The Efficacy of the Invisible Hand in Simple Models

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "The Efficacy of the Invisible Hand in Simple Models"

Transcription

1 Contemporary Issues and Ideas in Social Sciences December 2008 The Efficacy of the Invisible Hand in Simple Models Anjan Mukherji 1 Centre for Economic Studies and Planning Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi Abstract The paper shows how specifying economic models enables us to obtain simpler forms of stability conditions. A general form of stability result obtained in Mukherji (2007) is applied to simple three good models with a single produced 1 I am indebted to Professor K. L. Krishna, who, in his capacity as the Editor of the Journal of Quantitative Economics, had provided the original impetus to prepare a survey of Non-Linear Dynamics in Economics for his journal and which appeared as Mukherji (2000). Professor Krishna was also kind enough to chair the Inaugural lecture delivered on February 17, 2006 where I had discussed a preliminary version of results reported here. A sketch of the main argument presented in this paper was prepared in response to Patnaik (2008) and presented at the Conference organized by IDEAs in August A more complete version was presented at the Conference organized by JNU-CIGI-NIPFP in Delhi in November The current version owes a lot to helpful comments from Subrata Guha, and a referee, which uncovered an omission; these are gratefully acknowledged. anjan@mail.jnu.ac.in

2 2 CIISS December 2008 good, labour and a numeraire commodity; such models are routinely used in many contexts. In particular it is shown that restrictive assumptions need not be employed to ensure stability. Further the meaning of stability discussions and their significance and relevance are discussed. 1 Introduction From the time of Adam Smith, there was a belief that the so called Invisible Hand, the market force, should be successful in attaining equilibrium or a matching of demand and supply. That this force was believed to be as mysterious and powerful as the Force which Luke Skywalker is supposed to have battled the odds with, is perhaps not very surprising. What is surprising however, is the almost complete neglect of this area by economic theorists. To briefly recapitulate, the problem was discussed by Walras in the 19th century (1874) but then he assumed the problem away; it was redefined by Hicks in Value and Capital in 1940 and later by Samuelson in the Foundations in 1950 s and subjected to searching and probing analyses by Arrow and Hurwicz and McKenzie in the early 1960 s 2 ; a masterly survey was produced by Takashi Negishi in 1962; but around the same time two papers, one by Scarf (1960) and the other by Gale (1963), showed that things were not as satisfactory as they might have been taken to be. Briefly the situation was as follows: if demand and supply do not match, it was entirely expected that prices would adjust in the direction of excess demand (which is demand - supply) and would thus remove any vestige of mismatch. Even to this day, a sudden spurt of demand is associated with a 2 The paper by McKenzie (1960), contained the most general treatment of the subject.

3 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 3 rise in prices. The intuitive appeal of this story is however far more strong than its actual effectiveness. In fact, a commentator no less eminent than Edmond Malinvaud in 1993, while celebrating 40 years of the proof of existence of competitive equilibrium would indicate that this was one of failures of economic theory. This tendency of considering economic policies based on the workings of the Invisible Hand had been questioned by theorists of the stature of Frank Hahn (1984), (p. 308): Now one of the mysteries which future historians of thought will surely wish to unravel is how it came about that the Arrow- Debreu Model came to be taken descriptively; that is as sufficient in itself for the study and control of actual economies. But now with the clear winner amongst economic doctrines being the competitive markets and their working, it was even more inexplicable that very few undertook a close scrutiny of the conditions under which competitive markets work; in fact economists such as Sen (1999) (p. 112) advocated, The need for critical scrutiny of the standard preconceptions and political-economic attitudes have never been stronger. And the strange and unresolved question of the stability of competitive equilibrium, the effectiveness of the Invisible Hand in Motion was never re-examined! There were several reasons why the study of stability problems was in disrepute. A strong contender for the primary position amongst them was the question of the manner in which the equation of motion of the invisible hand was written. The equation of motion was represented as a system of differential equations of the type: ṗ = Φ(Z(p)) where p, Z(p) represent prices and excess demands respectively and Φ(.) is

4 4 CIISS December 2008 some sign-preserving function. It was difficult to see whose behavior was being described by these equations and why that person or decision maker was behaving in such a fashion. The answer that this was how the Invisible Hand worked, although was found acceptable during the time of Smith did not find too many takers in recent times. Fortunately, the recent experiments of Charles Plott of Caltech and his associates tackled this question directly 3 : Experimentalists have discovered that classical models, which are based on an assumption of tatonnement, have remarkable explanatory power even when applied to the non-tatonnement, continuous, double auction markets. The classical tatonnement is precisely what we have defined just now. Consequently, given the results of the experiments conducted by Plott and his associates, we may address ourselves to the analysis of the classical tatonnement, even though we are not sure whose behavior is being analyzed; thanks to the experimental results, we know that this analysis will be a good predictor of what to expect. As we have mentioned above, the primary point of concern about the classical tatonnement lay in the paucity of results: these were difficult to come by and involved restrictions which appeared to be unwarranted. Technically speaking, what was at stake was the convergence of the solution to the system defined earlier 4. Before we start looking at the convergence, it is best to mention that the 3 See Anderson et. al.(2004) and Hirota et. al. (2005), Divergence, Closed Cycles and Convergence in Scarf Environments: Experiments in the Dynamics of General Equilibrium Systems, Caltech Working Paper. 4 I should say that the motion could be thought of as being in discrete time as well, but we shall confine ourselves to the continuous time version of the Invisible Hand: it makes good sense to keep the steps of the Invisible Hand invisible as well.

5 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 5 classical tatonnement was introduced by Walras and essentially involved two things: first that price movement was in the direction of excess demand and second that transactions occur only at equilibrium so that along the path of price adjustment, no transactions took place. We have shown elsewhere 5 that it is possible to relax both of these conditions and still consider the convergence to equilibrium. I shall confine attention to the classical tatonnment, below. It may be important to recall that during the mid-seventies, a series of papers by Sonnenschein and Debreu established that almost any set of functions which satisfied the restrictions of Walras Law and Homogeneity of degree zero could be obtained as excess demand functions for an appropriate economy. These two properties of excess demand functions were not restrictive enough. This was the first type of result which has been termed to belong to the class of Anything Goes results in the literature. But examples of instability were there from the very beginning. Thus it was not possible to infer anything meaningful from the assumptions of rational behavior by decision makers: the source of meaningful theorems that Samuelson had advocated in the Foundations, proved to be woefully inadequate in this respect. In fact, this lack of generality of results was not peculiar to the stability problem; many developments in different branches of economic theory were dependent on special forms and restrictions as well. The only difference that I can find is that in these other theoretical developments, no one ever owned up to the fact that their conclusions depended on there being a straight line demand curve or on a special form of the utility function; on the contrary, in the area of general equilibrium, which was primarily responsible for analysing 5 Mukherji (1995), (1990).

