Confidence Intervals for an Autoregressive Coeffi cient Near One Based on Optimal Selection of Sequences of Point Optimal Tests

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Confidence Intervals for an Autoregressive Coeffi cient Near One Based on Optimal Selection of Sequences of Point Optimal Tests"

Transcription

1 Confidence Intervals for an Autoregressive Coeffi cient Near One Based on Optimal Selection of Sequences of Point Optimal ests Muhammad Saqib, David Harris Department of Economics, he University of Melbourne, Melbourne, Australia Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics Monash University, Clayton, Australia July 2, Abstract In this paper, we reconsider Elliot and Stock s 2001 method to construct confidence intervals for an autoregressive coeffi cient by inverting a sequence of invariant point optimal tests. We show that the power properties of the point optimal tests can vary greatly with the choice of the point under the alternative at which power is maximised. Some choices are shown to lead to inconsistent tests, including, in some cases, the rule of thumb proposed by Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock We propose the optimisation of a weighted power criterion as an alternative method to specify the point optimal tests and demonstrate that this provides tests with desirable asymptotic local power properties. Keywords Point optimal test, GLS detrending, asymptotic power, weighted power maximization, invariant Jeffreys prior. 1 Introduction In the last three decades enormous work has been done by different researchers in the area of unit root testing and construction of confidence intervals for the autoregressive root including local to unity framework proposed by Bobkovski 1983, Cavanagh 1985, Phillips 1987, and Chan and Wei As mentioned in Stock 1991, Cavanagh first constructed the confidence interval for the autoregressive root ρ in an AR1 model without deterministics using local to unity setting with ρ = 1 + c/ based on t-test statistic. However Stock 1991 extended Cavanagh s work by considering deterministic component in ARp model and constructed confidence interval for the largest autoregressive root by inverting the Dickey-Fuller t-test and Modified Sargan-Bhargava test statistics. Elliot and Stock 2001 henceforth ES proposed new asymptotic methods to construct confidence intervals for AR parameter using sequence of tests approach by coupling Stock s method with ideas given in Elliot, Rothenberg, and Stock 1996 henceforth ERS. ERS followed local to unity asymptotic approximations to the point optimal invariant test of King 1

2 1987 and based on Neyman-Pearson Lemma after assuming Gaussian distribution for the errors they described that the best test of ρ = 1 against any given alternative ρ = ρ 1 is the likelihood ratio test. his testing problem with ρ = 1 + c/ is the same as testing H 0 : c = 0 against H 1 : c = c 1 < 0 where the likelihood ratio test is the point optimal test. Contrary to Stock s OLS detrending, ERS suggested GLS transformation of the data to deal with deterministics that utilizes c 1 value under the local alternative. his constant is chosen such that the power curve of point optimal test is tangent to the power envelope at power one-half and hence results in famous choices of c 1 = 7 when x t = 1 and c 1 = 13.5 when x t = 1 t. ERS also provide simulation evidence that the tests based on GLS-demeaning/detrending of the data in the presence of deterministics are more powerful tests with power curves indistinguishable from the Gaussian power envelope compared to the same tests based on OLS transformation with poor power properties. By combining the ideas of Stock and ERS, ES use sequence of tests to obtain confidence set for the largest autoregressive root as a set of those values that are not rejected by the sequence of tests. Under this approach each test in the sequence is point optimal test of a particular null versus a particular alternative. he key inspiration behind their approach is the powerful test of a particular parameter value against different alternatives will produce accurate confidence intervals. he main objective behind this work is to revisit ES work where we generalize their testing problem to H 0 : c = c 0 for any c 0 instead of only c 0 0 for the purpose of constructing confidence interval of the autoregressive root under local to unity set up. his requires modification of the point optimal test and its asymptotic distribution. We do not ignore the possibility of mildly explosive root of a time series and take into account testing positive values of c 0. Our analysis shows that when testing for any positive c 0 the point optimal test can become inconsistent with lower sided alternatives and also has inferior power close to the null using upper tail test based on the alternative values proposed by ERS and ES and indicates that the choice of c 1 is more influential when c 0 > 0 then c 0 0. Moreover in two-sided testing case we reconsider with ES s choice of α L = 0.03 and α U = 0.02 where they justify the assignment of higher probability of type-i error to the left tail by the argument that the power curves are steeper at right tails. his choice is pragmatic and without any formal justification and we have strong conjecture that the choice of α L and α U is sensitive to varying c 0. hese observations also pointed out by ES in their conclusion motivate us to choose model parameters c 1L, c 1U for one-sided tests and c 1L, c 1U, α L, α U for two-sided tests based on some formal method using optimality criteria e.g. maximization of weighted powers. Simulation analysis proves the superiority of power curves of the test based on our proposed parameters compared to those based on ERS and ES and implies accuracy of resulting confidence intervals. he paper is organized as follows. he model and the method of construction of confidence intervals as discussed in ES is summarized in the next section. In section 3, we discuss about the 2

3 impact of different values of c 1 on one-tailed tests, inconsistency of the test caused by some of c 1 values and, alternative criteria for choosing c 1 optimally. We extend the analysis to two-sided tests and provide some formal methods to choose model parameters in section 4. Results are provide in section 5. Section 6 concludes. All proofs are provided in Appendix A. 2 he Model and Hypothesis esting Problem Consider a time series y t with the data generating process given by y t = x tγ + u t, t = 1,...,, 2.1 u t = ρu t 1 + ε t, u 0 = 0, 2.2 ρ = 1 + c/, ε t i.i.d.0, σ 2. where we treat x tγ in the DGP as deterministic component with usual two cases of constant mean x t = 1 and, constant and linear time trend x t = 1 can be extended to higher order time polynomials. t but of course the analysis Similarly the assumption that the initial condition u 0 = 0 is vital and follows ERS and will be maintained in this paper. Since we are interested only in the asymptotic properties of the point optimal test therefore our analysis here is restricted to disturbances ε t being i.i.d., however the approach is flexible to allow for other error structures for practical purposes. Also ε t obeys the Functional Central heorem such that 1/2 [ s] j=1 ε d j σbs, 0 s 1 where [.] represents greatest lesser integer function, Bs is a standard Brownian motion defined on C[0, 1], and d denotes weak convergence in distribution. Sequence test approach Suppose we want to construct 1001 α% confidence set CS α y for the autoregressive parameter ρ by inverting the sequence of tests with y as the test statistic of asymptotic size α that rejects for small values. For the hypothesis H 0 : ρ = ρ 0 against H 1 : ρ ρ 0, the test is performed over a range of values ρ 0 and the confidence set is then derived as the set of those values of ρ 0 that are not rejected by the tests as CS α y = {ρ : y > cv α ρ 0 } where cv is the critical value. his set exhibits the property that it has asymptotic coverage probability of at least 1 α for any true value of ρ, i.e. lim Pr [ρ CS α y] 1 α. We define the rejection probability of the test as π ρ = Pr y < cv α ρ 0. If the test fails to reject the false null H 0 : ρ = ρ provided that ρ 0 is true then the probability of inclusion of false value ρ in CS α y, is given by β = Pr ρ0 ρ CS α y. However accurate confidence intervals require the test to have smaller β implying high power. his paper therefore considers the construction of tests of good power properties. Under local to unity setting the autoregressive root is ρ = 1 + c/ and for any fixed value ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 / we can construct the test of H 0 : ρ = ρ 0 against the one-sided alternatives where 3

4 the side depends whether ρ 1 < ρ 0 or ρ 1 > ρ 0, i.e. H 1L : ρ = ρ 1 < ρ 0 or H 1U : ρ = ρ 1 > ρ 0. his problem is analogous to testing H 0 : c = c 0 vs. H 1 : c = c 1. For lower sided test we have c 1 < c 0 and upper sided test requires c 1 > c 0. One sided confidence set can be constructed as a set of those values of c 0 that are not rejected by the test, i.e. CS α,i y = {c 0 : i y does not reject}, i = L, U. where for upper sided test we have ĉ U = sup CS α,u y and the resulting confidence interval would be, ĉ U. Similarly ĉ L = inf CS α,l y and provides ĉ L, as the lower sided confidence interval for c. Construction of two-sided confidence interval in this framework for H 0 : c = c 0 requires inverting two one-sided tests corresponding to H 1L : c = c 1L < c 0 and H 1 : c = c 1U > c 0. Given the constraint that the probability of rejecting the true null is some fixed level α, the twosided confidence interval consists of those values of c 0 that are not rejected by both tests. We will explain more about this shortly. Once we obtain the confidence interval for c, confidence interval for ρ can be obtained simply by applying the transformation ˆρ = 1 + ĉ/. For above hypothesis with ρ j = 1 + c j /, j = 0, 1, ES have proposed point optimal invariant test that accounts for values of ρ under both the null and alternative as P c 0, c 1 = 1ˆσ 2 ˆε2 1,t 1 + c 1/ 1 + c 0 / ˆε2 0,t where 2.3 ˆε j,t = û j,t ρ j û j,t 1, j = 0, 1 û j,t = y t x tˆγ j, ˆγ j = arg min y j,t x γ j,tγ y j,t x j,tγ, j and y j,t, x j,t are quasi-differenced series obtained as From above equations we can also write ˆε j,t as { z t, t = 1, z j,t = z t 1 + c j / z t 1, t = 2,...,. ˆε j,t = y j,t x j,tˆγ j, j = 0, 1 Since we are interested in a test with high power at a specific value of the parameter against alternatives in either direction, so the asymptotic rejection probability of the point optimal test is given by πc; c 0, c 1 := lim PrP c 0, c 1 < k α ρ = 1 + c/. where k α = k α c 0, c 1 is the asymptotic critical value. his rejection probability πc; c 0, c 1 represents asymptotic power of the test where the test P c 0, c 1 rejects the null for small values 4

