Approximate Recursive Equilibrium with Minimal State Space

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Approximate Recursive Equilibrium with Minimal State Space"

Transcription

1 Approximate Recursive Equilibrium with Minimal State Space Raad, R. July 12, 2013 Department of Economics, Federal University of Minas Gerais, Brazil. Abstract This paper shows the existence of approximate recursive equilibrium with minimal state space in an environment of incomplete markets. We prove that the approximate recursive equilibrium implements an approximate sequential equilibrium which is always close to a Magill and Quinzii equilibrium without short sales for arbitrarily small errors. This implies that the competitive equilibrium can be implemented by using forecast statistics with minimal state space provided that agents will reduce errors in their estimates in the long run. We have also developed an alternative algorithm to compute the approximate recursive equilibrium with incomplete markets and heterogeneous agents through a procedure of iterating functional equations and without using the first order conditions of optimality. Keywords: Recursive Equilibrium, Computational Economics, Incomplete Markets, Approximate Equilibrium. JEL Classification: D50, D52, D58. Field: Economic Theory. 1 Introduction Magill and Quinzii (1996) provide an extension of some representative agent models such as Lucas Jr (1978) to an economy with infinite lived heterogeneous agents. They analyzed the equilibrium properties in sequential markets 1

2 under the assumption of common expectations on prices as in Radner (1972). In this model, markets are incomplete in the sense that at every date and for every commodity there will be some future dates and some events at those dates for which it will not be possible to make current contracts for future delivery contingent on those events. In this way, agents make consumption and investment plans contingent on the realizations of possible states of nature, under their own beliefs, basing the current choices on the optimal planning. The latter depends on how the agents have expectations on prices contingent on the observation of future events representing exogenous uncertainty, i.e., events whose realizations are independent of agents choices. This fact is the essence of the common expectations hypothesis which requires traders to associate the same future prices to the same future exogenous events, but does not require them to agree on the subjective probabilities associated with those events. There are two natural ways to explain how this equilibrium with common expectations can be achieved. The first regards to the high level of coordination among agents who propose to only negotiate at that contingent price level matched in the future. The second takes into account the computing capacity of the agents who use past variables and economic fundamentals to obtain a recursive relation between endogenous variables in two consecutive periods characterized, basically, by recursive transition functions. This set of functions, also called recursive equilibrium, 1 includes price estimators that represent a common recursive price expectation and implements the equilibrium in the sequential markets. Duffie et al. (1994) present a general result showing the existence of such estimators but with a domain containing a large number of variables, which calls into question the assumption that agents can compute the prices accurately. Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004), Spear (1985) and Hellwig (1982) point to a possible generic nonexistence of recursive equilibrium, with few variables in its domain, for the model of overlapping generations. But Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004) show that it is possible to obtain a stream of prices implemented recursively where agents trade goods and assets that make their utility arbitrary closed to the optimum. We can find in Citanna and Siconolfi (2010) a result of existence of recursive equilibrium, with reduced domain, outside of a residual set of 1 Sometimes we find in the literature references to recursive equilibrium as the sequential equilibrium implemented by the transition functions. Here, we find it more convenient to call the recursive equilibrium a set of transition functions, since we will show that these functions implement the sequential equilibrium. 2

3 utility functions and endowments, that is, a set of stationary utilities and endowments that is dense and is the countable intersection of open and dense sets. The methodology used in the literature to construct a recursive equilibrium is given in Duffie et al. (1994). Basically, they consider a state space S containing all pay-off relevant variables and a correspondence G : S Prob(S), where Prob(S) is the set of Borel probability measures over S. This correspondence is interpreted as the intertemporal consistency, derived from some particular model, embodying exogenous shocks, feasibility conditions, and the first order optimality conditions of dynamic programming problems of the agents. A measurable subset S S is said to be selfjustified if G(s) Prob(S ) for all s S. Under regular assumptions on G, DGMM show that, if there exists a non-empty compact self-justified set S S, then G admits a measurable selector and, using the Skorokhod s Theorem and this selector, they find a stationary function g defined 2 on S relating two consecutive realizations of the equilibrium stochastic process. The approximate recursive equilibrium defined in Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004) is a function playing the role of the selector g with domain containing few variables. However, in this case, the selector implements a competitive equilibrium which might be very far from exact equilibrium as presented in Kubler and Schmedders (2005). The latter paper exhibits an example that illustrates this fact, with zero intertemporal discount rate and the estimation error based only on the first order conditions in the optimization problem of the agents. Moreover, they develop theoretical foundations for an error analysis of approximate equilibrium providing sufficient conditions to ensure that approximate equilibrium are close to exact equilibrium. Kubler (2011) also examines the relationship between exact and approximate recursive equilibrium for economies whose fundamentals are semi-algebraic, that is, instantaneous utility and production functions can be described by finitely many polynomials. In this paper, we show the possibility of a sequential equilibrium be eventually achieved (and computed) with common expectations as in Radner (1972) or Magill and Quinzii (1996), even without assuming a high level of coordination among agents. As in Duffie et al. (1994) and in Kubler and 2 This function also depends on an extra coordinate that represents the effect of an uniform exogenous shock on the equilibrium. In some models it is possible to prove that actually, the recursive function does not depend on this process and, in this case, is called spotless recursive equilibrium. 3

4 Polemarchakis (2004), we construct estimators that implement the prices and allocations of consumption and asset shares so that agents maximize their expected utility but with arbitrarily small errors in the market clearing conditions. However, these estimators are constructed through a selector of a correspondence defined without using the first order conditions of optimality and so that one can always implement a sequential equilibrium arbitrary closed to an exact equilibrium. We do not need to assume further conditions such as in Kubler (2011) and, contrary to the definition of approximate equilibrium given in Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004), the optimality choices are exact in our approach, avoiding the criticism of Kubler and Schmedders (2005). We assume that the demand for current assets can not have arbitrarily large fluctuations as a function of asset endowments in the previous period and current prices, constructing an example with one good and one asset clarifying this assumption. Furthermore, we show that the recursive equilibrium is continuous and contains a domain with the smallest possible number of variables, also called minimal state space. 3 Contrary to Duffie et al. (1994), we use a constructive argument explaining how, in sequential markets, the equilibrium can be implemented recursively by the transition functions by showing explicitly the consecutive relations among the endogenous variables. Finally we show an alternative way to compute an equilibrium with heterogeneous agents obtaining the estimators, without using the first order conditions, through a procedure of iterating functional equations. Computing the value function and the demand through its argmax, we obtain approximations whose errors do not propagate over time as pointed out by Kubler and Schmedders (2005) about the method of Scarfh (1967) which approximates the first order conditions. Indeed, the value function is the optimal value among the current choices and all feasible plans over all future periods and the errors are generated only through the value function. 3 This set contains the portfolio asset endowment of previous period and the current state of nature. This set is minimal because an asset redistribution must change the equilibrium prices if, for instance, there exists agents with heterogeneity in the risk aversion. 4

5 2 The model 2.1 Definitions Suppose that there exists a finite set of types denoted by I = {1,..., I} and such that each type i I has a continuum of agents trading in a competitive environment. Time is indexed by t in the set N = {1, 2,...} for current periods and r N {0} for future periods. In this model, the uncertainty is exogenous, in the sense of being independent of agents actions. Each agent knows the whole set of possible exogenous variables 4 and trade contingent claims. Let be a finite set containing all states of the nature and its σ-algebra. Denote by ( τ, τ ) a copy of (, ) for all τ N. Exogenous uncertainty is described by the streams z τ = (z 1,..., z τ ) 1 τ = τ for all τ N, that is, the set of nodes of the event tree is given by τ N τ. There are a finite set J = {1,..., J} of goods and a finite set H = {1,..., H} of long lived real assets in net supply equal to one and with dividends characterized by measurable bounded functions ˆd : R JH ++ in units of goods. The matrix element ˆd jh (z) of ˆd(z) represents the amount of good j paid by one unit of asset h in the state of the nature z. Denote by Θ i R H + for all i I the convex set where asset choices are defined and C i R J + the convex set where agent i s consumption is chosen. Observe that we are not allowing for short-sales. Define the symbol without upper index as the Cartesian product. For instance, write C = i I Ci. Denote by { Q = (q c, q a ) R J + R H + : qj c + } qh a = 1 j J h H the set where the prices are defined and write Q = Q R J+H ++. The symbol q = (q c, q a ) Q stands for the consumption and asset prices in units of the numéraire respectively. We write q c ˆdh (z) := j J qc j ˆd jh (z) R + as the amount of the numéraire paid by one unit of asset h and write q c ˆd(z)θ i := h H qc ˆdh (z)θ i h R + as the amount of the numéraire paid by the portfolio θ i R H +. In addition, we define ˆd(z)θ i = h H ˆd h (z)θ i h RJ for all θ i Θ i as the amount of goods 1,..., J resulting from the ownership of the portfolio θ i. 4 Also called states of the nature or exogenous shocks. 5

