Nominal Rigidity and the Idiosyncratic Origin of Aggregate. Fluctuations

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Nominal Rigidity and the Idiosyncratic Origin of Aggregate. Fluctuations"

Transcription

1 Nominal Rigidity and the Idiosyncratic Origin of Aggregate Fluctuations Ernesto Pasten, Raphael Schoenle, Michael Weber Februay 2016 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE PLEASE DO NOT CITE Abstract We study the aggregate propagation of idiosyncratic, sectoral shocks in a multi-sector new-keynesian model with intermediate inputs featuring sectoral heterogeneity in price stickiness, sectoral GDP, and input-output linkages. Heterogeneity of price rigidity distorts the "granular" effect of the fat-failed distribution of sectors size as well as the "network" effect of the centrality of some sectors in the production network. This distortion involves the strength of the aggregate volatility generated by sectoral shocks as well as the identity of the most important sectors. The granular and the network effects may in fact be completely irrelevant while the empirical distribution of price stickiness may generate by itself sizable aggregate volatility from sectoral shocks. We calibrate our model to 350 sectors using US data to quantify the strenght and interaction of "granular", "network" and "frictional" sources of the aggregate propagation of sectoral shocks. JEL codes: Keywords: Pasten thanks the support of the Université de Toulouse Capitole during his stays in Toulouse. Weber gratefully acknowledges financial support from the University of Chicago, the Neubauer Family Foundation, and the Fama-Miller Center. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the position of the Central Bank of Chile. Central Bank of Chile and Toulouse School of Economics. ernesto.pasten@tse-fr.eu Brandeis University. schoenle@brandeis.edu. Booth School of Business, University of Chicago. michael.weber@booth.edu..

2 1 Introduction Recent literature has stressed that idiosyncratic, sectoral shocks at disagregated level may be behind sizable aggregate fluctuations contradicting what is known as the "diversification argument." Lucas (1977) argues that idiosyncratic shocks at a very disagregated level should "wash out" in the aggregate by the application of the law of large numbers. Similar view has been taken by Dupor (1999) and virtually anyone that conceptualizes business cycles fluctuations as the result of aggregate shocks. In contrast, Gabaix (2011) argues that when the contribution of firms in total GDP is fat-tailed (in what follows, sectors), the standard law of large numbers does not readily apply. Intuitively, when some sectors remain "granular", i.e., disproportional large as disaggregation becomes finer, shocks to those sectors matter for the aggregate. In turn, Acemoglu, Carvalho, Ozdaglar and Tahbaz-Salehi (2012) argue that the diversification argument neither applies when some sectors remain central in the production network for any level of disaggregation. Both, Gabaix (2011) and Acemoglu et al (2012), respectively show that the granularity and the network centrality of sectors in US data are enough for disaggregated sectoral shocks to generate sizable aggregate fluctuations. This paper asks about role of frictions in this debate in particular, price frictions. No matter whether because a sector is large or central in the network, its ability to adjust prices after a shock is crucial for the aggregate propagation of such a shock. To fix ideas, suppose that firms in a given sector do not adjust their prices at all after receiving a shock specific to their sector. Demand for goods produced in the sector would remain unchanged. Thus, the contribution of the shock to aggregate fluctuations would be zero regardless of the size of the sector. Besides, production costs of all firms that use the goods from the shocked sector as inputs would also remain unchanged, so their prices and thus their own demand would also be unchanged. Production in the shocked sector remains unchanged, so no firm in the sector would change its demand of the goods that use as inputs. Thus, regardless the centrality of the shocked sector in the production network, the aggregate effect of the shock would be just zero. Interestingly, it is well documented in the data the quite substantial heterogeneity of price rigidity across sectors. How does this heterogeneity in price rigidity affect the violation of the diversification argument either by the granular effect proposed by Gabaix (2011) or the network effect proposed by Acemoglu et al (2012)? To answer this question, this paper studies a new-keynesian model with multiple sectors where produc- 2

3 tion needs labor and intermediate inputs. Critically, our model allows for sectoral heterogeneity of price rigidity, size of sectors measured by sectoral GDP, and fully flexible input-output linkages across sectors. We first study a simple version of our model that allows for close-form solution to transparently show the interaction of price frictions and the granular and network mechanisms. The solution of this simple model nests the solution of the models of Gabaix (2011) and Acemoglu et al (2012) as special cases. Our main result is that price rigidity is central the aggregate propagation of idiosyncratic shocks. First, price rigidity distorts the strenght of the granular and network effects as well as the identity of the most important sectoral shocks for aggregate fluctuations. Under certain conditions, the granular and network mechanisms may be completely irrelevant for the violation of the diversification argument. We then explore the extrapolation of these results in a more elaborate version of our model and calibrate it to US data to quantify the aggregate volatility generated by idiosyncratic, sectoral shocks. For this we merge data for 350 sectors from the Input-Output Tables constructed by the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the micro data undelying the Producer Price Index constructed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Empirically, the sectoral distribution of price rigidity has the ability to generate by itself a mechanism to violate the diversification argument. However, although the negative correlation between price rigidity and sectoral size, and price rigidity and network centrality are weak, it is enough to generate quite large aggregate volatility from idiosyncratic, sectoral shocks. [ADD LITERATURE REVIEW] [ADD LAY OUT] 2 Model This section displays our multi-sector model with households and firms demanding goods from all sectors respectively for consumption and as intermediate inputs. There are three key ingredients of our model: (1) Households aggregate sectoral consumption using heterogeneous weights; (2) firms across sectors use different combination of goods for production; and (3) sectoral heterogeneity of price stickiness. 3

