Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification"

Transcription

1 Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification Johannes O. Royset Operations Research Department Naval Postgraduate School Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics University of California, Davis Abstract. Much of the development of lopsided convergence for bifunctions defined on product spaces was in response to motivating applications. A wider class of applications requires an extension that would allow for arbitrary domains, not only product spaces. This leads to an extension of the definition and its implications that include the convergence of solutions and optimal values of a broad class of minsup problems. In the process we relax the definition of lopsided convergence even for the classical situation of product spaces. We now capture applications in optimization under stochastic ambiguity, Generalized Nash games, and many others. We also introduce the lop-distance between bifunctions, which leads to the first quantification of lopsided convergence. This quantification facilitates the study of convergence rates of methods for solving a series of problems including minsup problems, (Generalized) Nash games, and various equilibrium problems. Keywords: lopsided convergence, lop-convergence, lop-distance, aw-distance epi-convergence, hypo-convergence, minsup problems, Generalized Nash games AMS Classification: 49M99, 65K10, 90C15, 90C33, 90C47 Date: August 22, Introduction The notion of lopsided convergence of bifunctions (= bivariate functions defined on a product space) was introduced in [3] for extended real-valued bifunctions. The focus on extended realvalued functions was motivated by the incentive to keep the development in concordance with the elegant duality results of Rockafellar [17, Chapters 33-37] and the subsequent convergence theory for saddle functions [4, 2, 14]. But this paradigm turned out to become unmanageable when confronted with a series of applications that required dealing with bifunctions that were 1

2 not of the convex-concave type. Eventually, this led to restricting the convergence theory for bifunctions to real-valued bivariate functions (only) defined on specific subsets of the product space, cf. [15, 19] and especially [16]. Lopsided convergence is emerging as a central tool in the study of linear and nonlinear complementarity problems, fixed points, variational inequalities, inclusions, noncooperative games, mathematical programs with equilibrium constraints, optimality conditions, Walras and Nash equilibrium problems, optimization under stochastic ambiguity, and robust optimization; see the recent developments in [15, 19, 20]. Already, Aubin and Ekeland [7, Chapter 6] brought to the fore the ineluctable connections between some of these applications when dealing with existence issues. Prior studies deal exclusively with bifunctions defined on a product space, but applications in Generalized Nash games, robust optimization, stochastic optimization with decision-dependent measures, and Generalized semi-infinite programming require extensions to bifunctions for which the second variable s domain depend on the first variable. For example, in a minsup problem this corresponds to the situation when the inner maximization has a feasible region that depends on the outer minimization variable, in a Generalized Nash game, the need arises when the set of feasible actions for any given agent depends on the actions of the other agents. We extend the definition of lopsided convergence to deal with these situations and establish an array of results addressing this wider setting. Specifically, we show that for this extended notion of lopsided convergence, optimal solutions and optimal values of approximate minsup problems tend to those of an original minsup problem. We also relax the definition of lopsided convergence for bifunctions defined on a product space and, therefore, broaden the area of application even in this classical situation. In the process, we recast, and in a couple of instances refine, the fundamental implications of epi-convergence in the present framework, i.e., for finite-valued functions defined on a subset of a metric space. For the first time we quantify lopsided convergence by defining the lop-distance. The lopdistance between two bifunctions is given in terms of the Attouch-Wets distance between the sup-projections of the bifunctions with respect to the second variable. Thus, we place firmly the emphasis on the outer minimization in a minsup problem at the expense of the inner maximization. This imbalance indeed motivated the terminology lopsided. In the context of minsup problems, Generalized Nash game, and many other situations, this perspective is reasonable as the inner problem is certainly secondary as illustrated below; the solution of the outer minimization being primary. For example, this leads to estimates of the rate of convergence of that outer solution as demonstrated in [20]. We note that the point of view differs from that of epi/hypo-convergence [4] and analysis of the convex/concave case [17, Chapters 33-37]. There the focus is on finding saddle-point pairs, which implies a certain balance between the inner and outer problems and indeed symmetry in the convex/concave case. Of course, our new viewpoint remains applicable in the convex/concave case and it yields somewhat sharper results not discussed here. 2

3 The article proceeds in 2 with a couple of motivating examples. In 3, we give the new definition, provide sufficiency conditions, and also discuss foundations related to epi-convergence. Consequences of lopsided convergence are established in 4 and the lop-distance is introduced in 5. 2 Motivation Throughout the article, we let (X, d X ) and (Y, d Y ) be two metric spaces and consider finitevalued bifunctions defined on subsets of X Y. In contrast to this article predecessors, e.g., [19], that deal with bifunctions of the form F : C D X Y IR with D a (fixed) subset of Y, we consider bifunctions with arbitrary domains. That is, the set D Y of permissible values for the second variable might depend on x X, the first variable. This extension is essential to deal with some applications as illustrated next. 2.1 Optimization under Stochastic Ambiguity Consider the minsup problem min x C sup y D(x) F (x, y), where D : C Y, C = dom D = { x : D(x) } X, and Y = P is the space of distribution functions defined on IR m, with an appropriate metric. It identifies an optimization model with stochastic ambiguity where C is a collection of feasible decisions, D(x) an ambiguity set of probability distributions, and F a bifunction that depends both on the decision and the distribution. For example, F (x, P ) = IE P [φ(x, ξ)], where ξ is a random vector with distribution function P and the expectation is therefore taken with respect to a distribution function that is determined by the inner maximization problem. In applications, it is sometimes crucial to allow the ambiguity set to depend in a nontrivial manner on the decision x to capture situations where the decision maker affects the uncertainty as modeled here via the set D(x); see [20] for a more comprehensive exposition as well as [21, 11, 13] for related models. 2.2 Generalized Nash Games As we shall see, the study of Generalized Nash games naturally leads to the study of bifunctions that are defined on a (proper) subset of a product space. An equilibrium of a Generalized Nash game with a finite set A of agents, is a solution x = ( x a, a A) that satisfies x a argmax xa D a ( x a ) r a (x a, x a ), for all a A, where x a = (x a : a A\{a}), r a is the payoff function for agent a, and D a ( x a ) is the set of available strategies for agent a; this means that the set of available strategies for agent a depends 3

4 on the choice of strategies by the other agents. Equilibria of such games are fully characterized by the minsup-points of the Nikaido-Isoda bifunction: F (x, y) = [ ] r a (x a, x a ) r a (y a, x a ) for x C, y D(x) a A with C = { } x : x a D a (x a ) for all a A and D(x) = D a(x a ). a A Clearly, the (effective) domain of this bifunction might be rather involved. 2.1 Proposition x C is an equilibrium if and only if it is a maxinf-point of F with nonnegative maxinf-value, i.e., x argmax x C inf y D(x) F (x, y) and inf y D( x) F ( x, y) 0. Proof. If x is a Nash equilibrium, then r a ( x a, x a ) r a (y a, x a ) for all y a D a ( x a ), a A. Thus, F ( x, y) 0 for all y D( x). For any x C, x D(x) and therefore inf y D(x) F (x, y) 0. In particular, inf y D( x) F ( x, y) = F ( x, x) = 0. Consequently, x argmax x C inf y D(x) F (x, y). For the converse, let x be a maxinf-point of F. Then, 0 inf y D( x) F ( x, y) = [ ] r a ( x a, x a ) sup ya D a A a( x a ) r a (y a, x a ). The lower bound of zero and the fact that x a D a ( x a ) for all a A imply that each term in the sum must be zero and the conclusion follows. 3 Lopsided Convergence As already mentioned in the Introduction, to encompass the family of applications sketched out in 2 and others, we need to extend the definition of lopsided convergence, and the resulting theory, to a larger class of bifunctions than those considered in earlier work. The domain, dom F, of a finite-valued bifunction F will no longer be restricted to a product subset of X Y but could be any subset. The family of all such bifunctions is denoted bfcns(x, Y ) := { F : dom F IR : = dom F X Y }. It is on this family we introduce the new definition of lopsided convergence. 4

5 3.1 Definition The (first) x-variable of a bifunction takes a primary role in our development leading us to the following description of the domain of a bifunction. We associate with a bifunction F, the set C := { x X : y Y such that (x, y) dom F } and the set-valued mapping D : C Y such that D(x) := { y Y : (x, y) dom F } for x C. Thus, dom F = { (x, y) X Y : x C, y D(x) }, with dom D = { x X : D(x) } = C; when dom F is a product set it agrees with having D a constant mapping. Figure 1 illustrates the case with a product set (left portion) and the general case (right portion). Throughout, we let C and D be the set and set-valued mapping, respectively, associated with a bifunction F. With a slight abuse of notation, occasionally we simply write D instead of D(x) when the set-valued mapping is constant on its domain. ( ) dom ( ) dom Figure 1: Domains of bifunctions: product set (left) and general (right). In applications, a bifunction might be defined on a large subset of X Y, possibly everywhere, but the context requires restrictions to some smaller subset for example dictated by constraints imposed on the variables. In this case, C and D would represent these restrictions and F in our notation would become the original bifunction restricted to the set {(x, y) X Y : x C, y D(x)}. In other applications, F might be the only problem data and then C and D would be specified by dom F. These differences are immaterial to the following development as both are captured by considering bfcns(x, Y ). With IN := {1, 2, 3,...}, every bifunction in the collection {F ν } ν IN bfcns(x, Y ) will analogously to the situation for F be associated with a slicing of its domain in terms of a set C ν X and a set-valued mapping D ν : C ν Y such that dom F ν = { (x, y) X Y : x C ν, y D ν (x) }. The extended definition of lopsided convergence takes the following form. 5

