naturally to lead prices to respond sluggishly to shocks. However, the presence of rational, competitive investors means that any predictability in returns that is not due to predictable changes in risk will be immediately arbitraged away. Rather, the intuition for predictability is more subtle. The strategic investor does respond sluggishly to shocks, which means that her risky asset holdings exhibit inertia relative to a competitive setting, underweighting new information and overweighting her current portfolio. The inertia is isomorphic to a change in the net supply of the asset, which changes the amount of risk borne by the uninformed investor and therefore the conditional risk premium. Because changes in informed holdings exhibit positive autocorrelation, they impart positive autocorrelation to returns in the short run. In the long run, the properties of the nontradeable endowment dominate, and since it is assumed to be mean reverting, tends to produce negative autocorrelation. In order to illustrate more precisely the intuition for why the strategic trader s holdings enter the price directly, it is useful to give a brief description of the key ingredients in the model. There is a risky asset in zero net supply. This asset pays a stream of dividends D t over an infinite horizon. For now, suppose the dividend follows a random walk. There are two types of investors, both with CARA utility over their respective consumption streams. The first investor is a strategic and accounts for her price impact when trading the risky asset. This trader is endowed with Z t units of a nontradeable asset whose dividend is perfectly correlated with that on the risky asset. One can think of this investor as large institutional Moskowitz, Ooi, and Pedersen 22 study time-series predictability, in which an asset s own past returns forecast its future returns. This is, in principle, distinct from the cross-sectional momentum of Jegadeesh and Titman 993 in which stocks that have done relatively well in the past continue to do relatively well in the near future. However Moskowitz, Ooi, and Pedersen 22 argue that cross-sectional momentum can be largely explained by the time-series autocorrelation of returns. 2

3 trader. The other investor is competitive and has no outside endowment. Despite the fact that the risky asset is in zero net supply, it is useful for sharing the risk of the nontradeable asset, so both investors will utilize it. As will be shown later, the optimal portfolio for the informed investor will take the form θ It+ = β I2 D t + Z t P t + + θ It. Hence, regardless of the realizations of the divided, endowment shock, and asset price, at each time t+ trader optimally chooses to hold on to fraction + ˆ of her prevoius portfolio θ It. This effectively reduces the free float of the asset, which reduces the amount of risk that must be borne by the uninformed trader and therefore reduces the conditional risk premium. Moreover, because changes in θ It are autocorrelated and are correlated with Z t it leads to predictable changes in risk premia. As suggested by the above discussion, the size and importance of momentum effects depends on the trader s concern about price impact. The symmetric information setting is therefore troublesome for at least two reasons. First, momentum effects may be attenuated relative to what we would expect in an arguably more realistic setting with asymmetric information in which traders are particularly concerned with price impact due to information leakage. Secondly, positing that there are two otherwise identical investors, one of whom accounts for price impact and one of whom does not may seem contrived. Hence, I consider a full version of the model in which the strategic trader also observes a private signal about next period s dividend, which provides a additional motivation for strategic behavior on her part. This causes her to further slow her trading speed and increases quantitatively the size and duration of momentum, which has the potential to better match stylized facts quantitatively. The model with asymmetric information is also of independent theoretical interest since it is, to my knowledge, the first model of dynamic trading in which investors behave strategically and are risk-averse, prices are set by market-clearing, and asymmetric information is preserved in equilibrium. Therefore, the model can be seen as an extension of Wang 994 to incorporate strategic behavior on the part of the informed investor, or a two-investor version of Vayanos 999 in which the equilibrium price does not perfectly reveal all private information. The model makes novel predictions relative to existing theories of return predictability. The results imply that short-run momentum should be larger in magnitude and longer lasting 3

4 in settings in which price impact is of greater concern to traders. For instance, settings in which large traders control a large amount of capital, in which informational heterogeneity is large, or in which there is less residual uncertainty. The model also does not require one to consider the risky asset as equity. This is especially appealing in light of recent work documenting momentum across many diverse asset classes Moskowitz, Ooi, and Pedersen 22, which may be hard to reconcile with some existing models that are specific to equity in individual firms. While this work provides one potential explanation for observed return predictability. Its predictions are not mutually exclusive with those of other theoretical models. Such works can be broadly classified in into risk-based rational explanations, and explanations based on various behavioral biases. Among the first type are Sagi and Seasholes 27 who show that realistic return autocorrelation patterns emerge from firms optimal decisions in a model of investment under uncertainty, Vayanos and Woolley 23 who demonstrate momentum and reversal can result from flows between active and passive funds, and Albuquerque and Miao 24 who appeal to advance information as a source of momentum. On the behavioral side, Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam 998 study a model of investor over- and underreaction, and Hong and Stein 999 consider a setting in which some investors neglect the information in prices and information diffuses slowly across the population. The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 I set up the full version of the model in which the strategic trader has private information on both her endowment and the dividend on the risky asset. Section 3 solves the special case in which there is no private information about the dividend and therefore, in equilibrium, the investors have symmetric information. The solution is much simpler in this case and the intuition comes through more clearly. Section 4 considers the version with asymmetric information, and Section 5 concludes. Appendix A presents a general solution of the dynamic programming problem faced by the agents in the model and is used to simplify the solution of the various cases, and most proofs are relegated to Appendix B. 2 Model 2. Setup Trade takes place at a set of discrete dates {th} t Z, where h > is a constant. 4

5 There are two assets in the economy, a risk-free asset with gross per-period return R h = e rh and a risky asset with per-period dividend hd t, where the rate D t follows D t+ = + φ D h D }{{} t + φ DG h G }{{} t + σ D h ε }{{} Dt+. a D a DG b D The dividend has a persistent component G t that follows an AR process The risky asset is in zero net supply. G t = + φ G hg t + σ }{{} G h ε }{{} Gt. a G b D As the focus of the paper is on the dynamics of conditional expected returns but not their unconditional level, this is without loss of generality. There are two types of agents in the economy. There is a single informed trader I. 2 This investor has discounted CARA utility over her consumption h exp{ ρhs α I c Is }. s= The informed agent is endowed with Z t units of a nontradeable asset whose payoff is perfectly correlated with the dividend, D t+. The endowment follows the process Z t+ = + φ Z h Z }{{} t + σ Z h ε }{{} Z,t. a Z b Z To ensure existence of a stationary equilibrium, it is a maintained assumption that all of a D, a G, and a Z are strictly less than the gross risk free rate R h. Also, for tractability, and similar to Vayanos 999, I assume that the informed trader also receives an endowment of cash Z t ha D D t + ha DG G t which is equal to the negative of the expected dividend next period. The informed agent observes G t and Z t directly, and she is allowed to condition on realized dividends and prices. Formally, an informed trader s filtration is F It = σ{g t, Z t, D t, P t }. 2 It is straightforward to extend the model to incorporate multiple informed traders, as long as they all observe the same private information. Without this assumption, the infinite regress problem renders the problem intractable Makarov and Rytchkov, 22; Singleton, 986. The qualitative results with multiple informed traders results are similar but the analysis is more complicated, so I do not present them here. 5

6 There is a competitive uninformed trader with CARA utility over consumption h exp { ρhs α U c us }. s= This trader can be considered as a representative agent for an underlying unit mass of infinitesimal uninformed investors, all with the same utility function. The uninformed trader does not observe the dividend growth rate G t nor the informed trader s private endowment Z t. I entertain the possibility that he can observe a noisy public signal about G t S Ut S Ut = hg t + σ U h }{{} b S ε Ut. This nests the special case of no signal, σ U, or perfect observation of G t, σ U =. The uninformed trader can also condition on realized dividends and the asset price. Formally, the uninformed trader s filtration is F Ut = σ{s Ut, D t, P t }. 2.2 Equilibrium definition Following Kyle 989 and Vayanos 999 I search for Nash equilibria in linear demand schedules with constant coefficients. 3 Each period, traders submit demand schedules to a Walrasian auctioneer, who aggregates the schedules and announces a market-clearing price at which trade takes place. Immediately before the risky-asset market opens at time t, the informed trader observes the realization of the dividend growth rate, G t, as well as her endowment of the nontradeable asset Z t. All traders also collect and thereby observe the time-t dividend hd t on their risky asset holdings from the previous round of trading. Let θ jt denote the number of shares of the risky asset and M jt the amount of cash holdings of the risk-free asset held by agent j entering the time-t trading round. Ĝ t E[G t F Ut and Ẑt E[Z t F Ut denote the uninformed agent s conditional expectations. I conjecture that both types I and U follow linear strategies that specify their time-t trades 3 There may exist other equilibria in which agents follow trigger punishment strategies. However, the existence and characteristics of such equilibria are, to my knowledge, still an unexplored question and are outside the scope of this paper. Let 6