4 2.1 Households The utility of a representative household is subject to ( max E 0 β t Ct 1 σ 1 1 σ t=0 ) 1+ϕ Lkjt g k I k 1 + ϕ dj k=1 W kt L kjt dj + Π kt + I t 1 B t 1 B t = Pt I c C t k k=1 k=1 W kt L kjt dj 1 I k k=1 where C t and P c t respectively are aggregate consumption and aggregate prices to be specified below, L kjt and W kt are labor employed and wages paid by firm j in sector k = 1,..., K, Π kt is transfers from firms in sector k, I t 1 is the gross interest rate paid by bonds holding at the beginning of period t, B t 1. Aggregate consumption is C t [ K k=1 ] η 1 1 η 1 η ωck C1 η kt where C kt is the aggregation of sectoral consumption given by (1) C kt [ n 1/θ k C 1 1 θ kjt I k ] θ dj θ 1. (2) where C kjt is the demand by households of the good produced by firm j in sector k. There is a continuum of goods indexed by j [0, 1] with total measure one. These goods, each produced by a given firm also indexed by j, belong to one of the K sectors in the economy. Mathematically, the set of goods is partitioned into subsets {I k } K k=1 respectively with measure n k such that K k=1 n k = 1. Although the sectoral subindex is redundant, we consider it clarifies exposition. We allow the elasticity of substitution across sectors η to differ from the elasticity of substitution within sectors θ. The first key feature of ingredient in our model is the vector of weights Ω c [ω c1,..., ω ck ] in the 4

5 aggregator of sectoral consumption in (1). These weights show up in households demand: ( ) η Pkt C kt = ω ck Pt c C t. In steady state (solved in the Appendix) all prices are identical, so these weights govern the sectoral in total consumption C. These weights satisfy ι Ω c = 1 where ι denotes a column-vector of ones. In our model, aggregate consumption is the best proxy to value-added production. Thus we interpret Ω c as the vector of sectoral shares in steady state GDP which we simply refer to as "GDP shares". Outside steady state, households sectoral demand is distorted by the respective sectoral price relative to the consumption aggregate prices P c t. P c t = [ K k=1 ω ck P 1 η kt ] 1 1 η (3) Given the interpretation of C as GDP, we call P c t as GDP deflactor. Within sectors, households demand for goods is given by C kjt = 1 ( ) θ Pkjt C kt for k {1,..., K}, n k P kt such that, in steady state, all firms in sector k share equally households demand for goods categorized in sector k. Outside the steady state, the demand of goods is distorted by its price and the sectoral price [ ] 1 1 P kt = P 1 θ n kjt dj 1 θ for k {1,..., K}. k I k From the first order conditions for households we also get labor supply and the Euler equation: W kt P c t = g k L ϕ kjt Cσ t for all k, j, (4) E t [β ( Ct+1 C t ) σ I t P c t P c t+1 ] = 1 (5) Implicitly in our specification for disutility of labor is the sectoral segmentation of the labor market, so labor supply in (4) holds for a sector specific wage {W kt } K k=1. In the Appendix we set the parameters 5

6 {g k } K k=1 to ensure a symmetric steady state across sectors. In turn, the Euler equation is standard. 2.2 Firms Goods are monopolistically produced. We refer to a firm producing good j categorized in sector k as "firm kj" which production function is given by Y kjt = e a kt L 1 δ kjt Zδ kjt, where a kt is a productivity shock specific to sector k following an AR(1) process with unconditional expectations E [a kt ] = 0, unconditional variance V [a kt ] = v 2 and persistence ρ a for all k, L kjt is labor hired and Z kjt is an aggregator of intermediate inputs demanded by firm k, j. The aggregator of intermediate inputs used by firm kj is Z kjt [ K r=1 ] η 1 η ωkr Z kjt (r) 1 1 η 1 η where, in turn, Z kjt (r) is the amount of goods from sector r demanded by firm k, j at period t. The second key ingredient of our model are the aggregator weights {ω kr } k,r denoted in matrix form by Ω. These weights satisfy ι Ω = 1 where ι denotes a column-vector of ones. Importantly, these weights are allowed to be different across sectors and with those specified for households, Ω c. Z kjt (r) aggregates demand of firm kj for goods in sector r according to Z kjt (r) [ n 1/θ ( r Z kjt r, j ) ] θ 1 1 θ dj θ 1 I r where Z kjt (r, j ) is the amount of goods produced by firm j in sector r that is demanded as input by firm kj. The demand of firm kj across and within sectors is ( ) η Prt Z kjt (r) = ω kr Pt k Z kjt, Z kjt ( r, j ) = 1 n r ( Prj t P rt ) θ Z kjt (r). 6

7 In steady state, when all prices are identical, the share of goods from sector r in the total costs of a firm in sector k is given by Ω k [ω k1,..., ω kk ]. We thus refer to Ω as the input-output structure of the economy and Ω k as the input-output linkages of sector k (as demander). Within each sector, demand of firm kj for goods in sector r in steady state is shared equally across firms in sector r. Outside the steady state, sectoral demand is distorted by sectoral prices relative to the aggregate price P k t relevant for firms in sector k which is given by P k t = [ K r=1 ω kr P 1 η rt ] 1 1 η for k {1,..., K} that uses the input-output linkages of sector k (as demander). Since input-output linkages are heterogeneous across sectors, there are K + 1 aggregate price indexes (one for households and one for each sector). In turn, relative demand within a given sector depends on firms prices relative to their respective sectoral price given by [ ] 1 1 P rt = P 1 θ 1 θ n rj t dj for r {1,..., K} r I r which are the same regardless of the demanding firm and are also the same to the one relevant for households demand. The third key ingredient of our model is sectoral heterogeneity in price rigidities. Specifically, we model price rigidities á la Calvo with parameter {α k } K k=1. Thus, the objective of firm j, k is max P kjt E t Q t,t+s α s k [P kjty kjt+s MC kt+s Y kjt+s ] s=0 ( ) δ where marginal costs are given by MC kt = 1 δ 1 δ 1 δ A 1 kt W 1 δ ( ) kt P k δ t in reduced form after imposing the optimal mix of labor and intermediate inputs: δw kt L kjt = (1 δ) P k t Z kjt. (6) In principle firms may like to discriminate among the different customers they have, either households or other firms. We assume that the elasticity of substitution across and within sectors, although allowed to be different among them, are the same for all households and all firms. This assumption shuts down the incentives of firms to discriminate among different customers, so the optimal pricing problem takes the 7