6 3.1 Definition (lopsided convergence) Let {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ). The bifunctions F ν converge lopsided, or lop-converge, to F, written F ν lop F, when (a) x ν C ν x C, y D(x), y ν D ν (x ν ) y such that liminf ν F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) and x ν C ν x / C, y ν D ν (x ν ) such that F ν (x ν, y ν ) ; (b) x C, x ν C ν x such that y ν D ν (x ν ) y Y, limsup ν F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) if y D(x) and F ν (x ν, y ν ) otherwise. Lop-convergence does not have a direct geometric interpretation. However, as discussed in 4, it is intimately tied to epi- and hypo-convergence, which are easily understood in terms of the convergence of epigraphs and hypographs; see 3.4. We can therefore understand, in part, lopconvergence through these geometric interpretations. A preview of the conclusions reached in 4 builds intuition at this stage: If the bifunctions F ν and F do not depend on y, then lopconvergence collapses to epi-convergence. Under mild assumptions, F ν lop F implies that sup y D ν ( ) F ν (, y) epi-converges to sup y D( ) F (, y). We also have that at every x C, F ν (x ν, ) hypo-converges to F (x, ) for some x ν x. We note that even in the case when dom F and dom F ν are product sets for all ν, our definition represents a relaxation of the requirements in prior definitions as {y ν } ν IN in condition (a) of Definition 3.1 for the case x C is not required to converge to y. Contrast with earlier definition for product sets. Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) have D, D ν Y so that F : C D IR and F ν : C ν D ν IR. In [16, 19], lopconvergence is defined to take place when (a ) x ν C ν x X, y D, y ν D ν y such that liminf ν F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) if x C and F ν (x ν, y ν ) otherwise; and (b ) x C, x ν C ν x such that y ν D ν y Y, limsup ν F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) if y D and F ν (x ν, y ν ) otherwise. The condition (b ) is exactly condition (b) of Definition 3.1 for the case of product sets. However, condition (a ) is stronger than condition (a) of Definition 3.1 as illustrated by the following trivial example. Let X = Y = IR, C ν = C = (0, 1], D ν = D = [0, 1], and F ν (x, y) = F (x, y) = 1/(x + y) for (x, y) in the their domains. It is clear that (a ) fails for y = 1, x = 0, and x ν = 1/ν as there is no y ν y such that F ν (x ν, y ν ). However, condition (a) of Definition 3.1 holds as one can take y ν = 1/ν in the case x C. Then, F ν (x ν, y ν ) = ν/2. If x C, then one can take y ν = y and obtain that F ν (x ν, y ν ) = F (x ν, y) F (x, y) by continuity of F. For condition (b) of Definition 3.1, one can take x ν = x and only be concerned with y Y due to the closedness of Y. Continuity of F then allows us to conclude that F ν lop F. In this case, with F ν = F, convergence is indeed natural and Definition 3.1 addresses this situation. 3.2 About Sufficiency One can come up with a wide collection of sufficient conditions for lop-convergence in terms of the way the components of a sequence of bifunctions F ν converge to those of the limiting 6

7 bifunction F ; note that it will be necessary to broaden convergence notions for functions and mappings to take into account the fact that the domains of these bifunctions are generally not identical. The following results are only meant to illustrate the possibilities and might not be as taut as possible and certainly not necessary. The more interesting ones come from specific applications such as those laid out in [15, 12] involving bifunctions whose domains are product sets and the more general family, when the domains are not restricted to product sets, such as the examples in 2 and those described in [20]. In the following, convergence of sequences in X Y are always in the sense of the product topology, i.e., (x ν, y ν ) X Y (x, y) X Y if max{d X (x ν, x), d Y (y ν, y)} 0. Convergence of sets are always in the sense of Painlevé-Kuratowski. Specifically, in a metric space, the outer limit of a sequence of sets {A ν } ν IN, denoted by Limsup A ν, is the collection of points x to which a subsequence of {x ν } ν IN, with x ν A ν, converges. The inner limit, denote by Liminf ν A ν, is the points to which a sequence of {x ν } ν IN, with x ν A ν, converges. If both limits exist and are identical to A, we say that A ν (set-)converges to A, which is denoted by A ν A; see [9, 18]. 3.2 Theorem (sufficiency when C = C ν ) For bifunctions { F, F ν, ν IN } bfcns(x, Y ), F ν lop F when (a) C = C ν, ν IN, are closed; (b) the mappings D ν continuously converge to D, relative to C, i.e., x ν C x C, D ν (x ν ) D(x); and (c) the bifunctions F ν continuously converge to F, relative to their domains, i.e., (x ν, y ν ) dom F ν (x, y) dom F, F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y). Proof. Since C is closed, given any x ν C x it always entails x C. Moreover, continuous convergence of the mappings D ν to D, relative to C, implies D ν (x ν ) D(x) which, in turn, implies that for any y D(x) one can find y ν D ν (x ν ) converging to y. From (b), the continuous convergence of the bifunctions F ν to F, implies F (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) which immediately yields condition (a) of Definition 3.1. To verify condition (b) of Definition 3.1, given any x C, by choosing the sequence {x ν = x, ν IN}, D ν (x) D(x) follows from continuous convergence of the mappings. Thus, whenever y ν D ν (x) y, y D(x). In turn, this means that we only have to check if limsup ν F ν (x, y ν ) F (x, y) which, of course, is satisfied since F ν (x, y ν ) F (x, y) in view of assumption (b). Next, we deal with the situation when the domains of the bifunctions are product sets or, equivalently, when the mappings D ν are constant on C. In fact the next statement can be viewed as a refinement of the earlier theorem. Below, we recall that a function f : C IR, with C X, with X any metric space, is lower semicontinuous (lsc) when, for all x ν C x X, liminf ν f(x ν ) f(x) if x C and f(x ν ) otherwise. 7

8 3.3 Proposition (sufficiency under product sets) Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) has C = C ν closed and D ν Y D Y, i.e., the set-valued mappings are constant. If in terms of some lsc bifunction F : X Y IR, F = F on C D and F ν = F on C D ν, then F ν lop F, provided that, for all x C, F (x, ) is usc. Proof. First, consider condition (a) of Definition 3.1, which now simplifies to finding, for every y D and x ν C ν x C, a sequence y ν D ν y such that liminf ν F (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y). This condition follows from the set-convergence of D ν to D and lower semicontinuity of F. Second, for condition (b) of Definition 3.1, we select x ν = x C for all ν. Since D ν D, any sequence y ν D ν y, implies y D. Thus, the condition simplifies to limsup ν F (x, y ν ) F (x, y) which holds in view of the last assumption of the proposition. Finally, we record a result for the case when there is approximation in the set controlling the (first) x-variable. 3.4 Proposition (sufficiency when C C ν ) Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) has C ν C and for some continuous set-valued mapping D : X Y, D = D on C and D ν = D on C ν and for some continuous bifunction F : X Y IR, Then, F ν lop-converges to F. F = F on dom F and F ν = F on dom F ν. Proof. Since C ν C, every x ν C ν x must have x C. Thus, condition (a) of Definition 3.1 simplifies to finding, for every x ν C ν x C and y D(x), a sequence y ν D(x ν ) y with liminf ν F (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y). Since D is continuous, such a sequence exists and the inequality therefore follows from the continuity of F. We next turn to condition (b) of Definition 3.1. Since D is continuous, y ν D(x ν ) y implies that y D(x) whenever x ν x. Thus, the condition simplifies to finding, for every x C, a sequence x ν C ν x such that limsup ν F (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) for all y ν D(x ν ) y D(x). Since C ν C, there is certainly a sequence x ν C ν x for all x C. The inequality then holds in view of the continuity of F. It is easy to find generalizations of the preceding results, for example rather than requiring continuous convergence of the F ν in Theorem 3.2 one could be satisfied with some semicontinuous convergence complemented with a pointwise upper semicontinuity condition. At this point, we shall not get involved in all the possibilities as eventually one is bound to be mostly interested in conditions that apply in specific applications. However, we caution that certain natural conditions are not sufficient as exemplified next. 8

9 Failure of lop-convergence under graphical convergence. Consider the following situation where F ν = F for all ν IN, with C = C ν = IR and D ν (x) = D(x) = [ 1, 1] if x 0, and {0} otherwise. Certainly the mappings D ν graphically converge to D since they are identical. However, when considering condition (a) of Definition 3.1 with x ν > 0 x = 0 and y = 1/2 D(x), there are no y ν D ν (x ν ) y and lop-convergence fails. We note that in this case pointwise convergence D ν (x) D(x) holds for all x IR and, consequently, the mappings are equi-osc [18, Theorem 5.40]. We next give a more involved example where pointwise convergence again holds, but now for problems with different solutions. Failure of lop-convergence under pointwise set-convergence. Suppose that C = C ν = [0, 1], D(x) = D ν (x) = {0} for x [0, 1), D ν (1) = [0, 1 + 1/ν], and D(1) = [0, 1]. Moreover, let F (x, y) = F ν (x, y) = 0 if x [0, 1), and F (1, y) = F ν (1, y) = 2 + y if y 1 and F ν (1, y) = 1 if y > 1. Clearly, for every x [0, 1], D ν (x) D(x). However, lop-convergence of F ν to F fails as for x = 1, x ν = 1 1/ν, and y = 1, there exists no sequence {y ν } ν IN, with y ν D ν (x ν ) = {0} that converges to y as required by condition (a) of Definition 3.1. Here, sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y) = 0 if x [0, 1) and sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y) = 1 if x = 1, and sup y D(x) F (x, y) = 0 if x [0, 1) and sup y D(x) F (1, y) = 1. Thus, the optimal value of min x C ν sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y), which is 0, does not converge to the optimal value of min x C sup y D(x) F (x, y), which is 1. Since a main purpose of a notion of variational convergence of bifunctions is to ensure convergence of such optimal values, it is clear that pointwise set-convergence is not strong enough. 3.3 Tightness A slight strengthening of lop-convergence that amounts to a relaxed compactness assumption becomes beneficial in 5 when deriving consequences. 3.5 Definition (ancillary-tight lop-convergence) The lop-convergence of {F ν } ν IN bfcns(x, Y ) to F bfcns(x, Y ) is ancilliary-tight if Definition 3.1 holds and for every ε > 0 and sequence x ν x selected in condition (b) of Definition 3.1, there exists a compact set B ε Y and an integer ν ε such that sup F ν (x ν, y) sup F ν (x ν, y) ε for all ν ν ε. y D ν (x ν ) B ε y D ν (x ν ) As usual, we interpret the supremum over an empty subset of IR as. The added requirement for ancillary-tightness is satisfied if all D ν (x ν ) are contained in a compact set. If ancillarytightness is combined with a similar condition for the outer minimization, we obtain a further strengthening of the notion. 3.6 Definition (tight lop-convergence) The lop-convergence of {F ν } ν IN bfcns(x, Y ) to the bifunction F bfcns(x, Y ) is tight if Definition 3.5 holds and for any ε > 0 one can find a compact set A ε X and an integer ν ε such that inf x C ν A ε sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y) inf x C ν sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y) + ε for all ν ν ε. 9