7 x j,t θ j,t+ θ j,t as x It = β I θ It + β I2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t + β I5 S Ut + β I6 D t + β I7 Ĝ t + β I8 Ẑ t + β I9 S Ut P t x Ut = β U θ Ut + β U2 D t + β U5 S Ut + β U6 D t + β U7 Ĝ t + β U8 Ẑ t + β U9 S Ut P t. 2 The dependence on lagged dividends, public signals, and expectations is unconventional. As will become clear in the derivation below, this dependence follows from the strategic behavior of the informed trader. At each time-t, she understands that her trade will result in the uninformed trader updating his conditional expectations. In order to compute the new values of those expectations she must keep track of both their most recent values as well as the most recent values of the other random quantities observed by the uninformed. Definition Equilibrium. An equilibrium in the economy is a collections of demand functions {x jt } t= and consumption rates {c jt } t=, measurable with respect to F jt, and a sequence of prices {P t } t= such that demands and consumptions solve the traders optimization problems max {x jt,c jt } E j [ h exp { ρhs α j c us } s= j {I, U}, s.t. M jt+ = R h M jt c jt h x jt P t x jt + θ jt + x jt hd t+ + {j=i} Z t hd t+ θ jt+ = θ jt + x jt, and the risky asset market clears at each time t x It + x Ut =, t. 3 Symmetric Information As a benchmark, it is useful to characterize the equilibrium when both traders observe G t and Z t. For consistency, I will continue to refer to trader I, who is strategic and receives the random endowment Z t, as informed, despite the fact that she has no information advantage in this setting. I conjecture and verify that traders follow linear strategies of the form x jt = β jx jt γ j P t 3 7

8 where X jt = θ jt D t G t Z t, and β j is a 5 vector. The equilibrium price will follow from imposing the market clearing condition. I solve the traders problems by dynamic programming. The candidate value functions take the form V j M jt, X jt = exp { αq j M jt 2 } αx jtq j X jt, 4 where Q j is a positive constant, and Q j is a symmetric matrix with generic element Q j ik, i, k {,..., n}. The following transversality condition guarantees that a function satisfying the Bellman equation characterizes an optimum lim E [ exp{ ρhs}vj M js,xjs. s 3. Informed trader s problem The informed trader behaves strategically. Following Kyle 989 I solve a less-restrictive problem in which she is allowed to optimize against the residual demand schedule of the uninformed trader, and then I show that this strategy can be implemented by submitting a demand schedule. Proposition 3.. Suppose that both traders observe G t and Z t directly. The informed investor s optimal demand can be implemented by submitting a demand schedule with coefficients β I = [ α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + Q I R h p Ix a IxQ I a Ix [ QI C Ixa I + a IxQ I a I α I B I x ˇQ I B I X = [ α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + Q I R h p Ix a IxQ I a Ix QI R h 6 where Q I = R h, h R h and Q I solves system Q I = [ A I Q I a R IC Ix R h p I + a IQ I a Ix α I B ˇQ I x I B I X C I 7 h Q I a IC Ix R h p I + a IQ I a Ix α I B I ˇQ x I B I X + 2 α I e e logr h + R h log R h 8 Rh h ρh + R h 2 log d I. 5

9 The matrices A U, B U, and C U are defined in the Appendix. I sketch the proof here, which is established rigorously in the Appendix. To determine the residual demand schedule at time t, substitute the conjectured uninformed demand function 3 into the market clearing condition and rearrange to yield P t x It = x It + β UX Ut = [ β U θ It + β U2 D t + β U3 G t + β U4 Z t + x It = p IX It + p Ix x It, where the second equality follows from the market clearing condition, which implies θ It = θ Ut, and where p I = β U and p Ix = /. The informed trader s cash holdings therefore follow M It+ = R h M It ch xp IX It + p Ix x + θ It + x + Z t hd t+, and the non-cash state variables follow X It+ = a D a DG a G a Z } {{ } a I X It + σ D h σ G h σ Z h } {{ } b I ε t+ + }{{} a Ix Setting up the Bellman equation and plugging into the conjectured value function in eq. 4 allows one to solve for the optimal demand and consumption x = [ α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + 2Q I R h p Ix a IxQ I a Ix [ QI C Ixa I + a IxQ I a I α I B I x ˇQ I B I X XIt c = α I R h [ α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + 2Q I R h p Ix a IxQ I a Ix QI R h p IX It [ Rh ρh log h + 2 log d R h I + α I M It + h 2 α IX ItB IC I B I X t. Plugging this back into the Bellman equation and matching terms yields the system in eq. 7. While the optimal demand above was derived by allowing the trader to optimize against the residual demand schedule of the uninformed traders, it can be implemented by submitting a demand schedule to the Walrasian auctioneer. In equilibrium, one has P t x = p I X It + p Ix x. Plugging in and rearranging to isolate x yields x = [ α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + Q I R h p Ix a IxQ I a Ix [ Q I C Ixa I + a IxQ I a I α I B I x ˇQ I B I X XIt Q I R h P t x Matching with the initial conjecture yields the system equations for the demand coefficients. 9 x.

10 3.2 Uninformed investor s problem The uninformed trader behaves competitively. Hence, she takes the equilibrium price as given when forming her optimal demand. Because of this, her residual demand schedule is simply equal to the equilibrium price, and one can solve her problem using standard methods with no additional effort to express her optimal demand as a schedule. Proposition 3.2. Suppose that both traders observe G t and Z t directly. The uninformed trader s optimal demand function has coefficients that satisfy where β U = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux [ QU C Uxa U + a UxQ U a U α U B U x ˇQ U B U X = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux QU R h. 9 and Q U solves the system Q U = R h, h R h Q U = R h [ A U Q U a UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B U x ˇQ U B U X C U QU a UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B U x ˇQ U B U X + 2 e e logr h + R h log α U R h Rh The matrices A U, B U, and C U are defined in the Appendix. h ρh + R h 2 log d I. To determine the equilibrium price at time t, substitute the conjectured demand functions 3 into the market clearing condition and rearrange to yield P t = β + γ IX It + β UX Ut U = [δ I δ U θ Ut + β I + β U G t + β I2 + β U2 Z t + β I3 + β U3 D t + = p UX Ut, β I + β U where p U = + The uninformed trader s cash holdings follow. M Ut+ = R h M Ut ch xp UX Ut + θ Ut + x Ut hd t+, 8

11 and the non-cash state variables follow X Ut+ = +φ D h φ DG h +φ G h +φ Z h } {{ } a U X Ut + The optimal demand and consumption are σ D h σ G h σ Z h } {{ } b U ε Ut+ + }{{} a Ux x. x = C U B U X Ut = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a [ UxQ U a Ux QU C Uxa U R h p U + a UxQ U a U α U B U ˇQ x U B U X XUt c = [ Rh ρh log + α U R h h 2 log d R h U + α U M Ut + h 2 α UX UtB UC U B UX Ut. Plugging back into the Bellman equation yields Q U in closed form and a system of equations for the matrix Q U Q U = A U B R UC U B U h + 2 α U e e logr h + R h log R h Q U = R h, h R h Rh ρh + R h 2 log d U h = A U Q U a R UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B ˇQ U x U B U X C U h QU a UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B U ˇQ x U B U X + 2 e e logr h + R h log α U R h Rh h ρh + R h 2 log d I In equilibrium P t = p U X Ut, so it is immediate that the optimal demand takes the form of a demand schedule x = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux [ QU C Uxa U + a UxQ U a U α U B U x ˇQ U B U X XUt [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux QU R h P t x Ut. To match the initial conjectured demand, one requires β U = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux [ QU C Uxa U + a UxQ U a U α U B U x ˇQ U B U X 2 = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux QU R h. 3