8 simple, standard form: Q t,t+s α s k Y kjt+s s=0 [ P kt where Y kjt+s is the total production of firm k, j at period t + s. θ ] θ 1 MC kt+s = 0 Since idiosyncratic shocks {a kt } K k=1 are defined at the sectoral level, the optimal adjusting price, P kt, is the same for all firms in a given sector. Thus, aggregating among all prices within sectors yields P kt = [ ] 1 (1 α k ) P 1 θ kt + α k P 1 θ 1 θ kt 1 for k = 1,..., K. (7) 2.3 Monetary policy Monetary policy controls I t which is set according to the Taylor rule: I t = 1 β ( P c t P c t 1 ) φπ ( ) φy Ct (8) C Note that monetary policy reacts to inflation using the GDP deflactor P c t and deviations from steady state of value-added production C t. There is no monetary shock. 2.4 Equilibrium conditions and definitions B t = 0, L kt = L kjt dj, I k Y kjt = C kjt + W t L t k =1 n k W kt, k=1 L kt. k=1 I k Z k j t (k, j) dj, The first of these equations is the equilibrium in the assets market. The second equation simply aggregates labor within sectors by summing up hours worked in all firms in a given sector. The last equation is 8

9 Walras law. The llast two equations are definitions of the aggregate wage and aggregate labor. 3 The core idea To provide intuition for our main results, in this section we solve in closed-form a simplified version of our model. Since our goal is to study the effect of sectoral idiosyncratic shocks on aggregate fluctuations, we focus on solving for the log-linear deviation from the steady state of value-added production c t. As standard, we denote log-deviations from steady state in small cases. Assumptions for this section. We make five assumptions. The first is that households have log utility of consumption. The second is that their disutility of labor is linear, ϕ = 0. This assumption implies that there is no sectorally segmented labor markets and labor supply is inelastic. The third assumption is that monetary policy does not follow the Taylor rule specified in (8) but P c t C t = M which targets of a given level of nominal GDP. Our forth assumption is that sectoral technology shocks a kt are i.i.d for all k. Our fifth, and last, assumption is a modified version of the pricing friction. All prices are assumed fully flexible although there is probability λ k that a firm in sector k must set its price before observing the realization of shocks, otherwise it does after. Thus the optimal price of a firm kj is P kjt = and sectoral prices are given by θ θ 1 E t 1 [MC kt ] with probability λ k, θ θ 1 MC kt with probability 1 λ k, P kt = θ [ (1 λ k ) MC 1 θ θ 1 kt + λ k E t 1 [MC kt ] 1 θ] 1 1 θ for k = 1,..., K (9) instead of the expression in (7). We allow for sectoral heterogeneity in the "degree of price flexibility" {1 λ k } K k=1. 9

10 Solution. The next proposition solves for the log-linear deviation of value-added output c t. Proposition 1 Under the assumptions imposed in this section, c t = χ a t where χ (I Λ) [I δ (I Λ) Ω ] 1 Ω c is the "influence vector", Λ is a diagonal matrix with the vector [λ 1,..., λ K ] as diagonal, and a t [a 1,..., a K ] is the vector of realizations of sectoral technology shocks. Proof. See Appendix. The solution for the log-deviation of value-added output is simply a linear combination of the realizations of sectoral shocks. Thus, given our assumption that V [a kt ] = v 2 for all k, we get v c = v K χ 2 k = χ 2 v (10) k=1 with χ 2 denoting the Euclidean norm of the influence vector χ. As Gabaix (2011) and Acemoglu et al (2012), we are interested in the rate of decay to zero of v c as the number of sectors K. Unlike these papers, we focus on the interaction of the heterogeneity of price rigidity across sectors with the features of the distribution of sectoral GDP shares in Ω c and/or the input-output structure of the economy in Ω that generate a slow rate of decay of v c. We are also interested in the effect of the distribution of price rigidity on the scale of v c and the identity of the sectors which idiosyncratic shocks have stronger effect in the aggregate. From this point on we find convenient to use the following definition. Definition 1 A given random variable X is said to follow a power-law distribution with power parameter β when Pr (X > x) = γx β for some constant γ. 3.1 The granular effect and price stickiness We now connect our work with Gabaix (2011) which demonstrates the importance of the distribution of sectoral size on the rate of decay of aggregate volatility. To do so, we shut down the effect of the input- 10

11 output structure of the economy by setting δ = 0 to get χ = ( I Λ ) Ω c or, simply, χ k = (1 λ k ) ω ck for all k. It is apparent from this expression that the convoluted distribution of price stickiness and sectoral size (here measured as steady-state GDP) governs the scale and rate of decay of the volatility v c of value-added output. To study this convoluted distribution, we proceed in steps. To start, we assume homogeneous price stickiness across sectors. Although Gabaix (2011) does not include price stickiness in his analysis, we can get the rate of decay of v c in this case by directly applying his Proposition 2. Proposition 2 (Granular effect) When production does not need intermediate inputs, δ = 0, all sectors have the same degree of price flexibility, so λ k = λ for all k, and steady state sectoral GDP {C k } follows a power-law distribution with power parameter β c > 1, v c v c u 0 K 1 1/β c v for β c (1, 2) u 0 K 1/2 v for β c > 2. where u 0 is a random variable independent of K and v. Proof. See Appendix. This proposition states the central idea of the "granular effect": When the size distribution of sectors is fat-tailed, which is a feature of the power law distribution when the power parameter lies in the (1, 2) interval, the rate of decay of aggregate volatility is slower than the standard rate K 1/2. If this parameter is close enough to 1, then sectoral idiosyncratic shocks have a sizable effect on aggregate volatility even if sectors are defined at a very disaggregated level. In intuitive terms, when the size distribution of sectors is fat-tailed, there are few sectors that remain disproportionally large as the number of sectors go to infinity. Lemma 1 When δ = 0 and price stickiness is homogeneous across sectors, λ k = λ for all k, v c = (1 λ) v C k K 1/2 V (C k ) + C 2 k 11