10 The infimum of an empty subset of IR is interpreted as. This further strengthening of the requirements would be satisfied if all C ν are contained in a compact set, but this is certainly not a necessity. 3.4 Epi- and Hypo-Convergence: A Brief Overview Before we develop consequences of lop-convergence, we give some background facts about epiand hypo-convergence for (univariate) functions; see [1, 8, 18] for comprehensive treatments. We present results for real-valued functions defined on (nonempty) subsets of (X, d X ); in many ways, this is just a variant of the more traditional framework that considers extended real-valued functions, cf. [8, 18]. Our focus will, thus, be on fcns(x) = { f : C IR : for some C X. } In this section, we let C = dom f and, similarly, C ν = dom f ν for f ν fcns(x). The epigraph of f, epi f X IR, consists of all points that lie on or above the graph of f; it is lsc if epi f is closed and, provided X is a linear space 1, it is convex if its epigraph is convex. The hypograph of f, hypo f X IR, consists of all points that lie on or below the graph of f; it is upper semicontinuous (usc) if hypo f is closed and, provided X is a linear space, it is concave if its hypograph is convex. A sequence of functions {f ν } ν IN fcns(x) epi-converges to a function f fcns(x), written f ν e f, when the epigraphs epi f ν set-converge to epi f; similarly, they hypo-converge, written f ν h f, if the hypographs hypo f ν set-converge to hypo f. Equivalently, epi-convergence can also be defined as follows: 3.7 Definition (epi- and hypo-convergence) A sequence of functions {f ν } ν IN fcns(x) epiconverges to a function f fcns(x) if and only the following conditions are satisfied: (a) x ν C ν x, liminf ν f ν (x ν ) f(x) if x C and f ν (x ν ) otherwise, (b) x C, x ν C ν x such that limsup ν f ν (x ν ) f(x). The functions f ν are said to epi-converges tightly to f when f ν e find a compact set B ε X and an index ν ε such that f and for all ε > 0, one can ν ν ε : inf x C ν B ε f ν (x) inf x C ν f ν (x) + ε. Moreover, f ν h f if and only if f ν e f and they hypo-converge tightly if the functions f ν epi-converge tightly to f. As follows immediately from the properties of set-limits, an epi-limit is always lsc and, provided that X is linear, it is convex whenever the functions f ν are convex. Moreover, a hypo-limit is 1 Statements about convexity/concavity are the only ones that require a linear space in this paper. 10

11 always usc and, provided that X is linear, it is concave whenever the functions f ν are concave. The topology induced by epi-convergence is metrizable, a property we leverage in 5. For f fcns(x), optimal values are denoted by inf f := inf{f(x) : x C} and sup f := sup{f(x) : x C}, and, with ε 0, (near-)optimal solutions by ε- argmin f := {x C : f(x) inf f + ε} and ε- argmax f := {x C : f(x) sup f ε}. Since C = dom f is nonempty for f fcns(x), inf f <. Moreover, inf f = implies that argmin f =. Convergence of optimal solutions and optimal values are summarized in the next theorem. The result and proof are mostly the same as those of [18, Theorem 7.31] and [16, Theorems 2.5 and 2.8], which consider X = IR n, but stated here for completeness with some clarification and improvements, especially regarding the role of finiteness of inf f and convergence of near-optimal solutions. We refer to [4] for early results of this kind. 3.8 Theorem (epi- and hypo-convergence: basic properties) Consider {f, f ν, ν IN} fcns(x). If f ν e f, then the following hold: (a) limsup ν (inf f ν ) inf f and {ε ν 0, ν IN}, Limsup ν ( ε ν -argmin f ν) argmin f. (b) If x is a cluster point of a sequence { x ν argmin f ν, ν IN }, i.e., the limit of a subsequence {x ν k }k IN, then lim k (inf f ν k ) = inf f. (c) inf f ν inf f > f ν e f tightly. (d) inf f ν inf f and ε > 0 = Liminf ν (ε- argmin f ν ) argmin f. (e) inf f ν inf f and X is separable 2 = {ε ν 0, ν IN} such that ε ν -argmin f ν argmin f. (f) {ε ν 0, ν IN} such that ε ν -argmin f ν argmin f = inf f ν inf f >. If f ν h f, then liminf ν (sup f ν ) sup f and (a)-(f) hold with min/inf replaced by max/sup, > by <, and tight epi-convergence by tight hypo-convergence. Proof. For part (a), we first suppose that inf f is finite and let ε > 0. There exists x C such that f(x) inf f + ε and also, by condition (b) of Definition 3.7, x ν C ν x such that limsup ν f ν (x ν ) f(x). Thus, limsup ν (inf f ν ) limsup ν f ν (x ν ) f(x) inf f + ε. Second, suppose that inf f = and let δ > 0. Then, there exists x C such that f(x) δ and also, by condition (b) of Definition 3.7, x ν C ν x such that limsup ν f ν (x ν ) f(x). Thus, limsup ν (inf f ν ) limsup ν f ν (x ν ) f(x) δ. Since ε and δ are arbitrary, the first result of 2 We deduce from a counterexample in [10] that the separability assumption cannot be relaxed. 11

12 part (a) is established. For the second result, suppose that x Limsup ν (ε ν -argmin f ν ). Then, there exists {x k ε ν k -argmin f ν k, k IN} x. Thus, limsup k f ν k (x k ) limsup k (inf f ν k + ε ν k ) inf f <. In view of condition (a) of Definition 3.7, this implies that x C and also f( x) liminf k f ν k (x k ) limsup k f ν k (x k ) inf f. Hence, x argmin f and the proof of part (a) is complete. For part (b), we observe in view of part (a) that x argmin f and also limsup ν (inf f ν ) inf f. Condition (a) of Definition 3.7 implies that liminf k (inf f v k ) = liminfk (f v k (x v k)) f( x) = inf f and the conclusion holds. Part (c), necessity. Suppose that inf f ν inf f > and let ε > 0. Then, there exist ν 1 IN such that inf f inf f ν + ε/3 for all ν ν 1 and also x C such that f( x) inf f + ε/3. In view of condition (b) of Definition 3.7, there exist x ν C ν x and ν 2 ν 1 such that f ν (x ν ) f( x) + ε/3 for all ν ν 2. Let B X be a compact set containing {x ν } ν IN. Thus, for ν ν 2, inf x C ν B f ν (x) f ν (x ν ) f( x) + ε/3 inf f + 2ε/3 inf f ν + ε. Part (c), sufficiency. For the sake of a contradiction let inf f =. Then, (a) implies that inf f ν. Since the epi-convergence is tight, there exists a compact set B X such that inf x C ν B f ν (x) and therefore also a sequence {x ν C ν B, ν IN} such that f ν (x ν ). The compactness of B implies that for some subsequence {x ν k }k IN and x B, lim k x ν k = x. In view of condition (a) of Definition 3.7, liminfk f ν k (x ν k) f(x) IR if x C and f ν k (x ν k) otherwise. However, both cases contradict f ν (x ν ) and thus inf f >. We next show that liminf ν (inf f ν ) inf f, which, together with (a) completes the proof of (c). We start by showing that for any compact set B X, {inf x C ν B f ν (x), ν IN}, except possibly for a finite number of indexes, is bounded away from. For the sake of a contradiction, suppose that for some subsequence {ν k } k IN we have inf x C ν k B f ν k (x) < inf f 1. Then, there exists {x k C ν k B, k IN} such that f ν k(x k ) < inf f 1. Since B is compact, there is a cluster point x B of {x k } k IN. By condition (a) of Definition 3.7 and the boundedness of {f ν k (x k )} k IN, x C. Then, the same condition gives that liminf k f ν k (x k ) f( x) inf f, which is a contradiction. Hence, {inf x C ν B f ν (x), ν IN}, except possibly for a finite number of indexes, is bounded away from. Next, for ε > 0, let the compact set B ε X and ν ε be such that inf x C ν B ε f ν (x) inf f ν + ε for all ν ν ε, which holds by the tightness assumption. Since {inf x C ν B f ν (x), ν IN} is eventually bounded away from, there exist ν ε ν ε and x ν C ν B ε such that f ν (x ν ) inf C ν B ε f ν + ε for all ν ν ε. Thus, ν ν ε, f ν (x ν ) inf x C ν B ε f ν (x) + ε inf f ν + 2ε. 12