5 and for true c 0 has asymptotic size equal to power given by πc 0 ; c 0, c 1 = α. Since the critical value and the power both depend on c 0 and c 1 the values under the null and local alternative respectively therefore there is no single uniformly most powerful invariant UMPI test however a family of Neyman-Pearson tests indexed by c 1. Each test in the family is most powerful at the point c 1 = c and forms the power envelope defined by πc; c 0, c πc; c 0, c 1. For one-sided confidence intervals for ρ, the test of H 0 : c = 0 with lower tail stationary alternative H 1 : c = c 1 < 0 is usual unit root test and the point optimal test in this case reduces to the one introduced and analyzed in detail by ERS. For the choice of c 1, ERS proposed inverting the envelope power function such that πc 1 ; 0, c 1 = 0.50 and the tests have power functions not too far from the power envelope over a substantial range. his results in c 1 = 7 for x t = 1 and c 1 = 13.5 for x t = 1, t. For two-sided confidence interval two different values of c 1 as c 1L and c 1U in ρ 1 = 1 + c 1 / are required to test the null H 0 : c = c 0 against the alternatives H 1 : c 1 = c 1L < c 0 and H 1 : c 1 = c 1U > c 0. For the sake of confidence interval construction, ES extend the testing problem to different values of c 0 = 0, 5, 10 and recommend using alternatives that are fixed distance from the null as H 1i : c 1 = c 0 + c 1i, i = L, U. hey use c 1L, c 1U = 7, 2 and 13.5, 5 respectively for x t = 1 and x t = 1, t. o make notations simple we define the events R αi c 0, c 1i = {P c 0, c 1i < k αi c 0, c 1i }, i = L, U where for instance R αl c 0, c 1L denotes the event that occurs when the lower tail test rejects the null at α i significance level. ES set the overall size of the test as α L +α U = α to have confidence intervals with desired coverage probability of 1001 α% where α i = Pr R αi c 0, c 1i ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 /, i = L, U is the size of the individual test. We now define the rejection probability of the two-sided test as π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L, α U = Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R αu c 0, c 1U ρ = 1 + c/. While size of the joint test is given by π α c 0 ; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L, α U = Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R αu c 0, c 1U ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 / = Pr R αl c 0, c 1L ρ = 1 + c 0 / + Pr R αu c 0, c 1U ρ = 1 + c 0 / Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R αu c 0, c 1U ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 / = α L + α U Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R αu c 0, c 1U ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 / α his implies that size of the joint test is bounded by α and if simultaneous rejections occur then choosing α L + α U < α results in a conservative test that yields unnecessary long confidence interval. herefore in our simulation experiments we will also keep eye on the size of the joint tests. Using α U = α α L, the rejection probability of the two-sided test reduces to 5

6 π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L = Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R α αl c 0, c 1U ρ = 1 + c/ he confidence set is a set of those values of ρ 0 that are not rejected by either of the two tests or both. his implies that neither of the two events R αl c 0, c 1L and R αu c 0, c 1U should occur. However due to the possibility of simultaneous rejection of lower and upper tail tests the overall size of the tests follows the constraint α L + α U α whereas α works as upper bound for the size of the test. Confidence set and the resulting confidence interval given α L and α U is CS = {c 0 : R αl c 0, c 1L c R αu c 0, c 1U c }, CI = ĉ L, ĉ U where ĉ L = inf c0 CS and ĉ U = sup c0 CS. he confidence interval for ρ is then ˆρ L, ˆρ U where ˆρ L = 1 + ĉ L / and ˆρ U = 1 + ĉ U /. 3 Modified Point Optimal est Ng and Perron 2001 have considered the modified point optimal tests and provide their limiting distributions that coincide with the feasible point optimal test of ERS when testing c 0 = 0. Since our objective is to extend the analysis to the general testing problem c = c 0 in ρ = 1 + c/, so we modify the point optimal test of Ng and Perron 2001 and denote it by MP. he test statistic and its limiting distribution for testing H 0 : c = c 0 against H 1 : c = c 1 are given for 1. Constant Case c MP c 0, c 1 = ˆσ c d c 2 1 c û 2 1,t 1 c 1 c 0 1 û 2 1, B c s 2 ds c 1 c 0 B c Constant and Linear rend Case MP c 0, c 1 = ˆσ 2 d c c û 2 1,t c 1 1 û 2 1, c V c,c1 s 2 ds + 1 c 1 V c,c1 1 2 c û 2 0,t 1 1 c 0 1 û 2 0, V c,c0 s 2 ds 1 c 0 V c,c

7 [ where V c,ci s = B c s s λb c λ i ] 1 0 sb csds, λ i = B c s is the Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process given by 1 c i 1 c i + 1, i = 0, 1, and 3 c2 i B c s = with B r as standard Brownian motion. 4 One-Sided esting s 0 exp c s r db r In this section we investigate the influence of different choices of c 1 under the alternative on asymptotic local power properties of the point optimal test for different c 0. We consider c 0 = 4 as a representative case for negative choices of c 0, c 0 = 4 for positive values and, the famous unit root case when c 0 = 0. All simulations in this paper are performed in GAUSS using = 1000 and 50, 000 replications for cases x t = 1 and x t = 1, t. 4.1 he effect of c 1 on lower tail tests he first two panels in figures 4.1 and 4.2 respectively correspond to c 0 = 0 and 4 where we observe that ERS and ES choices of c 1 result in power curves that are quite indistinguishable from the power envelope across all c. his property is also fairly robust to variations in c 1 as evident from the power curves for some arbitrary choices of c 1 that correspond to power higher than 50% at the power envelope. he most interesting behavior emerges for the final case as can be seen from third panel of above figures, where we have quite different findings for c 0 = 4. We observe that the choice of c 1 values can matter a great deal to the power properties of the point optimal test. Based on 50% rule of ERS, c 1 = 3.75 for demeaned case and c 1 = 2.25 for constant and linear trend case produce tests with non-monotonic power curves that are close to the envelope near the null but then decline towards zero as c moves away from the null. his behavior is explored further below. However c 1 equal to 3 for x t = 1 and 9.5 for x t = 1, t based on ES fixed distance from the null rule behaves reasonably well but unlike the examples of c 0 = 4, 0, there does not exist any single choice of c 1 that produces a test with power uniformly close to the power envelope. herefore the choice of c 1 when we test some positive value of c 0 is important and will be considered below in more detail Why is the test inconsistent for some c 1 when c 0 > 0? From above discussion we know that the point optimal test when applied to test c 0 = 4 against the lower tail local alternative based on c 1 of ERS and arbitrary value of 2.5 has non-monotonic 7

8 Figure 4.1: Power Curves: Constant Mean 8

9 Figure 4.2: Power Curves: Constant and linear trend 9

10 asymptotic power curves that approach to zero as c diverges from the null. his observation suggests that the test may be inconsistent. A possible explanation for this inconsistency of the test may be as follows. he point optimal test without deterministics as shown in appendix A is approximately P c 0, c 1 = 1ˆσ c c y2 t 1 + c 0 c 1 1 y and we reject the null for small values i.e. the test rejects when P c 0, c 1 < k α. Since the asymptotic distribution of point optimal test is independent of ˆσ 2, so we can replace it with known σ 2 to keep things simple. First consider the case of testing unit root against the stationary local alternatives that requires c 0 = 0 and c 1 < 0. he test given above becomes P 0, c 1 = 1 σ 2 c y2 t 1 c 1 1 y 2, and consists of entirely positive terms and leads to k α > 0. hus the test is consistent against fixed alternatives and its consistency can be shown as below. With ρ < 1, we have and 1 yt 1 2 p E yt 1 2 σ 2 = 1 ρ 2 y 2 d y 2, where y 2 represents a random variable with stationary distribution of y t, i.e. y σ 2 0, 1 ρ 2. hus P 0, c 1 d c2 1 1 ρ 2 c y 2 1. σ his convergence in distribution shows that under fixed alternatives P 0, c 1 = O p 1 or P 0, c 1 = O p 1. his implies that P 0, c 1 p 0 and hence we observe Pr P 0, c 1 < k α ρ < 1 1, i.e. the test statistic will be less than any positive critical value with probability approaching 1. herefore the test is consistent. Now consider the case such that c 0 > 0 and we test c 0 against the lower tail alternative c 1 < c 0. he signs of terms c 2 1 c2 0 2 y2 t 1 + c 0 c 1 1 y 2 of point optimal test in 4.1 depend on magnitudes of c 0 and c 1 contrary to the unit root test case with c 0 = 0 and c 1 < 0. Under this new situation with c 0 > 0 and c 1 < c 0, we have c 0 c 1 > 0 and so the second term c 0 c 1 1 y 2 > 0. Now we have two cases to conjecture about the sign of the first term as: 1. If c 1 > c 0, then c 2 1 c2 0 > 0 leads to c 2 1 c2 0 2 y2 t 1 > 0 and we are back to the situation with consistent test. 2. For c 1 < c 0, we have c 2 1 c2 0 < 0 implying c 2 1 c2 0 2 of c 1 we may have c 2 1 c2 0 2 y2 t 1 c 0 c 1 1 y 2 test P c 0, c 1 is not guaranteed to be positive or negative. 10 y2 t 1 < 0. For different values and so the point optimal