12 for a given number of sectors K, where C k and V ( ) respectively are the sample mean and sample variance of its argument. Since price stickiness is here homogeneous across sectors, its effect is confined only to the scale of aggregate volatility. As price stickiness increases, aggregate volatility becomes smaller in an economy with a given number of sectors. The reason is that the extent in which production of a sector changes following a technology shock crucially depends on the ability of firms in that sector to adjust their prices. We now move one step forward by allowing for heterogeneity in price stickiness that is uncorrelated with steady-state sectoral GDP. Proposition 3 When δ = 0, the degree of sectoral price flexibility {1 λ k } and steady-state sectoral GDP {C k } are mutually uncorreated, and both follow power-law distributions with respective power parameter β λ, β c > 1, v c v c u 1 K 1 1/ min{β λ,β c } v for min {β λ, β c } (1, 2) u 1 K 1/2 v for min {β λ, β c } > 2. where u 1 is a random variable independent of K and v. Proof. See Appendix. This proposition presents the first key result in this paper: the "granular effect" highlighted by Gabaix (2011) is completely irrelevant for the rate of decay of aggregate volatility when the sectoral distribution of price flexibility exhibits a fatter upper tail than the distribution of steady-state sectoral GDP, provided that they are uncorrelated and the two distributions are power-law. This result is direct application of Proposition 2 after using the property that the multiplication of two independent power-law random variables is also distributed power-law wtih the smallest of the two power parameters. The next proposition completes the characterization of the interaction between the heterogeneity of price stickiness and the granular effect. Proposition 4 When δ = 0, the distribution of {(1 λ k ) C k } follows a power-law distribution with power parameter β λc > 1 and marginal distributions for {1 λ k } and {C k } also following power-law distribu- 12

13 tions with respective power parameter β λ, β c, v c v c u 2 K 1 1/β λc v for β λc (1, 2) u 2 K 1/2 v for β λc > 2. where u 2 is a random variable independent of K and v, and β λc < (>) min {β λ, β c } when {1 λ k } and {C k } are positively (negatively) correlated. Proof. See Appendix. If the bigger sectors are also the most flexible sectors, then shocks to these sector would have even stronger aggregate than when price stickiness and sectoral size are uncorrelated. Thus, the rate of decay of aggregate volatility would be even slower provided that the convoluted distribution of price flexibility and sectoral size follows a power law with power parameter β λc (1, 2). The opposite is true when price flexibility and sectoral GDP are negatively correlated. Proposition 4 implies that conditions on the marginal distributions of price flexibility and sectoral GDP are not sufficient to characterize the rate of decay of aggregate volatility as the number of sectors increases. As a matter of fact, it may be the case that the rate of decay of aggregate volatility v c may be slow even when price flexibility and sectoral size are not fat-tailed at all (if their correlation is positive and high enough); v c could even diverge. However, such a strong implication is not relevant empirically in our numerical exercises that follow below, so we ignore here this possibility. Conversely, it is also possible that the decay of v c may be fast (i.e., K 1/2 ) even when price stickiness and sectoral size are both heavy-tailed if they are negatively correlated enough. Finally, we state the following result regarding the effect of heterogeneity in price stickiness on the level of aggregate volatility for a given number of sectors K. Lemma 2 When δ = 0 and price stickiness is heterogeneous across sectors, v c = v C k K 1/2 V ((1 λ k ) C k ) + [ COV (1 λ k, C k ) + ( 1 λ ) C k ] 2 for a given number of sectors K, where λ and COV ( ) respectively are the sample mean of λ k and the sample covariance of its argument. 13

14 Comparing this expression with the one in Lemma 1, the sectoral variation of price rigidity as well as its covariance with sectoral GDP contribute to the scale of aggregate volatility for a given number K of sectors. This lemma may be seen as a natural implication of Proposition The network effect and price stickiness We now connect our work with Acemoglu et al (2012) which demostrates the importance of the input-output network structure of the economy on the rate of decay of value-added output volatility. For this we assume δ (0, 1) and shut down the granular effect, so Ω c = 1 K ι where ι is a column-vector of ones. In this case, the influence vector in Proposition 1 solves χ = 1 K (I Λ) [ I δ (I Λ) Ω ] 1 ι. This expression nests the solution for the influence vector in Acemoglu et al (2012) when prices are fully flexible, i.e. λ k = 0 for all k = 1,..., K, with the only caveat that here ι χ = 1/ (1 δ). 1 To study the interaction between price stickiness and network effects, we proceed in steps. But first we borrow some useful definitions from Acemoglu et al (2012). Definition 2 (i) The vector of outdegrees d [d 1,..., d K ] is such that d k ω k k for all k = 1,..., K. k =1 (ii) The vector of second-order outdegrees q [q 1,..., q K ] is such that q k d k ω k k for all k = 1,..., K. k =1 These definitions are statistics capturing the "centrality" of sectors in the production network. The outdegrees measure the strength of the first-order input-output linkages across sectors, this is, the importance of sectors as suppliers of other sectors. The second-order ourdegrees measure the second-order input-output linkages, i.e., the importance of sectors as suppliers weighted by the importance of "costumer" sectors as 1 Acemoglu et al (2012) normalize the scale of shocks to get the sum of the influence vector equal to one. 14