12 3.3 Equilibrium Equilibrium is characterized by a solution to the informed trader demand equations 5 and 6, informed Bellman conditions 7, the uninformed demand equations 2 and 3, and the uninformed Bellman conditions. Due to the assumption of symmetric information, many of the equilibrium coefficients can be solved in closed form. The following proposition characterizes the equilibrium. Proposition 3.3 Symmetric information equilibrium. Supposing that both traders observe G t and Z t directly the equilibrium demand function coefficients are [ Q Q R h Q I + α 2 R2 h h2 a 2 DG b 2 I R h a D 2 G R h a G + b 2 2 D ha D β I = R h a D ha DG R h R h a D R h a G = Q R h β U = = Q R h a Z Q I4 Q R h +α I Q I44 Q2 b 2 h2 b 2 D R h Z R h a D + Q2 I4 b2 Z +α I Q I44 b 2 Z Q [ Q 2 I + α Rh 2h2 a 2 DG b 2 G I R h a D 2 R h a G + Q 2 2 b2 I4 D + b2 Z + α I Q I44 b 2 Z Q Q U + α 2 R2 h h2 a 2 DG b 2 U R h a D 2 G R h a G + b 2 2 D + Q2 U4 b2 Z +α U Q U44 b 2 Z ha D R h a D ha DG R h Q R h [ [ Q U + α U Q 2 R 2 h h2 R h a D 2 R h a D R h a G a Z Q U4 Q R h +α U Q U44 b 2 Z a 2 DG b 2 G R h a G 2 + b2 D where the Bellman coefficients Q jik are those that solve 7 and. Q 2 U4 + b2 Z + α U Q U44 b 2 Z + Q R h The following Corollary applies the market clearing condition and characterizes the equilibrium price. Corollary 3.4. Supposing that both traders observe G t and Z t directly, the equilibrium price of the risky asset is. where P t = a D a DG R h hd t + R h a D R h a D R h a G hg t + A Z Z t + A θ θ It, A Z = + + < A θ = + >. 2

13 With symmetric information, the equilibrium price is equal to the present value of expected dividends, minus an additive discount to compensate the uninformed traders for bearing a portion of the risk associated with the endowment Z t. These features are also true in a competitive environment Wang, 994. Strategic behavior also leads to a novel dependence on the current holdings of the informed trader, which is key for generating short-run momentum. 4 To understand why this term arises, it is useful to analyze the demand functions of the two types of traders. Define ˆ as the informed trader s price coefficient in the absence of price impact, ˆ =, and use the fact that β I = + demand of the informed trader as x It = β I2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t P t = = ˆ + ˆ ˆ + ˆ ˆ + θ It = β I2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t P t ˆγ θ It I ˆγI β I2 D t + ˆ β I3 G t + ˆγ I Z t ˆ P t θ It. Compare with the demand function for the uninformed trader x Ut = β U2 D t + β U3 G t + β U4 Z t P t θ Ut. to write the Both agents trade to close the gap between their current portfolio θ jt and a target portfolio that would be optimal in a competitive setting. competitive, she does so immediately, leading to a post-trade portfolio θ Ut+ = β U2 D t + β U3 G t + β U4 Z t P t. Because the uninformed trader is Due to her concern with price impact, the informed trader closes the gap slowly. Her new portfolio is a weighted average of the target portfolio and her previous holdings θ It+ = ˆ ˆ + ˆγI β I2 D t + ˆ β I3 G t + ˆγ I Z t ˆ P t + ˆ + θ It. Regardless of the realizations of the state variables governing the dividend and regardless of the asset price, the trader optimally chooses to hold + ˆ θ It units. This effectively changes 4 Equivalently, since θ It +θ Ut = in equilibrium, the price could be written as a function of the uninformed trader s holdings. 3

14 the net supply of the asset, which in turn, reduces the amount of risk that must be borne by the uninformed trader. This translates into an additional discount premium in the asset price when the informed holds a short long position. Moreover, because θ It is both autocorrelated and correlated with Z t, it leads to predictable dynamics in returns. Let R e t+ = P t+ + D t+ R h P t denote the excess dollar return on the risky asset in period t +. From Wang 993 and Albuquerque and Miao 24 it is known that in a competitive setting, returns exhibit negative autocorrelation at all horizons when a Z < /R h, positive autocorrelation when a Z > /R h, and no correlation when a Z = /R h. In a competitive setting, Z t represents the amount of aggregate risk that must be borne in the economy and any return predictability comes from this predictability in risk. With slow trading by the informed investor, the dynamics of aggregate risk borne by the uninformed are no longer purely exogenous and are affected by the dynamics of the informed inventory. The following Proposition characterizes the conditional expectation of R e t+k given R e t when a Z = /R h. It is possible to characterize the conditional expectation in the general case, which I do in the proof, but the expression is sufficiently complicated that presenting the expression here provides little insight. results. I will return to the general case in numerical Proposition 3.5. Suppose that a Z = /R h. The conditional expectation of the period t + k excess return given the period t excess return is E[Rt+k R e t e = A θa Z Covθ It+k Rθ It+k,Z t R h Z t +A 2 θ ak θ Covθ It+k R h θ It+k,θ It R h θ It R e VarRt e t where a θ = + = a k θ A Z A θ β U4 + VarZ t R h Z t + A 2 θ Var θ It R h θ It R VarR t, e t e is the persistence of the informed investor s position in the risky asset. The coefficient on R e t is strictly positive for all k and decays geometrically towards zero. The Proposition clarifies the mechanism by which strategic behavior leads to momentum. There are two effects, one direct and the other indirect. The direct effect comes from the fact that, innovations in the informed trader s holdings are themselves autocorrelated. Suppose 4

15 that the informed starts with a net short position. If the informed trader reduces her holdings today, the uninformed bear less risk take a smaller long position and therefore the price increases. Because of the natural persistence in informed holdings, this is also associated with reduced holdings in the near future, which are associated with further price increases. The indirect effect comes from the fact that shocks to the endowment of the nontradeable forecast additional buildup/drawdown of her holdings in the future. Supposing that Z t increases, the informed immediately sell an additional amount of the risky asset to hedge their exposure. This pushes the price down. Because of slow trading, she is also expected to continue reducing her holdings in the near future, thereby requiring the uninformed to bear more risk and further depressing the price. As indicated by the Proposition, strategic trading alone leads only to momentum. It is natural to expect that momentum effects will be stronger when the informed faces greater price impact and therefore trades more slowly. Figure 3.3 plots return autocorrelations at various horizons k for a baseline calibration as well as for various deviations from the baseline. The reported baseline parameters are based loosely on Campbell and Kyle 993, who calibrated them using annual data. When producing the plots, I have converted all parameters to a monthly frequency, to better match the horizons over which momentum studies are conducted. In Panel b, a doubling of the residual standard deviation σ D leads to momentum effects that are both larger in magnitude and take longer to converge. In Panel c, I fix the aggregate risk tolerance capital equal to that in the baseline, but give the informed trader only % of total capital. As her concern with price impact is now smaller, momentum is attenuated. Finally Panel d shows that a riskier endowment, for which the uninformed require a larger risk premium, increases price impact and leads to stronger momentum effects. In general, when a Z < /R, momentum no longer appears at all horizons. Rather, the relatively strong mean reversion in the endowment Z t dominates at longer horizons. Figure?? 4 Asymmetric information This section characterizes the equilibrium in the full version of the model with asymmetric information about both dividend growth and the endowment of the informed trader. Be- 5

16 corrr e k+t, r e t.2..8 corrr e k+t, r e t t a Baseline t b Higher residual var. corrr e k+t, r e t corrr e k+t, r e t t c Smaller % Informed t d Riskier endowment Figure : Autocovariance function of one-period returns. Panel a: Baseline calibration. Parameters: h =, α I = 9, α U = 3, R h =.5, a D =, a DG =, a G = /2, a Z = /.5, σ D =, σ G = 2, and σ Z = /2. Panel b: Residual variance σ D = 2, Panel c: Informed have % of agg. risk tol, α I = 45/2, α U = 5/2, Panel d: Riskier nontradeable endowment, σ Z =. 6