13 In view of (a), we conclude that {f ν } ν IN is bounded from above. The compactness of B ε implies that there exist a subsequence {x ν k }k IN and x B ε such that lim k x ν k = x. In view of condition (a) of Definition 3.7, x C because {f ν k (x ν k)}k IN is bounded from above. The same condition then implies that liminf k (inf f ν k ) + 2ε liminf k (inf x C ν k Bε f ν k (x)) + ε liminf k f ν k (x ν k ) f( x) inf f. Since this argument holds not only for {f ν } ν IN but also for all subsequences, liminf ν (inf f ν ) + 2ε inf f. We reach the conclusion of part (c) after recognizing that ε is arbitrary. For part (d), let x argmin f. Condition (b) of Definition 3.7 implies that there exist x ν C ν x and ν 1 IN such that f ν (x ν ) f( x) + ε/2 for all ν ν 1. Since inf f is finite, there is also ν 2 ν 1 such that inf f inf f ν + ε/2 for all ν ν 2. Thus, f ν (x ν ) f( x) + ε/2 = inf f + ε/2 inf f ν + ε for all ν ν 2 and we conclude that x Liminf ν (ε- argmin f ν ). Part (e). From (a), Limsup ν (ε ν -argmin f ν ) argmin f for any ε ν 0. Thus it suffices to show that Liminf ν (ε ν -argmin f ν ) argmin f for some ε ν 0. If argmin f =, then the inclusion is automatic. Thus, we can assume that argmin f and inf f is finite. Theorem 3.1 in [10] states the following result: For any collection {h, h ν, ν IN} of extended real-valued lsc functions on a separable metric space, if h ν e h and α IR, then there exists α ν α such that {x : h ν (x) α ν } {x : h(x) α}. To apply this theorem here, let lsc f ν be the lscregularization of f ν on X, i.e., the highest lsc function on X not exceeding f ν extended to the whole of X by assigning it the value outside its domain. Since lsc f ν e f, which already is lsc and can be extended in the same manner, it follows that there exists α ν inf f such that {x X : (lsc f ν )(x) α ν } {x X : f(x) inf f} = argmin f. Set {ε ν = 1/ν + max[0, α ν inf f ν ], ν IN}. Let x argmin f. In view of the above set convergence, there exists a sequence {x ν } ν IN, with (lsc f ν )(x ν ) α ν, converging to x. The definition of lsc-regularization implies that there exists {y ν C ν, ν IN} such that d X (x ν, y ν ) 1/ν and f ν (y ν ) (lsc f ν )(x ν ) + 1/ν. Thus, f ν (y ν ) (lsc f ν )(x ν ) + 1/ν α ν + 1/ν ε ν + inf f ν and therefore y ν ε ν -argmin f ν. Consequently, x Liminf ν (ε ν -argmin f ν ), which implies that Liminf ν (ε ν -argmin f ν ) argmin f. Since inf f ν inf f, ε ν 0 and the conclusion holds. For part (f), let x argmin f. The assumption permits the selection of ν IN and a sequence {x ν ε ν -argmin f ν, ν ν} x. Thus, by condition (a) of Definition 3.7, inf f = f( x) liminf ν f ν (x ν ) liminf ν (inf f ν + ε ν ) = liminf ν (inf f ν ). In view of part (a), the conclusion follows. 13

14 4 Consequences of Lopsided Convergence The main consequence of lop-convergence of F ν to F is the convergence of solutions of the approximate minsup problems min x C ν sup y D ν (x) F ν (x, y) to those of an actual minsup problem min x C sup y D(x) F (x, y). We give detailed results below, but start with fundamental properties associated with lopsided convergence. 4.1 Basic Properties For degenerate bifunctions that only depend on their first argument, lopsided convergence reduces to epi-convergence, a direct consequence of the definitions, as stated next. 4.1 Proposition (lop-convergence reduces to epi-convergence) Suppose that the bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) has dom F = C Y, dom F ν = C ν Y, F (x, y) = F (x, y ) for all x C and y, y Y, and F ν (x, y) = F ν (x, y ) for all x C ν and y, y Y. Then, for any y Y, F ν lop-converges to F F ν (, y) : C ν IR epi-converges to F (, y) : C IR. Lop-convergence implies hypo-convergence for certain functions as seen next. 4.2 Proposition (hypo-convergence of slices) For {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ), F ν lop F implies that for all x C, there exists x ν C ν x such that the functions F ν (x ν, ) : D ν (x ν ) IR hypo-converge to F (x, ) : D(x) IR. Proof. From condition (b) of Definition 3.1 there exists x ν C ν x such that the functions { F ν (x ν, ) : D ν (x ν ) IR} ν IN and F (x, ) : D(x) IR satisfy condition (a) of Definition 3.7. From condition (a) of Definition 3.1, for any y D(x) and x ν C ν x one can find y ν D ν (x ν ) y such that condition (b) of Definition 3.7 holds. The sup-projection (in y) of F bfcns(x, Y ), henceforth denoted by f, is given as f(x) := sup y D(x) F (x, y) whenever x C and sup y D(x) F (x, y) <. This means that the domain of f, dom f C; this inclusion could be strict. Conceivably, dom f could be empty in which case the sup-projection of F does not exist. Of course, there is no practical loss to exclude this pathological case, which in the case of a minsup problem corresponds to infeasibility. Since D(x) for x C, f(x) > and, thus, f : dom f IR. Similarly, the sup-projection of F ν bfcns(x, y) is denoted by f ν. It is clear that f ν might not exist even if f does and F ν lop F as the following example shows. Absence of sup-projection. Let C = C ν = [0, 1], D = D ν = {y IR : y 0}, F (x, y) = yx for (x, y) C D, and F ν (x, y) = y(x + 1/ν) for (x, y) C ν D ν. Clearly, the sup-projection of F has dom f = {0}. However, for F ν there exists no sup-projection for all ν IN. This 14

15 situation takes place even though on can show that F ν lop F. A consequence of lopsided convergence for the epigraphs of sup-projection is given next. 4.3 Theorem (containment of sup-projections) For bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ), with corresponding sup-projections {f, f ν, ν IN}, F ν lop F implies that Limsup ν ( epi f ν ) epi f. Proof. Suppose that (x, α) limsup ν (epi f ν ). Then there exists a sequence {(x ν, α ν )} ν N, with N a subsequence of IN, x ν C ν, sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) α ν, x ν N x, and α ν N α. If x C, then construct a sequence y ν D ν (x ν ) y such that F ν (x ν, y ν ) N, which exists by condition (a) of Definition 3.1. However, α ν sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) F ν (x ν, y ν ), ν N, implies a contradiction since α ν N α IR. Thus, x C. If sup y D(x) F (x, y) =, then there exists y D(x) such that F (x, y) α + 1. Condition (a) of Definition 3.1 ensures that there exists a sequence y ν D ν (x ν ) y such that liminf ν F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y). Consequently, α = liminf ν N α ν liminf ν N sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) liminf ν N F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y) α + 1, which is a contradiction. Hence, it suffices to consider the case with sup y D(x) F (x, y) finite. Given any ε > 0 arbitrarily small, pick y ε D(x) such that F (x, y ε ) sup y D(x) F (x, y) ε. Then condition (a) of Definition 3.1 again yields y ν D ν (x ν ) y ε such that liminf ν N sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) liminf ν N F ν (x ν, y ν ) F (x, y ε ) sup y D(x) F (x, y) ε, implying liminf ν N sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) sup y D(x) F (x, y). Since the conclusion follows. α = liminf ν N α ν liminf ν N sup y D ν (x ν ) F ν (x ν, y) sup y D(x) F (x, y), It is clear from the following example that lop-convergence does not guarantee that epi f ν epi f holds in general. Absence of tightness. For {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ), let C = C ν = X = IR, D = D ν = Y = IR, F (x, y) = 0 for (x, y) X Y, and F ν (x, y) = 1 if x X and y = ν, and zero otherwise. It is easy to show that F ν lop F. The sup-projection of F ν has f ν (x) = 1 for all x X and that of F has f(x) = 0 for all x X. Thus, the inclusion in Theorem 4.3 is strict. We observe that ancillary-tightness fails in this instance and that property is indeed key to eliminating such possibilities. 15

16 4.4 Theorem (epi-convergence of sup-projections) Suppose the bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) have corresponding sup-projections {f, f ν, ν IN}. If F ν lop-converges ancillarytightly to F, then epi f ν epi f or, equivalently, f ν e f. Proof. Let x dom f. Now, choose x ν C ν x such that F ν (x ν, ) : D ν (x ν ) IR hypoconverge to F (x, ) : D(x) IR, cf. Proposition 4.2. In fact, these functions hypo-converge tightly as an immediate consequence of ancillary-tightness. Thus, sup F ν (x ν, y ν ) sup F (x, y), y D ν (x ν ) y D(x) via Theorem 3.8. This fact together with Theorem 4.3 establish the first conclusion. The second conclusion is then immediate; see 4. It is clear that lop-convergence is a stronger condition than epi-convergence of the corresponding sup-projections. For example, if C = C ν = [0, 1], D = D ν = [0, 1], and F (x, y) = 1, F ν (x, y) = y for all (x, y) C D, then the corresponding sup-projections are identical and, certainly, f ν e f. However, condition (a) of Definition 3.1 fails and therefore F ν does not lop-converge to F. We end this subsection by listing consequences for semicontinuity, concavity, and convexity. 4.5 Proposition (usc and concavity) For bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) and any x C, F ν lop F implies that the (univariate) function F (x, ) : D(x) IR is usc. When Y is a linear space and for all x ν C ν x, F ν (x ν, ) : D ν (x ν ) IR is concave, it also implies that F (x, ) is concave. Proof. In view of Proposition 4.2, for every x C, there exists x ν C ν x such that F ν (x ν, ) hypo-converges to F (x, ), which therefore must be usc. If F ν (x ν, ) are concave, its hypo-limit must also be concave, which establishes the conclusions. 4.6 Proposition (lsc and convexity) Suppose the bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) have corresponding sup-projections {f, f ν, ν IN}. If F ν lop-converges ancillary-tightly to F, then f is lsc and also convex provided that X is a linear space, D ν is constant on C ν, and F ν (, y) is convex for all y D ν. Proof. In view of Theorem 4.4, f is an epi-limit and thus lsc. Convexity is guaranteed if f ν = sup y D ν ( ) F ν (, y), ν IN, are convex, which holds by the stated assumptions. 4.2 Consequence for Minsup Problems We have now reached the main results of the paper. The minsup-value of a bifunction F bfcns(x, Y ) is defined as minsup F := inf x C sup y D(x) F (x, y), 16