11 Note that for this second case, the test is still the likelihood ratio test but may cause inconsistency in some cases. Under the fixed alternative case ρ < 1 we have P c 0, c 1 d c 2 1 c ρ 2 + c y 2 0 c 1. σ his implies that P c 0, c 1 = O p 1 or P c 0, c 1 p 0 for fixed alternative case as before. But the inconsistency arises given c 2 1 c2 0 < 0 and the critical value may be negative i.e. k α < 0. he reason why this negative critical value causes inconsistency is that if P c 0, c 1 p 0 and k α < 0 then Pr P c 0, c 1 < k α converges to zero instead of one. For instance, in demeaned case for c 0 = 4 if we choose c 1 such that < c 1 < 4, the resulting test is inconsistent. his is the underlying reason for non-monotonic power curves when testing some positive value of c 0. As c, the local to unity model behaves like a stationary model and the point optimal test does not have power against stationary models. his logic is not applicable to local to unity model itself, i.e. the test with c 1 < 4 e.g. c 1 = 2.5 as evident from figure 4.1 may have good local power properties near the null but has poor properties further from the null suggesting not to choose that test. hus based on our simulation experiments we find that; for a test with constant we need c , and with constant and linear trend we need c 1 < in order for the P test to be consistent against stationary alternatives. 4.2 he effect of c 1 on upper tail tests o see if c 1 matters in case of upper tail testing, power curves are presented in figures 4.3 and 4.4 respectively for demeaned and detrended cases. First two panels in these figures correspond to c 0 = 0 and c 0 = 4 respectively. In both specifications of x t we see that the power curves produced by using different values of c 1 are fairly close to the power envelope and we are indifferent in using either of these values with an exception of the subjective choice of c 1 = 4 in case of c 0 = 0. he test when used with c 1 = 4 a value that is a bit far from the null has low power for all c that are close to the null but as c moves away from the null the power gets closer to the power bound. his power loss for values near the null make c 1 = 4 an inferior choice compared to ERS and ES. As evident from final panels of above figures, some different behavior emerges for c 0 = 4. We have c ERS 1 = and c ES 1 = 6 for constant mean case and c ERS 1 = 4.5 and c ES 1 = 9 for constant and linear trend case with some arbitrary choices of c 1 as a value between c ERS 1 and c ES 1 or a value greater than c ES 1. We observe that in both cases power curves of the test based on c ERS 1 are reasonably close to the power envelope until their tangency to the envelope at c 1 itself but afterwards remain below and, contrary to other two cases of c 0 = 4, 0, never get quite close to the envelope. On the other hand, power of the test based on c ES 1 remains substantially low for c that are near to the null as manifested by nearly horizontal segment of the power curve. However as c increases further away from the null the power curve starts rising quickly towards the power 11

12 Figure 4.3: Power Curves: Constant mean 12

13 Figure 4.4: Power Curves: Constant and linear trend 13

14 bound in demeaned case but behaves rather poorly in linear trend case. In summary, the choice of c 1 has a substantial effect on the power properties of the tests for c 0 = 4. It will therefore be necessary to consider ways of choosing c Is the test inconsistent for upper tail testing? o answer this question of inconsistency for the upper tail test we again focus on the two terms given in the point optimal test. Since c 1 > c 0, so the second term c 0 c 1 1 y 2 in point optimal test is always negative. he first term c 2 1 c2 0 2 y2 t 1 might be positive or negative depending on c 2 1 c2 0. However, for upper tail test none of this matters in the same way that it does for the consistency of lower tail tests against stationary alternatives. In the latter case the statistic converges to zero, so the sign of the critical value is important for the consistency or otherwise of the test. In considering the consistency of a test against explosive alternatives, we have both 2 + and 1 y 2 p +. More specifically, for the DGP y t = ρy t 1 + ε t with ρ > 1, we find from heorem 2 of Lai and Wei 1983 see equations 2.1 and 2.3 that ρ 2 y 2 = O p 1 and ρ 2 y2 t 1 = O p 1, so the two terms in the test statistic are actually the same order when ρ > 1. But notice that y2 t 1 is divided by 2 while y 2 is only divided by in the statistic, so the asymptotic behavior of the statistic when ρ > 1 is determined entirely by c 0 c 1 1 y 2. For any upper tailed test i.e. any c 0, c 1 such that c 0 < c 1 we have c 0 c 1 1 y 2 p, and the test rejects for small values of P, so it will reject with probability converging to one against explosive alternatives. hus inconsistency is not an issue here. y2 t 1 p 5 Alternative criteria to choose c 1 Based on previous discussion we find that the alternatives proposed in the literature work fairly well when applied to testing c 0 taking zero or negative values. But for testing positive values of c 0, the test becomes inconsistent for lower sided testing or has low power near the null for upper tail testing. his issue motivates us to find some alternative choices of the model parameters. As discussed in Patterson 2011, Cox and Hinkley 1974 provide the following three possible choices when there does not exist any uniformly most powerful test. i. Use the most powerful test for a representative ρ 1 value under the alternative. ii. Maximize power for an alternative very local to the null. iii. Maximize the weighted power for a range of local alternatives. o achieve our objective we will use i and iii and some other criteria as well. o this end, let π α c; c 0, c 1i and π α c; c 0, c respectively denote the asymptotic local power function and the asymptotic power envelope of test of size α and 14

15 where π α c 0 ; c 0, c 1i = α. Criterion 1 Power curves tangency π α c; c 0, c 1i := lim Pr P c 0, c 1i < k α ρ = 1 + c/ Based on i above, we can apply power curves tangency rule to obtain c 1i as a value such that the asymptotic power curve is tangent to the power envelope at some pre-decided power π, i.e. π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1i = π where π = 50% or 80%. Note that ERS s choice of c 1i is based on this criterion using π = 0.50 with emphasis on the treatment of deterministics under the alternatives local to the null. Criterion 2 Minimax criterion In addition to the criteria above, we could choose the optimal value of c 1 as the value that minimizes the largest power loss relative to the power envelope, i.e. c 1i = arg min c 1i Criterion 3 Optimal weighted average power max π α c; c 0, c π α c; c 0, c 1i. c Based on rule iii given above following Cox and Hinkley 1974, we can define the optimal weighted average power function as c 1i = arg max c 1i C j π α c; c 0, c 1i wcdc, j = l, u where π α c 0 ; c 0, c 1i = α and wc 0 represents weights as a function of c, Cl =, c 0 ] for lower tailed test and C u = [c 0, when the test is upper tailed. C j One problem with the set C j is that the integral Cj π α c; c 0, c 1i wcdc need not exist if is unbounded. We can either choose w c such that Cj w c dc < or restrict wc to interval/truncated domain C j C j so that the integral π α c; c 0, c 1i wcdc exists when defined on C j with C l = [c l, c 0 ] and C u = [c 0, c u ]. For instance, for lower tailed test the integral can become c0 b π α c; c 0, c 1L wcdc. Now the question arises of how to choose b? As a practical matter we can choose b such that for any small ε > 0 we observe power envelope within ε of maximum attainable power of 1, i.e. 1 π α b; c 0, b ε. For two-sided tests we will stick to the choice of weighted average power maximization. As given above the rejection probability of the two-sided test using α U = α α L is π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L = Pr R αl c 0, c 1L R α αl c 0, c 1U ρ = 1 + c/ 15

16 So in general we can set about choosing c 1L, c 1U, α L to maximize weighted power, i.e. {c 1L, c 1U, α L} = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L w c dc. {c 1L,c 1U,α L } C Using the optimal value α L, we can find optimal value of α U from α U = α α L. However for fixed α L and hence α U like the case of ES, we can obtain separately the optimal values of c 1L and c 1U as c 1i = max c 1i π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U w c dc, C i i = L, U. But rather than setting an arbitrary value for α L, we will investigate to choose it optimally with other parameters. Some possible choices of weight function wc are as follows. { 1 if c Cj, i. Uniform weights: wc = 0 if c / C j. his choice of weight function results in simple average of power, so the optimal value of c 1 for the local alternatives is chosen as a value that maximizes simple average of powers. For one-sided tests c 1i = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1 dc, j = l, u c 1 C j and for two-sided tests {c 1L, c 1U, α L} = arg max {c 1L,c 1U,α L } C π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L dc ii. wc = I c 1/2 Jeffreys Prior ii.a. Jeff reys prior based on full likelihood Phillips 1991 suggests using Jeffreys prior instead of flat priors in response to the criticism by Sims and Uhlig 1991 on frequentists approach to unit roots. Phillips considers fixed ρ in the autoregressive model with and without deterministic trend and both conditional and unconditional cases. However for our purpose we assume the conditional case u 0 = 0, known σ 2 and with no deterministics to translate his results using ρ = 1 + c/ to take asymptotic approximations. he corresponding Fisher s information matrix see appendix for the derivation is given by { 1 e 2c 1 2c 2c 1 if c 0, I c = 1 2 if c = 0. he prior is plotted in figure 5.1 below. From this diagram we observe that the prior increases slowly to the value 1/ 2 at c = 0 as the information content increases with, but 16