15 suppliers. We now start our analysis by assuming no across-sectors variation of price rigidity. Proposition 5 (Network effect) When δ (0, 1), all sectors are homogeneous in their degree of price flexibility, so λ k = λ for all k, and steady-state sectoral GDP, so Ω c = 1 K ι, the distribution of outdegrees {d k } and second-order outdegrees {q k } are independent and follow power-law distributions with respective power parameter β d, β q > 1 v c v c u 3 K 1 1/ min{β d,β q} v for min { } β d, β q (1, 2) u 3 K 1/2 v for min { } β d, β q > 2. where u 3 is a random variable independent of K and v. Proof. See Appendix. This proposition summarizes the essence of the "network effect": The rate of decay of aggregate volatility is bounded below by the fattest-tailed distribution between the outdegrees and the second-order outdegrees, provided that they are independent and each follow power-law distributions. Thus, if there are some sectors disproportionally central in the production network, sectoral idiosyncratic shocks have sizable effect on aggregate volatility even if sectors are defined at a very disaggregated level. Although Acemoglu et al (2012) do not study price rigidities, we can get this proposition by directly combining their main results. 2 The intuition comes from noticing that, when price rigidities and sectoral GDP in steady state are homogeneous across sectors, the solution for the influence vector is χ = 1 λ K ι [I (1 λ) δω] 1. (11) = 1 λ (1 λ) τ δ τ ι Ω τ K τ=0 given that all elements of Ω lie outside the unit circle. Further, truncating the expression for χ to τ = 2 and 2 In particular, theorems 2 and 3 and corollaries 1 and 2 in their paper. 15

16 using d = ι Ω and q = ι Ω 2 yields χ 1 λ K [ ] 1 + (1 λ) δd + (1 λ) 2 δ 2 q (12) ehere the inequality follows from Ω > 0. Thus, from (10), the rate of decay of v c is at least the fattest-tailed distribution between outdegrees and sectoral outdegrees. We now use equation (11) to look at the scale effect on v c of the (homogeneous) price rigidity λ. Lemma 3 For δ (0, 1), Ω c = 1 K ι and λ k = λ for all k, and given a number of sectors K: (i) Aggregate volatility v c is decreasing in λ (ii) λ has stronger effect on the contribution to v c of the second-order outdegrees q than the contribution of outdegrees d. For part (i) of this lemma, it is clear from (11) that χ is decreasing in λ. For instance, if the production network is symmetric, i.e., Ω = 1 K ιι, then v c = 1 λ 1 (1 λ) δ K 1/2 v. For part (ii) of this lemma, note from (10) that the cross-sectional variation of d and q contribute to v c and from (12) that d is multiplied by 1 λ while q is multiplied by (1 λ) 2. Therefore, even when the rate of decay of aggregate volatility may be slow because of the second-order outdegrees, the scale of their effect is smaller as price rigidity increases. This result is important to highlight because in the empirical analysis of Acemoglu et al (2012) it is the second-order outdegrees what have the strongest network effect. In the data, producer prices are in average quite rigid, so this result suggest that second-order outdegrees are irrelevant quantitatvely. [CONFIRM THIS IN NUMERICAL EXERCISES WITH THE FULL MODEL]. As another intermediate step, we now assume that price rigidity is heterogeneous across sectors but the production network is symmetric. Proposition 6 For δ (0, 1), Ω c = 1 K ι, a symmetric production network, so Ω = 1 K ιι, and the degree of 16

17 sectoral price flexibility {1 λ k } follows a power-law distribution with power parameter β λ > 1, then v c v c u 4 K 1 1/β λ v for β λ (1, 2) u 4 K 1/2 v for β λ > 2. where u 4 is a random variable independent of K and v. Proof. See Appendix. This proposition shares its flavor with Proposition 3: When the only souce of heterogeneity across sectors is their degree of price flexibility, the rate of decay of aggregate volatility is slow when this distribution is fat-tailed. Regarding the level of aggregate fluctutations given a number of sectors, it is useful to establish the following result. Lemma 4 When δ (0, 1), Ω c = 1 K ι, and λ k is heterogeneous across sectors, v c = K 1/2 v 1 ( 1 λ ) δ V (1 λ) + ( 1 λ ) 2. Comparing this result with Lemma 3 for the case when the production network is symmetric, this lemma states that cross-sectoral variation of price rigidities contributes positively to aggregate volatility. The final step in this section is to allow for sectoral heterogeneity in price rigidity and input-output linkages such that the production network is assymetric. Before stating our main results, it is convenient to make the following definitions. Definition 3 (i) The vector of modified outdegrees d [ d1,..., d ] K is such that d k (1 λ k ) ω k k for all k = 1,..., K. k =1 (ii) The vector of modified second-order outdegrees q [ q 1,..., q K ] is such that q k (1 λ k ) d k ω k k for all k = 1,..., K. k =1 17

18 Keeping a similar logic with Definition 2, we here define some statistics that capture the interaction between the heterogeneity in price rigidities across sectors with centrality in the production network. The modified outdegrees measure the first-order input-output linkages weighting them by the degree of price flexibility of the "costumer" sector. Similarly, the modified second-order outdegrees measure the secondorder input-output linkages weighted by the degree of price flexibility and the modified outdegrees of the costumer sectors. For our main theoretical result, we drop the assumption of homoegenous steady-state sectoral GDP. Proposition 7 For δ (0, 1), Ω c = 1 K ι, heterogeneous price rigidity and asymmetric production network: (i) The influence vector χ satisfies χ k ω ck (1 λ k ) [1 + δ d k + δ 2 q ] k { } (ii) Assume that {1 λ k }, {ω ck } dk and { q k } follow all power-law distributions, the rate of decay of v c depends on their power parameters and their mutual correlations. Proof. See Appendix. This is the most important result in the paper regarding the network effects: The importance of centrality in the network for the aggregate propagation of sectoral shocks is distorted by its interaction with price rigidities. This interaction is captured by the modified outdegrees d and the second-order modified outdegrees q. Besides, revisiting Proposition 4, the importance of the distribution of sectoral size on the aggregate propagation of sectoral shocks. Finally, these two distorted granular and network effects interact depending on their own mutual correlation. The next corollary highlights another effect of price rigidities. Corollary 1 Heterogeneity of price stickiness may change the identity of the sectors with the largest contribution to aggregate volatility. This corollary simply states a direct implication of Proposition 7, so it needs no proof. The most important sectors for aggregate volatility do not need to be the largest sectors or the most central sectors in the production network, but a complicated mix between them and the sectoral distribution of price rigidities. 18