17 cause the derivation is sufficiently novel, I walk through how to set up the state equations and discuss the uninformed investor s inference problem in the main text rather than the Appendix. At a high level, the derivation is analogous to that in the case of symmetric information. One must solve the traders consumption/portfolio problems using dynamic programming. Having characterized the optimal demand functions, the equilibrium is determined by matching the coefficients with those conjectured in eq. and 2. The equilibrium price follows by imposing the market clearing condition. The derivation is similar to that in Vayanos 999, complicated by the fact that the uninformed investor is not able to perfectly infer G t from the equilibrium price, or Wang 994, complicated by the fact that the informed trader behaves strategically. 4. Uninformed investor s problem Before solving the informed trader s problem, I determine a random variable that is informationally equivalent to the incremental information conveyed by the time-t price and solve his learning problem using the Kalman filter. Given the conjectured demands in eq. and 2, the equilibrium price is [ P t = β I θ It + β U θ Ut + β I2 + β U2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t + β I5 + β U5 S Ut + + β I6 + β U6 D t + β I7 + β U7 Ĝt + β I8 + β U8 Ẑt + β I9 + β U9 S Ut [ = β I + β U θ Ut + β I2 + β U2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t + β I5 + β U5 S Ut + + β I6 + β U6 D t + β I7 + β U7 Ĝt + β I8 + β U8 Ẑt + β I9 + β U9 S Ut [β θ Ut + β 2 D t + β I3 G t + Z t + β 5 S Ut + β 6 D t + β 7 Ĝ t + β 8 Ẑ t + β 9 S Ut γ 4 where the second equality uses the fact that in equilibrium θ It + θ Ut = since the asset is in zero net supply. It follows from eq. 4 that when used in combination with the current dividend and public signal, as well as past realizations of these variables, the asset price allows the uninformed traders to infer the statistic S P t γp t β θ Ut β 2 D t β 5 S Ut β 6 D t β 7 Ĝ t β 8 Ẑ t β 9 S Ut = β I3 G t + Z t. 7

18 Since the uninformed does not observe, G t or Z t, she must filter them from observation of realized dividends, prices, and public signals, {D t, S P t, S Ut }. The following proposition characterizes the conditional mean and variance matrix of G t, Z t using results from Liptser and Shiryaev 2. Proposition 4.. The conditional distribution of G t, Z t given {D t, S P t, S Ut } is normal with mean Ĝt, Ẑt νg ν and covariance matrix ν = GZ. ν GZ The conditional mean satisfies the difference equation ν Z Ĝt ag = a Z Ẑ t Ĝt Ẑ t where K is a 2 3 matrix with elements K i,j given by D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t + K S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t, S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t K, = K,2 = K,3 = K 2, = K 2,2 = a DG b 2 Sa Z b 2 G β2 I3 +a Gb 2 Z β2 I4ν G b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4+a G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 β 2 I3 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4ν G b 2 S β I3b 2 D b2 G +a Ga G a Z b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gν G b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4+a G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 β 2 I3 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4ν G b 2 D b2 G b2 Z hβ2 I4 +ha2 Z b2 D b2 G β2 I3 +a2 G b2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 Z β2 I4ν G b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4+a 2 G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 βi3 2 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4ν 2 G a DG b 2 Z a G b 2 S +a Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 β I3 ν G +a DG a Zb 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4ν 2 GZ b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4+a 2 G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 βi3 2 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4ν 2 G b 2 Z b 2 Db 2 S +b2 G h2 +a 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 ν G a Z b 2 D a G b 2 S +a Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 β I3 ν GZ b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4+a 2 G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 βi3 2 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 βi4ν 2 G K 2,3 = b 2 Z hβ I3b 2 D b2 G +a Ga G a Z b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gν G+a Z b 2 D ha Zb 2 G β2 I3 +a Gb 2 Z β2 I4ν GZ b 2 Db 2 G b2 S β2 I3 +b2 Zb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4+a G a Z 2 b 2 D +a2 DG b2 Gb 2 S +a2 Z b2 D b2 G h2 β 2 I3 +b2 Za 2 G b2 D h2 +a 2 DGb 2 S +b2 G h2 β 2 I4ν G. The conditional variance of G t satisfies ag a Z 2 b 2 D + a 2 DGb 2 G b 2 S + a 2 Zb 2 Db 2 Gh 2 βi3 2 + b 2 Z a 2 G b 2 Dh 2 + a 2 DG b 2 S + b 2 Gh 2 βi4 2 ν 2 G and a 2 DGb 2 Gb 2 Sb 2 Zβ 2 I4 + b 2 D a 2 Z b 2 Gb 2 Sβ 2 I3 + b 2 Z b 2 Db 2 Gb 2 Sb 2 Zβ 2 I4 = ν GZ = β I3 ν G 2 βi3 ν Z = ν G. a 2 G b 2 S b 2 Gh 2 βi4 2 νg 8

19 Having solved the uninformed trader s filtering problem, it remains to solve for her optimal portfolio and consumption rules. Augmenting with a constant, the vector of non-cash state variables for the uninformed investor is X Ut = θ Ut D t S P t S Ut D t Ĝ t Ẑ t S Ut. In Appendix??, I solve the dynamic programming problem for a CARA investor given arbitrary dynamics for the state variables. One can apply the results there once the dynamics of M Ut and X Ut are written in form in eq.??. Let ε U t+ be a 3 vector composed of the forecast errors of the uninformed investor ε U Dt+ = D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t ε U P t+ = S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t ε U Ut+ = S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t. It follows from Proposition 4. that under the uninformed investors filtration, ε U t+ is iid over time and is normally distributed with mean zero and covariance matrix a 2 DG ν G + b 2 D a DG a G a Z β I3 ν G a DG a G hν G Σ U = a DG a G a Z β I3 ν G βi3 2 a G a Z 2 ν G + βi3 2 b2 G + β2 I4 b2 Z hβ I3a G a G a Z ν G + b 2 G. a DG a G hν G hβ I3 a G a G a Z ν G + b 2 G h2 a 2 G ν G + b 2 G + b2 S First, consider his cash holdings M Ut. The equilibrium price in eq. 4, which depends on the state variables X Ut can be written compactly as p U X Ut, where p U is a 9 vector with elements given by the coefficients in the price function 4. M Ut+ = R h M Ut c Ut h x Ut P t + θ Ut + x Ut hd t+ = R h M Ut c Ut h x Ut p UX Ut + e 2X Ut + x Ut he 3X Ut+ = R h M Ut c Ut h x Ut p UX Ut + X Ute 2 e 3hX Ut+ + x Ut he 3X Ut+. 9

20 The non-constant elements of X Ut+ obey the difference equations θ Ut+ = θ Ut + x Ut D t+ = a D D t + a DG Ĝ t + ε U Dt+ S P t+ = β I3 a G Ĝ t + a Z Ẑ t + ε U P t+ S Ut+ = S Ut + ha G Ĝ t + ε U Ut+ where D t = D t Ĝ t = a G Ĝ t + K D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t + K 2 S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t + K 3 S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t Ẑ t = a Z Ẑ t + K 2 D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t + K 22 S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t + K 23 S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t S Ut = S Ut S P t = γp t β θ Ut β 2 D t β 5 S Ut β 6 D t β 7 Ĝ t β 8 Ẑ t β 9 S Ut. Collecting terms and defining â U = and a D + a DG β I3 a G ha G a Z K 2 β K 22 β K K 2 β 2 K 2 K 22 β 2 K 3 K 2 β 5 K 23 K 22 β 5 a D K K 2 β 6 a D K 2 K 22 β 6 K 2 a DG β I3 a G + β 6 K 22 K 23 ha G K 2 a Z + β 8 a Z a Z + β 7 K 22 K 3 K 2 β 9 K 23 K 22 β 9 a G K a DG β I3 a G + β 7 K 2 K 3 ha G b U =, a UP = a DGK 2 γ γβ I3 a G K 2 + a Z K 22 ha G K 2 γ K 2 γ K 22 γ, 2