17 which clearly is the optimal value of the minsup problem min x C sup y D(x) F (x, y). The corresponding ε-optimal solutions, referred to as ε-minsup-points of F, are given by ε- argminsup F := { x C : sup y D(x) F (x, y) minsup F + ε }, for ε 0. If ε = 0, we simply refer to such points as minsup-points. 4.7 Theorem (bounds on minsup-value) Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) has sup-projections, F ν lop F, and {x ν argminsup F ν, ν IN} exist. Then, the following hold: (a) If {x ν } ν IN has a cluster point, then liminf ν (minsup F ν ) minsup F. (b) If lop-convergence is ancillary-tight, then limsup ν (minsup F ν ) minsup F and {ε ν 0, ν IN}, Limsup ν (ε ν - argminsup F ν ) argminsup F. (c) If lop-convergence is ancillary-tight and x is a cluster point of {x ν } ν IN, i.e., the limit of a subsequence {x ν k }k IN, then lim k (minsup F ν k ) = minsup F. Proof. We first consider (a): Let {x ν k }k IN be a convergent subsequence of {x ν } ν IN tending to x. If x dom f, then by Theorem 4.3 liminf ν (minsup F ν ) = liminf ν f ν (x ν ) f( x) minsup F. If x dom f, then also by Theorem 4.3 liminf ν (minsup F ν ) = liminf ν f ν (x ν ) and the conclusion holds. Second, consider (b) and (c): Theorem 4.4 implies that f ν e f and thus the conclusion is a direct application of Theorem 3.8. Tight lop-convergence implies the following strengthening of the result for minsup-points and values. 4.8 Theorem (approximating minsup-points) Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) have sup-projections and F ν lop F tightly. Then, (a) minsup F ν minsup F, which is finite; (b) for ε > 0, Liminf ν (ε- argminsup F ν ) argminsup F ; (c) for X separable, {ε ν 0, ν IN} such that ε ν - argminsup F ν argminsup F. Proof. The assumptions imply those of Theorem 4.4 and thus f ν e f. In view of Definition 3.6, the epi-convergence is tight; see Definition 3.7. The conclusion is then a direct application of Theorem 3.8. It is well-known that the infimum of a lsc function with a domain contained in a compact set is attained. Consequently, if the sup-projection f for some bifunction F bfcns(x, Y ) is lsc, which holds under mild assumptions (cf. Proposition 5.1), and C is contained in some compact set (and thus also dom f), then there exists a minimizer of f and thus also a minsup-point of F. We next state a result that relaxes the compactness requirement. 17

18 4.9 Theorem (existence of minsup-points) Suppose that {F, F ν, ν IN} bfcns(x, Y ) have sup-projections, F ν lop F ancillary-tightly, {f ν, ν IN} are lsc, and there are compact sets {B ν X, ν IN} such that C ν B ν. Then, {x ν argminsup F ν, ν IN} exist and every cluster point of {x ν } ν IN is a minsup-point of F. Proof. The discussion prior to the theorem ensures the existence of minsup-points of F ν for every ν. The result is then a consequence of Theorem 4.7. Theorem 4.9 does not ensure the existence of a cluster point of {x ν } ν IN. Still, it provides an approach for establishing the existence of a minsup-point of F : first construct a sequence {F ν } ν IN, with the required properties, that lop-converges ancillary-tightly to F and, second, prove that {x ν } ν IN has a cluster point. 5 Quantification of Lopsided Convergence We next turn to a definition of distance between bifunctions that in some sense characterizes lop-convergence. We would like the distance between F ν and F to tend to zero if and only if F ν lop-converges to F. In this section, we develop for the first time such a distance, which essentially characterizes lop-convergence after passing to certain equivalence classes of bifunctions. We begin with establishing a foundation regarding a distance between (univariate) functions. 5.1 Attouch-Wets Distance between Functions We limit the scope to the subset of fcns(x) consisting of lsc functions and let lsc-fcns(x) := {h fcns(x) : h lsc}. This set is equipped with the Attouch-Wets (aw) distance dl aw, which is given for a fixed but arbitrary point 3 x X. Specifically, the aw-distance is defined for any h, g lsc-fcns(x) as dl aw (h, g) := where the ρ-aw-distance, for any ρ 0 is given by 0 dl aw ρ (h, g)e ρ dρ, dl aw ρ (h, g) := sup { dist ( (x, α), epi h ) dist ( (x, α), epi g ) : d X (x, x) ρ, α ρ } and dist ( (x, α), epi h ) := inf {max{d X (x, x ), α α } : (x, α ) epi h}, 3 Although the topology induced by the aw-distance is the same for any point selected, the value of the distance will depend on this choice; see [5] and [18, Section 7.J] for details. 18

19 with a similar expression pertaining to epi g. We observe that x serves as the center of a ball on which dl aw ρ is computed. It is immediate that dl aw is a metric on lsc-fcns(x). We deduce from [9, Theorem 3.1.7] that for h ν, h lsc-fcns(x), dl aw (h ν, h) 0 = h ν e h. If (X, d X ) is a proper 4 metric space, then the converse also holds in view of [9, Theorem 3.1.7] and [5, Theorem 4.2, Lemma 4.3]. The latter results are stated only for IR n, but the arguments hold for any proper metric space. 5.2 Lop-Distance Parallel to the restriction to lsc-fcns(x) in the definition of dl aw, we focus on bifunctions with lsc sup-projections. Specifically, let lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) := { F bfcns(x, Y ) with lsc sup-projection }. In view of Theorem 4.6, the sup-projection of a bifunction to which a sequence of bifunctions lop-converge ancillary-tightly must be lsc. In fact, it is well-known that sup-projections are lsc under mild assumptions. Sufficient conditions are given next, a result essentially in [6, Theorem 2, Section 2.5.2] but proved here for completeness. 5.1 Proposition (lsc sup-projection) When it exists, the sup-projection f of a bifunction F bfcns(x, Y ) is lsc if either (a) D is inner semicontinuous 5 and F is lsc; or (b) D Y, i.e., the set-valued mapping is constant, and F (, y) is lsc for all y D. Proof. Let x ν dom f x dom f. Then sup y D(x) F (x, y) is finite and for every ε > 0 there is a y ε D(x) such that sup y D(x) F (x, y) F (x, y ε ) + ε. Moreover, the inner semicontinuity of D implies that there exists a sequence y ν ε D(x ν ) y ε. Since F is lsc, there exists ν such that for all ν ν, F (x ν, y ν ε ) F (x, y ε ) ε. Thus, for ν ν, sup y D(x ν ) F (x ν, y) F (x ν, y ν ε ) F (x, y ε ) ε sup y D(x) F (x, y) 2ε. Since ε is arbitrary, liminf ν sup y D(x ν ) F (x ν, y) sup y D(x) F (x, y). Next, suppose that x ν dom f x dom f. We consider two cases. First, let x C. Then, there exist y ν D(x ν ) such that F (x ν, y ν ). Thus, sup y D(x ν ) F (x ν, y). Second, let x C, but sup y D(x) F (x, y) =. Then, for every M < there is a y M D(x) such that F (x, y M ) > M. Following a similar argument as earlier, we find that liminf ν sup y D(x ν ) F (x ν, y) > M. Since M is arbitrary, the first conclusion follows. In the second case with D constant, the sequence {yε ν } can be selected to coincide with y ε for all ν and lsc in x only suffices. 4 A metric space is proper if all its closed balls are compact. 5 D : C Y is inner semicontinuous if for every x ν C x C, Liminf ν D(x ν ) D(x). 19