17 wc 3 JP IJP c Figure 5.1: Jeffreys prior and Invariant Jeffreys prior then it starts growing exponentially for all c > 0. his higher density for c > 0 is due to our prior knowledge about the parameter that when true value of c 0 > 0 in ρ = 1 + c/, the data will carry more information about c 0. ii.b. Jeff reys prior based on invariant likelihood Since in this analysis we are applying point optimal test of King 1987 that is invariant to transformations of the form y y + Xb, where y = y 1,..., y and X = x 1,..., x, following King 1980 and King and Hillier 1985, we can derive Jeffreys prior based on invariant likelihood. Although King and Hillier discuss both invariance to the regressors and to scaling but we follow ERS and use invariance only to the regressors and not to scaling which is handled by dividing the point optimal statistic by an estimate of the variance. By assuming Gaussian errors the information matrix using invariant maximum likelihood when x t = 1 is the same as the one we have obtained from full maximum likelihood. However for x t = 1 t, this information matrix is given by I c = 1 2c e 2c 1 2c 1 1 c 2 3c 2e 2c + ce 2c + 2c c 3 1 c + c c + c c 6 1 c + c2 3 2, c 0 Note that I c 0 as c 0 and is evident from the plot of this prior given in figure 5.1. his observation is also pointed out by Marsh

18 Since Jeffreys prior is the square root of the information matrix, so we can use the weight function wc = I c 1/2 and the optimal choice of c 1 is given by c 1i = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1 I c 1/2 dc, j = l, u c 1i C j {c 1L, c 1U, α L} = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L I c 1/2 dc. {c 1L,c 1U,α L } C iii. wc based on the Symmetrized Asymptotic Reference Prior SARP Berger and Yang 1994 provide the symmetrized asymptotic reference prior that maximizes the Kullback-Leibler divergence between prior and posterior that results in the following prior. For large, this is approximately π ρ exp π ρ E ρ log π ρ y 1 2 E ρ log but has different orders of for different ρ. Berger and Yang 1994 suggest using the normalized π ρ for ρ < 1, then use transformation ρ 1/ρ for ρ > 1.his leads to the following asymptotic symmetric reference prior. y 2 t 1 { 1/ 2π 1 ρ 2, ρ < 1 π SR = 1/ 2π ρ ρ 2 1, ρ > 1 Berger and Yang discuss some of the important features of this prior as; 1. it a proper prior since it integrates to one, 2. it assigns equal probability of one-half to ρ < 1 and ρ > 1, 3. contrary to Jeffreys prior as a weight function that assigns finite weight to the stationary case where ρ < 1 but unreasonable infinite weight to the explosive case ρ > 1, this prior assigns more weight to the values that are close to c = 0 but as c moves away from zero the weights start shrinking; in particular, for c > 0 the weights converge to zero, 4. usually we can not use improper priors for testing but above mentioned properties of SR prior make it suitable for use in testing. his asymptotic reference prior makes sense under local to unity setting ρ = 1 + c/ with and becomes 1 π R c exp 2 E c log B c s 2 ds

19 where B c s is the Ornstein-Uhlen process. his prior is similar to Jeffreys prior but is flexible to imposing symmetry about c = 0. For computational purpose we approximate E c log 1 0 B c s 2 ds by simulation, as E c log 1 0 B c s 2 ds 1 R R 1 log n 2 r=1 n z 2 c,r,t where z c,r,t is generated from z c,r,t = 1 + c z c,r,t 1 + η r,t, with z c,r,0 = 0 and { } n η r,t being pseudo-random drawings from the i.i.d. standard normal distribution. he sample size n and number of repeated samples R are chosen to be large in the usual way to reduce simulation error. he resultant reference prior is 1 1 R 1 n π R c = exp log 2 R n 2 zc,r,t 2. r=1 Following diagram presents asymmetric and symmetric versions of the reference prior along with Jeffreys. Figure 5.2: Asymmetric and Symmetric Reference Prior Now we assume the weight function wc = π R c and obtain optimal values of c 1 for both one and two-sided tests as c 1i = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1 π R c dc, i = l, u c 1 C i {c 1L, c 1U, α L} = arg max π α c; c 0, c 1L, c 1U, α L π R c dc. {c 1L,c 1U,α L } C 19

20 6 Results 6.1 One-sided tests Constant mean case In able 6.1 below, we have reported optimal values of c 1L and c 1U obtained after using different criteria discussed above for individual one-sided point optimal test when x t = 1. Power curves corresponding to these optimal values for c 0 = 0, 4 are presented in figure 6.1. We observe that these power curves for lower tailed alternatives given in panel 1 and 2 are indistinguishable from the power envelope. Similarly for upper tailed alternatives we find that some of optimal c 1L values produce power curves slightly below the envelope near the null only. But these differences are negligible, except for invariant Jeffreys prior case when c 0 = 0, and hence we can happily use any of these values for confidence interval construction. However looking at figure 6.2 for c 0 = 4 we observe that some of the power curves given in the first panel for lower tailed test indicate the inconsistency of the test for some c 1L values. In particular, we find c 1L values obtained by using ERS, minimax, π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1 = 0.85 rules and, the Jeffreys prior as weight function are all greater then the threshold value of c 1 = for constant case. As a consequence of using these values we get inconsistent tests with powers converging to zero instead of one as c moves away from the null. Further we also find that none of these criteria produce power uniformly close to the power envelope. Specifically power curves based on ES behave poorly for alternatives not far from the null compared to other three choices. able 6.1: Optimal values of model parameters for one- sided tests: Constant only H 0 : c 0 = 4 c 0 = 0 c 0 = 4 Criterion c 1L c 1U c 1L c 1U c 1L c 1U ERS/ π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1 = π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1 = Elliot and Stock Mini-Max Simple Average Jeffreys Prior Invariant JP Symmetric Reference Prior Power curves for upper tail test of c 0 = 4 using the same criteria are presented in second panel of figure 6.2 where inconsistency is not an issue. he best choice of c 1U depends on the position of the power curve relative to the power envelope, that is, the value of c 1U that produces power curve closer to the power envelope is preferred. But we observe none of the curve is uniformly close to 20

21 Figure 6.1: Lower-sided power curves with different criteria x t = 1 21

22 Figure 6.2: Lower-sided power curves with different criteria x t = 1 22

23 the power envelope and hence we can not select such value. However we find that value of c 1U proposed by ES has very low power for all the alternatives that are close to the null 4 < c < 4.85 but as c moves away from the null there is a sharp rise in the power and the curve gets close to the power bound. All other criteria provide c 1U values with power curves that are fairly close to the envelope so we can use any of these values Constant and linear trend case able 6.2 reports the optimal values of parameters c 1L and c 1U for constant and linear trend case and corresponding power curves are presented in figures 6.3 and 6.4 below. Like demeaned case above, we find that when testing c 0 = 4 and c 0 = 0, c 1L and c 1U for lower and upper sided tests respectively produce power curves close to the power envelope and hence make these c 1 values from certain criteria feasible. able 6.2: Optimal values of model parameters for one- sided tests: Drift and Linear rend H 0 : c 0 = 4 c 0 = 0 c 0 = 4 Criterion c 1L c 1U c 1L c 1U c 1L c 1U ERS/π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1 = π α c 1 ; c 0, c 1 = Elliot and Stock Mini-Max Simple Average Jeffreys Prior Invariant Jeffreys Prior Symmetric Reference Prior From figure 6.4 for c 0 = 4 case we observe that only ERS rule does not provide monotonic power curve and hence causes an inconsistent test for lower sided alternatives. Simulation evidence shows that all c 1L > will produce negative critical values and hence will make the test inconsistent. We also observe that the value of c 1L based on ES rule produces a test that has lower power for alternatives near the null. We also examine that c 1L based on minimax criterion produces the power curve that is not close to the envelope for values far from the null and also making it an inferior choice compared to other c 1L values. Similarly for upper tailed testing we observe that c 1U based on ES rule works poorly since the corresponding power curve has a flatter portion for 4 < c < 6.5 with very low power, then a big jump in power towards power envelope near c = 6.5. Also power curve based on c 1U from reference prior produces slightly low power for alternatives close to the null but then has power very close to the envelope therefore we should not rule out this value from the list of optimal values of model parameters. 23

24 Figure 6.3: One-sided power curves with different criteria constant and linear trend 24

25 Figure 6.4: One-sided power curves with different criteria constant and linear trend 25

26 6.2 wo Sided est Following the discussion in section 3 about two-sided testing and using only the criterion of optimal weighted average power we have computed optimal values of parameters α L, α U, c 1L and c 1U for both demeaned and detrended cases for confidence interval construction. he results are reported in table 6.4 and the corresponding power curves for different c 0 in 6.2 below. able 6.3 reports values based on the Elliot and Stock s rule discussed above with fixed α L = 0.03 and α U = able 6.3: Model Parameters based on ES Rule Demeaned Case Detrended Case c 0 c 1,L c 1,U c 1,L c 1,U From the following table we have quite different optimal values of model parameters from those proposed by ES. We find varying values of α L, α U across different choices of c 0 instead of fixed values proposed by ES. We observe that for positive c 0, all the different choices of weight functions assign higher probability of type-i error to the left tail i.e. higher α L that is even higher than the ES value of α L = 0.03 for a test of overall size α = able 6.4: Optimal values of model parameters for two sided tests Weight Function Demeaned Case Detrended Case H 0 : c 0 = 4 c 1L c 1U α L c 1L c 1U α L Simple Average Jeffreys Prior Symmetric Reference Prior Invariant Jeffreys Prior Same as Jeffreys prior H 0 : c 0 = 0 Simple Average Jeffreys Prior Symmetric Reference Prior Invariant Jeffreys Prior Same as Jeffreys prior H 0 : c 0 = 4 Simple Average Jeffreys Prior Symmetric Reference Prior Invariant Jeffreys Prior Same as Jeffreys prior