21 one can write the dynamics of the state vector compactly as X Ut+ = â U X Ut + b U ε U t+ + e 2 x Ut + a UP P t = â U X Ut + b U ε U t+ + e 2 x Ut + a UP p U X Ut = a U X Ut + b U ε U t+ + a Ux x Ut, with a U = â U + a UP p U and a Ux = e 2. One can now appeal to the general formulation of the dynamic programming problem in Appendix A and the solution proceeds similarly to the symmetric information case. 4.2 Informed investor s problem Since the informed investor directly observes all random variables in the model, her state vector X It follows immediately. As with the uninformed investor, it is convenient to also augment with a constant X It = θ It D t G t Z t S Ut D t Ĝ t Ẑ t S Ut. The informed trader is strategic, and following Kyle 989 her optimal demand can be determined by allowing her to optimize against the residual demand schedule of the uninformed trader. Under the conjectured function in 4, her residual demand schedule P t x It follows from rearranging the market clearing condition to yield x It + β U θ Ut + β U2 D t + β U5 S Ut + β U6 D t + β U7 Ĝ t + β U8 Ẑ t + β U9 S Ut P t =. P t x It = [ x It + β U θ Ut + β U2 D t + β U5 S Ut + β U6 D t + β U7 Ĝ t + β U8 Ẑ t + β U9 S Ut Since market clearing requires θ It + θ Ut =, this can be written purely as a function of random variables directly observed by the trader P t x It = [ x It β U θ It + β U2 D t + β U5 S Ut + β U6 D t + β U7 Ĝ t + β U8 Ẑ t + β U9 S Ut The residual demand schedule can be written compactly as P t x It = p IX It + p Ix x It. 5 2

22 where the vector p I and scalar p Ix are easily computed from the expressions above. The informed trader s cash position evolves as M jt+ = R h M jt c jt h x jt P t + θ jt + x jt hd t+ + Z t hd t+ The non-constant variables in the informed state vector obey θ It+ = θ It + x It D t+ = a D D t + a DG G t + b D ε Dt+ G t+ = a G G t + b G ε Gt+ Z t+ = a Z Z t + b Z ε Zt+ S Ut+ = S Ut + ha G G t + hb G ε Gt+ + b S ε Ut+ D t = D t Ĝ t = a G Ĝ t + K D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t + K 2 S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t + K 3 S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t Ẑ t = a Z Ẑ t + K 2 D t a D D t a DG Ĝ t + K 22 S P t β I3 a G Ĝ t a Z Ẑ t + K 23 S Ut S Ut ha G Ĝ t S Ut = S Ut where S P t = γp t x It β θ Ut β 2 D t β 5 S Ut β 6 D t β 7 Ĝ t β 8 Ẑ t β 9 S Ut. and P t x It = p IX It + p Ix x It so that the trader correctly understands that she controls the uninformed trader s belief update via the P t term in S P t and takes as given the conditional expectations Ĝt and Ẑt held by the uninformed trader entering the period. 22

23 and Let â I = a D a DG a G a Z ha G + K 2 β K 22 β K K 2 β 2 K 2 K 22 β 2 K 3 K 2 β 5 K 23 K 22 β 5 a D K K 2 β 6 a D K 2 K 22 β 6 K 2 a DG β I3 a G + β 6 K 22 K 23 ha G K 2 a Z + β 8 a Z a Z + β 7 K 22 K 3 K 2 β 9 K 23 K 22 β 9 a G K a DG β I3 a G + β 7 K 2 K 3 ha G b D b G b I = b Z b S, a IP = K 2 γ K 22 γ. Let ε I t = ε D,t, ε G,t, ε Z,t, σ Ut and write the dynamics of the state vector as X It+ = â I X It + b I ε I t+ + e 2 x It + a IP P t x It = â I X t + b I ε I t+ + e 2 x It + a IP p IX t + p Ix x It = a I X It + b I ε I t+ + a Ix x It with a I = â I + a IP p I and a Ix = e 2 + a IP p Ix., One can now appeal to the general formulation of the dynamic programming problem in Appendix A and the solution proceeds similarly to the symmetric information case. 5 Conclusion This paper has studied return predictability in a model of dynamic trading. Results indicate that when investors slow their trading due to a concern with price impact it leads naturally 23

24 to short-run momentum in returns. The mechanism is simple: the portfolio of a strategic trader exhibits inertia, which effectively changes the net supply of the asset available to other traders in the market. Gradual and predictable flows of capital as the strategic trader adjusts her portfolio lead to predictable changes in risk and therefore in risk premia. Numerical calibration suggests that the size and duration of momentum effects are more pronounced in settings in which concern for price impact is larger, such as when informed traders control a larger fraction of capital in the market or there is greater residual uncertainty in asset payoffs. The model also predicts that returns should revert in the long-run due to mean reversion in non-informational motives for trade. Here, those motives were captured by a correlated nontradeable, but the intuition should be robust to other mechanisms. While I have relied on numerical solutions for most of the results, it would be interesting to further explore whether analytical results are available, even if only in special cases. This would help further illuminate the economic mechanisms. It would also be useful to carefully calibrate the model to various markets other than US equities and see how well it can reconcile the cross-market evidence in Moskowitz, Ooi, and Pedersen 22. I leave these problems for future work. 24

25 A General dynamic programming problem In this section, I solve the infinite-horizon consumption-portfolio problem for a trader with discounted CARA utility over consumption and who faces asset prices driven by an n + dimensional state vector. The analysis nests the cases in which the trader does and does not have price impact. Proposition A.. Consider a trader with utility s= h exp{ ρhs αc s} whose cash holdings evolve as in eq. 7, driven by a n + vector of observable state variables X t, the dynamics of which are specified in eq. 6. Supposing that the matrix equation Q = A B C B+ a + 2 α e loga + a a log a h ρh + log d e a 2 where A, B, and C are defined below has a symmetric solution in Q and that the matrix C is negative semidefinite, then the trader s optimal portfolio and consumption choices exist and are given by ˆx = C B ˆX t c = [ a ρh log αa h and her value function is where V M t, X t = exp + 2 log d + α a a M t a c 2 α ˆX ta B C B ˆX t, { αq M t 2 αx tqx t }, Q = a a c Let M t denote the trader s cash position. Let X t denote the n + -dimensional vector of non-cash state variables. Let x R m be the vector of non-consumption choice variables. Suppose that X t has dynamics X t+ = ax t + bε t+ + a x x 6 where a is an n + n + matrix, b is an n + k matrix, a x is an n + m matrix, all of which can depend on h. Suppose further that the first element of ˆX is the constant. 25

26 Suppose that the dynamics of M t are M t+ = a M t + a X t + b bε t+ + a c c + a x x + c X X t x 2 x c x x + 2 X tc XX X t 7 + C X X t + C x x X t+ + 2 X t+c XX X t+, 8 where a and a c are constants, a is n +, b is k, a x is m, c X is m n +, c x is m m, c XX is a symmetric n + n + matrix, C X is n + n +, and C x is n + m, and C XX is a symmetric n + n + matrix. Consider the problem of the investor. Conjecture that her value function V is exponentiallinear in M t and exponential-quadratic in the other state variables, ˆXt V M t, X t = exp { αq M t 2 } αx tqx t, where Q is a constant and Q is an n + n + symmetric positive semidefinite matrix. The Bellman equation is V M t, X t = max x { h exp{ αc} E t [ exp { ρh αq M t+ 2 αx t+qx t+ }}. 9 26