20 5.2 Definition (lop-distance) For any two bifunctions F, F lsc-bfcns(x, Y ), with sup-projections f, f, the lop-distance dl lop( F, F ) := dl aw( f, f ). It is immediately clear that the lop-distance is only a pseudometric on lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) as there are nonidentical bifunctions with the same sup-projection. Thus, we pass to equivalence classes. 5.3 Definition (equivalence classes of bifunctions) Bifunctions F, F lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) are equivalent, denoted by F F, if their sup-projections exist and are identical. We note that F F might hold even if C C as long as every x C that is not in C has sup y D(x) F (x, y) = and every x C that is not in C has sup y D (x) F (x, y) =. Thus, dom f = dom f and F F holds provided that the sup-projections exist (i.e., dom f = dom f ) and coincide on the domain. It is clear that dl lop is a metric on the quotient set of lsc-bfcns(x, Y ). 5.4 Theorem (quantification of lop-convergence) For bifunctions {F, F ν, ν IN} lsc-bfcns(x, Y ), the following hold. (a) If dl lop (F ν, F ) 0, then there exist F ν, F lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) such that F ν F ν, F F, and F ν lop F. (b) If F ν lop F ancillary-tightly and (X, d X ) is proper, then dl lop (F ν, F ) 0. Proof. For part (a), set C = dom f and D(x) = Y for all x C. Let F (x, y) = f(x) for x C and y Y. Since F lsc-bfcns(x, Y ), f exists. Thus, C is nonempty and F : C Y IR. By construction, for x C, sup y Y sup y D(x) F (x, y ) = f(x) <. Consequently, f, the sup-projection of F, exists and dom f = C. Moreover, f = f on C. where f is the sup-projection of F. Thus, F lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) and F F. An identical construction with C ν = dom f ν, Dν (x) = Y for all x C ν, and F ν : C ν Y IR having F ν (x, y) = f ν (x) for x C ν and y Y results in F ν lsc-bfcns(x, Y ) and F ν F ν. We then obtain for any y Y that ( dl aw F ν (, y), F ) ( ) (, y) = dl aw (f ν, f) = dl lop F ν, F 0. Since dl aw ( F ν (, y), F (, y)) 0 implies that F ν (, y) : C ν IR epi-converges to F (, y) : C IR, it follows from Proposition 4.1 that F ν lop-converges to F. For part (b) we conclude from Theorem 4.4 that f ν epi-converges to f. Thus, dl aw (f ν, f) 0 under the additional assumption that (X, d X ) is proper and the result follows from the definition of the lop-distance. 20

21 We recall that ancillary-tightness is ensured, for example, by some compactness property on the sets over which the inner maximization is taking place. Thus, a restriction to bifunctions satisfying such properties would ensure that the lop-distance fully characterizes lopsided convergence on this class provided that (X, d X ) is proper. Thus, the lop-distance generates what we define as the lop-topology on the space of equivalence classes of such bifunctions. Acknowledgement. This work in supported in parts by DARPA under grant HR References [1] H. Attouch. Variational Convergence for Functions and Operators. Applicable Mathematics Sciences. Pitman, [2] H. Attouch, D. Azé, and R. Wets. Convergence of convex-concave saddle functions: continuity properties of the Legendre-Fenchel transform with applications to convex programming and mechanics. Annales de l Institut H. Poincaré: Analyse Nonlinéaire, 5: , [3] H. Attouch and R. J-B Wets. Convergence des points min/sup et de points fixes. Comptes Rendus de l Académie des Sciences de Paris, 296: , [4] H. Attouch and R. J-B Wets. A convergence theory for saddle functions. Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 280(1):1 41, [5] H. Attouch and R. J-B Wets. Quantitative stability of variational systems: I. the epigraphical distance. Transactions of the American Mathematical Society, 328(2): , [6] J.-P. Aubin. Mathematical Methods of Game and Economic Theory. North-Holland, [7] J.-P. Aubin and I. Ekeland. Applied Nonlinear Analysis. Issue 1237 of Pure and applied mathematics. Wiley, [8] J.-P. Aubin and H. Frankowska. Set-Valued Analysis. Birkhäuser, [9] G. Beer. Topologies on Closed and Closed Convex Sets, volume 268 of Mathematics and its Applications. Kluwer, [10] G. Beer, R. T. Rockafellar, and R. Wets. A characterization of epi-convergence in terms of convergence of level sets. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 116(3): , [11] A. Ben-Tal, L. El Ghaoui, and A. Nemirovski. Robust Optimization. Princeton University Press,

Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification

Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification Lopsided Convergence: an Extension and its Quantification Johannes O. Royset Operations Research Department Naval Postgraduate School Monterey, California, USA joroyset@nps.edu Roger J-B Wets Department

More information

Optimality Functions and Lopsided Convergence

Optimality Functions and Lopsided Convergence Optimality Functions and Lopsided Convergence Johannes O. Royset Operations Research Department Naval Postgraduate School joroyset@nps.edu Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics University of California,

More information

VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY

VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY SIAM J. OPTIM. Vol. 27, No. 2, pp. 1118 1149 c 2017 Work carried out by an employee of the US Government VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY JOHANNES O. ROYSET AND ROGER J.-B.

More information

Keywords. 1. Introduction.

Keywords. 1. Introduction. Journal of Applied Mathematics and Computation (JAMC), 2018, 2(11), 504-512 http://www.hillpublisher.org/journal/jamc ISSN Online:2576-0645 ISSN Print:2576-0653 Statistical Hypo-Convergence in Sequences

More information

COSMIC CONVERGENCE. R.T. Rockafellar Departments of Mathematics and Applied Mathematics University of Washington, Seattle

COSMIC CONVERGENCE. R.T. Rockafellar Departments of Mathematics and Applied Mathematics University of Washington, Seattle COSMIC CONVERGENCE R.T. Rockafellar Departments of Mathematics and Applied Mathematics University of Washington, Seattle Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics and Institute of Theoretical Dynamics University

More information

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q)

On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) On Semicontinuity of Convex-valued Multifunctions and Cesari s Property (Q) Andreas Löhne May 2, 2005 (last update: November 22, 2005) Abstract We investigate two types of semicontinuity for set-valued

More information

MULTIVARIATE EPI-SPLINES AND EVOLVING FUNCTION IDENTIFICATION PROBLEMS

MULTIVARIATE EPI-SPLINES AND EVOLVING FUNCTION IDENTIFICATION PROBLEMS MULTIVARIATE EPI-SPLINES AND EVOLVING FUNCTION IDENTIFICATION PROBLEMS Johannes O. Royset Operations Research Department Naval Postgraduate School joroyset@nps.edu Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics

More information

Epiconvergence and ε-subgradients of Convex Functions

Epiconvergence and ε-subgradients of Convex Functions Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 1 (1994), No.1, 87 100 Epiconvergence and ε-subgradients of Convex Functions Andrei Verona Department of Mathematics, California State University Los Angeles, CA 90032,

More information

Introduction to Correspondences

Introduction to Correspondences Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Introduction to Correspondences KC Border September 2010 Revised November 2013 In these particular notes, all spaces are metric spaces. The set of extended

More information

Semicontinuities of Multifunctions and Functions

Semicontinuities of Multifunctions and Functions Chapter 4 Semicontinuities of Multifunctions and Functions The notion of the continuity of functions is certainly well known to the reader. This topological notion plays an important role also for multifunctions.

More information

REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE

REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE Form Approved OMB NO. 0704-0188 The public reporting burden for this collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per response, including the time for reviewing instructions,

More information

VARIATIONAL CONVERGENCE OF BIFUNCTIONS: MOTIVATING APPLICATIONS

VARIATIONAL CONVERGENCE OF BIFUNCTIONS: MOTIVATING APPLICATIONS VARIATIONAL CONVERGENCE OF BIFUNCTIONS: MOTIVATING APPLICATIONS Alejandro Jofré CMM and DIM Universidad de Chile, Santiago ajofre@dim.uchile.cl Roger J-B Wets Department of Mathematics University of California,

More information

On duality theory of conic linear problems

On duality theory of conic linear problems On duality theory of conic linear problems Alexander Shapiro School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, Georgia 3332-25, USA e-mail: ashapiro@isye.gatech.edu

More information

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces

Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Optimization and Optimal Control in Banach Spaces Bernhard Schmitzer October 19, 2017 1 Convex non-smooth optimization with proximal operators Remark 1.1 (Motivation). Convex optimization: easier to solve,

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo January 29, 2012 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications

Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications Subdifferential representation of convex functions: refinements and applications Joël Benoist & Aris Daniilidis Abstract Every lower semicontinuous convex function can be represented through its subdifferential

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation

Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Translative Sets and Functions and their Applications to Risk Measure Theory and Nonlinear Separation Andreas H. Hamel Abstract Recently defined concepts such as nonlinear separation functionals due to

More information

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions

Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions Local strong convexity and local Lipschitz continuity of the gradient of convex functions R. Goebel and R.T. Rockafellar May 23, 2007 Abstract. Given a pair of convex conjugate functions f and f, we investigate

More information

Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of his 70th birthday

Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of his 70th birthday VARIATIONAL GEOMETRIC APPROACH TO GENERALIZED DIFFERENTIAL AND CONJUGATE CALCULI IN CONVEX ANALYSIS B. S. MORDUKHOVICH 1, N. M. NAM 2, R. B. RECTOR 3 and T. TRAN 4. Dedicated to Michel Théra in honor of

More information

AW -Convergence and Well-Posedness of Non Convex Functions

AW -Convergence and Well-Posedness of Non Convex Functions Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 10 (2003), No. 2, 351 364 AW -Convergence Well-Posedness of Non Convex Functions Silvia Villa DIMA, Università di Genova, Via Dodecaneso 35, 16146 Genova, Italy villa@dima.unige.it

More information

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. Minimization Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. 1 Minimization A Topological Result. Let S be a topological

More information

Document downloaded from: This paper must be cited as:

Document downloaded from:  This paper must be cited as: Document downloaded from: http://hdl.handle.net/10251/50602 This paper must be cited as: Pedraza Aguilera, T.; Rodríguez López, J.; Romaguera Bonilla, S. (2014). Convergence of fuzzy sets with respect

More information

A projection-type method for generalized variational inequalities with dual solutions

A projection-type method for generalized variational inequalities with dual solutions Available online at www.isr-publications.com/jnsa J. Nonlinear Sci. Appl., 10 (2017), 4812 4821 Research Article Journal Homepage: www.tjnsa.com - www.isr-publications.com/jnsa A projection-type method

More information

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 29, No. 3, August 2004, pp. 479 491 issn 0364-765X eissn 1526-5471 04 2903 0479 informs doi 10.1287/moor.1040.0103 2004 INFORMS Some Properties of the Augmented