27 In diagram 6.5 below, left and right panels correspond respectively to the power curves for demeaned case and the detrended case. We find well behaved power curves using the optimal values of c 1L, c 1U, α L, α U obtained from multiple choices of weights. On comparison we observe varying slope of the curves particularly at right tails for different c 0. We also find that our proposed values produce power curves that outperform the power curves based on ES in almost all cases especially at the lower tails. We observe significant power gains using our proposed values over those of ES particularly when we test some positive value of c 0. hese vital differences support our hypothesis of varying slope of the power curves for different c 0 values and hence different values for the model parameters. Figure 6.5:Power Curves for two-tailed test with different criteria On comparison we observe that power curves corresponding to the parameter values from the weighted powers using the uniform and symmetric reference prior weights are superior to those from Jeffreys prior weights at the left tails for each c 0. While the test achieves higher power in detrended case with Jeffreys invariant prior weights compared to Jeffreys prior weights when c 0 is either 4 or 0. By looking at the right tails of the curves we find that for all alternative c values the test has almost identical powers using optimal values. he most interesting case is that of testing c 0 = 4 where we find ES as a poor choice since it has low power close to the null. Also 27

28 both types of Jeffreys prior weights have identical power at right tail but have slight differences in powers at left tail. However for detrended case, when we compare the powers at left tails we find significantly lower powers from Jeffreys prior weights compared to powers from uniform and symmetric reference prior weights. Given this simulation analysis we observe that there does not exist any unique set of parameters with uniformly better power across the grid of c values. Despite this outcome we find that our proposed set of values produce powers that are relatively higher than powers proposed by ES. In particular we observe that the point optimal test has good power properties when computed from the parameters generated from uniform and symmetric reference prior weight functions for all c 0 and for both demeaned and detrended cases. 7 Conclusions In this paper, we have analyzed and extended Elliot and Stock s method to construct confidence intervals, by inverting a sequence of invariant point optimal tests, for the autoregressive root local to one. Our analysis of one-sided testing problems shows that in the presence of deterministics the choices of model parameters based on ERS and ES work fairly well when testing zero or negative values of parameter c 0. However for some positive c 0, the test based on the ERS rule becomes inconsistent for lower sided stationary alternatives. Also the test based on the ES rule has low power for alternative values close to the null. For upper tail test, this behavior remains the same whether the deterministic component involves constant mean or constant and linear trend. We provide the reason of the inconsistency of the test for lower sided alternatives for some choices of parameter c 1L. Similarly for two-sided test, instead of using fixed values of α L = 0.03 and α U = 0.02 and c 1L, c 1U that are fixed distance from the null, we search for optimal values of these parameters that are jointly determined by the maximization of weighted powers using different weight functions. Our results indicate that optimal values of these parameters are very sensitive to changes in c 0. In particular we find that all types of weight functions considered here, except Jeffreys prior, provide optimal α L > 0.03 for different c 0. However, weights based on symmetric reference prior result in the largest α L close to the nominal level of We acknowledge that none of these weight functions produce uniformly higher power so that we prefer one weight function over the other. But simulation results prove that our proposed values of the parameters particularly from uniform and symmetric reference prior weights result in more powerful test compared to those provided by ES. Based on these findings we can say that out proposed values may yield more accurate confidence intervals. Possible extensions to this work include; the derivation of an invariant symmetric reference prior following the same approach we used for the invariant Jeffreys prior, allowing for serially correlated errors in the usual way, and consideration of the effect of the initial condition on these 28

29 tests. 8 References Berger, J. O., and R. Y. Yang 1994 "Noninformative Priors and the Bayesian esting for the AR1 Model," Econometric heory 10, Bobkovski, M.J "Hypothesis esting in Nonstationary ime Series," Unpublished Ph.D. hesis, Department of Statistics, University of Wisconsin. Cavanagh, C "Roots Local to Unity," Unpublished Manuscript, Department of Economics, Harvard University. Chan, N. H., and C. Z. Wei 1987 "Asymptotic Inference for Nearly Nonstationary AR1 Processes," Annals of Statistics 15, Cox, D. R., and D. V. Hinkley 1974 heoretical Statistics. Chapman & Hall, London. Elliot, G.,. J. Rothenberg, and J. H. Stock 1996 "Effi cient ests for an Autoregressive Unit Root," Econometrica 64, Elliot, G., and J.H. Stock 2001 "Confidence Intervals for Autoregressive Coeffi cients Near One," Journal of Econometrics 103, Lai,. L., and C. Z. Wei 1983 "Asymptotic Properties of General Autoregressive Models and Strong Consistency of Least-Squares Estimates of their Parameters," Journal of Multivariate Analysis 13, King, M. L "Robust ests for Spherical Symmetry and their Applications to least Squares Regression," he Annals of Statistics 8, King, M. L., and G. H. Hillier 1985 "Best Invariant ests of the Error Covariance Matrix of the Linear Regression Model," Journal of Royal Statistical Society. Series B 47, King, M. L "owards a heory of Point Optimal esting," Econometric Reviews 6, Marsh, P "he Available Information for Invariant ests of a Unit Root," Econometric heory 23, Ng, S., and P. Perron 2001 "Lag Length Selection and Construction of Unit Root ests with Good Size and Power," Econometrica 69, Phillips, P. C. B "owards a Unified Asymptotic heory for Autoregression," Biometrika 48, Phillips, P. C. B "o Criticize the Critics: An Objective Bayesian Analysis of Stochastic rends," Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol. 6, Patterson, K Unit Root tests in ime Series Volume 1. Palgrave Macmillan, UK. Sims, C. A., and Uhlig, H "Understanding Unit Rooters: A Helicopter our," Econometrica 59,

30 Stock, J.H "Confidence Intervals for the Largest Autoregressive Root in U.S. Macroeconomic ime Series," Journal of Monetary Economics 28, Appendix A 1 Derivation of Jeffreys Prior We derive here the expression for Jeffreys prior in the autoregressive model under local to unity setting, whereas this prior is the positive square root of Fisher s information matrix. he loglikelihood function based on ε t being i.i.d. in equation 2.2 is given by log Lc σ 2 = 2 log2π 2 log σ2 1 2σ 2 u t 1 + c 2 u t 1, the score function with respect to c is given by log Lc σ 2 c and the derivative of the score function is = 1 σ 2 u t u t c u 2 t 1, 2 log Lc σ 2 c 2 = 2 σ 2 u2 t 1 = 2 σ 2 1 t=0 u2 t. By recursively iterating u t = 1 + c/ u t 1 + ε t, we obtain hus we have u t = t 1 j=0 1 + c j εt j Eu 2 t = σ 2 t 1 j=0 E 1 t=0 u2 t = σ c c 1 + c 2j geometric series 2t 2 2t = σ c 1 c2 2c +. = σ 2 1 t= c c2 2c + 1 = σ c2 2c + 2t 1 1 t=0 1 + c 2t he information matrix is then obtained as 30

31 2 log Lc σ 2 I = E c 2 = 2 σ 2 E 1 t=0 u2 t = 2 1 σ 2 σ2 1 c2 2c + = 1 2c + c2 = 1 2c + c2 = 1 2c + c2 2 c 0 1 4c 2 e 2c 1 2c = 1 2c 1 1 t= c c c 2 1 2c + c2 1 2c + c2 + 1 e 2c 1 2c c 2t 1 + c 2c c If c 0, then by L Hopital s rule we get I =1/2. hus in the limit we have { 1 e 2c 1 2c 2c 1 if c 0, I c = 1 2 if c = 0. 2 Point Optimal and Modified Point Optimal ests and heir Asymptotic Distributions 2.1 Point optimal test in the absence of determinsitcs First of all we derive the point optimal test without deterministics as this will help explaining why the test statistic becomes inconsistent for some choices of c 0 and secondly we can also use this expression to derive modified point optimal test. he point optimal test is given by P ρ 0, ρ 1 = ˆσ 2 ˆε 2 1,t ρ 1 ρ 0 ˆε j,t = û j,t ρ j û j,t 1, û j,t = y t x tˆγ j ˆε 2 0,t, Suppose we have no deterministics i.e. x tγ = 0, so that the original model given in 2.1 and 2.2 becomes y t = u t, and û j,t = y t u t = ρu t 1 + ε t, u 1 = ε 1. 31

32 and he point optimal test of H 0 : ρ = ρ 0 against H 1 : ρ = ρ 1 is then P ρ 0, ρ 1 = ˆσ 2 = ˆσ 2 Consider the term in the parenthesis = y t ρ 1 y t 1 2 ρ 1 ρ 0 1 ρ 1 ρ 0 = 1 ρ 0 ρ 0 ρ 1 y 2 + ε 2 1,t ρ 1 ρ 0 ε 2 0,t y t ρ 1 y t 1 2 ρ 1 ρ 0 y t ρ 0 y t 1 2 = y 2 t 1 y ρ 0 ρ 1 + ρ 2 1 ρ 1 ρ 0 y 2 t 1. y t ρ 0 y t ρ 1 ρ 0 y 2 t 1 his statistic is applied with ρ 0 = 1 + c 0 / and ρ 1 = 1 + c 1 /, so 1 ρ 0 ρ 1 = c 0 ρ 0 ρ 1 = c 0 c c 1 so for large which is what concerns us for choice of c 1 P c 0, c 1 c0 c 1 = c 0 c 1 P c 0, c 1 = c 2 1 c y 2 c 0 + c 1 = c 0 + c 1 y 2 t 1 1 y 2 c 0 + c 1 2 y 2 t + ρ 2 1 ρ 1 ρ 0 c 0c 1 2, yt 1 2 y 2 t 1 yt c 0 c 1 1 y and we reject for small values. it s worth not omitting the c 0 c 1 at the front of second last term above so as not to mess with the sign of the statistic, and hence the rejection tail. 2.2 Asymptotic distributions in the presence of deterministics but no autocorrelation in error term ε t Now we incorporate the deterministic component and assuming no serial correlation in error term ε t derive the asymptotic distribution of the test statistic under the local to unity framework. he model is given by 32

Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea. Abstract

Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea. Abstract On the finite sample power of modified Dickey Fuller tests: The role of the initial condition Steven Cook University of Wales Swansea Abstract The relationship between the initial condition of time series

More information

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis.