6 6 CIISS December 2008 the workings of the Invisible Hand, researchers were trying to show how special the theory was and how careful one must be to draw the correct inferences. This spirit led me to investigate whether any set of meaningful economic conditions could be identified as being necessary for the stability of equilibrium; such conditions were found and the fact that these are substantial requirements were noted 6 ; it is only relatively recently 7 that the result was rescued from its mimeographed and privately circulated status. There is another reason for general results being scarce; this has to do with the state of mathematics for the system of differential equations that we wrote down; a problem has been that economists generally conceive of their domain of discussion as one involving n variables; and to be respectable, one must not specify what n should be except to say that n 2. However, one must be careful with higher dimensions: this is because of the results of Stephen Smale, recipient of the Fields Medal 8 who showed that if the system of differential equations involved three equations, or more, then rather arbitrary behavior is possible in the sense that the attractors, the sets to which the solutions converge, could be arbitrary. This fact is often neglected by economists who treat dynamic results in lower dimensions with disdain. There is yet another problem that needs to be overcome viz. that of nonlinearity of the functions concerned; excess demand functions must necessarily be non-linear: this follows from the Walras Law. Even the straightforward forms of non-linearity in a differential equation system may lead to very complicated dynamics Consider, for example the equations defining the so 6 Mukherji (1989). 7 See, McKenzie (2002), p Smale was awarded a Fields Medal at the International Congress at Moscow in 1966.

7 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 7 Figure 1: The Rössler Attractor called Rössler Attractor: ẋ ẏ z = where σ, r, b are positive constants. y z x + σy rx bz xz The solution to the above system has a very complicated long-term behavior 9. See for example the Figure 1 where the values σ = 0.36, r = 0.4, b = 4.5 have been used. Notice that the extent of non-linearity is quite mild: the 9 Notice that there is no convergence to an equilibrium and limiting configurations are complicated in nature: such limiting configurations fall in the category of what are called strange attractors.

8 8 CIISS December 2008 non-linear term appearing only in one equation. This is a well known system and the attractor is called the Rössler Attractor. Thus on the basis of dynamical systems alone, we have another source of Anything Goes. On several counts, therefore, general results are not possible. It appears that these aspects have not been as well appreciated as they ought to have been. 2 Preliminary Considerations: The Single Market To motivate our analysis, we consider first of all, the case of two goods so that there is a single market. In a single market, the notion of a locally stable equilibrium is identified with the slope of the excess demand curve being negative at the equilibrium. But there does not seem to be any easy identification of global stability with any property even in such a simple setup. Consider the following example due to Gale (1963). There are two persons A,B with utility functions defined over commodities (x, y) as follows: U A (x, y) = min(x, 2y) and U B (x, y) = min(2x, y); their endowments are specified by w A = (1, 0), w B = (0, 1); routine computations lead to the excess demand function of the first good (x), Z(p), where p is the relative price of good x: Z(p) = p 1 (p + 2)(2p + 1) Thus the unique interior equilibrium is given by p = 1 10 ; now notice that if 10 There is an equilibrium at infinity; see for example, Figure 2.

9 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 9 Figure 2: Excess Demand - The Gale Example the adjustment on prices is given by ṗ = h(p) (1) where h(p) has the same sign as Z(p) and is continuously differentiable, then the solution to (1) say p t (p o ) is well defined for any initial point p o > 0. As Gale (1963) says, Arrow and Hurwicz have shown that for the case of two goods, one always has global stability... Nevertheless, some queer things can happen even in this case. To see the queer things referred to, consider the function 11 V (p t ) = (p t 1) 2 and notice that along the solution to the equation (1), we have V (t) > 0 for all t, if p o 1: so that the price moves further away from equilibrium and there is no tendency to approach the unique equilibrium. Consequently, even for two goods or the single market case, we need to identify conditions which will help us rule out such cases. Alternatively, a look at Figure 2 should convince us that the unique in- 11 Notice that this is just the square of the distance from equilibrium.

10 10 CIISS December 2008 Figure 3: Excess Demand under α and β terior equilibrium is unstable under the usual adjustment of prices. How do we rule out such situations? As an illustration of our analysis below, consider the following assumptions for the single market (two-good case) 12 : α: Z x (p), Z y (p) are continuous functions of p for all p > 0 and satisfies Walras Law viz., pz x (p) + Z y (p) = 0, p > 0; further lim p 0 Z x (p) > 0; similarly, lim p Z y (p) > 0. It is easy to check that condition α implies that the set of equilibria E = {p > 0 : Z x (p) = 0} is non-empty 13. Moreover, if Z x (p) is differentiable, then there must exist at least one p E such that Z x(p ) < 0: that is there must be at least one locally stable equilibrium. For global stability considerations however, we must proceed further. β: p E Z x(p) We shall write Z x (p), Z y (p) as the excess demand functions for the two goods x, y respectively with p being the relative price of good x. 13 See, for instance Mukherji (2002), p. 16.

11 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 11 Figure 4: Excess Demand for the Gale Example with a switch in endowments With conditions α, β however, we can show the following: first of all, there are only a finite number of points in E and secondly, for any p o > 0, p t (p o ) p E for some p E: this may be considered to be the counterpart of global stability when there are multiple equilibria. Thus the situation will be as in Figure 3, then. Thus one may say that overall the excess demand curve is downward sloping: since it begins from somewhere near the vertical axis and ends up below the horizontal axis. It should be noted that the boundary condition in α enforces the fact that excess demand functions have a negative slope most of the time; this is enough for global stability. We also know that the negative slope of excess demand function may be related to a Law of Demand; thus this condition, that excess demand functions be mainly downward sloping, may seem to

12 12 CIISS December 2008 be a generalization. We shall investigate below whether it will be possible to extend these conditions to cover the case when there are two or more markets. There is one other aspect of the Gale example we should note; suppose for example, we interchange the endowments i.e., A has (0, 1) while B has (1, 0); recomputing excess demand functions, we note that the situation is as in Figure 4: the unique interior equilibrium is now globally stable. One may therefore say that we had instability of the interior equilibrium because the distribution of purchasing power had not been right previously. Now, both α, β are met and excess demand curve becomes downward sloping. 3 General Global Stability Conditions In our search for natural or meaningful stability conditions, our discussion of the single market case leads us to the following conditions: If the excess demand curve is overall downward sloping, say as dictated by conditions α and β, in disequilibrium the prices will always move towards some equilibrium. Alternatively there may be some redistribution of purchasing power which might lead to a stable equilibrium. We shall see below how these can be extended to cover the two market case; recall that for larger dimensions, that is for more than two markets, stringent conditions need to be employed as indicated by Smale (1976). So to start afresh, in two dimensons, or on the plane, the basic adjustment process is given by, writing Z i (p) denotes the excess demand function for the