More information

Optimality, identifiability, and sensitivity

Optimality, identifiability, and sensitivity Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Optimality, identifiability, and sensitivity D. Drusvyatskiy A. S. Lewis Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract Around a solution of an optimization

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo September 6, 2011 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

A Geometric Framework for Nonconvex Optimization Duality using Augmented Lagrangian Functions

A Geometric Framework for Nonconvex Optimization Duality using Augmented Lagrangian Functions A Geometric Framework for Nonconvex Optimization Duality using Augmented Lagrangian Functions Angelia Nedić and Asuman Ozdaglar April 15, 2006 Abstract We provide a unifying geometric framework for the

More information

Maximal Monotone Inclusions and Fitzpatrick Functions

Maximal Monotone Inclusions and Fitzpatrick Functions JOTA manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Maximal Monotone Inclusions and Fitzpatrick Functions J. M. Borwein J. Dutta Communicated by Michel Thera. Abstract In this paper, we study maximal

More information

Zangwill s Global Convergence Theorem

Zangwill s Global Convergence Theorem Zangwill s Global Convergence Theorem A theory of global convergence has been given by Zangwill 1. This theory involves the notion of a set-valued mapping, or point-to-set mapping. Definition 1.1 Given

More information

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε 1. Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games 6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Asu Ozdaglar MIT February 25, 2010 1 Introduction Outline Uniqueness of a Pure Nash Equilibrium for Continuous Games Reading: Rosen J.B., Existence

More information

RANDOM APPROXIMATIONS IN STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING - A SURVEY

RANDOM APPROXIMATIONS IN STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING - A SURVEY Random Approximations in Stochastic Programming 1 Chapter 1 RANDOM APPROXIMATIONS IN STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING - A SURVEY Silvia Vogel Ilmenau University of Technology Keywords: Stochastic Programming, Stability,

More information

Strongly convex functions, Moreau envelopes and the generic nature of convex functions with strong minimizers

Strongly convex functions, Moreau envelopes and the generic nature of convex functions with strong minimizers University of Wollongong Research Online Faculty of Engineering and Information Sciences - Papers: Part B Faculty of Engineering and Information Sciences 206 Strongly convex functions, Moreau envelopes

More information

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06

A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 A SET OF LECTURE NOTES ON CONVEX OPTIMIZATION WITH SOME APPLICATIONS TO PROBABILITY THEORY INCOMPLETE DRAFT. MAY 06 CHRISTIAN LÉONARD Contents Preliminaries 1 1. Convexity without topology 1 2. Convexity

More information

Maths 212: Homework Solutions

Maths 212: Homework Solutions Maths 212: Homework Solutions 1. The definition of A ensures that x π for all x A, so π is an upper bound of A. To show it is the least upper bound, suppose x < π and consider two cases. If x < 1, then

More information

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM

CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM CHAPTER I THE RIESZ REPRESENTATION THEOREM We begin our study by identifying certain special kinds of linear functionals on certain special vector spaces of functions. We describe these linear functionals

More information

Product metrics and boundedness

Product metrics and boundedness @ Applied General Topology c Universidad Politécnica de Valencia Volume 9, No. 1, 2008 pp. 133-142 Product metrics and boundedness Gerald Beer Abstract. This paper looks at some possible ways of equipping

More information

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han Set, functions and Euclidean space Seungjin Han September, 2018 1 Some Basics LOGIC A is necessary for B : If B holds, then A holds. B A A B is the contraposition of B A. A is sufficient for B: If A holds,

More information

Some Background Material

Some Background Material Chapter 1 Some Background Material In the first chapter, we present a quick review of elementary - but important - material as a way of dipping our toes in the water. This chapter also introduces important

More information

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics EPI-DIFFERENTIABILITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS FOR AN EXTREMAL PROBLEM UNDER INCLUSION CONSTRAINTS T. AMAHROQ, N. GADHI AND PR H. RIAHI Université

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.st] 21 Jan 2018

arxiv: v2 [math.st] 21 Jan 2018 Maximum a Posteriori Estimators as a Limit of Bayes Estimators arxiv:1611.05917v2 [math.st] 21 Jan 2018 Robert Bassett Mathematics Univ. California, Davis rbassett@math.ucdavis.edu Julio Deride Mathematics

More information

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION HALUK ERGIN AND TODD SARVER Abstract. Suppose (i) X is a separable Banach space, (ii) C is a convex subset of X that is a Baire space (when endowed

More information

ZERO DUALITY GAP FOR CONVEX PROGRAMS: A GENERAL RESULT

ZERO DUALITY GAP FOR CONVEX PROGRAMS: A GENERAL RESULT ZERO DUALITY GAP FOR CONVEX PROGRAMS: A GENERAL RESULT EMIL ERNST AND MICHEL VOLLE Abstract. This article addresses a general criterion providing a zero duality gap for convex programs in the setting of

More information

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets Definition. An initial segment is {n N n n 0 }. Definition. A finite set can be put into one-to-one correspondence with an initial segment. The empty set is also considered

More information

WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY

WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY WHY SATURATED PROBABILITY SPACES ARE NECESSARY H. JEROME KEISLER AND YENENG SUN Abstract. An atomless probability space (Ω, A, P ) is said to have the saturation property for a probability measure µ on

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

Convex Optimization Notes

Convex Optimization Notes Convex Optimization Notes Jonathan Siegel January 2017 1 Convex Analysis This section is devoted to the study of convex functions f : B R {+ } and convex sets U B, for B a Banach space. The case of B =

More information

Could Nash equilibria exist if the payoff functions are not quasi-concave?

Could Nash equilibria exist if the payoff functions are not quasi-concave? Could Nash equilibria exist if the payoff functions are not quasi-concave? (Very preliminary version) Bich philippe Abstract In a recent but well known paper (see [11]), Reny has proved the existence of

More information

VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY

VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 VARIATIONAL THEORY FOR OPTIMIZATION UNDER STOCHASTIC AMBIGUITY JOHANNES O. ROYSET AND ROGER J-B WETS Abstract. Stochastic ambiguity provides a rich

More information

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory

Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Empirical Processes: General Weak Convergence Theory Moulinath Banerjee May 18, 2010 1 Extended Weak Convergence The lack of measurability of the empirical process with respect to the sigma-field generated

More information

Yuqing Chen, Yeol Je Cho, and Li Yang

Yuqing Chen, Yeol Je Cho, and Li Yang Bull. Korean Math. Soc. 39 (2002), No. 4, pp. 535 541 NOTE ON THE RESULTS WITH LOWER SEMI-CONTINUITY Yuqing Chen, Yeol Je Cho, and Li Yang Abstract. In this paper, we introduce the concept of lower semicontinuous

More information

What to remember about metric spaces

What to remember about metric spaces Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences What to remember about metric spaces KC Border These notes are (I hope) a gentle introduction to the topological concepts used in economic theory. If the

More information

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness CHAPTER 7 Connectedness 7.1. Connected topological spaces Definition 7.1. A topological space (X, T X ) is said to be connected if there is no continuous surjection f : X {0, 1} where the two point set

More information

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Main Definitions We start with providing the central definitions of convex functions and convex sets. Definition 1. A function f : R n R + } is called convex,

More information

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces

Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces Continuity of convex functions in normed spaces In this chapter, we consider continuity properties of real-valued convex functions defined on open convex sets in normed spaces. Recall that every infinitedimensional

More information

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract Pure strategy dominance with quasiconcave utility functions Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam Abstract By a result of Pearce (1984), in a finite strategic form game, the set of a player's serially

More information

Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control

Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control Duality and dynamics in Hamilton-Jacobi theory for fully convex problems of control RTyrrell Rockafellar and Peter R Wolenski Abstract This paper describes some recent results in Hamilton- Jacobi theory

More information

Identifying Active Constraints via Partial Smoothness and Prox-Regularity

Identifying Active Constraints via Partial Smoothness and Prox-Regularity Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 11 (2004), No. 2, 251 266 Identifying Active Constraints via Partial Smoothness and Prox-Regularity W. L. Hare Department of Mathematics, Simon Fraser University, Burnaby,

More information

A Unified Analysis of Nonconvex Optimization Duality and Penalty Methods with General Augmenting Functions

A Unified Analysis of Nonconvex Optimization Duality and Penalty Methods with General Augmenting Functions A Unified Analysis of Nonconvex Optimization Duality and Penalty Methods with General Augmenting Functions Angelia Nedić and Asuman Ozdaglar April 16, 2006 Abstract In this paper, we study a unifying framework

More information

Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class

Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class Introduction to Convex Analysis Microeconomics II - Tutoring Class Professor: V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha TA: Cinthia Konichi April 2010 1 Basic Concepts and Results This is a first glance on basic convex

More information

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M. COMPACTNESS If C R n is closed and bounded, then by B-W it is sequentially compact: any sequence of points in C has a subsequence converging to a point in C Conversely, any sequentially compact C R n is

More information

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints. 1 Optimization Mathematical programming refers to the basic mathematical problem of finding a maximum to a function, f, subject to some constraints. 1 In other words, the objective is to find a point,

More information

Approximation Metrics for Discrete and Continuous Systems

Approximation Metrics for Discrete and Continuous Systems University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Departmental Papers (CIS) Department of Computer & Information Science May 2007 Approximation Metrics for Discrete Continuous Systems Antoine Girard University

More information

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA address:

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA  address: Topology Xiaolong Han Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA E-mail address: Xiaolong.Han@csun.edu Remark. You are entitled to a reward of 1 point toward a homework

More information

Two-Term Disjunctions on the Second-Order Cone

Two-Term Disjunctions on the Second-Order Cone Noname manuscript No. (will be inserted by the editor) Two-Term Disjunctions on the Second-Order Cone Fatma Kılınç-Karzan Sercan Yıldız the date of receipt and acceptance should be inserted later Abstract

More information

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits (October 3, 2017) 02. Measure and integral Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/real/notes 2017-18/02 measure and integral.pdf]

More information

Contents. Index... 15

Contents. Index... 15 Contents Filter Bases and Nets................................................................................ 5 Filter Bases and Ultrafilters: A Brief Overview.........................................................