A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis. A Test of Cointegration Rank Based Title Component Analysis Author(s) Chigira, Hiroaki Citation Issue 2006-01 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13683 Right

More information

E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity

E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity E 4101/5101 Lecture 9: Non-stationarity Ragnar Nymoen 30 March 2011 Introduction I Main references: Hamilton Ch 15,16 and 17. Davidson and MacKinnon Ch 14.3 and 14.4 Also read Ch 2.4 and Ch 2.5 in Davidson

More information

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments

1 Procedures robust to weak instruments Comment on Weak instrument robust tests in GMM and the new Keynesian Phillips curve By Anna Mikusheva We are witnessing a growing awareness among applied researchers about the possibility of having weak

More information

Simulating Properties of the Likelihood Ratio Test for a Unit Root in an Explosive Second Order Autoregression

Simulating Properties of the Likelihood Ratio Test for a Unit Root in an Explosive Second Order Autoregression Simulating Properties of the Likelihood Ratio est for a Unit Root in an Explosive Second Order Autoregression Bent Nielsen Nuffield College, University of Oxford J James Reade St Cross College, University

More information

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller

Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated Time Series by Ulrich K. Müller Comment on HAC Corrections for Strongly Autocorrelated ime Series by Ulrich K. Müller Yixiao Sun Department of Economics, UC San Diego May 2, 24 On the Nearly-optimal est Müller applies the theory of optimal

More information

E 4160 Autumn term Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test

E 4160 Autumn term Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test E 4160 Autumn term 2016. Lecture 9: Deterministic trends vs integrated series; Spurious regression; Dickey-Fuller distribution and test Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo 24 October

More information

The Impact of the Initial Condition on Covariate Augmented Unit Root Tests

The Impact of the Initial Condition on Covariate Augmented Unit Root Tests The Impact of the Initial Condition on Covariate Augmented Unit Root Tests Chrystalleni Aristidou, David I. Harvey and Stephen J. Leybourne School of Economics, University of Nottingham January 2016 Abstract

More information

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1 John C. Chao April 25, 2017 1 These notes are based in large part on Chapter 16 of Stock and Watson (2011). They are for instructional purposes

More information

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED by W. Robert Reed Department of Economics and Finance University of Canterbury, New Zealand Email: bob.reed@canterbury.ac.nz

More information

Nonstationary Time Series:

Nonstationary Time Series: Nonstationary Time Series: Unit Roots Egon Zakrajšek Division of Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board Summer School in Financial Mathematics Faculty of Mathematics & Physics University of Ljubljana September

More information

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis Muhammad Irfan Malik and Atiq-ur- Rehman International Institute of Islamic Economics, International

More information

The Number of Bootstrap Replicates in Bootstrap Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests

The Number of Bootstrap Replicates in Bootstrap Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests Working Paper 2013:8 Department of Statistics The Number of Bootstrap Replicates in Bootstrap Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests Jianxin Wei Working Paper 2013:8 June 2013 Department of Statistics Uppsala

More information

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis Introduction to Time Series Analysis 1 Contents: I. Basics of Time Series Analysis... 4 I.1 Stationarity... 5 I.2 Autocorrelation Function... 9 I.3 Partial Autocorrelation Function (PACF)... 14 I.4 Transformation

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY & Contents PREFACE xiii 1 1.1. 1.2. Difference Equations First-Order Difference Equations 1 /?th-order Difference

More information

Econometrics. Week 4. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

Econometrics. Week 4. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Econometrics Week 4 Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague Fall 2012 1 / 23 Recommended Reading For the today Serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in

More information

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors

Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Comparing Nested Predictive Regression Models with Persistent Predictors Yan Ge y and ae-hwy Lee z November 29, 24 Abstract his paper is an extension of Clark and McCracken (CM 2, 25, 29) and Clark and

More information

On Perron s Unit Root Tests in the Presence. of an Innovation Variance Break

On Perron s Unit Root Tests in the Presence. of an Innovation Variance Break Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 3, 2009, no. 27, 1341-1360 On Perron s Unit Root ests in the Presence of an Innovation Variance Break Amit Sen Department of Economics, 3800 Victory Parkway Xavier University,

More information

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests 1 Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests Walter Enders and Yu Liu * University of Alabama in Tuscaloosa and University of Texas at El Paso Abstract: We propose a simple modification

More information

Taking a New Contour: A Novel View on Unit Root Test 1

Taking a New Contour: A Novel View on Unit Root Test 1 Taking a New Contour: A Novel View on Unit Root Test 1 Yoosoon Chang Department of Economics Rice University and Joon Y. Park Department of Economics Rice University and Sungkyunkwan University Abstract

More information

GLS-based unit root tests with multiple structural breaks both under the null and the alternative hypotheses

GLS-based unit root tests with multiple structural breaks both under the null and the alternative hypotheses GLS-based unit root tests with multiple structural breaks both under the null and the alternative hypotheses Josep Lluís Carrion-i-Silvestre University of Barcelona Dukpa Kim Boston University Pierre Perron

More information

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models

Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models Econ. 513, Time Series Econometrics Fall 00 Chris Sims Testing Restrictions and Comparing Models 1. THE PROBLEM We consider here the problem of comparing two parametric models for the data X, defined by

More information

Efficiency Tradeoffs in Estimating the Linear Trend Plus Noise Model. Abstract

Efficiency Tradeoffs in Estimating the Linear Trend Plus Noise Model. Abstract Efficiency radeoffs in Estimating the Linear rend Plus Noise Model Barry Falk Department of Economics, Iowa State University Anindya Roy University of Maryland Baltimore County Abstract his paper presents

More information

The Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji

The Role of Leads in the Dynamic Title of Cointegrating Regression Models. Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji he Role of "Leads" in the Dynamic itle of Cointegrating Regression Models Author(s) Hayakawa, Kazuhiko; Kurozumi, Eiji Citation Issue 2006-12 Date ype echnical Report ext Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/13599

More information

Department of Economics, UCSD UC San Diego

Department of Economics, UCSD UC San Diego Department of Economics, UCSD UC San Diego itle: Spurious Regressions with Stationary Series Author: Granger, Clive W.J., University of California, San Diego Hyung, Namwon, University of Seoul Jeon, Yongil,

More information

Trend and initial condition in stationarity tests: the asymptotic analysis

Trend and initial condition in stationarity tests: the asymptotic analysis Trend and initial condition in stationarity tests: the asymptotic analysis Anton Skrobotov Gaidar Institute for Economic Policy, The Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration

More information

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY

Time Series Analysis. James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY Time Series Analysis James D. Hamilton PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY PREFACE xiii 1 Difference Equations 1.1. First-Order Difference Equations 1 1.2. pth-order Difference Equations 7

More information

BCT Lecture 3. Lukas Vacha.

BCT Lecture 3. Lukas Vacha. BCT Lecture 3 Lukas Vacha vachal@utia.cas.cz Stationarity and Unit Root Testing Why do we need to test for Non-Stationarity? The stationarity or otherwise of a series can strongly influence its behaviour

More information

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span

Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Understanding Regressions with Observations Collected at High Frequency over Long Span Yoosoon Chang Department of Economics, Indiana University Joon Y. Park Department of Economics, Indiana University

More information

11/18/2008. So run regression in first differences to examine association. 18 November November November 2008

11/18/2008. So run regression in first differences to examine association. 18 November November November 2008 Time Series Econometrics 7 Vijayamohanan Pillai N Unit Root Tests Vijayamohan: CDS M Phil: Time Series 7 1 Vijayamohan: CDS M Phil: Time Series 7 2 R 2 > DW Spurious/Nonsense Regression. Integrated but

More information

GLS detrending and unit root testing

GLS detrending and unit root testing Economics Letters 97 (2007) 222 229 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase GLS detrending and unit root testing Dimitrios V. Vougas School of Business and Economics, Department of Economics, Richard Price Building,

More information

Extended Tests for Threshold Unit Roots and Asymmetries in Lending and Deposit Rates

Extended Tests for Threshold Unit Roots and Asymmetries in Lending and Deposit Rates Extended Tests for Threshold Unit Roots and Asymmetries in Lending and Deposit Rates Walter Enders Junsoo Lee Mark C. Strazicich Byung Chul Yu* February 5, 2009 Abstract Enders and Granger (1998) develop

More information

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Econometrics II Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Morten Nyboe Tabor Course Outline: Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing 1 Stationarity and Deviation from Stationarity Trend-Stationarity

More information

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series Analysis: Conditional and Unconditional Densities, Stationarity, ARMA Processes Prof. Massimo Guidolin 20192 Financial Econometrics Spring/Winter 2017 Overview Motivation:

More information

LM threshold unit root tests

LM threshold unit root tests Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C., & Chul Yu, B. (2011). LM Threshold Unit Root Tests. Economics Letters, 110(2): 113-116 (Feb 2011). Published by Elsevier (ISSN: 0165-1765). http://0- dx.doi.org.wncln.wncln.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2010.10.014