27 Using the equations for X t+, the expression in the exponent in eq. 9 becomes αq a M t + a X t + b bε t+ + a c c + a x x + c X X t x 2 x c x x + 2 X tc XX X t + C X X t + C x x ax t + bε t+ + a x x αq 2 ax t + a x x C XX ax t + a x x + [C XX ax t + a x x bε t+ + 2 [bε t+ C XX bε t+ 2 α ax t + a x x Q ax t + a x x α[q ax t + a x x bε t+ 2 α[bε t+ Qbε t+ = αq a M t αq a c c 2 αq X t e a + C Xa + e a + C Xa + c XX X t αq X te a x + c X + C Xa x + a C x x 2 αq x C xa x + a xc x c x x αq b e + C X X t + C x x bε t+ 2 α ax t + a x x Q + Q C XX ax t + a x x α[q + Q C XX ax t + a x x bε t+ 2 α[bε t+ Q + Q C XX bε t+ = αq a M t αq a c c 2 αx t Q e a + C Xa + e a + C Xa + c XX + a Q + Q C XX a X t αx t Q e a x + c X + C Xa x + a C x + a Q + Q C XX a x x 2 αx Q C xa x + a xc x c x + a xq + Q C XX a x x α Q b e + C X + Q + Q C XX ax t + Q C x + Q + Q C XX a x x bε t+ 2 α[bε t+ Q + Q C XX bε t+ = αq a M t αq a c c 2 αx ta XX X t αx ta Xxx 2 αx A xx x α B X X t + B x x bε t+ 2 α[bε t+ Q + Q C XX bε t+, with A XX = Q e a + C Xa + e a + C Xa + c XX + a Q + Q C XX a A Xx = Q e a x + c X + C Xa x + a C x + a Q + Q C XX a x A xx = Q C xa x + a xc x c x + a xq + Q C XX a x B X = Q b e + C X + Q + Q C XX a B x = Q C x + Q + Q C XX a x. 27

28 Taking the expectation using Lemma?? gives E t [exp { ρh αq M t+ 2 } αx t+qx t+ { = E t [exp ρh αq a M t αq a c c 2 αx ta XX X t αx ta Xxx 2 αx A xx x 2 log d + } 2 α2 B X X t + B x x ˇQ BX X t + B x x where Σ = bb, d = I + αq + Q C XX Σ, and ˇQ = ΣI + αq + Q C XX Σ. Letting A = A XX αb X ˇQB X B = A Xx αb x ˇQB X C = A xx αb x ˇQB x the expectation can be written compactly as { exp ρh 2 log d αq a M t αq a c c 2 αx tax t αx BX t } 2 αx Cx. Hence, the Bellman equation can be written { V M t, X t = max exp{ αc + log h} x exp{ ρh 2 log d αq a M t αq a c c 2 αx tax t αx BX t } 2 αx Cx} It is clear that x can be solved for separately from c. The first-order condition with respect to ˆx is BX t + Cx =, with associated second-order condition, evaluated at the x satisfying the FOC, Rearranging the FOC yields the optimal ˆx C. ˆx = C B ˆX t. Substituting back into the Bellman equation leaves { V M t, X t = max exp{ αc + log h} c exp{ ρh 2 log d αq a M t + a c c 2 αx tax t + } 2 αx tb C BX t } 28

29 The first order condition for c is α exp{ αc + log h} + αa c Q exp{ ρh 2 log d αq a M t + a c c 2 αx ta B C BX t } =, and the second-order condition is α 2 exp{ αc + log h} αa c Q 2 exp{ ρh 2 log d αq a M t + a c c 2 αx ta B C BX t }, which is always satisfied. Rearranging the FOC for c yields c = [ρh log a c Q + 2 α a c Q log d + log h + αq a M t + 2 αx ta B C BX t Finally, plug back into the Bellman equation { V X t = exp log a c Q + a cq a c Q log a c Q h a c Q ρh + log d 2 αq a a c Q M t 2 α a c Q X ta B C BX t Matching coefficients with the original conjecture yields a system of equations for Q and the submatrix ˆQ Q = a Q 2 a c Q Q = A B C B 2 a c Q + 2 α e log a c Q + a cq ac Q log ρh + log d e a c Q h a c Q 2 22 Note that the constant Q can be solved explicitly as. Q = a a c Plugging this back into the equation for ˆQ yields Q = A B C B a + 2 α e loga + a a log a h 29 ρh + log d e a 2 }

30 The expression for Q, also delivers the optimal consumption in terms of model primitives and the remaining elements of Q c = [ a ρh log + αa h 2 log d + α a a M t a c 2 α ˆX ta B C B ˆX t. B Proofs Proof of Proposition 3.. I will apply Proposition A. from Appendix A to solve the trader s problem. To apply that result one must write the cash dynamics in the form of eq. 7 M t+ = a M t + a X t + b bε t+ + a c c + a x x + c X X t x 2 x c x x + 2 X tc XX X t + C X X t + C x x X t+ + 2 X t+c XX X t+. Adding I subscripts, this is achieved by defining a I = R h, a I x = R h h c I X = R h p I, c I x = 2R h p Ix, c IXX = C I X = h, CI x = h, C IXX = a I =, b I =, a I x =. Further define the matrices A I XX = Q I C IXâ I + C IXâ I + â ˆQ I I â I A I Xx = Q I â IC Ix R h p I + â I ˆQ I â Ix A I xx = 2Q I R h p Ix + â ˆQ Ix I â Ix B IX = Q I C IX + ˆQ I â I B Ix = Q I C Ix + ˆQ I â Ix Σ I = b I b I ˇQ I = Σ I I + α I Q I Σ I, 3

31 and A I = A I XX α I B I X ˇQ I B I X B I = A I Xx α I B I x ˇQ I B I X C I = A I xx α I B I x ˇQ I B I x. Applying Proposition A. the optimal demand and consumption are x = C I B I X It = [α I B Ix ˇQ I B Ix + 2Q I R h p Ix â Ix ˆQ I â Ix [Q I C Ixâ I R h p I + â Ix ˆQ I â I α I B I ˇQ x I B I X c = [ Rh ρh log + α I R h h 2 log d R h I + α I M It + h 2 α IX ItB IC I B I X t. Substituting the optimal demand and consumption into the Bellman equation and equating terms yields Q I in closed form Q I = R h, h R h and produces a matrix equation that Q I must solve Q I = A I B R IC I B I h logr h + R h log R h Rh ρh + R h 2 log d I + 2 e e α I h = A I Q I a R IC Ix R h p I + a IQ I a Ix α I B ˇQ I x I B I X C I h QI a IC Ix R h p I + a IQ I a Ix α I B I ˇQ x I B I X + 2 α I e e logr h + R h log R h Rh h ρh + R h 2 log d I. X It Proof of Proposition. To place the cash dynamics in the form of Proposition A., let a U = R h, a U x = R h h c U X = R h p U, c U x = C U X = h, CU x = h a U =, b U =, a U x =. 3

32 Using the above expressions, define the matrices A U XX = Q U C UXa U + C UXa U + a UQ U a U A U Xx = Q U c UX + a UC Ux + a UQ U a Ux A U xx = Q U c Ix + a UxQ U a Ux B UX = Q U C UX + Q U a U B Ux = Q U C Ux + Q U a Ux Σ U = b U b U ˇQ U = Σ U I + α U Q U Σ U and A U = A U XX α U B U ˇQ X U B U X B U = A U Xx α U B U ˇQ x U B U X C U = A U xx α U B U ˇQ x U B U x. The optimal demand and consumption are x = C U B U X Ut = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a [ UxQ U a Ux QU C Uxa U R h p U + a UxQ U a U α U B U ˇQ x U B U X XUt c = [ Rh ρh log + α U R h h 2 log d R h U + α U M Ut + h 2 α UX UtB UC U B UX Ut. Plugging back into the Bellman equation yields Q U in closed form and a system of equations for the matrix Q U Q U = A U B R UC U B U h + 2 α U e e logr h + R h log R h Q U = R h, h R h Rh ρh + R h 2 log d U h = A U Q U a R UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B ˇQ U x U B U X C U h QU a UC Ux R h p U + a UQ U a Ux α U B U ˇQ x U B U X + 2 e e logr h + R h log α U R h 32 Rh h ρh + R h 2 log d I