6 We suppose that each asset is given in net supply one. 5 Therefore, write { Θ = θ Θ : } θ h i = 1 for all h H. i I An element θ Θ stands for the mean asset choice of the agents. Let S = Θ be the space of state variables endowed with the product topology with a typical element denoted by s = ( θ, z). Write S the Borel subsets of S and (S τ, S τ ) a copy of (S, S ) for all τ N. Write the set of all continuous 6 functions ˆq : S Q by Q and the set of all continuous functions ˆq : S Q by Q. Every Cartesian product of topological spaces is endowed with the product topology and any set of bounded continuous functions is endowed with the topology induced by the sup norm. The norm in R n considered here is the max norm, that is, x = max{ x 1,..., x n }. 2.2 Agents features In every current period, preferences are represented by a instantaneous utility given by a bounded real valued function u i : R J + R + strictly concave and strictly increasing for all i I. The symbol j u i (c i ) stands for the partial derivative of u i with respect to the j-th coordinate evaluated at the point c i. Each agent i has a measurable endowment e i : R J + of goods 1,..., J and a discount factor β i for each i I. Agents beliefs at every fixed date r are characterized by the continuous 7 map µ i r : Prob( r ) for r N, anticipating future exogenous states of the nature given the realization of the current state of nature z. We suppose that these beliefs are predictive in the context of Blackwell and Dubins (1962) with continuous probability transition rules 8 λ i : Prob(). More precisely, the measure µ i r satisfies for a rectangle A 1 A r : µ i r(z)(a 1 A r ) = λ i (z r 1, dz r ) λ i (z, dz 1 ). (1) A 1 A r 5 Since we are interested only in the case of symmetric equilibrium, we assume that each agent of the same type i chooses the same portfolio θ i and, consequently, this portfolio can be viewed as the mean asset choice of type i agents. 6 And hence bounded because S is compact. 7 The set Prob( r ) is endowed with the weak topology. 8 The space Prob() is also endowed with the weak topology. 6

7 Remark 2.1. See Stokey et al. (1989) Chapters 8 and 9 for details about the topology of Prob(), the construction of a probability measure based on the composition of probability transition rules and results about expectations over this measure. We write, with a slight abuse of notation, λ i (z)(a) as λ i (z, A) and µ i r(z)(a r ) as µ i r(z, A r ). Observe that the measure µ i r(z) is the Carathodory extension of the measure defined by the right side of (1) for rectangles. Remark 2.2. Consider a stochastic process { z τ } τ N defined on some underlying probability space and with range in the probability space. A probability transition rule on the period τ can be regarded as a generalization of the notion of conditional probability of z τ+1 given z τ with respect to agents subjective probability within the framework of Savage (1954). 9 We follow the approach of contingent choices as given in Radner (1972). As the model described here does not assume market completeness, then the agents may not be willing to make contracts that implement some future path of consumption as in the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. Since agents do not perfectly anticipate the future states of nature, which are given exogenously, rationality leads them to make plans for the future at each current period contingent to all possible future trajectories of the states of nature. Therefore we have the definition below. Definition 2.3. The agent i s plan at some period is defined as the current period choice (c i 0, θ i 0) C i Θ i and the streams {c i r} r N and {θ i r} r N of measurable functions c i r : r C i and θ i r : r Θ i for all r N representing future plans. Remark 2.4. In each current period, the quantity c i r(z r ) can be interpreted as the value planned for consumption r periods ahead if z r is the partial history of prices actually observed at these periods. The asset plan {θ j r} r N has analogous interpretation. We assume that the agents choose a feasible plan of consumption and investment that maximizes the expected utility, under their own beliefs, among all other feasible plans. The next definitions characterize the feasibility of a plan and how agents calculate its expected value. 9 Moreover, consider ϕ i : a measurable function. If agent i assumes that the process { z τ } τ N satisfies z τ+1 = ϕ i ( z τ, ɛ τ ) for some i.i.d. error process { ɛ τ } τ N with the same distribution of ɛ, then we can define λ i (z, A) = P i (ϕ i (z, ɛ) A), where P i is the subjective probability defined for the underlying space. 7

8 Definition 2.5. Let B i : Θ i Q C i Θ i be defined as B i (θ i -, z, q) = {(c i, θ i ) C i Θ i : q c c i + q a θ i (q a + q c ˆd(z))θ i - + q c e i (z)}. Let q = {q r : r Q} r 0 be a stream of contingent prices for a given q 0 Q. A plan (c i, θ i ), for an agent i I, is feasible from (θ i -, z, q) if (c i 0, θ i 0) B i (θ i -, z, q 0 ) and (c i r(z r ), θ i r(z r )) B i (θ i r 1(z r 1 ), z r, q r (z r )) for all z r r and for all r N. Denote by F i (θ i -, z, q) the set of all feasible plans from (θ i -, z, q). Now we can define the expected utility. Definition 2.6. Let C i be the set of all sequence of measurable functions {c i r : r C i } r 0 with c i 0 C i for r N. We define the agent i s expected utility U i : C i R for consuming c i given the state z : U i (c i, z) = u i (c i 0) + (β i ) r u i (c i r(z r ))µ i r(z, dz r ). r N r Definition 2.7. Define the value function ˆv i : Θ i R by: ˆv i (θ i -, z, q) = sup{u i (c i, z) : (c i, θ i ) F i (θ i -, z, q)}. (2) The following definition characterizes the agents demand. Although this demand is independent of time, it yields the current choice at period t given some past and current observed variables for each t N. This approach allows us to use the recursive methods and compute the sequential equilibrium. Definition 2.8. We define the agent i s demand for good and asset by: 10 δ i (θ i -, z, q) = argmax{u i (c i, z) : (c i, θ i ) F i (θ i -, z, q)}. The result below can be found in Raad (2012) using that the intertemporal budget correspondence is continuous in the product topology and the Berge Maximum Theorem. 10 This correspondence can be empty when C i Θ i is not compact. 8

9 Proposition 2.9. The value function ˆv i is continuous on the set {(θ i -, z, q) : (q a 0 + q c 0 ˆd(z))θ i - + q c 0e i (z) > 0}. The lemma below ensures that the demand becomes arbitrarily large for arbitrarily low prices. Lemma For each compact C Θ Int(C Θ) there exists γ > 0 such that if ( θ, z, c, θ, q) satisfies (c i, θ i ) δ i ( θ i, z, q), (c i 0, θ i 0) C i Θ i and (c i r(z r ), θ i r(z r )) C i Θ i for all z r r and all i I then q 0 γ. Proof: See Lemma 7.13 in the Appendix. 3 Recursive and sequential equilibrium Roughly speaking, we can say that a recursive equilibrium is a function relating the variables of equilibrium between two consecutive periods. Duffie et al. (1994) shows the existence of recursive equilibrium in models with heterogeneous agents and state space containing all pay-off relevant variables. Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004) argues that a recursive equilibrium having a reduced state 11 space may not exist in a model of overlapping generations and heterogeneous agents. Furthermore, Kubler and Schmedders (2002) also shows an example of the non existence of recursive equilibrium for the case of a minimal space state pointing to the study of approximate recursive equilibrium as a solution to the problem of coordination and the calculation of the sequential equilibrium numerically. This is our goal hereafter. The next definition specifies the sequential equilibrium of the economy, also called competitive equilibrium. Definition 3.1. Consider the following measurable 1. q := {q r : r Q } r 0 contingent prices; 2. c := {c r : r C} r 0 contingent consumption allocation; 3. θ := {θ r : r Θ} r 0 contingent portfolio allocation. 11 Recall that the state space is defined as the domain of the recursive functions. 9