More information

On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach

On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach On detection of unit roots generalizing the classic Dickey-Fuller approach A. Steland Ruhr-Universität Bochum Fakultät für Mathematik Building NA 3/71 D-4478 Bochum, Germany February 18, 25 1 Abstract

More information

Maximum Non-extensive Entropy Block Bootstrap

Maximum Non-extensive Entropy Block Bootstrap Overview&Motivation MEB Simulation of the MnEBB Conclusions References Maximum Non-extensive Entropy Block Bootstrap Jan Novotny CEA, Cass Business School & CERGE-EI (with Michele Bergamelli & Giovanni

More information

Long-Run Covariability

Long-Run Covariability Long-Run Covariability Ulrich K. Müller and Mark W. Watson Princeton University October 2016 Motivation Study the long-run covariability/relationship between economic variables great ratios, long-run Phillips

More information

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics The Effect of Linear Time Trends on Cointegration Testing in Single Equations Uwe Hassler Nr. 111 Arbeitspapiere des Instituts für Volkswirtschaftslehre Technische

More information

On Consistency of Tests for Stationarity in Autoregressive and Moving Average Models of Different Orders

On Consistency of Tests for Stationarity in Autoregressive and Moving Average Models of Different Orders American Journal of Theoretical and Applied Statistics 2016; 5(3): 146-153 http://www.sciencepublishinggroup.com/j/ajtas doi: 10.11648/j.ajtas.20160503.20 ISSN: 2326-8999 (Print); ISSN: 2326-9006 (Online)

More information

The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series

The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series The Restricted Likelihood Ratio Test at the Boundary in Autoregressive Series Willa W. Chen Rohit S. Deo July 6, 009 Abstract. The restricted likelihood ratio test, RLRT, for the autoregressive coefficient

More information

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods Robert V. Breunig Centre for Economic Policy Research, Research School of Social Sciences and School of

More information

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962

DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WITH NEAR UNITY. Peter C. B. Phillips. December 2014 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1962 DYNAMIC PANEL GMM WIH NEAR UNIY By Peter C. B. Phillips December 04 COWLES FOUNDAION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 96 COWLES FOUNDAION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSIY Box 088 New Haven, Connecticut 0650-88

More information

Econometrics of Panel Data

Econometrics of Panel Data Econometrics of Panel Data Jakub Mućk Meeting # 6 Jakub Mućk Econometrics of Panel Data Meeting # 6 1 / 36 Outline 1 The First-Difference (FD) estimator 2 Dynamic panel data models 3 The Anderson and Hsiao

More information

Econometrics Summary Algebraic and Statistical Preliminaries

Econometrics Summary Algebraic and Statistical Preliminaries Econometrics Summary Algebraic and Statistical Preliminaries Elasticity: The point elasticity of Y with respect to L is given by α = ( Y/ L)/(Y/L). The arc elasticity is given by ( Y/ L)/(Y/L), when L

More information

Tests of the Co-integration Rank in VAR Models in the Presence of a Possible Break in Trend at an Unknown Point

Tests of the Co-integration Rank in VAR Models in the Presence of a Possible Break in Trend at an Unknown Point Tests of the Co-integration Rank in VAR Models in the Presence of a Possible Break in Trend at an Unknown Point David Harris, Steve Leybourne, Robert Taylor Monash U., U. of Nottingam, U. of Essex Economics

More information

Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series

Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series 1 Introduction Econ 623 Econometrics II Topic 2: Stationary Time Series In the regression model we can model the error term as an autoregression AR(1) process. That is, we can use the past value of the

More information

Testing for unit roots with stationary covariates

Testing for unit roots with stationary covariates Journal of Econometrics 115 (2003) 75 89 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Testing for unit roots with stationary covariates Graham Elliott a;, Michael Jansson b a Department of Economics, University of

More information

Bayesian Analysis of AR (1) model

Bayesian Analysis of AR (1) model Abstract: Bayesian Analysis of AR (1) model Hossein Masoumi Karakani, University of Pretoria, South Africa Janet van Niekerk, University of Pretoria, South Africa Paul van Staden, University of Pretoria,

More information

ECONOMETRICS II, FALL Testing for Unit Roots.

ECONOMETRICS II, FALL Testing for Unit Roots. ECONOMETRICS II, FALL 216 Testing for Unit Roots. In the statistical literature it has long been known that unit root processes behave differently from stable processes. For example in the scalar AR(1)

More information

Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test

Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test Christopher F Baum Jesús Otero Stata Conference, Baltimore, July 2017 Baum, Otero (BC, U. del Rosario) DF-GLS response surfaces

More information

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science

Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science Introduction to Econometrics FIFTH EDITION Christopher Dougherty London School of Economics and Political Science OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents INTRODU CTION 1 Why study econometrics? 1 Aim of this

More information

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Econometrics II Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Morten Nyboe Tabor Course Outline: Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing 1 Stationarity and Deviation from Stationarity Trend-Stationarity

More information

Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test

Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test Response surface models for the Elliott, Rothenberg, Stock DF-GLS unit-root test Christopher F Baum Jesús Otero UK Stata Users Group Meetings, London, September 2017 Baum, Otero (BC, U. del Rosario) DF-GLS

More information

On the Long-Run Variance Ratio Test for a Unit Root

On the Long-Run Variance Ratio Test for a Unit Root On the Long-Run Variance Ratio Test for a Unit Root Ye Cai and Mototsugu Shintani Vanderbilt University May 2004 Abstract This paper investigates the effects of consistent and inconsistent long-run variance

More information

Unit Root Tests: The Role of the Univariate Models Implied by Multivariate Time Series

Unit Root Tests: The Role of the Univariate Models Implied by Multivariate Time Series econometrics Article Unit Root Tests: The Role of the Univariate Models Implied by Multivariate Time Series Nunzio Cappuccio 1 and Diego Lubian 2, * 1 Department of Economics and Management Marco Fanno,

More information

On Bootstrap Implementation of Likelihood Ratio Test for a Unit Root

On Bootstrap Implementation of Likelihood Ratio Test for a Unit Root On Bootstrap Implementation of Likelihood Ratio Test for a Unit Root ANTON SKROBOTOV The Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration February 25, 2018 Abstract In this paper

More information

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing

Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Econometrics II Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing Morten Nyboe Tabor Course Outline: Non-Stationary Time Series and Unit Root Testing 1 Stationarity and Deviation from Stationarity Trend-Stationarity

More information

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA)

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA) Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA) Lecture 3: Statistical Building Blocks and Econometric Basics Prof. Dr. Michael Stein michael.stein@vwl.uni-freiburg.de Albert-Ludwigs-University of Freiburg

More information

Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, / 91. Bruce E.

Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, / 91. Bruce E. Forecasting Lecture 3 Structural Breaks Central Bank of Chile October 29-31, 2013 Bruce Hansen (University of Wisconsin) Structural Breaks October 29-31, 2013 1 / 91 Bruce E. Hansen Organization Detection

More information

New Methods for Inference in Long-Horizon Regressions

New Methods for Inference in Long-Horizon Regressions JOURNAL OF FINANCIAL AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS Vol. 46, No. 3, June 2011, pp. 815 839 COPYRIGHT 2011, MICHAEL G. FOSTER SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON, SEATTLE, WA 98195 doi:10.1017/s0022109011000135

More information

Vector Autoregressive Model. Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions I.

Vector Autoregressive Model. Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions I. Vector Autoregressive Model Vector Autoregressions II Empirical Macroeconomics - Lect 2 Dr. Ana Beatriz Galvao Queen Mary University of London January 2012 A VAR(p) model of the m 1 vector of time series

More information

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions

The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions The Generalized Cochrane-Orcutt Transformation Estimation For Spurious and Fractional Spurious Regressions Shin-Huei Wang and Cheng Hsiao Jan 31, 2010 Abstract This paper proposes a highly consistent estimation,

More information

Introduction to Econometrics

Introduction to Econometrics Introduction to Econometrics T H I R D E D I T I O N Global Edition James H. Stock Harvard University Mark W. Watson Princeton University Boston Columbus Indianapolis New York San Francisco Upper Saddle

More information

Testing for Unit Roots in the Presence of a Possible Break in Trend and Non-Stationary Volatility

Testing for Unit Roots in the Presence of a Possible Break in Trend and Non-Stationary Volatility esting for Unit Roots in the Presence of a Possible Break in rend and Non-Stationary Volatility Giuseppe Cavaliere a, David I. Harvey b, Stephen J. Leybourne b and A.M. Robert aylor b a Department of Statistical

More information

Moreover, the second term is derived from: 1 T ) 2 1

Moreover, the second term is derived from: 1 T ) 2 1 170 Moreover, the second term is derived from: 1 T T ɛt 2 σ 2 ɛ. Therefore, 1 σ 2 ɛt T y t 1 ɛ t = 1 2 ( yt σ T ) 2 1 2σ 2 ɛ 1 T T ɛt 2 1 2 (χ2 (1) 1). (b) Next, consider y 2 t 1. T E y 2 t 1 T T = E(y

More information

Financial Time Series Analysis: Part II

Financial Time Series Analysis: Part II Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, Finland Spring 2017 1 Unit root Deterministic trend Stochastic trend Testing for unit root ADF-test (Augmented Dickey-Fuller test) Testing

More information

A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER. Donald Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger

A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER. Donald Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger A CONDITIONAL-HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR THE AUTOREGRESSIVE PARAMETER BY Donald Andrews and Patrik Guggenberger COWLES FOUNDATION PAPER NO. 1453 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN

More information

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 08-17

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 08-17 Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 08-17 Modified Fast Double Sieve Bootstraps for ADF Tests Patrick Richard Modified Fast Double Sieve Bootstraps

More information

Unit root testing based on BLUS residuals

Unit root testing based on BLUS residuals Unit root testing based on BLUS residuals Dimitrios V. Vougas To cite this version: Dimitrios V. Vougas. Unit root testing based on BLUS residuals. Statistics and Probability Letters, Elsevier, 2009, 78

More information

A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration. July 31, Preliminary and Incomplete

A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration. July 31, Preliminary and Incomplete A PANIC Attack on Unit Roots and Cointegration Jushan Bai Serena Ng July 3, 200 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract his paper presents a toolkit for Panel Analysis of Non-stationarity in Idiosyncratic

More information

Final Exam November 24, Problem-1: Consider random walk with drift plus a linear time trend: ( t

Final Exam November 24, Problem-1: Consider random walk with drift plus a linear time trend: ( t Problem-1: Consider random walk with drift plus a linear time trend: y t = c + y t 1 + δ t + ϵ t, (1) where {ϵ t } is white noise with E[ϵ 2 t ] = σ 2 >, and y is a non-stochastic initial value. (a) Show

More information

Økonomisk Kandidateksamen 2004 (I) Econometrics 2. Rettevejledning

Økonomisk Kandidateksamen 2004 (I) Econometrics 2. Rettevejledning Økonomisk Kandidateksamen 2004 (I) Econometrics 2 Rettevejledning This is a closed-book exam (uden hjælpemidler). Answer all questions! The group of questions 1 to 4 have equal weight. Within each group,

More information

Economic modelling and forecasting. 2-6 February 2015

Economic modelling and forecasting. 2-6 February 2015 Economic modelling and forecasting 2-6 February 2015 Bank of England 2015 Ole Rummel Adviser, CCBS at the Bank of England ole.rummel@bankofengland.co.uk Philosophy of my presentations Everything should

More information

10. Time series regression and forecasting

10. Time series regression and forecasting 10. Time series regression and forecasting Key feature of this section: Analysis of data on a single entity observed at multiple points in time (time series data) Typical research questions: What is the

More information

by Ye Cai and Mototsugu Shintani

by Ye Cai and Mototsugu Shintani ON THE LONG-RUN VARIANCE RATIO TEST FOR A UNIT ROOT by Ye Cai and Mototsugu Shintani Working Paper No. 05-W06 March 2005 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS VANDERBILT UNIVERSITY NASHVILLE, TN 37235 www.vanderbilt.edu/econ

More information

Econometrics I. Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics 25-1/25. Part 25: Time Series

Econometrics I. Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics 25-1/25. Part 25: Time Series Econometrics I Professor William Greene Stern School of Business Department of Economics 25-1/25 Econometrics I Part 25 Time Series 25-2/25 Modeling an Economic Time Series Observed y 0, y 1,, y t, What

More information

Ch 6. Model Specification. Time Series Analysis

Ch 6. Model Specification. Time Series Analysis We start to build ARIMA(p,d,q) models. The subjects include: 1 how to determine p, d, q for a given series (Chapter 6); 2 how to estimate the parameters (φ s and θ s) of a specific ARIMA(p,d,q) model (Chapter

More information

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots

A nonparametric test for seasonal unit roots Robert M. Kunst robert.kunst@univie.ac.at University of Vienna and Institute for Advanced Studies Vienna To be presented in Innsbruck November 7, 2007 Abstract We consider a nonparametric test for the

More information

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω)

Online Appendix. j=1. φ T (ω j ) vec (EI T (ω j ) f θ0 (ω j )). vec (EI T (ω) f θ0 (ω)) = O T β+1/2) = o(1), M 1. M T (s) exp ( isω) Online Appendix Proof of Lemma A.. he proof uses similar arguments as in Dunsmuir 979), but allowing for weak identification and selecting a subset of frequencies using W ω). It consists of two steps.

More information

TESTING FOR NORMALITY IN THE LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL: AN EMPIRICAL LIKELIHOOD RATIO TEST

TESTING FOR NORMALITY IN THE LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL: AN EMPIRICAL LIKELIHOOD RATIO TEST Econometrics Working Paper EWP0402 ISSN 1485-6441 Department of Economics TESTING FOR NORMALITY IN THE LINEAR REGRESSION MODEL: AN EMPIRICAL LIKELIHOOD RATIO TEST Lauren Bin Dong & David E. A. Giles Department

More information

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017

Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION. September 2017 Supplemental Material for KERNEL-BASED INFERENCE IN TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT COINTEGRATING REGRESSION By Degui Li, Peter C. B. Phillips, and Jiti Gao September 017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

More information

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors

On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors On the Correlations of Trend-Cycle Errors Tatsuma Wada Wayne State University This version: December 19, 11 Abstract This note provides explanations for an unexpected result, namely, the estimated parameter

More information

Block Bootstrap Prediction Intervals for Vector Autoregression

Block Bootstrap Prediction Intervals for Vector Autoregression Department of Economics Working Paper Block Bootstrap Prediction Intervals for Vector Autoregression Jing Li Miami University 2013 Working Paper # - 2013-04 Block Bootstrap Prediction Intervals for Vector

More information

MA Advanced Econometrics: Applying Least Squares to Time Series

MA Advanced Econometrics: Applying Least Squares to Time Series MA Advanced Econometrics: Applying Least Squares to Time Series Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD February 15, 2011 Karl Whelan (UCD) Time Series February 15, 2011 1 / 24 Part I Time Series: Standard

More information

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, vol.1, no.1, 2012, 55-67 ISSN: 2241-0988 (print version), 2241-0996 (online) International Scientific Press, 2012 A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity

More information

Regression with time series

Regression with time series Regression with time series Class Notes Manuel Arellano February 22, 2018 1 Classical regression model with time series Model and assumptions The basic assumption is E y t x 1,, x T = E y t x t = x tβ

More information

Sequential Procedure for Testing Hypothesis about Mean of Latent Gaussian Process

Sequential Procedure for Testing Hypothesis about Mean of Latent Gaussian Process Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 4, 2010, no. 62, 3083-3093 Sequential Procedure for Testing Hypothesis about Mean of Latent Gaussian Process Julia Bondarenko Helmut-Schmidt University Hamburg University

More information

Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2

Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2 Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2 Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, UiO 25 February 2010 Main issues and references The Arellano and Bond method for GMM estimation of dynamic panel data models A stepwise

More information

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12 ECON 4160, 2016. Lecture 11 and 12 Co-integration Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics 9 November 2017 1 / 43 Introduction I So far we have considered: Stationary VAR ( no unit roots ) Standard inference

More information

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Topic 4 Unit Roots. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University Topic 4 Unit Roots Gerald P. Dwyer Clemson University February 2016 Outline 1 Unit Roots Introduction Trend and Difference Stationary Autocorrelations of Series That Have Deterministic or Stochastic Trends

More information

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016 Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics (5th ed, 2012) Chapter 11: OLS with time series data Stationary and weakly dependent time series The notion of a stationary

More information

Estimation and Hypothesis Testing in LAV Regression with Autocorrelated Errors: Is Correction for Autocorrelation Helpful?

Estimation and Hypothesis Testing in LAV Regression with Autocorrelated Errors: Is Correction for Autocorrelation Helpful? Journal of Modern Applied Statistical Methods Volume 10 Issue Article 13 11-1-011 Estimation and Hypothesis Testing in LAV Regression with Autocorrelated Errors: Is Correction for Autocorrelation Helpful?

More information

Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors

Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors Testing for a Trend with Persistent Errors Graham Elliott UCSD August 2017 Abstract We develop new tests for the coe cient on a time trend in a regression of a variable on a constant and time trend where

More information

Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University While it is known that pseudo-out-of-sample methods are not optimal for

Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University While it is known that pseudo-out-of-sample methods are not optimal for Comment Atsushi Inoue Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University (atsushi.inoue@vanderbilt.edu) While it is known that pseudo-out-of-sample methods are not optimal for comparing models, they are nevertheless

More information

Economics 536 Lecture 7. Introduction to Specification Testing in Dynamic Econometric Models

Economics 536 Lecture 7. Introduction to Specification Testing in Dynamic Econometric Models University of Illinois Fall 2016 Department of Economics Roger Koenker Economics 536 Lecture 7 Introduction to Specification Testing in Dynamic Econometric Models In this lecture I want to briefly describe

More information

Construction of Stationarity Tests Title Distortions.

Construction of Stationarity Tests Title Distortions. Construction of Stationarity Tests Title Distortions Author(s) Kurozumi, Eiji Citation Issue 2005-11 Date Type Technical Report Text Version URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/16931 Right Hitotsubashi University

More information

Robust methods for detecting multiple level breaks in autocorrelated time series

Robust methods for detecting multiple level breaks in autocorrelated time series Robust methods for detecting multiple level breaks in autocorrelated time series by David I. Harvey, Stephen J. Leybourne and A. M. Robert Taylor Granger Centre Discussion Paper No. 10/01 Robust Methods

More information

Volume 29, Issue 1. On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates

Volume 29, Issue 1. On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates Volume 29, Issue 1 On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates Hyeongwoo Kim Auburn University Young-Kyu Moh Texas Tech University Abstract

More information

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication

G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri. WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication G. S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri WILEY A John Wiley and Sons, Ltd., Publication TEMT Foreword Preface to the Fourth Edition xvii xix Part I Introduction and the Linear Regression Model 1 CHAPTER 1 What is Econometrics?

More information