33 In equilibrium P t = p U X Ut, so it is immediate that the optimal demand can be implemented by submitting a demand schedule satisfying x = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a [ UxQ U a Ux QU C Uxa U + a UxQ U a U α U B U ˇQ x U B U X XUt [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux QU R h P t x Ut. To match the initial conjectured demand, one requires β U = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a [ UxQ U a Ux QU C Uxa U + a UxQ U a U α U B U ˇQ x U B U X = [ α U B Ux ˇQ U B Ux a UxQ U a Ux QU R h. Proof of Proposition 3.3. The result follows directly from substituting into eqs. 7 3 and doing some tedious algebra, so I suppress the details for brevity. Other than Q j, Q j4, and Q j44 Bellman terms are available in closed form ha D Q j2 = Q a D R h ha DG R h Q j3 = Q R h a D R h a G Q jik =, i, k {2, 2, 2, 3, 3, 3, 2, 4, 3, 4}. The six equations for Q j, Q j4, and Q j44, j {I, U} are obtained by substituting the above Q coefficients, as well as the demand function coefficients from the statement of the Proposition, into eqs. 7 and. Proof of Corollary 3.4. Summing up the demand functions from Prop. 3.3 and imposing the market clearing condition gives P t = [β + γ IX It + β UX Ut U [ = β I + β U + = X It + [β I β U θ It + β I2 + β U2 D t + β I3 + β U3 G t + + β U4 Z t, where the second equality follows because θ Ut = θ It in equilibrium. Substituting in from Prop. 3.3 yields the coefficients on D t, G t, and Z t immediately. To derive the coefficient on 33

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework Online Appendix to the paper Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework October 5, 2015 Part I: Maturity specific shocks in affine and equilibrium models This Appendix present

More information

FINM6900 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets

FINM6900 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets FINM69 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets February 3, 212 Reference Anat R. Admati, A Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multi-Asset Securities Markets,

More information

Measuring the informativeness of economic actions and. market prices 1. Philip Bond, University of Washington. September 2014

Measuring the informativeness of economic actions and. market prices 1. Philip Bond, University of Washington. September 2014 Measuring the informativeness of economic actions and market prices 1 Philip Bond, University of Washington September 2014 1 I thank Raj Singh for some very constructive conversations, along with a seminar

More information

Information Percolation, Momentum, and Reversal

Information Percolation, Momentum, and Reversal Reversal Daniel Andrei Julien Cujean a b c Banque de France, Mars 2014 Reversal 0 / 14 Time-Series Momentum and Reversal: Evidence T-Statistic T-Statistic by Month, All Asset Classes 6 5 4 3 2 1 0-1 -2-3

More information

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions Songzi Du Haoxiang Zhu September 2013 This document supplements Du and Zhu (2013. All results

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco FEUNL February 2016 Francesco Franco (FEUNL) Macroeconomics Theory II February 2016 1 / 18 Road Map Research question: we want to understand businesses cycles.

More information

A Correction. Joel Peress INSEAD. Abstract

A Correction. Joel Peress INSEAD. Abstract Wealth, Information Acquisition and ortfolio Choice A Correction Joel eress INSEAD Abstract There is an error in my 2004 paper Wealth, Information Acquisition and ortfolio Choice. This note shows how to

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

market prices 1 Philip Bond, University of Washington July 2015

market prices 1 Philip Bond, University of Washington July 2015 Measuring the informativeness of economic actions and market prices 1 Philip Bond, University of Washington July 2015 1 I thank Mehmet Eckmekci and Raj Singh for some very constructive comments, along

More information

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi Political Cycles and Stock Returns Ľuboš Pástor and Pietro Veronesi University of Chicago, National Bank of Slovakia, NBER, CEPR University of Chicago, NBER, CEPR Average Excess Stock Market Returns 30

More information

Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information Strategic Market Order Models

Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information Strategic Market Order Models Kyle Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Strategic Market Order Models Markus K. Brunnermeier Princeton University August 17, 2007 Kyle A of Market Microstructure Models simultaneous submission of demand schedules

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Insider Trading and Multidimensional Private Information

Insider Trading and Multidimensional Private Information Insider Trading and Multidimensional Private Information Tomasz Sadzik, UCLA, Chris Woolnough, NYU March 2014 Tomasz Sadzik, UCLA, Chris Woolnough, NYU Insider ( ) Trading and Multidimensional Private

More information

Endogenous Information Choice

Endogenous Information Choice Endogenous Information Choice Lecture 7 February 11, 2015 An optimizing trader will process those prices of most importance to his decision problem most frequently and carefully, those of less importance

More information

Technical Appendix Information sales and strategic trading

Technical Appendix Information sales and strategic trading Technical Appendix Information sales and strategic trading Diego García Francesco Sangiorgi April 1, 2011 Abstract In this technical appendix we extend the results in the paper Information sales and strategic

More information

Knowing What Others Know: Coordination Motives in Information Acquisition

Knowing What Others Know: Coordination Motives in Information Acquisition Knowing What Others Know: Coordination Motives in Information Acquisition Christian Hellwig and Laura Veldkamp UCLA and NYU Stern May 2006 1 Hellwig and Veldkamp Two types of information acquisition Passive

More information

Wealth, Information Acquisition and Portfolio Choice: A Correction

Wealth, Information Acquisition and Portfolio Choice: A Correction Wealth, Information Acquisition and Portfolio Choice: A Correction Joel Peress INSEAD There is an error in our 2004 paper Wealth, Information Acquisition and Portfolio Choice. This note shows how to correct

More information

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM Perold: The CAPM Perold starts with a historical background, the development of portfolio theory and the CAPM. Points out that until 1950 there was no theory to describe the equilibrium determination of

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

Complex Systems Workshop Lecture III: Behavioral Asset Pricing Model with Heterogeneous Beliefs

Complex Systems Workshop Lecture III: Behavioral Asset Pricing Model with Heterogeneous Beliefs Complex Systems Workshop Lecture III: Behavioral Asset Pricing Model with Heterogeneous Beliefs Cars Hommes CeNDEF, UvA CEF 2013, July 9, Vancouver Cars Hommes (CeNDEF, UvA) Complex Systems CEF 2013, Vancouver

More information

Cross-Asset Speculation in Stock Markets

Cross-Asset Speculation in Stock Markets Cross-Asset Speculation in Stock Markets DA BERHARDT and BART TAUB Abstract In practice, heterogeneously-informed speculators combine private information about multiple stocks with information in prices,

More information

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Volatility Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Volatility Characteristics of Time Series Heteroskedasticity Simpler Estimation Strategies Exponentially Weighted Moving Average Use

More information

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013 HARVARD UNIVERSITY DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 203 You have FOUR hours. Answer all questions Part A (Prof. Laibson): 48 minutes Part B (Prof. Aghion): 48

More information

Financial Econometrics Return Predictability

Financial Econometrics Return Predictability Financial Econometrics Return Predictability Eric Zivot March 30, 2011 Lecture Outline Market Efficiency The Forms of the Random Walk Hypothesis Testing the Random Walk Hypothesis Reading FMUND, chapter

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006 Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Model June 20, 2006 The Representative Agent Hypothesis and its Notion of Equilibrium 9.2.1 An infinitely lived Representative Agent Avoid terminal period problem Equivalence

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Local Interactions in a Market with Heterogeneous Expectations

Local Interactions in a Market with Heterogeneous Expectations 1 / 17 Local Interactions in a Market with Heterogeneous Expectations Mikhail Anufriev 1 Andrea Giovannetti 2 Valentyn Panchenko 3 1,2 University of Technology Sydney 3 UNSW Sydney, Australia Computing

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are: Econ 510a second half Yale University Fall 2006 Prof. Tony Smith HOMEWORK #5 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, December 8 in Marnix Amand s mailbox. Solution 1. a In the Mehra-Prescott

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley Working Paper #2018-02 Infinite Horizon CCAPM with Stochastic Taxation and Monetary Policy Revised from the Center for Risk Management Research Working Paper 2018-01 Konstantin Magin, University of California,

More information

Information Diversity and Complementarities in Trading and Information Acquisition

Information Diversity and Complementarities in Trading and Information Acquisition THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 4 AUGUST 05 Information Diversity and Complementarities in Trading and Information Acquisition ITAY GOLDSTEIN and LIYAN YANG ABSTRACT We analyze a model in which different

More information

ASSET PRICING WITH HIGHER-ORDER BELIEFS

ASSET PRICING WITH HIGHER-ORDER BELIEFS ASSET PRICING WITH HIGHER-ORDER BELIEFS Kenneth Kasa 1 Todd Walker 2 Charles Whiteman 3 1 Department of Economics Simon Fraser University 2 Department of Economics Indiana University 3 Department of Economics