19 4 Concluding remarks TO BE ADDED. 5 References TO BE ADDED. 19

20 Appendix: Proofs [TO BE COMPLETED] Note: Log-linear deviations from steady state are denoted by small cases. Proposition 1. Production efficiency in (6) implies mc kt = (1 δ) w kt + δp k t a kt where w kt is the sectoral wage and p k t is the the aggregate price relevant for firms in sector k: p k t = ω kk p k t. k =1 Using labor supply in (4) with ϕ = 0 and σ = 1 yields w kt = c t + p c t where p c t is the aggregate price relevant for households (also interpreted as GDP deflactor): p c t = ω ck p k t. k =1 Given that there are no monetary policy shocks, the policy rule implies c t = p c t, so mc kt = δp k t a kt. From the assumption that {a kt } are i.i.d. follows that E t 1 [mc kt ] = 0. Combining these results with the log-linearized equation (9) yields p kt = δ (1 λ k ) p k t (1 λ k ) a kt and using again c t = p c t solves c t = ( I Λ ) [ I δ ( I Λ ) Ω ] 1 Ω c a t. Proposition 2. This proof heavily relies on Gabaix (2011), proof of Proposition 2. 20

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy E. Pasten 1 R. Schoenle 2 M. Weber 3 1 Banco Central de Chile and Toulouse University 2 Brandeis University 3 Chicago Booth

More information

Working Paper Series. Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. No 2102 / October 2017

Working Paper Series. Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. No 2102 / October 2017 Working Paper Series Ernesto Pasten, Raphael Schoenle, Michael Weber Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations ECB - Lamfalussy Fellowship Programme No 2102 / October 2017 Disclaimer:

More information

Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations

Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations Bank of Finland Research Discussion Papers 3 2018 Ernesto Pasten Raphael Schoenle Michael Weber Price rigidities and the granular origins of aggregate fluctuations Bank of Finland Research Bank of Finland

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE RIGIDITIES AND THE GRANULAR ORIGINS OF AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS. Ernesto Pasten Raphael Schoenle Michael Weber

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE RIGIDITIES AND THE GRANULAR ORIGINS OF AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS. Ernesto Pasten Raphael Schoenle Michael Weber NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE RIGIDITIES AND THE GRANULAR ORIGINS OF AGGREGATE FLUCTUATIONS Ernesto Pasten Raphael Schoenle Michael Weber Working Paper 23750 http://www.nber.org/papers/w23750 NATIONAL

More information

The Macro Impact of Micro Shocks: Beyond Hulten s Theorem

The Macro Impact of Micro Shocks: Beyond Hulten s Theorem The Macro Impact of Micro Shocks: Beyond Hulten s Theorem David R. Baqaee and Emmanuel Farhi Discussion by Basile Grassi 1 1 Department of Economics, Nuffield College, University of Oxford 25th CEPR European

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano March, 28 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive

More information

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle David de la Croix 1,3 Gregory de Walque 2 Rafael Wouters 2,1 1 dept. of economics, Univ. cath. Louvain 2 National Bank of Belgium

More information

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3) MakØk3, Fall 2 (blok 2) Business cycles and monetary stabilization policies Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen Lecture 3, November 3: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter

More information

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania A Modern Equilibrium Model Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1 Household Problem Preferences: max E X β t t=0 c 1 σ t 1 σ ψ l1+γ t 1+γ Budget constraint: c t + k t+1 = w t l t + r t

More information

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007 Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational

More information

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Jordi Galí CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE April 215 Jordi Galí (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) Monetary Policy and Unemployment April 215 1 / 16

More information

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno Background Much progress made on constructing and estimating models that fit quarterly data well (Smets-Wouters,

More information

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy Leonardo Melosi London Business School 24 May 2012 Motivation Disperse information about aggregate fundamentals Morris and Shin (2003), Sims (2003), and Woodford (2002)

More information

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 Monetary Economics Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one Chris Edmond 2nd Semester 214 1 This class Unemployment fluctuations in the new Keynesian model, part one Main reading:

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí June 28 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

The New Keynesian Model

The New Keynesian Model The New Keynesian Model Basic Issues Roberto Chang Rutgers January 2013 R. Chang (Rutgers) New Keynesian Model January 2013 1 / 22 Basic Ingredients of the New Keynesian Paradigm Representative agent paradigm

More information

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro Stagnation Traps Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro May 2015 Research question and motivation Can insu cient aggregate demand lead to economic stagnation? This question goes back, at least, to the Great

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010 The Basic New Keynesian Model by Jordi Galí November 2 Motivation and Outline Evidence on Money, Output, and Prices: Short Run E ects of Monetary Policy Shocks (i) persistent e ects on real variables (ii)

More information

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction The New Keynesian Model: Introduction Vivaldo M. Mendes ISCTE Lisbon University Institute 13 November 2017 (Vivaldo M. Mendes) The New Keynesian Model: Introduction 13 November 2013 1 / 39 Summary 1 What

More information

Cascades in Networks and Aggregate Volatility

Cascades in Networks and Aggregate Volatility Cascades in Networks and Aggregate Volatility Daron Acemoglu, Asuman Ozdaglar, and Alireza Tahbaz Salehi First version: August 2010 This version: October 2010 Abstract We provide a general framework for