13 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 13 i-th good: ṗ i = φ i (Z i (p)), i = 1, 2 with p 3 1 (2) where φ i (Z i (p)).z i (p) > 0 whenever Z i (p) 0 and is 0 otherwise; thus a natural candidate for the function φ i (Z i ) = γ i Z i where γ i > 0 is a constant and is interpreted as the speed of adjustment in the i-th market. Also the choice of p 3 being fixed as unity reflects that the prices of goods in the first two markets are measured relative to the third good, the numeraire good. While considering the motion on the plane, a very strong result in differential equations theory becomes available: the Poincaré-Bendixson Theorem 14 which states that if the solution to (2) is bounded, i.e., remains within a bounded region, then it either approaches an equilibrium or cycles around an equilibrium. Basically then, if cycles are eliminated by some argument and if solutions are bounded, convergence to equilibrium follows. It is a pity that this result is valid only for motion on the plane or for our case, the situation with two markets. We mention here the results obtained in Mukherji (2007), which enable one to carry out the task described in the last paragraph. The condition 15 envisaged is the following: There is a differentiable function θ(p) : R 2 ++ R and such that div(θ(p)φ 1 (p), θ(p)φ 2 (p)) is not identically zero on R 2 nor does it change sign on R 2 where div(θ(p)φ 1 (p), θ(p)φ 2 (p)) = θ(p)φ 1(p) p 1 14 See, for example Hirsch and Smale (1974). 15 This condition is known as Dulac s Condition. + θ(p)φ 2(p) p 2.

14 14 CIISS December 2008 If one can find such a function θ, there can be no cycles. At an equilibrium therefore: θ(p)φ 1 (p) p 1 + θ(p)φ 2(p) p 2 = θ(p)[ φ 1(p) p 1 + φ 2(p) p 2 ] which has the sign of θ(p)(z 11 (p) + Z 22 (p)) this follows because of the sign restriction on the function φ i, the partial derivatives of the functions φ i and Z i should be identical at equilibrium. Recall too at this juncture that Z ii (p) is the same thing as the slope of the excess demand curve in the case of the single market and under conditions such as α and β there would be some equilibrium; moreover, there would be an equilibrium where the slope is negative. Further if in fact there is a function θ which satisfies the above, then so does θ and we may hence take θ to be positive, if indeed there is such a function. Consequently, the above condition would reduce to requiring that div(θ(p)φ 1 (p), θ(p)φ 2 (p)) < 0, everywhere: which is the generalization of the requirement that excess demand curve be downward sloping. Remember that we still need to keep the solution in some bounded region: this too be can be ensured by requiring that φ i (Z i (p)) Z i (p) for example and all requirements are met. The interested reader may refer to Mukherji (2007) for proofs. We note that this same paper contains an example of such a θ function which is used to prove stability in the case of Scarf s example, when endowments are perturbed. However notice that we have not made any specific assumptions about the nature of the economy which gives rise to such excess demand functions. What we shall do next is to make the model specific and as we hope to show, the nature of requirements become much simpler.

15 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 15 4 A Three Good Model with Production Let there be three goods: a consumption good denoted by x, labour l used to make the consumption good x via a production function x = f(l) where, to begin with, we shall assume that f (l) > 0, f (l) < 0 and a numeraire good y which is available in fixed quantity with household sector. There are two types of agents: households and firms; households as we have said own the numeraire and labor and they use these to buy the consumption good and numeraire; the firms produce the consumption good and spend their entire earnings on the numeraire. Thus firms maximize profits p.x wl subject to x = f(l) so that demand for labour is given by l d = f 1 (w/p), supply by x s = f(l d ) and profits by π = px s wl d. We may assume that the above is aggregate firm behavior with there being many firms, each having their own technology and similar looking labour demand and supply and profit functions. The households maximize: U h (x, y), an increasing strictly quasi-concave utility subject to the budget constraint p.x + y w.l h + y h o ; this leads to demand for the consumption good x h d(p, w) and hence the aggregate demand x h d (p, w) = x d (p, w) so that the excess demand in the consumption good market is given by Z x = x d x s ; in the labour market, the total supply of labour is l h = l is fixed so that excess demand in the labour market is given by Z l = l d l. Notice that the demand for the numeraire comes from households y h (p, w) and from firms π so that excess demand for the numeraire is given by Z y = h y h (p, w) + π h y h o. As a check observe that p.x h d(p, w)+y h (p, w) = w.l h +y h o h and that π = p.x s w.l d so that summing over all households and firms we have p. h x h d(p, w) + h y h (p, w) + π = w.( h l h l d ) + p.x s + h y h o p.z x + Z y + w.z l = 0 (p, w) > (0, 0). which

16 16 CIISS December 2008 of course is Walras Law. It should also be noted that the excess demand functions are homogenous of degree zero in all prices. We shall also require some restriction on the nature of these excess demand functions when (p, w) becomes very large and when they become very small; notice that this may be considered to be the counterpart of the condition (α) in the present context. If one may recall that apart from Walras Law and continuity of excess demand functions, and homogeneity of degree zero in all prices, their properties when relative prices approach zero, had to be specified. To do so now, it would be more convenient to use the notation (p 1, p 2, p 3 ) for the price system, where p 1 stands for p, p 2 for the wage rate w and p 3 for the price of the numeraire y; we shall choose the last to be unity in later considerations. (α ) Let P s = (p s 1, p s 2, p s 3) be some sequence such that for sp s i = 1 for some i and 16 P s + ; then Z i (P s ) +. Remark 1 Among other things, the above ensures that when some price (say p 1 ) goes to zero (and at least one does not), once can construct such a system P by dividing through out by p 1 ; the resultant P will become larger and larger, and excess demand for good 1 should then go to infinity. Reverting to our notation (p, w), (p 3 = 1) we may also conclude by virtue of the above that there is K 1 such that p > K 1 implies Z y (p, w) > 0; if no such K 1 exists, then we have a sequence (p s, w s ) such that p s + and Z y (p s, w s ) 0; consider the system P s = (p s, w s, 1) and this will directly contradict the assumption. We use the same argument to establish that there is some K 2 such that w > K 2 implies that Z y (p, w) > 0 and let K = max K i. We shall return to these considerations at a later point of time. 16 P = (p p p 2 3), if P = (p 1, p 2, p 3 )