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 This note describes very briefly how to conduct quantitative analysis on a linearized

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Private Information, Diversification, and Asset Pricing

Private Information, Diversification, and Asset Pricing Private Information, Diversification, and Asset Pricing John Hughes, Jing Liu and Jun Liu First Version: May 20, 2004 Current Version: March 29, 2005 John Hughes and Jun Liu are from the UCLA Anderson

More information

Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models

Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models Nabil I. Al-Najjar & Northwestern University Eran Shmaya Tel Aviv University RUD, Warwick, June 2014 Forthcoming: Journal of Political Economy Motivation

More information

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession ONLINE APPENDIX INVESTMENT HANGOVER A1 Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession By MATTHEW ROGNLIE, ANDREI SHLEIFER, AND ALP SIMSEK APPENDIX A: CALIBRATION This appendix describes

More information

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Background Much progress made on constructing and estimating models that fit quarterly data well (Smets-Wouters,

More information

Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing

Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing Leyla Jianyu Han 1 Kenneth Kasa 2 Yulei Luo 1 1 The University of Hong Kong 2 Simon Fraser University December 15, 218 1 /

More information

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium Tianxiao Zheng SAIF 1. Introduction We have studied single agent problems. However, macro-economy consists of a large number of agents including individuals/households,

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics Thomas M. Mertens NYU Stern Risk Economics Lab April 17, 2012 1 / 78 Motivation Many problems in finance and economics are high dimensional. Dynamic Optimization:

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics

Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Papers in Economics No. 10/11 A General Equilibrium Corporate Finance Theorem for Incomplete Markets: A Special Case By Pascal Stiefenhofer, University of York Department of Economics and Related

More information

Multivariate GARCH models.

Multivariate GARCH models. Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600. Alternative Methods of Discrete Time Intertemporal Optimization We will start by solving a discrete time intertemporal

More information

Endogenous growth with addictive habits

Endogenous growth with addictive habits Endogenous growth with addictive habits Warwick, 2012 Habit formation Habits may play a role in consumption behavior. Individual satisfaction can be affected by the change over time in customary consumption

More information

Housing and the Business Cycle

Housing and the Business Cycle Housing and the Business Cycle Morris Davis and Jonathan Heathcote Winter 2009 Huw Lloyd-Ellis () ECON917 Winter 2009 1 / 21 Motivation Need to distinguish between housing and non housing investment,!

More information

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution Per Krusell IIES, University of Göteborg, CEPR, NBER Anthony A. Smith, Jr. Yale University, NBER March 2014 WORK-IN-PROGRESS!!! Overall goals

More information

Forecasting the Forecasts of Others: Implications for Asset Pricing

Forecasting the Forecasts of Others: Implications for Asset Pricing Forecasting the Forecasts of Others: Implications for Asset Pricing Igor Makarov and Oleg Rytchkov Abstract We study the properties of rational expectation equilibria (REE) in dynamic asset pricing models

More information

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Yulei Luo The University of Hong Kong Jun Nie Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Eric R. Young University

More information

ASSET PRICING MODELS

ASSET PRICING MODELS ASSE PRICING MODELS [1] CAPM (1) Some notation: R it = (gross) return on asset i at time t. R mt = (gross) return on the market portfolio at time t. R ft = return on risk-free asset at time t. X it = R

More information

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019.

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019. Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019. Page xi, section title for Section 11.4.3 should be Endogenous Margin Requirements. Page 20, equation 1.49), expectations operator E should

More information

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS Peter Ireland Boston College Spring 2018 These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike 4.0 International

More information

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models

Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Uncertainty aversion and heterogeneous beliefs in linear models Cosmin Ilut Duke & NBER Pavel Krivenko Stanford March 2016 Martin Schneider Stanford & NBER Abstract This paper proposes a simple perturbation

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 28, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 9 November 28, 2017. 1 / 41 First-Generation Models

More information

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications George W. Evans University of Oregon and University of St Andrews Bruce McGough University of Oregon WAMS, December 12, 2015 Outline Introduction Shadow-price

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004 Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 5b (Part I), Spring 2004. Consider an exchange economy with two (types of) consumers. Type-A consumers comprise fraction λ of the economy s population and type-b

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions Leopold von Thadden University of Mainz and ECB (on leave) Advanced Macroeconomics, Winter Term 2013 1 / 36 I Motivation This Lecture considers some applications

More information

A Memory Based Model of Bounded Rationality

A Memory Based Model of Bounded Rationality A Memory Based Model of Bounded Rationality Sendhil Mullainathan published in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2002 January 16, 2012 Introduction Can memory imperfections help explain observed economic

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015 ANSWER KEY University of California, Davis Date: June, 05 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomic Theory Reading Time: 0 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer four

More information

Players as Serial or Parallel Random Access Machines. Timothy Van Zandt. INSEAD (France)

Players as Serial or Parallel Random Access Machines. Timothy Van Zandt. INSEAD (France) Timothy Van Zandt Players as Serial or Parallel Random Access Machines DIMACS 31 January 2005 1 Players as Serial or Parallel Random Access Machines (EXPLORATORY REMARKS) Timothy Van Zandt tvz@insead.edu

More information

Why is capital slow moving? Liquidity hysteresis and the dynamics of limited arbitrage.

Why is capital slow moving? Liquidity hysteresis and the dynamics of limited arbitrage. Why is capital slow moving? Liquidity hysteresis and the dynamics of limited arbitrage. James Dow, Jungsuk Han and Francesco Sangiorgi May 17, 2018 Abstract Will arbitrage capital flow into a market experiencing

More information

Trading and Information Diffusion in Over-the-Counter Markets. (preliminary)

Trading and Information Diffusion in Over-the-Counter Markets. (preliminary) Trading and Information Diffusion in Over-the-Counter Markets preliminary Ana Babus Imperial College London Péter Kondor Central European University First draft: August 31, 2012, This version: October

More information

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR Aeimit Lakdawala Michigan State University December 7 This appendix contains

More information

Financial Markets where Traders Neglect the Informational Content of Prices

Financial Markets where Traders Neglect the Informational Content of Prices Financial Markets where Traders Neglect the Informational Content of Prices Erik Eyster London School of Economics Matthew Rabin University of California Berkeley Dimitri Vayanos London School of Economics

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3 Pairs Trading by Cointegration Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Distance method Cointegration Stationarity

More information

A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis

A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis Ricardo Lagos NYU Randall Wright Penn 1 Introduction 2 We develop a framework that unifies micro and macro models of monetary exchange Why? Existing

More information

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Notes on Recursive Utility Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Section 1 (or Chapter 29, LeRoy & Werner, 2nd Ed.) Let u st be the continuation utility at s t. That

More information

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Benjamin Moll G Online Appendix: The Model in Discrete Time and with iid Shocks This Appendix presents a version

More information

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620 May 16, 2006 Philip Bond 1 Are cheap talk and hard evidence both needed in the courtroom? Abstract: In a recent paper, Bull and Watson (2004) present a formal model of verifiability in which cheap messages

More information

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time David Laibson 9/30/2014 Outline Lectures 9-10: 9.1 Continuous-time Bellman Equation 9.2 Application: Merton s Problem 9.3 Application:

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default, Econometrica 2000 Notes on Alvarez Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000 Jonathan Heathcote November 1st 2005 1 Model Consider a pure exchange economy with I agents one

More information

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM 4.2 Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM Empirical evidence indicates that the CAPM beta does not completely explain the cross section of expected asset returns. This suggests that additional factors may be required.

More information

Asset Pricing. Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. # X E β t U(c t ) t=0

Asset Pricing. Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. # X E β t U(c t ) t=0 Asset Pricing 1 Lucas (1978, Econometrica) Question: What is the equilibrium price of a stock? Defn: a stock is a claim to a future stream of dividends. 1.1 Environment Tastes: " # X E β t U( ) t=0 Technology:

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences

Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences Higher-Order Dynamics in Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences Walt Pohl Karl Schmedders Ole Wilms Dept. of Business Administration, University of Zurich Becker Friedman Institute Computational

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information