10 Let θ be a previous portfolio distribution and z a current state of the nature in a period t. Then these allocations and prices constitute an equilibrium for E in a period t if satisfy for all z r r : 1. optimality: (c i, θ i ) δ i ( θ i, z, q); 2. asset markets clearing: 12 i I θi r(z r ) = 1 R H ; 3. good markets clearing: i I ci r(z r ) = ˆd(z r ) 1 + i I ei (z r ). The concept approximate sequential equilibrium is similar to that given in Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004), consisting of a set of allocations of consumption and portfolio and a stream of prices balancing all markets approximately. However, contrary to Kubler and Polemarchakis (2004), here agents maximize the expected utility achieving the exact optimal benefit at that level of prices. Definition 3.2. Given ɛ > 0, consider the following measurable 1. q := {q r : r Q } r 0 contingent prices; 2. c := {c r : r C} r 0 contingent consumption allocation; 3. θ := {θ r : r Θ} r 0 contingent portfolio allocation. Let θ be a previous portfolio distribution and z a current state of the nature. Then these allocations and prices constitute an ɛ-approximate sequential equilibrium for E in some period if satisfy for all z r r : 1. (c i, θ i ) δ i (θ i -, z, q); 2. i I θi r(z r ) 1 ɛ; 3. i I ci r(z r ) e i (z r ) ˆd(z r ) 1 ɛ. We introduce now the concept of approximate recursive equilibrium and show in the appendix that it implements the sequential equilibrium of the economy. The recursive demand will be constructed using the value function. The latter is defined as the optimal value among all feasible plans, given the income and current portfolio endowments and, in addition, the transitions of the endogenous variables such as prices and asset distribution. 12 Define 1 as the vector (1,..., 1) R H. 10

11 Write Θ the space of all continuous functions ˆθ : S Θ representing the transition of asset distributions. A well known result states that for each i I there exists a bounded value function v i : Θ i S Q Θ R satisfying the Bellman Equation: } v i (θ-, i s, ˆq, ˆθ) = sup {u(c i ) + β i v i (θ i, (ˆθ(s), z ), ˆq, ˆθ)λ i (z, dz ) (3) over all 13 (c i, θ i ) B i (θ-, i z, ˆq(s)). Indeed, write V the space of all bounded continuous value functions v i : Θ i S Q Θ R endowed with the sup norm and consider the operator T i : V V, defined by } T i (v i )(θ-, i s, ˆq, ˆθ) = sup {u(c i ) + β i v i (θ i, (ˆθ(s), z ), ˆq, ˆθ)λ i (z, dz ) (4) over all (c i, θ i ) B i (θ-, i z, ˆq(s)). Clearly, T satisfies Blackwell s sufficient conditions for a contraction and hence has a fixed point. See Stokey et al. (1989) for further details. Definition 3.3. Define the agent i s consumption and portfolio policy correspondence x i : Θ i S Q Θ C i Θ i as } x i (θ-, i s, ˆq, ˆθ) = argmax {u(c i ) + β i v i (θ i, (ˆθ(s), z ), ˆq, ˆθ)λ i (z, dz ) over all (c i, θ i ) B i (θ i -, z, ˆq(s)); Remark 3.4. Notice that the policy correspondence satisfy x i (θ i -, s, ˆq, ˆθ) B i (θ i -, z, ˆq(s)) for all (θ i -, s, ˆq, ˆθ) Θ i S Q Θ. (5) Observe also that when x i is a function, then it can be written as x i = ( c i, θ i ) for continuous functions c i : Θ i S Q Θ C i and θ i : Θ i S Q Θ Θ i. The lemma below and the strict concavity of u i assure that we can assume, without loss of generality, that x i is actually a function. To show this, it suffices to note that the optimal portfolio choices are unique within the portfolio reallocations that result in the same pay off. Lemma 3.5. Suppose that C i Θ i = R J+H. Then the correspondence x i has a continuous selector. 13 Recall that s = ( θ, z). 11

12 Proof: See Lemma 7.9 in the Appendix. Definition 3.6. We say that the economy has an ɛ-approximate recursive equilibrium if there exist continuous functions ĉ i : S C i, ˆθ i : S Θ i for i I and ˆq : S Q satisfying for each s = ( θ, z) S 1. (ĉ i (s), ˆθ i (s)) x i ( θ i, s, ˆq, ˆθ) for all i I and s S; 2. i I ĉi (s) e i (z) ˆd(z) 1 ɛ; 3. i I ˆθ i (s) 1 ɛ. Example 3.7. Consider a model with one good and one asset and agents with instantaneous utility function defined by 14 u i ( ) ln( ) for i = 1, 2. Suppose that there is not exogenous uncertainty, that is, = {1} and S = Θ. Dividends are given by ˆd and there is not good endowments. We must impose that C i R ++ and Θ i R ++ because u i is defined only for R ++. The value function satisfies v i (θ-, i θ, ˆq, ˆθ) { = sup u i (c i ) + β i v i (θ i, ˆθ( θ), ˆq, ˆθ) } : (c i, θ i ) B i (θ-, i ˆq(s)) (6) and is strictly concave 15 on θ i -. Since u i is strictly concave on c i then, in this example, the policy correspondence x i given in definition 3.3 is actually function. Let θ i : Θ i Θ Q Θ Θ i and c i : Θ i Θ Q Θ C i be the policy functions as in Remark 3.4. Lemma 7.7 in appendix assures that ( c i, θ i ) is nonempty and satisfies ( c i, θ i ) > 0. Observe that: c i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) = ˆp( θ) θ i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) + (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i - (7) where we write ˆp ˆq a /ˆq c. Fix (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) Θ i Θ Q Θ with θ i - > 0. We claim that θ i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) = βi (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i - ˆp( θ) and c i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) = (1 β i )(ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i That preferences can be viewed as a Cobb-Douglas preferences on c i and θ i by the closed form of the value function. See Faro (2013) for more details about the axiomatization of Cobb-Douglas preferences. 15 See Stokey et al. (1989) Chapter 4 for more details. 12

13 Indeed, using that u (c) = 1/c and applying the Benveniste and Scheinkman Theorem 16 given in Benveniste and Scheinkman (1979) we conclude that and hence 1 v i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) = u i ( c i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ))(ˆp( θ) + ˆd) = (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)/((1 β i )(ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i -) = 1/((1 β i )θ i -) 1 v i ( θ i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ), ˆθ( θ), ˆq, ˆθ) = 1/((1 β i ) θ i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ)) for all (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) Θ i Θ Q Θ. Therefore = ˆp( θ)/((1 β i )β i (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i -) ˆp(θ) u i ( c i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ)) = ˆp(θ)/((1 β i )(ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i -) = β iˆp(θ)/((1 β i )β i (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i -) = β i 1 v i ( θ i (θ i -, θ, ˆq, ˆθ), ˆθ( θ), ˆq, ˆθ) which implies that θ i satisfies the first order condition on θ i of the Bellman Equation (6) replacing c i by ˆp( θ)θ i + (ˆp( θ) + ˆd)θ i -. The strict concavity of u i and of v i on the first coordinate is sufficient to conclude our assertion. The next definition provides more details of how the recursive functions can implement an ɛ-approximate sequential equilibrium. Observe that at the equilibrium each agent i has initial endowment θ i - = θ i and optimal choices on Θ, that is, each agent chooses the mean portfolio relative to its own type. Definition 3.8. We say that the functions ĉ : S C, ˆθ : S Θ and ˆq : S Q generate the process (c r, θ r, q r ) r 0 starting from θ Θ and z if for all z r r q0 = ˆq( θ, z), θ i 0 = ˆθ i ( θ, z), c i 0 = ˆθ i ( θ, z) and recursively for r N c i r(z r ) = ĉ i (θ r 1 (z r 1 ), z r ) θ i r(z r ) = ˆθ i (θ r 1 (z r 1 ), z r ) (8) for i I and q r (z r ) = ˆq(θ r 1 (z r 1 ), z r ). (9) 16 See also Stokey et al. (1989) for more details about this theorem. 13