17 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 17 Notice that if there is an equilibrium then Z l = 0 w/p = δ (3) since a downward sloping demand curve of labour reaches the level of full employment at a unique real wage. Consequently, the levels of w, p are then determined by the equilibrium in the goods market Z x = 0; further, in disequilibrium, we have: ṗ = γ 1 Z x (w, p) and ẇ = γ 2 Z l (w, p) (4) where γ i > 0, i = 1, 2. Notice that: Z x p Z xp = x dp x s p < 0; Z l w Z lw < 0; and Z lp > 0 assuming that consumption good is normal. Notice too that Z xw = x dw x s w where the second term is positive (including the - sign) while the first is positive. 4.1 Phase Diagrams We return to the general form of price adjustment equations contained in (2). We consider then, in the w p plane, the various combinations of w, p which would equilibrate the labour market i.e., Z l = 0 or w/p = δ. Notice too the regions where there is excess demand for labour (marked by +) and the region where there is excess supply of labour (marked with a -). A similar diagram for the goods market may also be constructed.

18 18 CIISS December 2008 w Figure 5: Excess Demand for Labour ø d + p Figure 6: Excess Demand for Goods + w Z x (w,p) = 0 ø p

19 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 19 When we put the two diagrams together, that is combine the Z l = 0 with Z x = 0 there are two possibilities, assuming that an equilibrium exits. Since the Z x = 0 is upward rising there may be two cases: one where at the intersection, the line Z x = 0 is steeper and one where the Z l = 0 line is steeper. We shall consider each of these cases below. However, first we need to establish that the equilibrium, if it exists will be unique. In the circumstances that equilibrium is non-unique there would be at least two points of intersection between the curves Z x = 0 and Z l = 0; or there would be two distinct configurations w 1, p 1 and w 2, p 2 such that w i /p i = δ and x d (w i, p i, 1) = f( l), the full employment output. Suppose then that p 1 > p 2 and consider the budget constraint: x + y p i = w i p i l h + yho p i = δl h + yho p i Thus we would expect that x h d(w 1, p 1, 1) < x h d(w 2, p 2, 1) for each h and hence it is not possible to have x d (w i, p i, 1) = f( l) and hence multiple equilibrium is not possible. Consider then putting Figure 5 together with Figure 6; recall that we have two possibilities. Consider first Figure 7, where the Z x = 0 curve is steeper than the Z l = 0 line at intersection. The arrows indicate the direction of price, wage movements in each sector of the diagram. Price movements are to read by the arrow parallel to the p axis and the wage movement is to be read by arrows parallel to the w axis. Notice that the region in between the two curves are such that price movement from these regions can never lead to prices outside the regions: consequently wage price revisions are such that equilibrium is attained. These regions are called absorbing states. From the remaining two regions, notice that wage price revisions lead to the absorbing states. Thus Equilibrium I depicts a globally stable equilibrium. It may

20 20 CIISS December 2008 Figure 7: Equilibrium I w Z x (w,p) =0 d p however be the case that we have the following Figure 8: Equilibrium II. Here the Z l = 0 line is steeper than the Z x = 0 line at equilibrium; the absorbing states disappear; in the regions trapped between the two curves, wage price movements are away from the equilibrium; however the wage price movements in the other two regions remain the same and wage price movement initiated from these regions take the economy to the region in between the two curves and hence away from equilibrium. However there is just one solution, from some initial points which lead to equilibrium. Equilibrium II depicts thus a saddle-point equilibrium; if initial conditions are right then equilibrium will be reached other wise solutions become unbounded. As we shall see below (α ) rules out such cases. To sum up, thus, without imposing additional restrictions of any kind, we have a globally stable equilibrium (Equilibrium I). In the case of

21 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 21 Figure 8: Equilibrium II w d Z x (w,p) =0 p Equilibrium II, the area above the δ ray and below the Z x = 0 curve contains the possibility of Z x < 0 when p 0 with w positive: but this is ruled out by α Firms are Privately owned Recall that in the above, the households did not receive income from profits and profit income was exclusively spent on the numeraire; while this may be of some interest, we need to consider the case when firms are privately owned so that each household h receives a share λ h π of profit income with λ h 0 h λ h = 1. With this modification, notice first of all that the budget constraint of each household changes to p.x + y w.l h + yo h + λ h π(p, w). Notice too this modification does not affect the claim that equilibrium is unique. This follows since along the δ-ray π(p, w) = pf( l) w l so that

22 22 CIISS December 2008 Figure 9: Excess Demands in the Goods Market w δ E p along this ray π/p is a constant. So the earlier argument for uniqueness may be repeated. We have then the following situation: Recall that along the δ-ray, π/p is constant; at E (p.w ), h x h (p.w ) = f( l); above E, p > p, h x h (δp, p) < f( l) so that Z x < 0 and similarly, below E, Z x > 0. This indicates the region where Z x = 0 must lie. But as should be clear this does not clinch matters; since we do not know whether the curve slopes up or down. It is possible to have Z xp > 0 or < 0; similarly for Z xw two possibilities arise; and thus there are four logically possible situations. This ambiguity stems from the fact that variation in p and w causes profit income to change and hence the phenomenon like the net sellers income effect comes into play. Clearly then the assumption α is not adequate. We need to impose some restriction in addition to deduce global stability. As we shall see, a version of overall downward sloping nature of excess demands will be helpful.

23 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 23 Remark 2 First we ensure that α is sufficient to ensure that the solution is bounded. As we see from Figure 9, irrespective of the position of the Z x = 0 line, along any solution to (4), neither p nor w can become zero. We proceed to demonstrate, following Mukherji (2007) that any solution to (4) must lie in a bounded region. Consider the arc drawn in Figure 9 to represent the equation p 2 /γ 1 + w 2 /γ 2 = M where M = 1 + K 2 /γ where K is as defined in Remark 1 and γ = min γ i ; then it must be the case that either p > K or w > K along the arc for otherwise p 2 /γ 1 + w 2 /γ 2 < M. Consider the function V (p, w) = p 2 /γ 1 + w 2 /γ 2. Thus along the arc, we must have V = 2[pZ x (p, w) + w.z l (p, w)] = 2Z y (p, w) < 0 the last inequality follows since along the arc, we have just shown that either p > K or w > K and then the conclusions noted in Remark 1 apply. Thus the solution must lie below the arc and hence in a bounded region. Consider next the following version of overall downward sloping excess demand: β : γ 1 Z xp (p, w) + γ 2 Z lw (p, w) is of the same sign on R 2 ++ and is not identically zero on R Remark 3 We do not restrict the sign of the expression in any manner; it could be non-positive on the entire region or non-negative over the entire region, and the only restrictions are that it is not identically zero nor does it change sign; as we shall soon see, this will imply that the sign must be negative at equilibrium. Which is why we refer to this as being a requirement that generally, excess demand curves are downward sloping. Now notice that we can immediately apply Dulac s criterion to conclude that there can be no cyclical orbit: choose θ = 1. The Poincaré-Bendixson Theorem now ensures that the only possibility is convergence to an equilibrium. This basically ensures that term in β must be negative at equilibrium:

24 24 CIISS December 2008 since otherwise we shall not be able to converge to it. This basically means that Z xp cannot be too positive, since Z lw < 0. Thus, as in the single market case, we have obtained a stability condition which may be interpreted in terms of slopes of excess demand functions. Specific examples may be constructed to show that even a weaker condition is enough by allowing choice of θ which is more complicated. If for example, Z xp < 0, as in the previous section notice that β is automatically satisfied. 4.2 The Case of Constant Returns to Scale In the last section, we assumed as is standard in such situations that the production function f(l) is strictly concave. What happens if the production occurs under constant returns to scale? To examine this variation, which is what Walras had originally assumed, we proceed below. In fact, because of constant returns to scale, profits are zero so that the scale of production is determined by the level of demand; so the notion of excess demand (demand - supply) is not really defined. Consequently, the earlier set-up describing the working of the Invisible Hand becomes inadmissible. Walras was naturally aware of this aspect and hence assumed that adjustment of prices took place in the factor markets. We shall show how this happens. Let f(l) = τl where τ > 0 is a constant; consequently profits are given by the expression p.τl wl = (p.τ w)l; thus w/p = τ to allow perfect competition to prevail with positive level of outputs; p = w/τ. There is no profit maximizing response and firms try to meet whatever is demanded. To determine demand, consider the budget constraint of each household, recalling that profits are zero: x + y/p = τl h ; or w.x + τy = w.τl h

25 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 25 specifying any w determines x h d(w) and hence the market demand x d (w) = h x h d(w) and hence the demand for labour is given by l d = x d (w)/τ; and excess demand in the labour market is now well defined by Z l = l d l; from the budget constraint, we can see, that assuming that the consumption good is normal, we have x h d (w) < 0 provided the income effect does not dominate; it follows that then Z l(w) < 0 and since we are back in a single market world, the equilibrium is globally stable. More importantly the condition that x h d (w) < 0 is the same as the condition for a single market equilibrium i.e., the net sellers income effect does not dominate. Thus consideration of constant returns to scale, makes matters simpler and we can conclude that the equilibrium is globally stable merely on the basis of say, the downward sloping nature of the excess demand curve for labour. Even the weaker α will also yield global stability. 5 Concluding Comments We have shown how the requirement of excess demand curve being on the whole downward sloping, in a single market (conditions α and β ) generalize to the case of two markets. We also show how imposing some structure like production eases conditions considerably 17 and we do not need to look around for some complicated function while searching for θ. At least in simple models, when profit income is spent entirely on the numeraire, a condition like α is sufficient to ensure that the Invisible Hand does work. But notice some such condition is always necessary. We have not covered the case of multiple (more than two) markets; this 17 This conclusion is in line with a study undertaken many years ago, Mukherji (1974).

26 26 CIISS December 2008 Figure 10: No Equilibrium I w d Z x (w,p) =0 p is because we know that this would require stringent restrictions due to the general conclusions by Smale (1976). However, we may report that in even in such cases, some progress has been achieved in arriving at restrictions on the distribution of purchasing power to ensure stability in Mukherji (2008). Two points need to be emphasized: one, a specific point relating to the production model and the other, a general point about any exercise of the type attempted here. First the specific item. It was taken for granted that an equilibrium exists in the production model of the last section. What happens if there is no equilibrium? Consider the Figure 10. Here the Z x = 0 lies below the Z l = 0; the arrows would indicate that wage price movements would lead to the middle region and which incidentally cannot be left. When the Z x = 0 lies above, (Figure 11) similarly one may show that that wage price movements go to zero or that the relative price of the numeraire becomes infinite.

27 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 27 Figure 11: No Equilibrium II w Z x (w,p) =0 d p These are the two situations when equilibrium does not exist. Basically in the first case, there is no reason for any one to hold the numeraire whereas in the second case there is no reason to hold any of the other goods and the model breaks down. In fact what we have is essentially a failure of condition α ; in the first case, as we have remarked above, dynamics is confined to the middle portion with both w, p increasing without bounds; thus even though the price of the numeraire (relative to any of the other goods) goes to zero, it has an excess supply. In the second case too, the middle region is attracting and here though p is approaching zero, there is excess supply. Notice then by insisting on a single condition α, we may rule out these cases. What happens if we try to identify the numeraire commodity with money? It is a fault of the model itself, if for example, one tries to identify the numeraire with money unless adequate safeguards (viz., condition α ) have

28 28 CIISS December 2008 been put in place to ensure that people wish to hold money as well as the other goods 18. Identifying the numeraire with money may require situating the model in a many period framework or alternatively ensuring that condition α is met. Secondly the general point about what does the process itself mean? Is it historical time that the Invisible Hand was supposed to function in? That is the time-derivatives that we see in say in equations (2), for example are derivatives with respect to historical time? This cannot be naturally; what then is t? It would be more sensible to consider this variable to be the number of bids by the unsuccessful agents when they realize that markets do not clear. In fact while solving such differential equations on the computer, convergence takes place quickly that is within a small number of bids, the difference between prices and equilibrium are negligible in convergent situations. Finally the experiments of Plott and associates should remove any doubt that one may have in analyzing such processes since the experiments have demonstrated beyond reasonable doubt, that the tatonnment is a very good predictor of how prices may move. Why this is so is not clear as yet. We hope an explanation will eventually emerge. 18 See, for example, the criticisms of Patnaik (2008) of mainstream economics. I would consider it more appropriate to direct the criticism towards inappropriate modeling.