More information

SOME REMARKS ON SUBDIFFERENTIABILITY OF CONVEX FUNCTIONS

SOME REMARKS ON SUBDIFFERENTIABILITY OF CONVEX FUNCTIONS Applied Mathematics E-Notes, 5(2005), 150-156 c ISSN 1607-2510 Available free at mirror sites of http://www.math.nthu.edu.tw/ amen/ SOME REMARKS ON SUBDIFFERENTIABILITY OF CONVEX FUNCTIONS Mohamed Laghdir

More information

Introduction and Preliminaries

Introduction and Preliminaries Chapter 1 Introduction and Preliminaries This chapter serves two purposes. The first purpose is to prepare the readers for the more systematic development in later chapters of methods of real analysis

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Equilibria in Games with Weak Payoff Externalities

Equilibria in Games with Weak Payoff Externalities NUPRI Working Paper 2016-03 Equilibria in Games with Weak Payoff Externalities Takuya Iimura, Toshimasa Maruta, and Takahiro Watanabe October, 2016 Nihon University Population Research Institute http://www.nihon-u.ac.jp/research/institute/population/nupri/en/publications.html

More information

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem MS&E 336 Lecture 8: Supermodular games Ramesh Johari April 30, 2007 In this lecture, we develop the theory of supermodular games; key references are the papers of Topkis [7], Vives [8], and Milgrom and

More information

On Gap Functions for Equilibrium Problems via Fenchel Duality

On Gap Functions for Equilibrium Problems via Fenchel Duality On Gap Functions for Equilibrium Problems via Fenchel Duality Lkhamsuren Altangerel 1 Radu Ioan Boţ 2 Gert Wanka 3 Abstract: In this paper we deal with the construction of gap functions for equilibrium

More information

A PROOF OF A CONVEX-VALUED SELECTION THEOREM WITH THE CODOMAIN OF A FRÉCHET SPACE. Myung-Hyun Cho and Jun-Hui Kim. 1. Introduction

A PROOF OF A CONVEX-VALUED SELECTION THEOREM WITH THE CODOMAIN OF A FRÉCHET SPACE. Myung-Hyun Cho and Jun-Hui Kim. 1. Introduction Comm. Korean Math. Soc. 16 (2001), No. 2, pp. 277 285 A PROOF OF A CONVEX-VALUED SELECTION THEOREM WITH THE CODOMAIN OF A FRÉCHET SPACE Myung-Hyun Cho and Jun-Hui Kim Abstract. The purpose of this paper

More information

Non-reactive strategies in decision-form games

Non-reactive strategies in decision-form games MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Non-reactive strategies in decision-form games David Carfì and Angela Ricciardello University of Messina, University of California at Riverside 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/29262/

More information

On smoothness properties of optimal value functions at the boundary of their domain under complete convexity

On smoothness properties of optimal value functions at the boundary of their domain under complete convexity On smoothness properties of optimal value functions at the boundary of their domain under complete convexity Oliver Stein # Nathan Sudermann-Merx June 14, 2013 Abstract This article studies continuity

More information

Generalized metric properties of spheres and renorming of Banach spaces

Generalized metric properties of spheres and renorming of Banach spaces arxiv:1605.08175v2 [math.fa] 5 Nov 2018 Generalized metric properties of spheres and renorming of Banach spaces 1 Introduction S. Ferrari, J. Orihuela, M. Raja November 6, 2018 Throughout this paper X

More information

Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion

Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion Michel Théra LACO, UMR-CNRS 6090, Université de Limoges michel.thera@unilim.fr reporting joint work with E. Ernst and M. Volle

More information

Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization

Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization 72 CHAPTER 7 Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization 1. First Order Conditions In this section we consider first order optimality conditions for the constrained problem P : minimize f 0 (x)

More information

MATH 51H Section 4. October 16, Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous:

MATH 51H Section 4. October 16, Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous: MATH 51H Section 4 October 16, 2015 1 Continuity Recall what it means for a function between metric spaces to be continuous: Definition. Let (X, d X ), (Y, d Y ) be metric spaces. A function f : X Y is

More information

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics http://jipam.vu.edu.au/ Volume 2, Issue 1, Article 12, 2001 ON KY FAN S MINIMAX INEQUALITIES, MIXED EQUILIBRIUM PROBLEMS AND HEMIVARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES

More information

Mathematical Methods in Economics (Part I) Lecture Note

Mathematical Methods in Economics (Part I) Lecture Note Mathematical Methods in Economics (Part I) Lecture Note Kai Hao Yang 09/03/2018 Contents 1 Basic Topology and Linear Algebra 4 1.1 Review of Metric Space and Introduction of Topological Space........ 4

More information

Filters in Analysis and Topology

Filters in Analysis and Topology Filters in Analysis and Topology David MacIver July 1, 2004 Abstract The study of filters is a very natural way to talk about convergence in an arbitrary topological space, and carries over nicely into

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information

NONSMOOTH ANALYSIS AND PARAMETRIC OPTIMIZATION. R. T. Rockafellar*

NONSMOOTH ANALYSIS AND PARAMETRIC OPTIMIZATION. R. T. Rockafellar* NONSMOOTH ANALYSIS AND PARAMETRIC OPTIMIZATION R. T. Rockafellar* Abstract. In an optimization problem that depends on parameters, an important issue is the effect that perturbations of the parameters

More information

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 Christopher Heil Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces Last Updated: March 10, 2018 c 2018 by Christopher Heil Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces

More information

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1 ECONOMICS 594: LECTURE NOTES CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008. 1. Introduction Many economic problems have the following structure: (i) a linear function

More information

APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues

APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues APPENDIX C: Measure Theoretic Issues A general theory of stochastic dynamic programming must deal with the formidable mathematical questions that arise from the presence of uncountable probability spaces.

More information

WEAK LOWER SEMI-CONTINUITY OF THE OPTIMAL VALUE FUNCTION AND APPLICATIONS TO WORST-CASE ROBUST OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEMS

WEAK LOWER SEMI-CONTINUITY OF THE OPTIMAL VALUE FUNCTION AND APPLICATIONS TO WORST-CASE ROBUST OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEMS WEAK LOWER SEMI-CONTINUITY OF THE OPTIMAL VALUE FUNCTION AND APPLICATIONS TO WORST-CASE ROBUST OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEMS ROLAND HERZOG AND FRANK SCHMIDT Abstract. Sufficient conditions ensuring weak lower

More information

Statistical Estimation: Data & Non-data Information

Statistical Estimation: Data & Non-data Information Statistical Estimation: Data & Non-data Information Roger J-B Wets University of California, Davis & M.Casey @ Raytheon G.Pflug @ U. Vienna, X. Dong @ EpiRisk, G-M You @ EpiRisk. a little background Decision

More information

WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE

WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE Fixed Point Theory, Volume 6, No. 1, 2005, 59-69 http://www.math.ubbcluj.ro/ nodeacj/sfptcj.htm WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE YASUNORI KIMURA Department

More information

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convex Functions and Optimization Chapter 5 Convex Functions and Optimization 5.1 Convex Functions Our next topic is that of convex functions. Again, we will concentrate on the context of a map f : R n R although the situation can be generalized

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018 Supplement A: Mathematical background A.1 Extended real numbers The extended real number

More information

Jørgen Tind, Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Copenhagen, Universitetsparken 5, 2100 Copenhagen O, Denmark.

Jørgen Tind, Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Copenhagen, Universitetsparken 5, 2100 Copenhagen O, Denmark. DUALITY THEORY Jørgen Tind, Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Copenhagen, Universitetsparken 5, 2100 Copenhagen O, Denmark. Keywords: Duality, Saddle point, Complementary

More information

EXISTENCE OF PURE EQUILIBRIA IN GAMES WITH NONATOMIC SPACE OF PLAYERS. Agnieszka Wiszniewska Matyszkiel. 1. Introduction

EXISTENCE OF PURE EQUILIBRIA IN GAMES WITH NONATOMIC SPACE OF PLAYERS. Agnieszka Wiszniewska Matyszkiel. 1. Introduction Topological Methods in Nonlinear Analysis Journal of the Juliusz Schauder Center Volume 16, 2000, 339 349 EXISTENCE OF PURE EQUILIBRIA IN GAMES WITH NONATOMIC SPACE OF PLAYERS Agnieszka Wiszniewska Matyszkiel

More information

A Robust von Neumann Minimax Theorem for Zero-Sum Games under Bounded Payoff Uncertainty

A Robust von Neumann Minimax Theorem for Zero-Sum Games under Bounded Payoff Uncertainty A Robust von Neumann Minimax Theorem for Zero-Sum Games under Bounded Payoff Uncertainty V. Jeyakumar, G.Y. Li and G. M. Lee Revised Version: January 20, 2011 Abstract The celebrated von Neumann minimax

More information

MA651 Topology. Lecture 10. Metric Spaces.

MA651 Topology. Lecture 10. Metric Spaces. MA65 Topology. Lecture 0. Metric Spaces. This text is based on the following books: Topology by James Dugundgji Fundamental concepts of topology by Peter O Neil Linear Algebra and Analysis by Marc Zamansky

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information