More information

Network Connectivity, Systematic Risk and Diversification

Network Connectivity, Systematic Risk and Diversification Network Connectivity, Systematic Risk and Diversification Monica Billio 1 Massimiliano Caporin 2 Roberto Panzica 3 Loriana Pelizzon 1,3 1 University Ca Foscari Venezia (Italy) 2 University of Padova (Italy)

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE NETWORK ORIGINS OF LARGE ECONOMIC DOWNTURNS. Daron Acemoglu Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE NETWORK ORIGINS OF LARGE ECONOMIC DOWNTURNS. Daron Acemoglu Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE NETWORK ORIGINS OF LARGE ECONOMIC DOWNTURNS Daron Acemoglu Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi Working Paper 19230 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19230 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018 Advanced Macroeconomics II Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 208 Motivation Empirical Evidence Macro evidence on the e ects of monetary policy shocks (i)

More information

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Gerzensee, August 27 Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand.

More information

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008) Getting to page 31 in Galí 2008) H J Department of Economics University of Copenhagen December 4 2012 Abstract This note shows in detail how to compute the solutions for output inflation and the nominal

More information

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1 December 14, 2006 Exercise 1 A Households Households maximise their intertemporal utility function by optimally choosing consumption, savings, and the mix of

More information

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen October 15, 2013 Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen () Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations October 15, 2013 1 / 43 Introduction

More information

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé Martín Uribe Duke University September 2007 1 Welfare-Based Policy Evaluation: Related Literature (ex: Rotemberg and Woodford,

More information

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions Monetary Economics Problem Set #4 Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions This problem set is marked out of 100 points. The weight given to each part is indicated below. Please contact me asap if

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Jesper Lindé Sveriges Riksbank Mathias Trabandt Freie Universität Berlin November 28, 2016 Lindé and Trabandt Multipliers () in Nonlinear Models November 28, 2016

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective Jordi Galí CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE May 218 Jordi Galí (CREI, UPF and Barcelona GSE) Monetary Policy and Unemployment May 218 1 / 18 Introducing

More information

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics Lawrence Christiano and Yuta Takahashi July 26, 2018 Multiple Equilibria Standard NK Model Standard, New Keynesian (NK) Monetary Model: Taylor rule satisfying Taylor

More information

Sectoral Price Facts in a Sticky-Price Model

Sectoral Price Facts in a Sticky-Price Model Sectoral Price Facts in a Sticky-Price Model (Appendix still incomplete) Carlos Carvalho Federal Reserve Bank of New York Jae Won Lee Rutgers University First draft: September, 29 This draft: July, 21

More information

The Network Origins of Large Economic Downturns

The Network Origins of Large Economic Downturns The Network Origins of Large Economic Downturns Daron Acemoglu Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi This version: June 2013 Abstract This paper shows that large economic downturns may result from the

More information

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018 Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle Jesper Lindé Sveriges Riksbank Mathias Trabandt Freie Universität Berlin June 7, 218 Motivation Key observations during the Great Recession: Extraordinary contraction

More information

Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk

Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk Monica Billio 1 Massimiliano Caporin 2 Roberto Panzica 3 Loriana Pelizzon 1,3 1 University Ca Foscari Venezia (Italy) 2 University of Padova (Italy) 3 Goethe University

More information

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics DSGE-Models Calibration and Introduction to Dynare Dr. Andrea Beccarini Willi Mutschler, M.Sc. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics willi.mutschler@uni-muenster.de Summer 2012 Willi Mutschler

More information

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I Name: Students ID: ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I I. Short Questions (21/2 points each) Mark the following statements as True (T) or False (F) and give a brief explanation of your answer in each case. 1. 2.

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory) 14.581 Week 9 Spring 2013 14.581 (Week 9) Gravity Models (Theory) Spring 2013 1 / 44 Today s Plan 1 The Simplest Gravity Model: Armington

More information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4 1 Basic Model 1.1 Uzawa Utility E 0 t=0 θ t U (c t, h t ) θ 0 = 1 θ t+1 = β (c t, h t ) θ t ; β c < 0; β h > 0. Time-varying discount factor With a constant

More information

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Roberto Robatto March 12, 2014 Abstract I present an irrelevance proposition for some open market operations that exchange money and

More information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks Eric R. Sims University of Notre Dame and NBER January 17, 2012 Abstract In a standard New Keynesian model, a Taylor-type interest rate rule moves the equilibrium real

More information

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005 Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy by Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli March 2005 Motivation The new Keynesian model for the closed economy - equilibrium dynamics: simple

More information

Learning and Global Dynamics

Learning and Global Dynamics Learning and Global Dynamics James Bullard 10 February 2007 Learning and global dynamics The paper for this lecture is Liquidity Traps, Learning and Stagnation, by George Evans, Eran Guse, and Seppo Honkapohja.

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations? A Bayesian DSGE Approach Ippei Fujiwara 1 Yasuo Hirose 1 Mototsugu 2 1 Bank of Japan 2 Vanderbilt University August 4, 2009 Contributions of this paper

More information

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8 1 General Assumptions Ignore variations in the capital stock There are differentiated goods with Calvo price stickiness Wages are not sticky Monetary policy is a choice

More information

The Smets-Wouters Model

The Smets-Wouters Model The Smets-Wouters Model Monetary and Fiscal Policy 1 1 Humboldt Universität zu Berlin uhlig@wiwi.hu-berlin.de Winter 2006/07 Outline 1 2 3 s Intermediate goods firms 4 A list of equations Calibration Source

More information

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework Dongpeng Liu Nanjing University Sept 2016 D. Liu (NJU) Solving D(S)GE 09/16 1 / 63 Introduction Targets of the

More information

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model Lawrence J. Christiano August 4, 04 Baseline NK model with no capital and with a competitive labor market. private sector equilibrium conditions