29 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 29 References C. M. Anderson, S. Granat, C. R. Plott, K-I. Shimomura, (2004), Global Instability in Experimental General Equilibrium: The Scarf Example, J. Econ. Theory, 115, K. J. Arrow and L. Hurwicz, (1958), On the Stability of Competitive Equilibrium I, Econometrica, 26, G. Debreu (1974), Excess Demand Functions, J. Math. Econ. 1 (1974), D. Gale (1963), A Note on the Global Instability of Competitive Equilibrium, Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, F. H. Hahn (1984), Equilibrium and Macroeconomics, Basil Blackwell, Oxford. J. R. Hicks (1946), Value and Capital (2nd Edition), Clarendon Press, Oxford. M. Hirota, M. Hsu, C. Plott and B. Rogers (2005), Divergence, Closed Cycles and Convergence in Scarf Environments: Experiments in the Dynamics of General Equilibrium Systems, Caltech Social Science Working Paper, 1239, October M. W. Hirsch, S. Smale (1974), Differential Equations, Dynamical Systems and Linear Algebra, Academic Press, New York. L. W. McKenzie, (1960), Stability of Equilibrium and the Value of Positive Excess Demand, Econometrica, 28, L. W. McKenzie, (2002), Classical General Equilibrium Analysis, Princeton University Press, New Jersey. A. Mukherji, (1974), Stability in an Economy with Production, in Trade, Stability and Macroeconomics, Essays in honor of Lloyd Metzler eds., G. Horwich and P. A. Samuelson, Academic Press, New York,

30 30 CIISS December 2008 A. Mukherji, (1989), On Tatonnement Processes, Centre for Economic Studies and Planning Working Paper, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi. A. Mukherji, (1990), A Non-Tatonnement Process, in Economic Theory and Policy: Essays in honor of Professor D. Banerjee, (eds.), Debraj Ray et. al., Oxford University Press: Delhi. A. Mukherji, (1995), A Locally Stable Adjustment Process, Econometrica, 63, A. Mukherji (2000), Non-linear Dynamics with applications to economics: Stability of Competitive equilibrium reconsidered, Journal of Quantitative Economics 16, A. Mukherji (2002), An Introduction to General Equilibrium Analysis, Walrasian and Non-Walrasian Equilibria, Oxford University Press, Delhi. A. Mukherji (2007), Global Stability Conditions on the Plane: A General Law of Demand, Journal of Economic Theory Vol. 134, May 2007, A. Mukherji (2008), The Stability of a Competitive Economy: A Reconsideration, International Journal of Economic Theory, June 2008, Vol. 4, (Special Issue in honour of Takashi Negishi) T. Negishi (1962), Stability of a Competitive Economy, Econometrica, 30, P. Patnaik, (2008), The Value of Money, Tulika, Delhi and Columbia U. Press, New York. P. A. Samuelson (1947), Foundations of Economic Analysis, Harvard University Press: Cambridge, Mass. H. Scarf (1960), Some Examples of Global Instability of the Competitive Equilibrium, Int. Econ. Rev. 1, A. K. Sen (1999), Development as Freedom, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

31 Mukherji: Invisible Hand 31 S. Smale (1976), On the Differential Equations of Species in Competition, Journal of Mathematical Biology, 3, 5-7. H. Sonnenschein (1972), Market Excess Demand Functions, Econometrica, 40,

National Institute of Public Finance and Policy

National Institute of Public Finance and Policy The Second Fundamental Theorem of Positive Economics Anjan Mukherji Working Paper No: 2012-98 March- 2012 National Institute of Public Finance and Policy The Second Fundamental Theorem of Positive Economics

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Partial and General Equilibrium Giorgio Fagiolo giorgio.fagiolo@sssup.it http://www.lem.sssup.it/fagiolo/welcome.html LEM, Sant Anna School of Advanced Studies, Pisa (Italy) Part

More information

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation

Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation 18 th World IMACS / MODSIM Congress, Cairns, Australia 13-17 July 009 http://mssanz.org.au/modsim09 Scarf Instability and Production: A Simulation Fukiharu, T., K.Imamura Faculty of Economics, Hiroshima

More information

Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium Competitive Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 16, October 26 Outline 1 Pareto Effi ciency 2 The Core 3 Planner s Problem(s) 4 Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium Decentralized vs. Centralized Economic

More information

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions Chapter 1 Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions 1.1 Arrow-Debreu model of an economy via Walras equilibrium problem. Let us consider first the so-called Arrow-Debreu model. The presentation

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes

Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes Uniqueness, Stability, and Gross Substitutes Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 21, November 14 Outline 1 Uniquenness (in pictures) 2 Stability 3 Gross Substitute Property Uniqueness and Stability We have dealt

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Problem Set Suggested Answers Problem Set 3 --- Suggested Answers 1. In chapters 15 18 the treatment is generalized to unbounded production technologies, resulting in the observation that when general equilibrium prices are announced,

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

Slope Fields: Graphing Solutions Without the Solutions

Slope Fields: Graphing Solutions Without the Solutions 8 Slope Fields: Graphing Solutions Without the Solutions Up to now, our efforts have been directed mainly towards finding formulas or equations describing solutions to given differential equations. Then,

More information

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Abstract: This paper gives a non-fixed point theoretic proof of equilibrium existence when the excess demand function of an exchange

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations We ve shown that any Walrasian equilibrium allocation (any WEA) is in the core, but it s obvious that the converse is far from

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

1 Second Welfare Theorem

1 Second Welfare Theorem Econ 701B Fall 018 University of Pennsylvania Recitation : Second Welfare Theorem Xincheng Qiu (qiux@sas.upenn.edu) 1 Second Welfare Theorem Theorem 1. (Second Welfare Theorem) An economy E satisfies (A1)-(A4).

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth International Journal of Sciences: Basic and Applied Research (IJSBAR) ISSN 2307-453 (Print & Online) http://gssrr.org/index.php?journaljournalofbasicandapplied ---------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory Lecture 1 History of general equilibrium theory Adam Smith: The Wealth of Nations, 1776 many heterogeneous individuals with diverging interests many voluntary but uncoordinated actions (trades) results

More information

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad Unlinked llocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One ad Chiaki Hara Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University pril 16,

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Equilibrium in a Production Economy Equilibrium in a Production Economy Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2012 Sims (ND) Equilibrium in a Production Economy Fall 2012 1 / 23 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in

More information

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Opportunity Cost (or "Wow, I coulda had a V8!") The underlying idea is derived

More information

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes *

A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * A Reversal of Rybczynski s Comparative Statics via Anything Goes * Hugo F. Sonnenschein a and Marcus M. Opp b a Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 6 E. 59 th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 h-sonnenschein@uchicago.edu

More information

Chaotic Price Dynamics, Increasing Returns & the Phillips Curve. by Graciela Chichilnisky, Columbia University Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School

Chaotic Price Dynamics, Increasing Returns & the Phillips Curve. by Graciela Chichilnisky, Columbia University Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School Chaotic Price Dynamics, Increasing Returns & the Phillips Curve by Graciela Chichilnisky, Columbia University Geoffrey Heal, Columbia Business School Yun Lin, Columbia University March 1992, Revised February