14 The next result assures that the recursive equilibrium can actually be used to construct the sequential equilibrium. In this result, we must redefine the state space S as S = Θ because of condition 3. in Definition 3.6. Indeed, in Definition 3.8, the recursive relations must be defined in the image of ˆθ. In order to simplify notation, we keep the symbol S to denote the new state space. Theorem 3.9. If (ĉ, ˆθ, ˆq) is an ɛ-approximate recursive equilibrium then its implemented process (c, θ, q) starting from ( θ, z) S is an ɛ-approximate sequential equilibrium of the economy with initial asset holdings θ Θ and initial state of the nature z. Proof: See Theorem 7.8 in the appendix. 4 Existence and Convergence Results 4.1 Existence of an approximate recursive equilibrium In this section we will demonstrate the existence of approximate recursive equilibrium with state space S = Θ. For simplicity, we will make a slight change in notation. Notation 4.1. Write L = {1, 2,..., L} for L = H + J 2. Consider X i = C i Θ i R L + convex with 0 X and Q R L ++ the set of generalized prices. 17 Define 18 Xi as the set of all bounded continuous functions ˆx i : S X i and Q the set of all bounded continuous functions ˆq : S Q both endowed with the topology induced by the sup metric. Recall that Q is the set of all bounded continuous normalized prices ˆq : S Q. Consider V i : X i S X Q R a bounded continuous function such that V i (, s, ˆx, ˆq) is concave and increasing for all (s, ˆx, ˆq) S X Q and all i I. Moreover we suppose that V i (x i, s, ˆx, ) is homogenenous of degree zero for all (x i, s, ˆx) X i S X. Write ŵ i : S W i R J+H as the agent i s contingent endowments with W i compact convex. Recall that we consider as the max norm in R L, that is, x = max{ x 1,..., x n }. 17 In the equilibrium, actually, the prices will be normalized, that is belongs to Q Q. 18 Notice that we are using the hat symbol to denote the space of functions from S to the set specified. 14

15 The next definitions will be useful in the main result of this section. Definition 4.2. Define ˇv i : S X Q R by ˇv i (s, ˆx, ˆq) = sup { V i (x i, s, ˆx, ˆq) : x i X i and ˆq(s)x i ˆq(s)ŵ i (s) } (10) and ˇx i : S X Q R by ˇx i (s, ˆx, ˆq) = argmax { V i (x i, s, ˆx, ˆq) : x i X i and ˆq(s)x i ˆq(s)ŵ i (s) }. (11) Remark 4.3. Note that ˇv i (s, ˆx, ) and ˇx i (s, ˆx, ) are homogeneous of degree zero for all (s, ˆx) S X. We will define below the Lipschitz property. This property is related to the level of oscillation of a function. For differentiable functions it means that the function must have bounded derivative. Definition 4.4. A function f : Y R n R m is M-Lipschitz for M R ++ if f(y) f(y ) M y y for all y, y Y. When M R m ++ then we say that f = (f 1,..., f m ) is M-Lipschitz if f k : Y R n R is M k -Lipschitz for k = 1,..., m. We write Lp(M) the space of all M-Lipschitz functions. Remark 4.5. Notice that a function f : Y R n R m Lp(M) for M R m ++ then f Lp( M ). The following lemma is useful in the proof of the main result of this section. Its result will be used to construct an operator whose fixed point is the recursive equilibrium. Lemma 4.6. Consider Y R n and M, N R ++. Suppose that f : Y Y is such that f Lp(M) and g : Y Y Lp(N). Then f g Lp(MN), f + g Lp(M + N). Proof: See Lemma 7.4 in the Appendix. The next assumption holds for the model on which V i is defined using the value function v i as clarified by Theorem Assumption 4.7. For each compact X Int X there exists γ > 0 such that if ˆq Q satisfies ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆq)(S) X i for all i I and some ˆx X, then ˆq l (s) γ for all l L and all s S. 15

16 The hypothesis below precludes the possibility of a situation similar to that described by Hellwig (1982) for the case of approximate recursive equilibrium. It states that small variations in asset endowments can not produce arbitrary large fluctuations in asset demand considering that prices fluctuate in a controlled magnitude. Hellwig (1982) points to the impossibility of existence of a stationary function that relates the equilibrium variables, with rational expectations, between two arbitrary consecutive periods providing and example with demand having arbitrary large fluctuation. Remark 4.10 explains how the example 3.7 satisfies this assumption. Lemma 7.12 provides conditions in the primitives of Lucas model with heterogeneous agents so that the assumption below is satisfied. Assumption 4.8. For each compact subsets X R IL +, Q R L ++ and each i I, there exists a continuous selector of ˇx i given in (11) and denoted by ˇδ i : S X Q X i. In addition, the function ˆδ i : X Q X i defined by ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆq)(s) = ˇδ i (s, ˆx, ˆq) for all s = ( θ, z) S and all i I (12) satisfies the following property: there exists M q, M x > 0 with M x + M w M q /I and such that if ˆq Q Lp(M q ) and ˆx X Lp(M x ) then ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆq) Lp(M x ). Remark 4.9. For the case in which the selector has range in R L + we can redefine it so that the image of the new selector is contained in a given compact X i R L + and coinciding with the the initial correspondence on the inverse image of X i. Indeed, choose m i = sup X i R L ++ and define δ i (ˆx, ˆq)(s) = min{m i, ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆq)(s)} X i for all s S. Clearly, x i (s) = δ i (ˆx, ˆq) implies ˆq(s)ˆx(s) ˆq(s)ŵ i (s) and 19 δi (ˆx, ˆq) Lp(M x ) if ˆq Lp(M q ) and ˆx Lp(M x ) by Lemma 7.6 in the Appendix. Remark Clearly, the demand equation obtained in Example 3.7 satisfies the Assumption 4.8. Indeed, consider P R ++ closed. 20 Clearly, the function g i : Θ P R + defined by g i (θ-, i p) = (1 + d/p)θ- i satisfies g i Lp(M ) for some constant M, since it has bounded derivative. Consider c i and θ i as given in Example 3.7. Clearly, it is possible to find M x = (M c, M a ) and M q such that the function θ θ i ( θ i, θ, ˆq, ˆθ) = β i g i ( θ i, ˆq a ( θ)/ˆq c ( θ)) Lp(M a ) 19 See Lemma 7.6 in the appendix for details about this claim. 20 Note that P is bounded away from zero. 16

17 and that 21 c i Lp(M c ) by using (7) if ˆq Lp(M q ) and ˆθ Lp(M a ) Theorem Suppose Assumptions 4.8 and 4.7 and consider that ˆδ i defined in Assumption 4.8 for i I. Then for each fixed ɛ > 0 there exist continuous functions ˆx i : S R L + for all i I and ˆq : S Q such that ˆx i ˆδ i ɛ(ˆx, ˆq) for all i I and i I (ˆxi (s) ŵ i (s)) ɛ where is the max norm and ˆx = (ˆx i ) i I. Proof: We can suppose without loss of generality that 22 ɛ 1. Define X i a compact convex cube containing the compact set 23 X i = Pr i ({x R LI + : x i max{ŵ i (s) : s S} + 1 i I i I }) (13) in its interior relative to R L +. Write X = i I Xi and let ˆδ ɛ i the correspondence given in (12). Let ˆξ : X W R L be the excess of demand function defined by ˆξ(x, w) = i I (xi w i ). Since ˆξ is continuous and X W is compact, there exists N ξ > 0 such that ˆξ N ξ. Consider Q = {ξ R L + : ɛ 2 γ 2 /(LN ξ ) ξ N ξ }. Define Q = {ˆq : S Q ˆq Lp(M q )} and X = {ˆx : S X ˆx Lp(M x )}. Ascoli s Theorem in Royden (1963) and the compactness of Q and X assure that Q and X are compact. Define the function ˆ : X Q as ˆ (ˆx)(s) = max{ɛ 2 γ 2 /(LN ξ ), ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s))} for all s S with γ given in Assumption 4.7 with respect to the compact X. Let T : X X be the continuous convex valued correspondence (function) defined by: T (ˆx) = ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆ (ˆx)). i I Since X is a nonempty compact convex space endowed with a locally convex Hausdorff topology and T has closed graph, we can apply the Kakutani-Fan- Gliksberg Fixed Point Theorem in Aliprantis and Border (1999), Theorem 17.55, to conclude that T has a fixed point, say, ˆx. Write ˆq = ˆ (ˆx). 21 Note that ( c i, θ i ) is independent of (ĉ i, ˆθ i ). 22 In the case of ɛ > 1 remake all arguments replacing ɛ by A cube in R L is a product of a compact interval contained in R. Moreover, for a set X i R L +, write sup X i = (sup X i l ) l L R L + where X i l R + is the projection of X i into the l-th coordinate. Observe also that 0 X. 17