More information

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture 1 B&W s derivation of the Phillips curve Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture Ragnar Nymoen University of Oslo, Department of Economics Ch 12.3: The Battle of the mark-ups as a framework

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Lecture Notes for January 23, 2012: Existence of general equilibrium in an economy with an excess demand function

Lecture Notes for January 23, 2012: Existence of general equilibrium in an economy with an excess demand function Lecture Notes for January 23, 2012: Existence of general equilibrium in an economy with an excess demand function The plan of the course for the next month is to create a model of a competitive economy

More information

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A December, 2016, Ted Bergstrom, UCSB I asked students to try to answer any 7 of the 8 questions. I intended the exam to have some relatively easy parts and

More information

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0}

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0} Economics 201B Second Half Lecture 10, 4/15/10 Debreu s Theorem on Determinacy of Equilibrium Definition 1 Let F : R L 1 + R LI + R L 1 be defined by F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω The Equilibrium

More information

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES Prerequisites Almost essential General equilibrium: Basics Useful, but optional General Equilibrium: Price Taking GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM: EXCESS DEMAND AND THE RÔLE OF PRICES MICROECONOMICS Principles and

More information

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction Microeconomic Theory -- Introduction. Introduction. Profit maximizing firm with monopoly power 6 3. General results on maximizing with two variables 8 4. Model of a private ownership economy 5. Consumer

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018) Recitation #2 (August 1st, 2018) 1. [Checking properties of the Cobb-Douglas utility function.] Consider the utility function u(x) = n i=1 xα i i, where x denotes a vector of n different goods x R n +,

More information

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu 1a The following is a Edgeworth box characterization of the Pareto optimal, and the individually rational Pareto optimal, along with some

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting The second section of Chapter 11 of Dornbusch (1980) draws on Dornbusch (1976) Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political

More information

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Economics 401 Sample questions 2 Economics 401 Sample questions 1. What does it mean to say that preferences fit the Gorman polar form? Do quasilinear preferences fit the Gorman form? Do aggregate demands based on the Gorman form have

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium Introduction to General Equilibrium Juan Manuel Puerta November 6, 2009 Introduction So far we discussed markets in isolation. We studied the quantities and welfare that results under different assumptions

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

MATH 415, WEEK 11: Bifurcations in Multiple Dimensions, Hopf Bifurcation

MATH 415, WEEK 11: Bifurcations in Multiple Dimensions, Hopf Bifurcation MATH 415, WEEK 11: Bifurcations in Multiple Dimensions, Hopf Bifurcation 1 Bifurcations in Multiple Dimensions When we were considering one-dimensional systems, we saw that subtle changes in parameter

More information

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses. Microeconomic Theory Summer 206-7 Mid-semester Exam 2 There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.. Consider the following 2 2 economy. The utility functions are: u (.) = x x 2

More information

First Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem First Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 17, October 31 Outline 1 First Welfare Theorem 2 Preliminaries to Second Welfare Theorem Past Definitions A feasible allocation (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I. Lecture Notes October 18, 2012 Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I. Economic General Equilibrium Partial and General Economic Equilibrium PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM S k (p o ) = D k k (po

More information

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 19, November 7 Outline 1 Welfare Theorems in the differentiable case. 2 Aggregate excess

More information

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium 2.1 Art and Bart each sell ice cream cones from carts on the boardwalk in Atlantic City. Each day they independently decide where to position their

More information

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions. Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 3: Optimization - interior optima 1 Session: 11-12 Aug 2015 (Thu/Fri) 10:00am 1:00pm I. Optimization: introduction Decision-makers (e.g. consumers,

More information

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty 1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty Sofarwehaveassumedawayaggregatefluctuations (i.e., business cycles) in our description of the incomplete-markets economies with uninsurable idiosyncratic risk

More information

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16 14.452 Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Theorem 2. Normative Representative Household Theorem 3. Representative Firm Theorem (Recitation 2 on November 6, 2009) (Reference: "Introduction to Modern

More information

LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR

LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR LECTURE 14 WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM IN THE CASE OF A SINGLE LABOR SECTOR JACOB T. SCHWARTZ EDITED BY KENNETH R. DRIESSEL Abstract. We continue to develop the consequences of the definition of a price equilibrium

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 6 October, 2017 Properties of the Profit Function Recall the following property of the profit function π(p, w) = max x p f (x)

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem

Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem Communications to SIMAI Congress, ISSN 1827-9015, Vol. 2 2007 DOI: 10.1685/CSC06159 Computational procedure for a time-dependent Walrasian price equilibrium problem M. B. DONATO 1 and M. MILASI 2 Department

More information

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy Economics 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2013 Outline 1 Introduction 2 The Basic DGE Closed Economy 3 Golden Rule Solution 4 Optimal Solution The Euler Equation

More information

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata General Equilibrium Equilibrium in Consumption GE begins (1/3) 2-Individual/ 2-good Exchange economy (No production, no transaction costs, full information..) Endowment (Nature): e Private property/ NO

More information

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory

Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory Chapter 9 Nathan Smooha Economic Core, Fair Allocations, and Social Choice Theory 9.1 Introduction In this chapter, we briefly discuss some topics in the framework of general equilibrium theory, namely

More information

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications Lecture 18: Auctions and Mechanism Design II: a little social choice theory, the VCG Mechanism, and Market Equilibria Kousha Etessami Reminder: Food for Thought:

More information

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics Topics Volume 9, Issue 1 2009 Article 43 Simple Economies with Multiple Equilibria Theodore C. Bergstrom Ken-Ichi Shimomura Takehiko Yamato University of California,

More information

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION Prerequisites Almost essential Welfare: Basics Welfare: Efficiency WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell July 2017 1 Social Welfare Function Limitations

More information

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium 1.1 Introduction What is an equilibrium (EQM)? Loosely speaking, an equilibrium is a mapping from environments (preference, technology, information, market

More information

Dynamical Systems and Chaos Part I: Theoretical Techniques. Lecture 4: Discrete systems + Chaos. Ilya Potapov Mathematics Department, TUT Room TD325

Dynamical Systems and Chaos Part I: Theoretical Techniques. Lecture 4: Discrete systems + Chaos. Ilya Potapov Mathematics Department, TUT Room TD325 Dynamical Systems and Chaos Part I: Theoretical Techniques Lecture 4: Discrete systems + Chaos Ilya Potapov Mathematics Department, TUT Room TD325 Discrete maps x n+1 = f(x n ) Discrete time steps. x 0

More information

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path Ryoji Ohdoi Dept. of Industrial Engineering and Economics, Tokyo Tech This lecture note is mainly based on Ch. 8 of Acemoglu

More information

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences 1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences In what follows we ll discuss aggregation. What do we mean with this term? We say that an economy admits aggregation if the behavior

More information

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium 1.1 There are only two goods in the economy and there is no way to produce either good. There are n individuals, indexed by i = 1,..., n. Individual i owns

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium. Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis

Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium. Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis Stochastic Stability of General Equilibrium Antoine Mandel and Herbert Gintis June 1, 2012 1 Introduction The stability of Walrasian general equilibrium was widely studied in the years immediately following

More information

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model New Notes on the Solow Growth Model Roberto Chang September 2009 1 The Model The firstingredientofadynamicmodelisthedescriptionofthetimehorizon. In the original Solow model, time is continuous and the

More information

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition On Hotelling s Stability in Competition Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Manuscript received March, 1978; revision received June, 1978 Abstract The purpose of this

More information

The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model : USA

The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model : USA Advances in Management & Applied Economics, vol. 4, no.5, 014, 53-6 ISSN: 179-7544 (print version), 179-755(online) Scienpress Ltd, 014 The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model : USA Vesna D. Jablanovic

More information

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017 Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived

More information

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade Alfonso A. Irarrazabal University of Oslo September 25, 2007 Contents 1 Simple Ricardian Model 3 1.1 Preferences................................. 3 1.2 Technologies.................................

More information

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Ömer Özak SMU Macroeconomics II Ömer Özak (SMU) Economic Growth Macroeconomics II 1 / 78 Preliminaries Introduction Foundations of Neoclassical Growth Solow model: constant

More information

A Metzlerian business cycle model with nonlinear heterogeneous expectations

A Metzlerian business cycle model with nonlinear heterogeneous expectations A Metzlerian business cycle model with nonlinear heterogeneous expectations Michael Wegener Frank Westerhoff Georg Zaklan April 11, 2008 University of Bamberg, Feldkirchenstr. 21, 96045 Bamberg, Germany

More information

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples*

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 34, 180-186 (1984) No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* AHMET ALKAN Bogaripi Universitesi, Istanbul, Turkey Received December 20, 1982; revised October 14. 1983

More information

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

The General Neoclassical Trade Model The General Neoclassical Trade Model J. Peter Neary University of Oxford October 15, 2013 J.P. Neary (University of Oxford) Neoclassical Trade Model October 15, 2013 1 / 28 Plan of Lectures 1 Review of

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2 Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory 2.1. The Keynesian Consumption Function 2.2. The Complete Keynesian Model 2.3. The Keynesian-Cross Model 2.4. The IS-LM Model 2.5. The Keynesian AD-AS Model 2.6. Conclusion

More information

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions AAU - Business Mathematics I Lecture #1, February 27, 2010 1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions 1.1 Constants, Variables, and Sets A constant is something that does not change, over time or otherwise:

More information

A model for competitive markets

A model for competitive markets A model for competitive markets Manuela Girotti MATH 345 Differential Equations Contents 1 Competitive markets 1 1.1 Competitive market with only one good......................... 2 1.2 Competitive market

More information

Mechanics, Heat, Oscillations and Waves Prof. V. Balakrishnan Department of Physics Indian Institute of Technology, Madras

Mechanics, Heat, Oscillations and Waves Prof. V. Balakrishnan Department of Physics Indian Institute of Technology, Madras Mechanics, Heat, Oscillations and Waves Prof. V. Balakrishnan Department of Physics Indian Institute of Technology, Madras Lecture - 21 Central Potential and Central Force Ready now to take up the idea

More information

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability Chapter 7 Nathan Smooha Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability 7.1 Introduction Brouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Let X be a non-empty, compact, and convex subset of R m. If

More information

Fundamentals of Operations Research. Prof. G. Srinivasan. Indian Institute of Technology Madras. Lecture No. # 15

Fundamentals of Operations Research. Prof. G. Srinivasan. Indian Institute of Technology Madras. Lecture No. # 15 Fundamentals of Operations Research Prof. G. Srinivasan Indian Institute of Technology Madras Lecture No. # 15 Transportation Problem - Other Issues Assignment Problem - Introduction In the last lecture

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

The Integers. Peter J. Kahn

The Integers. Peter J. Kahn Math 3040: Spring 2009 The Integers Peter J. Kahn Contents 1. The Basic Construction 1 2. Adding integers 6 3. Ordering integers 16 4. Multiplying integers 18 Before we begin the mathematics of this section,

More information

Substitute Valuations with Divisible Goods

Substitute Valuations with Divisible Goods Substitute Valuations with Divisible Goods Paul Milgrom Bruno Strulovici December 17, 2006 Abstract In a companion paper, we showed that weak and strong notions of substitutes in economies with discrete

More information

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Mathematical Foundations -- Constrained Optimization Constrained Optimization An intuitive approach First Order Conditions (FOC) 7 Constraint qualifications 9 Formal statement of the FOC for a maximum

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Game Theory 1 / 43 Introduction Why game theory? In the introductory lecture, we defined Industrial Organization as the economics

More information

FACTORIZATION AND THE PRIMES

FACTORIZATION AND THE PRIMES I FACTORIZATION AND THE PRIMES 1. The laws of arithmetic The object of the higher arithmetic is to discover and to establish general propositions concerning the natural numbers 1, 2, 3,... of ordinary

More information

Introductory Quantum Chemistry Prof. K. L. Sebastian Department of Inorganic and Physical Chemistry Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore

Introductory Quantum Chemistry Prof. K. L. Sebastian Department of Inorganic and Physical Chemistry Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore Introductory Quantum Chemistry Prof. K. L. Sebastian Department of Inorganic and Physical Chemistry Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore Lecture - 4 Postulates Part 1 (Refer Slide Time: 00:59) So, I

More information

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t )

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t ) Eco504, Part II Spring 2006 C. Sims FTPL WITH MONEY 1. FTPL WITH MONEY This model is that of Sims (1994). Agent: [ ] max E β t log C t {C t,m t,b t } t=0 s.t. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) + M t + B t + τ t R t

More information

Lecture 2 Optimal Indirect Taxation. March 2014

Lecture 2 Optimal Indirect Taxation. March 2014 Lecture 2 Optimal Indirect Taxation March 2014 Optimal taxation: a general setup Individual choice criterion, for i = 1,..., I : U(c i, l i, θ i ) Individual anonymous budget constraint Social objective

More information