18 To show the market clearing conditions notice that since ˆq(s)ˆx i (s) ˆq(s)ŵ i (s) then ˆq(s)(ˆx i (s) ŵ i (s)) 0 for all s S and if we add over i I these budget restrictions we get ˆq(s)ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) 0 for all s S. (14) Suppose that ˆξ l (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) > ɛγ for some s S and some l L. Write L = {k L : ˆξ k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) > ɛ 2 γ 2 /(LN ξ )} and L = {k L : ˆξ k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) ɛ 2 γ 2 /(LN ξ )}. Then ˆq k ( s) := ˆ k (ˆx)( s) = ˆξ k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) for all k L and 24 ˆq( s)ˆξ(ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) = k L ˆq k ( s)ˆξ k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) + k L ˆq k ( s)ˆξ k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) = ˆξ2 k (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) + ɛ2 γ 2 ˆξk (ˆx( s), ŵ( s)) LN k L ξ k L > ɛ 2 γ 2 (L 1)N ξ ɛ 2 γ 2 /(LN ξ ) > 0 that is a contradiction with (14). We have thus proved that ˆξ l (ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) γɛ for each s S and l L. (15) To show that ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) ɛ 1, notice first that, using (15) we can conclude that ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) γɛ 1 1 for all s S and all i I. Therefore, ˆx(s) X Int X and hence ˆq(s)ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) = 0 for all s S. Indeed, all budget inequalities must bind because ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) 1 implies ˆx i (s ) Int X i for all i I. Choosing for each l L, the normalized price ˇq l (s) = ˆq l (s)/ ( k L ˆq k(s) ) for all s S, then ˆx i = ˆδ i (ˆx, ˆq) = ˆδ i (ˆx, ˇq) for all i I by Remark 4.3. Moreover, Assumption 4.7 assures that ˇq γ because ˆx(S) X Int X. Clearly, ˇq(s)ˆξ(ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) = 0 for each s S and using equation (15) we get ˇq l (s)ˆξ l (ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) = k l ˇq k (s)ˆξ k (ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) γɛ. Therefore, ˆξ l (ˆx(s), ŵ(s)) γɛ/ˇq l (s) ɛ for each l L. 24 Observe that l L. 18

19 4.2 Lucas tree model In this section we describe how to apply Theorem 4.11 to the Lucas tree model with heterogeneous agents. The Lemma 7.12 shows that Assumption 4.8 is satisfied for the case in which the model has one asset and one consumption good. Lemma Suppose that J = H = 1. Define S = {( θ, z) R+ LI θ : i I i = 1} and S its Borel σ-algebra. Write X i = C i Θ i with C i = R J + and Θ i = R H +. Suppose that V i : X i S Q X R is given by V i (c i, θ i, s, ˆq, ˆθ) = u(c i ) + β i v i (θ i, (ˆθ(s), z ), ˆq, ˆθ)λ i (z, dz ) (16) where v i is the value function given by (3). Then there exist conditions on { u i, u i, β i, λ i } i I such that Assumption 4.8 is satisfied for the demand correspondence ˇx i given by (11). Proof: See Lemma 7.12 in the Appendix. Theorem Let V i : X i S Q X R be given by (21) and ˇx i be given by (11) with respect to V i. Suppose that ˇx i satisfies Assumption 4.8 for all i I. Then Theorem 4.11 holds for {V i } i I where ˆx := (ĉ, ˆθ) and ŵ i (s) := ( ˆd(z) θ i, θ i ). Proof: In this case, all hypothesis satisfied by V i in Theorem 4.11 are assured. Indeed, Assumption 4.7 is a direct application of Lemma 2.10 and Theorem 3.9 because (ˆx, ˆq) implement the optimal choices (c, θ, q) given s = ( θ, z) such that (c i, θ i ) δ i ( θ i, z, q) for all i I. The argument used to show optimality of the equilibrium even considering C i Θ i = R J+H is standard. 25 For this, it is enough to use that u i is concave and that the optimum belongs to the interior of C i Θ i. 4.3 Convergence to an exact equilibrium In this section, we describe how the intertemporal variables of the economy could be close to a sequential competitive equilibrium through a possible 25 See Debreu (1959) or Mas-Colell et al. (1995) for further details. 19

20 anticipation of a recursive relation among them. First, we will define the concept of Jordan temporary equilibrium 26 similarly to that given in Jordan (1977) where agents can remake their plans in a given period if they fail to coordinate on the same price stream {q t } t N and show that it can be arbitrarily close to an exact sequential equilibrium with intertemporal consistency. The later would be the competitive equilibrium in which the economy would actually reach up if agents reduce their computational errors gradually. In this case, they have no incentive to deviate from their expectations on future prices and the plans do not change anymore. Notation The index tr indicates the variable planned at date t for r 1 periods ahead. In case r = 0, the index t0 indicates the current variable at period t. Definition Let θ be an initial portfolio distribution and for each period t, consider the following measurable q t (z t ) := {q tr (z t ) : r Q } r 0 contingent prices; 2. c t (z t ) := {c tr (z t ) : r C} r 0 contingent consumption allocation; 3. θ t (z t ) := {θ tr (z t ) : r Θ} r 0 contingent portfolio allocation. Then these allocations and prices constitute a Jordan temporary equilibrium for E if satisfy for all z t t and all t N: 1. optimality: (c i t(z t ), θ i t(z t )) δ i (θ i t 1,0(z t 1 ), z t, q t (z t )); 2. asset markets clearing: i I θi tr(z t )(z r ) = 1 for all r N; 3. good markets clearing: i I ci tr(z t )(z r ) = ˆd(z r ) 1+e i (z r ) for all r N. where we adopt by convention that θ i 00(z 0 ) = θ. Remark Note that if there exists t N such that the Jordan temporary equilibrium satisfies for each r N (c tr, θ tr, q tr )(z t )(z r ) = (c t+r,0, θ t+r,0, q t+r,0 )(z t+r ) then the economy eventually achieves a competitive equilibrium with intertemporal consistency, that is, a Magill-Quiinze equilibrium with infinite lived assets without short sales. 26 This concept incorporates the possibility of intertemporal inconsistency. 27 When r = 0 consider (c t0 (z t ), θ t0 (z t ), q t0 (z t )) constant. 20

21 The result below is an application of Theorem 4.11 and clarify how a competitive equilibrium can be approximated by implemented ɛ t -approximated recursive equilibrium for t N. Theorem Consider a sequence of errors {ɛ t} t N. Then there exists a sequence of ɛ t -approximate recursive equilibrium {ĉ t, ˆθ t, ˆq t } t N with ɛ t ɛ t and a Magill-Quiinze competitive equilibrium {c tr, θ tr, q t } r 0 with initial distribution θ and such that the distance 28 from the equilibrium implemented by {ĉ t, ˆθ t, ˆq t } t N starting from (θ t0 (z t 1 ), z t ) and {c tr, θ tr, q tr } r 0 is smaller than ɛ t for all t N. Proof: Fix t and suppose that s t = (θ t 1,0 (z t 1 ), z t ) is given. Choose ɛ k = 1/k for k N. Consider {ĉ k, ˆθ k, ˆq k } the ɛ k -approximate recursive equilibrium and {c trk, θ trk, q tk } r 0 its implemented ɛ k -approximate sequential equilibrium choices and plans starting from s t. Since is finite, 29 we can choose, passing to a subsequence, {c trkn, θ trkn, q tkn } n N such that {c tr, θ tr, q t } := lim n {c trkn, θ trkn, q tkn } for all r N. We claim that the limit prices {q t } t N are positive. Indeed, the compact set X given in 4.11 was chosen independent of ɛ and hence, Lemma 2.10 can be applied. Using Proposition 2.9 we conclude that the value function ˆv j given in Definition 2.7 is continuous on (θt 1,0(z j t 1 ), z t, q t ) and hence (c j t, θ j t ) δ j (θt 1,0(z j t 1 ), z t, q t ). Therefore the profile {c t, θ t, q t } t N is actually a Magill-Quiinze equilibrium with infinite lived assets without short sales because plans and choices satisfy the exact market clearing conditions, by construction and equations (18) and (19), defining the optimal intertemporal consistent plans {c tr } r 0 and {θ tr } r 0 as the limit of implemented plans. To conclude the proof, for a fixed t N, pick n N such that ɛ n := 1/k n ɛ t and that d((c tkn, θ tkn, q tkn ), (c t, θ t, q t )) ɛ t. Choosing ɛ t = ɛ n and (ĉ t, ˆθ t, ˆq t ) = (ĉ kn, ˆθ kn, ˆq kn ), we get the desired property using induction on t with initial conditions {s t } t N. 28 See Aliprantis and Border (1999) Section 3.9 about the metric in the Cartesian product. 29 Using the product topology, the Tychonoff Product Theorem and the fact that {c trk, θ trk, q trk } k N is contained in a compact set. 21

22 Remark Theorem 4.17 allow us to conclude that if agents update the recursive statistics with arbitrary small errors then, in the long run, they are close to the behavior of competitive equilibrium models presented in Radner (1972) or Magill and Quinzii (1996) with intertemporal consistency, even basing their choices in anticipation of approximate future prices using continuous statistics with minimal state space to compute the equilibrium. We conclude that the transition functions of the recursive equilibrium represent an important instrument of coordination among agents if the measurement errors become small enough to avoid that agents deviate from their previous plans. 5 Numerical Method The numerical method used here is similar to that found in Judd (1998). Basically, we proceed iterating functions recursively to find the solution of a certain functional equation as a fixed function on the limit 30. To clarify the method, given a price ˆq and a transition ˆθ, write ˆθ ( θ i, θ, z, ˆq, ˆθ) = ( θ i ( θ i, θ, z, ˆq, ˆθ)) i I for all ( θ, z) S where θ i : Θ i Θ Q Θ Θ i is the argmax of Bellman Equation (3). We compute first the value function v i (,, ˆq, ˆθ) on a finite set called grids S using the standard Bellman Method iterating value functions given an initial function v i 0. After that, we compute the asset excess demand ˆξ a ( θ, z) = i I θ i ( θ i, θ, z, ˆq, ˆθ) 1 for all ( θ, z) S, using the argmax of the value function v i (,, ˆq, ˆθ) on grids. Choosing a price ˆq = ˆq + ˆq Q where ˆq is an increment proportional to excess demand function ˆξ a, with the proportionality constant chosen appropriately to ensure the speed of convergence; we compute again ˆθ = { θ i ( θ i, θ, z, ˆθ, ˆq )} i I for all ( θ, z) grids and repeat the previous step until the desired precision. Notice that the convergence of the algorithm implies that the increment ˆq is near zero and therefore the excess demand ˆξ a also tends to zero in the limit. 30 On the sup norm. 22

23 Figure 1: Graphics of θ 1 ˆθ 1 ( θ 1, 1 θ 1 ) and θ 2 ˆθ 2 (1 θ 2, θ 2 ) for e 1 (z) = p1 and λ 2 (z) = p2 for all s {z 1, z 2 } Figure 2: Graphics of θ 1 ˆq( θ 1, 1 θ 1, z 1 ) and θ 1 ˆq( θ 1, 1 θ 1, z 2 ) We suppose that agents have homogeneous beliefs λ i = λ and heterogeneous instantaneous income e i : R ++ depending on the states of the nature. The budget set becomes for i = 1, 2 B i (θ i -, z, q) = {(c i, θ i ) C i Θ i : q c c i + q a θ i (q a + q c ˆd(z))θ i - + q c e i (z)} and we choose e 1 (z 1 ) = 1, e 1 (z 2 ) = 1, e 2 (z 1 ) = 1 and e 2 (z 2 ) = 2 that is, this example includes aggregate risk on the income. Type 1 has initial asset endowment θ 1 0 = 0.1 and type 2 has initial asset endowment θ 1 0 = 0.9. As a result we get linear affine policy functions and the dynamics of the simulations shows that all agents survive and the consumption and asset stream eventually becomes a stationary process. Figure 1 shows the policy functions. It is clear graphically that these functions are linear affine. Figure 2 shows that prices are independent of the income distribution and figure 3 shows that average consumption and asset stream becomes stationary over time. 6 Conclusion There exists a recursive equilibrium with minimal state space implementing a sequential equilibrium arbitrarily closed to a Magill Quinzii competitive equilibrium. Therefore, if agents update the recursive statistics with arbitrary small errors then, in the long run, they are close to the behavior of competitive equilibrium models presented in Radner (1972) or Magill and Quinzii Figure 3: Graphics of the asset average stream r 5000 (ci 1t)(z t r)/5000 for i = 1, 2 on the left, r 5000 (θi 2t)(z t r)/5000 for i = 1, 2 on the right, r = 5000 trajectories of (z r1, z r2,..., z rt ), T = 100 and λ 2 (z) = p = (0.4, 0.6) for all s {z 1, z 2 }. 23

24 (1996) with intertemporal consistency, even basing their choices in anticipation of approximate future prices using continuous statistics with minimal state space to compute the equilibrium. We conclude that the transition functions of the recursive equilibrium represent an important instrument of coordination among agents if the measurement errors become small enough to avoid that agents deviate from their previous plans. Moreover, it is possible o compute the approximate recursive equilibrium without using the first order conditions of optimality, through a method of iterating functional equations. 7 Appendix Notation 7.1. Recall that L = {1, 2,..., L}. Consider, X i R L +, Q = {q R L + : l L q l = 1}, Q = Q R L ++, Q γ = Q [γ, 1] L and S a topological space. Define X i as the set of all bounded continuous functions ˆx i : S X i and Q the set of all bounded continuous functions ˆq : S Q both endowed with the topology induced by the sup metric. Define Q analogously. The absence of the upper index stands for the Cartesian product on i I and we write 1 = (1, 1,..., 1) R L +. Lemma 7.2. Suppose that X i R L + is a compact convex set with 0 X i and that W i = R L +. Let B i : W i Q X i be the budget correspondence defined by B i (w i, q) = {x i X i : qx i qw i }. Then B i is continuous. Proof: If X i = {0} is trivial. Suppose that X i {0}. The upper hemicontinuity follows from the fact that B i has closed graph and compact range space. To show the lower hemicontinuity, let (w i n, q n ) A i converging to ( w i, q) A i as n and x i B i ( w i, q). Suppose first that q w i > 0. Then there exists an open set 31 O of A i containing ( w i, q) such that qw i > 0 for all (w i, q) O. Let Int B i : O X i be the correspondence defined by Int B i (w i, q) = {x i X i : qx i < qw i }. 31 Recall that we are using the relative topology. 24

25 Since 0 X i, Int B i is nonempty on the set O and X i is convex, then 32 B i (w i, q) = cl[int B i (w i, q)] for all (w i, q) O. Clearly, Int B i has open graph. Therefore, using that an open graph correspondence is lower hemicontinuous and that the closure of a lower hemicontinuous correspondence is lower hemicontinuous, we conclude that B i is lower hemicontinuous on O and hence there exists an N N and a sequence 33 x i n B i (wn, i q n ) for each n N such that x i n x i as n. If q w i = 0 then x i = 0. Since q 1 > 0, 0 X i and X i is convex non degenerated, there exists N N such that q 1n > 0 and (q n wn/q i 1n, 0) X i for n N. Choose the sequence x i 1n = q n wn/q i 1n and x i ln = 0 for l > 1 and n N. Then x i 1n = q n wn/q i 1n q w i / q 1 = 0 and hence x i n x i = 0 as n. Moreover, by construction, x i n B i (wn, i q n ) for each n N. Lemma 7.3. Consider Ỹ, Y metric spaces with Ỹ compact and Ỹ Y endowed with the product topology. Suppose that f : Ỹ Y RL is continuous. Let C(Ỹ, RL ) be the space of all bounded continuous functions h : Ỹ RL endowed with the sup norm. Then the function g : Y C(Ỹ, RL ) defined by g(y)( ) = f(, y) is continuous. Proof: Consider a sequence y n y and fix ɛ > 0. Then the set Y = {y n } n N {y} is compact. Therefore, f is uniformly continuous on Ỹ Y and hence the exists δ > 0 such that for all ỹ, ỹ Ỹ d((ỹ, y ), (ỹ, y)) < δ and y Y implies f(ỹ, y ) f(ỹ, y) ɛ. Assuming that 34 d((ỹ, y ), (ỹ, y)) = dỹ (ỹ, ỹ) + d Y (y, y) then choosing n 0 such that n n 0 implies d Y (y n, y) < δ we conclude that n n 0 implies d((ỹ, y n ), (ỹ, y)) < δ for all y Ỹ and hence f(ỹ, y n) f(ỹ, y) ɛ for all ỹ Ỹ. Thus f(, y n) converges uniformly to f(, y). Lemma 7.4. Consider Y R n. Suppose that f : Y Y and g : Y Y satisfy f Lp(M f ) and g Lp(Mg). Then f g Lp(M f M g ). Moreover, 32 To see the inclusion B i (w i, q) cl[int B i (w i, q)], given x i B i (w i, q) notice that if we choose x i Int B i (w i, q) then x i n := (1 1/n)x i + x i /n Int B i (w i, q) and x i n x i. Thus x i cl[int B i (w i, q)]. 33 The set N is chosen such that (w i n, q n ) O for each n N. 34 Clearly, this metric induces the product topology on Ỹ Y. 25

26 if f N f and γ g g N g for n = 1 and N f, N g, γ g > 0 then h = f/g Lp(N g M f + N f M g )/γg), 2 the sum f + g Lp(M f + M g ) and the product fg Lp(N g M f + N f M g ). Proof: Fix y, y Y. Thus f(g(y)) f(g(y )) M f g(y) g(y ) M f M g y y. Moreover, for n = 1 Therefore, Furthermore, f(y)g(y ) f(y )g(y) f(y)g(y ) f(y )g(y ) + f(y )g(y ) f(y )g(y) g(y ) f(y) f(y ) + f(y ) g(y) g(y ) (N g M f + N f M g ) y y. h(y) h(y ) = f(y)g(y ) f(y )g(y) / g(y)g(y ) y y (N g M f + N f M g )/ g(y)g(y ) (N g M f + N f M g ) y y /γ 2 g. f(y)g(y) f(y )g(y ) f(y)g(y) f(y )g(y) + f(y )g(y) f(y )g(y ) g(y) f(y) f(y ) + f(y ) g(y) g(y ) (N g M f + N f M g ) y y. Lemma 7.5. Consider Y, Y, Y k R n : k = 1, 2. Suppose that f : Y 1 Y 2 Y and g k : Y Y k satisfy f Lp(M f ) and g k Lp(M k ) for k = 1, 2. Then h : Y Y defined by h(y) = f(g 1 (y), g 2 (y)) for all y Y satisfies h Lp(M f max{m 1, M 2 }). Proof: h(y) h(y ) = f(g 1 (y), g 2 (y)) f(g 1 (y ), g 2 (y )) M f max{ g 1 (y) g 1 (y ), g 2 (y) g 2 (y ) } M f max{m 1 y y, M 2 y y } = M f max{m 1, M 2 } y y 26

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Discussion Papers in Economics

Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Papers in Economics No. 10/11 A General Equilibrium Corporate Finance Theorem for Incomplete Markets: A Special Case By Pascal Stiefenhofer, University of York Department of Economics and Related

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Working Papers Institute of Mathematical Economics 430 April 2010 Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Tomoki Inoue IMW Bielefeld University Postfach 100131 33501 Bielefeld Germany

More information

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes

Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Notes on Measure Theory and Markov Processes Diego Daruich March 28, 2014 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Motivation The objective of these notes will be to develop tools from measure theory and probability to allow

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Natural monopoly 1 C. Constant returns to scale 21 D. The CRS economy 26 E. pplication

More information

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Ömer Özak SMU Macroeconomics II Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 78 Preliminaries Introduction Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Solow model: constant

More information

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints Cuong Le Van IPAG Business School, CNRS, Paris School of Economics Ngoc-Sang Pham EPEE, University of Evry Yiannis

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

MULTIPLE-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA IN OLG MODELS WITH AMBIGUITY

MULTIPLE-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA IN OLG MODELS WITH AMBIGUITY MULTIPLE-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA IN OLG MODELS WITH AMBIGUITY by Kiyohiko G. Nishimura Faculty of Economics The University of Tokyo and Hiroyuki Ozaki Faculty of Economics Tohoku University

More information

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Notes on Recursive Utility Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in Section 1 (or Chapter 29, LeRoy & Werner, 2nd Ed.) Let u st be the continuation utility at s t. That

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production

Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production Recursive equilibria in dynamic economies with stochastic production Johannes Brumm DBF, University of Zurich johannes.brumm@googlemail.com Dominika Kryczka DBF, University of Zurich and Swiss Finance

More information

MULTI-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA: INDETERMINACY, COMPLEXITY AND SUSTAINED DEFLATION

MULTI-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA: INDETERMINACY, COMPLEXITY AND SUSTAINED DEFLATION JSPS Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (S) Understanding Persistent Deflation in Japan Working Paper Series No. 058 December 2014 MULTI-BELIEF RATIONAL-EXPECTATIONS EQUILIBRIA: INDETERMINACY, COMPLEXITY

More information

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand KC Border Revised Fall 2011; Winter 2017 Preferences For the purposes of this note, a preference relation

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lectures 5-7 November 7, 9 and 14, 2017. 1 / 83 Introduction

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies Takashi Kamihigashi September 28, 2015 Abstract We show a simple no-bubble theorem that applies to a wide range of deterministic sequential

More information

Chapter 2 Metric Spaces

Chapter 2 Metric Spaces Chapter 2 Metric Spaces The purpose of this chapter is to present a summary of some basic properties of metric and topological spaces that play an important role in the main body of the book. 2.1 Metrics

More information

Negishi s method for stochastic OLG models

Negishi s method for stochastic OLG models Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Felix Kubler University of Zurich QSPS, May 2013 Motivation OLG models are important tools in macro and public finance Unfortunately, humans typically live for 80 years...

More information

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model Supplemental material for: Fixed Term Employment Contracts in an Equilibrium Search Model Fernando Alvarez University of Chicago and NBER Marcelo Veracierto Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago This document

More information

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne Intertemporal equilibrium with production: bubbles and efficiency Stefano BOSI, Cuong LE VAN, Ngoc-Sang PHAM 2014.43 Maison des Sciences Économiques,

More information

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 202 Answer Key to Section 2 Questions Section. (Suggested Time: 45 Minutes) For 3 of

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth Daron Acemoglu MIT December 10, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 13 December 10, 2013. 1 / 52 Stochastic Growth Models Stochastic

More information

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA WORKING PAPERS Cycles and chaos in the one-sector growth model with elastic labor supply Gerhard Sorger May 2015 Working Paper No: 1505 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA All our working papers

More information

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Piero Gottardi EUI Sept. 20, 2015 Piero Gottardi (EUI) Microeconomics, Block I Part 2 Sept. 20, 2015 1 / 48 Pure Exchange Economy H consumers with: preferences described

More information

Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models

Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models Bernard CORNET, Lionel DE BOISDEFFRE Abstract In a financial economy with asymmetric information and incomplete markets, we study how agents,

More information

Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium

Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium Felix Kubler Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania fkubler@gmail.com Karl Schmedders Kellogg MEDS Northwestern University

More information

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Peter J. Hammond 1 Department of Economics, Stanford University, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. 1 Introduction and outline 1.1 Markets and social choice

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model

Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Stochastic Dynamic Programming: The One Sector Growth Model Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University March 26, 2012 Esteban Rossi-Hansberg () Stochastic Dynamic Programming March 26, 2012 1 / 31 References

More information

Arbitrage and Equilibrium with Portfolio Constraints

Arbitrage and Equilibrium with Portfolio Constraints Arbitrage and Equilibrium with Portfolio Constraints Bernard Cornet Ramu Gopalan October 25, 2009 Abstract We consider a multiperiod financial exchange economy with nominal assets and restricted participation,

More information

Maths 212: Homework Solutions

Maths 212: Homework Solutions Maths 212: Homework Solutions 1. The definition of A ensures that x π for all x A, so π is an upper bound of A. To show it is the least upper bound, suppose x < π and consider two cases. If x < 1, then

More information

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Microeconomics II MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3 Problem 1 Consider an economy 1 1, with one firm (or technology and one consumer (firm owner, as in the textbook (MWG section 15.C. The set of

More information

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017 Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived

More information

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Abstract: This paper gives a non-fixed point theoretic proof of equilibrium existence when the excess demand function of an exchange

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming

University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists 1 of 63 University of Warwick, EC9A0 Maths for Economists Lecture Notes 10: Dynamic Programming Peter J. Hammond Autumn 2013, revised 2014 University of

More information

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale. Increasing returns to scale and monopoly pricing 2. Constant returns to scale 19 C. The CRS economy 25 D. pplication to trade 47 E. Decreasing

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

Berge s Maximum Theorem

Berge s Maximum Theorem Berge s Maximum Theorem References: Acemoglu, Appendix A.6 Stokey-Lucas-Prescott, Section 3.3 Ok, Sections E.1-E.3 Claude Berge, Topological Spaces (1963), Chapter 6 Berge s Maximum Theorem So far, we

More information

Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles

Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles Adverse Selection, Risk Sharing and Business Cycles Marcelo Veracierto Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago February 2016 Abstract: I consider a real business cycle model in which agents have private information

More information

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014 Comprehensive Exam Macro Spring 2014 Retake August 22, 2014 You have a total of 180 minutes to complete the exam. If a question seems ambiguous, state why, sharpen it up and answer the sharpened-up question.

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

7 Complete metric spaces and function spaces

7 Complete metric spaces and function spaces 7 Complete metric spaces and function spaces 7.1 Completeness Let (X, d) be a metric space. Definition 7.1. A sequence (x n ) n N in X is a Cauchy sequence if for any ɛ > 0, there is N N such that n, m

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery João Correia-da-Silva Faculdade de Economia. Universidade do Porto. PORTUGAL. Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Facultad de Económicas. Universidad

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION Jan Werner European University Institute May 2010 1 I. Price Bubbles: An Example Example I.1 Time is infinite; so dates are t = 0,1,2,...,.

More information

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006 Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Model June 20, 2006 The Representative Agent Hypothesis and its Notion of Equilibrium 9.2.1 An infinitely lived Representative Agent Avoid terminal period problem Equivalence

More information

Chapter 3. Dynamic Programming

Chapter 3. Dynamic Programming Chapter 3. Dynamic Programming This chapter introduces basic ideas and methods of dynamic programming. 1 It sets out the basic elements of a recursive optimization problem, describes the functional equation

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

Social Welfare Functions for Sustainable Development

Social Welfare Functions for Sustainable Development Social Welfare Functions for Sustainable Development Thai Ha-Huy, Cuong Le Van September 9, 2015 Abstract Keywords: criterion. anonymity; sustainable development, welfare function, Rawls JEL Classification:

More information

Stochastic Dynamic Programming. Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Stochastic Dynamic Programming. Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania Stochastic Dynamic Programming Jesus Fernande-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Introducing Uncertainty in Dynamic Programming Stochastic dynamic programming presents a very exible framework to handle

More information

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 Index Page 1 Topology 2 1.1 Definition of a topology 2 1.2 Basis (Base) of a topology 2 1.3 The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3 1.4 Basic topology concepts: limit points, closed sets,

More information

Topological properties

Topological properties CHAPTER 4 Topological properties 1. Connectedness Definitions and examples Basic properties Connected components Connected versus path connected, again 2. Compactness Definition and first examples Topological

More information

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600. Alternative Methods of Discrete Time Intertemporal Optimization We will start by solving a discrete time intertemporal

More information

January 2018 No: 1152

January 2018 No: 1152 The social value of information in economies with mandatory savings Pablo F. Beker & Conrado Cuevas (This paper also appears as CRETA Discussion Paper No: 40) January 2018 No: 1152 Warwick Economics Research

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

Exhaustible Resources and Economic Growth

Exhaustible Resources and Economic Growth Exhaustible Resources and Economic Growth Cuong Le Van +, Katheline Schubert + and Tu Anh Nguyen ++ + Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, CNRS, Paris School of Economics ++ Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne,

More information

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014 You will have three hours to complete this exam. Please write your solution to question one in blue book 1 and your solutions to the subsequent questions in blue

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders

Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders Price and Wealth Dynamics in a Speculative Market with an Arbitrary Number of Generic Technical Traders Mikhail Anufriev Giulio Bottazzi S.Anna School for Advanced Studies, Pisa, Italy February 20, 2005

More information

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, 2017 9:00 am - 2:00 pm INSTRUCTIONS Please place a completed label (from the label sheet provided) on the

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1 Review Questions: Overlapping Generations Econ720. Fall 2017. Prof. Lutz Hendricks 1 A Savings Function Consider the standard two-period household problem. The household receives a wage w t when young

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

1 General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium 1 General Equilibrium 1.1 Pure Exchange Economy goods, consumers agent : preferences < or utility : R + R initial endowments, R + consumption bundle, =( 1 ) R + Definition 1 An allocation, =( 1 ) is feasible

More information

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Michael Florig Jorge Rivera Cayupi First version November 2001, this version May 2005 Abstract We study an economy where all goods entering

More information

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University February 7, 2007 2 Contents 1 Metric Spaces 1 1.1 Basic definitions...........................

More information

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006)

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006) A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics by Clementi and Hopenhayn - Quarterly Journal of Economics (2006) A Presentation for Corporate Finance 1 Graduate School of Economics December, 2009

More information

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem Set 2: s Math 201A: Fall 2016 Problem 1. (a) Prove that a closed subset of a complete metric space is complete. (b) Prove that a closed subset of a compact metric space is compact. (c) Prove that

More information

First Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem First Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 17, October 31 Outline 1 First Welfare Theorem 2 Preliminaries to Second Welfare Theorem Past Definitions A feasible allocation (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal

More information

Equilibrium with Transaction Costs

Equilibrium with Transaction Costs National Meeting of Women in Financial Mathematics IPAM April 2017 Kim Weston University of Texas at Austin Based on Existence of a Radner equilibrium in a model with transaction costs, https://arxiv.org/abs/1702.01706

More information

Kevin X.D. Huang and Jan Werner. Department of Economics, University of Minnesota

Kevin X.D. Huang and Jan Werner. Department of Economics, University of Minnesota Implementing Arrow-Debreu Equilibria by Trading Innitely-Lived Securities. Kevin.D. Huang and Jan Werner Department of Economics, University of Minnesota February 2, 2000 1 1. Introduction Equilibrium

More information

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems Craig Burnside Duke University September 2010 Craig Burnside (Duke University) Competitive Equilibrium September 2010 1 / 32 Competitive Equilibrium and

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013 arxiv:1304.3284v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013 Existence and uniqueness of Arrow-Debreu equilibria with consumptions in L 0 + Dmitry Kramkov Carnegie Mellon University and University of Oxford, Department of

More information

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Existence, ncentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Yeneng Sun, Lei Wu and Nicholas C. Yannelis Abstract The rational expectations equilibrium (REE), as introduced

More information

Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory

Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory Ken URAI and Akihiko YOSHIMACHI October, 2003 Abstract The aim of this paper is to develop fixed point theorems

More information

1 Second Welfare Theorem

1 Second Welfare Theorem Econ 701B Fall 018 University of Pennsylvania Recitation : Second Welfare Theorem Xincheng Qiu (qiux@sas.upenn.edu) 1 Second Welfare Theorem Theorem 1. (Second Welfare Theorem) An economy E satisfies (A1)-(A4).

More information

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Real Business Cycle Model The Real Business Cycle Model Macroeconomics II 2 The real business cycle model. Introduction This model explains the comovements in the fluctuations of aggregate economic variables around their trend.

More information

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model Virginia Sánchez-Marcos Macroeconomics, MIE-UNICAN Macroeconomics (MIE-UNICAN) A simple macro dynamic model with

More information

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces Part III 10 Topological Space Basics Topological Spaces Using the metric space results above as motivation we will axiomatize the notion of being an open set to more general settings. Definition 10.1.

More information

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation

Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Lecture 5: The Bellman Equation Florian Scheuer 1 Plan Prove properties of the Bellman equation (In particular, existence and uniqueness of solution) Use this to prove properties of the solution Think

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER SCARLETT LI Abstract. The focus of this paper is proving Brouwer s fixed point theorem, which primarily relies on the fixed point property of the

More information

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0 Part 6 1. Borrowing Constraints II 1.1. Borrowing Constraints and the Ricardian Equivalence Equivalence between current taxes and current deficits? Basic paper on the Ricardian Equivalence: Barro, JPE,

More information

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015 Lecture 2 (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis Erick Sager September 14, 2015 Econ 605: Adv. Topics in Macroeconomics Johns Hopkins University, Fall 2015 Erick Sager Lecture 2 (9/14/15) 1 /

More information

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Dynamic Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Dynamic Economies A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Dynamic Economies Takashi Kamihigashi June 23, 2015 Abstract In this paper we show a simple no-bubble theorem that applies to a wide range of deterministic

More information

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability Chapter 7 Nathan Smooha Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability 7.1 Introduction Brouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Let X be a non-empty, compact, and convex subset of R m. If

More information

Distributed Optimization. Song Chong EE, KAIST

Distributed Optimization. Song Chong EE, KAIST Distributed Optimization Song Chong EE, KAIST songchong@kaist.edu Dynamic Programming for Path Planning A path-planning problem consists of a weighted directed graph with a set of n nodes N, directed links

More information

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

Slides II - Dynamic Programming Slides II - Dynamic Programming Julio Garín University of Georgia Macroeconomic Theory II (Ph.D.) Spring 2017 Macroeconomic Theory II Slides II - Dynamic Programming Spring 2017 1 / 32 Outline 1. Lagrangian

More information

4 Countability axioms

4 Countability axioms 4 COUNTABILITY AXIOMS 4 Countability axioms Definition 4.1. Let X be a topological space X is said to be first countable if for any x X, there is a countable basis for the neighborhoods of x. X is said

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information