More information

The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations Daron Acemoglu Vasco M. Carvalho Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi October 2011

The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations Daron Acemoglu Vasco M. Carvalho Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi October 2011 The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations Daron Acemoglu Vasco M. Carvalho Asuman Ozdaglar Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi October 2011 Barcelona GSE Working Paper Series Working Paper nº 587 The Network Origins

More information

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes. 14.452. Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes. Olivier Blanchard May 12, 2007 Nr. 1 Look at three issues: Time consistency. The inflation bias. The trade-off between inflation and activity. Implementation and

More information

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World Jesper Lindé and Mathias Trabandt ECB-EABCN-Atlanta Nonlinearities Conference, December 15-16, 2014 Sveriges Riksbank and Federal Reserve Board December 16, 2014

More information

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj Macro II (UC3M, MA/PhD Econ) Professor: Matthias Kredler Problem Set 1 Due: 29 April 216 You are encouraged to work in groups; however, every student has to hand in his/her own version of the solution.

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation Daron Acemoglu MIT September 19, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition and Innovation September 19, 2011. 1 / 51 Competition and Innovation

More information

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano Foundations for the New Keynesian Model Lawrence J. Christiano Objective Describe a very simple model economy with no monetary frictions. Describe its properties. markets work well Modify the model to

More information

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions George-Marios Angeletos Jennifer La O July 2017 How should fiscal and monetary policy respond to business cycles when firms have imperfect information

More information

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information Guido Lorenzoni (MIT) Class notes, 06 March 2007 Nominal rigidities: imperfect information How to model demand shocks in a baseline environment with imperfect info?

More information

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection Eric Bartelsman, John Haltiwanger & Stefano Scarpetta American Economic Review (2013) Presented by Beatriz González January

More information

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages Lawrence J. Christiano August 25, 203 Baseline NK model with no capital and with a competitive labor market. private sector equilibrium

More information

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University Lecture 7 The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 2013 Phillips Department of Economics Lakehead University 7.1 Outline 1 2 3 4 5 Phillips Phillips 7.2 Market Equilibrium:

More information

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information Guido Lorenzoni (MIT) WEL-MIT-Central Banks, December 2006 Motivation Central bank observes an increase in spending Is it driven

More information

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2017 1 Introduction Most modern dynamic macro models have at their core a prototypical real business

More information

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks Satya P. Das @ NIPFP Satya P. Das (@ NIPFP) New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks 1 / 20 1 Blanchard-Kiyotaki Model 2 New Keynesian Phillips Curve 3 Utility

More information

Internation1al Trade

Internation1al Trade 4.58 International Trade Class notes on 4/8/203 The Armington Model. Equilibrium Labor endowments L i for i = ; :::n CES utility ) CES price index P = i= (w i ij ) P j n Bilateral trade ows follow gravity

More information

Risk Sharing with (Dis)Aggregate Shocks

Risk Sharing with (Dis)Aggregate Shocks Risk Sharing with Dis)Aggregate Shocks Emmanouil Kitsios International Monetary Fund Manasa Patnam CREST ESAE) March, 2014 Abstract In this paper we examine conditions under which optimal risk sharing

More information

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle Lawrence J. Christiano April 1, 2013 Outline We present baseline

More information

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models Davide Debortoli Jordi Galí October 2017 Davide Debortoli, Jordi Galí () Insights from TANK October 2017 1 / 23 Motivation Heterogeneity

More information

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary Lawrence J. Christiano March 30, 2013 Baseline developed earlier: NK model with no capital

More information

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

0. Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides Monetary Policy, 7/3 2018 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen "0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic

More information

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress Daron Acemoglu MIT September 15, 2016. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 15, 2016.

More information

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Schumpeterian Growth Models Schumpeterian Growth Models Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 2012 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch14 Introduction Most process innovations either increase the quality of an existing

More information

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation? Benjamin Moll G Online Appendix: The Model in Discrete Time and with iid Shocks This Appendix presents a version

More information

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Real Business Cycle Model (RBC) Seyed Ali Madanizadeh November 2013 RBC Model Lucas 1980: One of the functions of theoretical economics is to provide fully articulated, artificial economic systems that

More information

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy Robert Barsky, Alejandro Justiniano, and Leonardo Melosi Online Appendix 1 1 Introduction This appendix describes the extended DSGE model

More information

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION ONLINE APPENDIX CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION By ERIC BARTELSMAN, JOHN HALTIWANGER AND STEFANO SCARPETTA This appendix presents a detailed sensitivity

More information

Topic 8: Optimal Investment

Topic 8: Optimal Investment Topic 8: Optimal Investment Yulei Luo SEF of HKU November 22, 2013 Luo, Y. SEF of HKU) Macro Theory November 22, 2013 1 / 22 Demand for Investment The importance of investment. First, the combination of

More information

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model Toulouse School of Economics, 2009-2010 Macroeconomics II Franck Portier Homework 1 Problem I An AD-AS Model Let us consider an economy with three agents (a firm, a household and a government) and four

More information

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations Chapter 4 Applications/Variations 149 4.1 Consumption Smoothing 4.1.1 The Intertemporal Budget Economic Growth: Lecture Notes For any given sequence of interest rates {R t } t=0, pick an arbitrary q 0

More information

Sticky Leverage. João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke. September 28, 2013

Sticky Leverage. João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke. September 28, 2013 Sticky Leverage João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke September 28, 213 Introduction Models of monetary non-neutrality have traditionally emphasized the importance of sticky

More information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II Macroeconomics Theory II Francesco Franco Nova SBE March 9, 216 Francesco Franco Macroeconomics Theory II 1/29 The Open Economy Two main paradigms Small Open Economy: the economy trades with the ROW but

More information

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence Carlo Coen Castellino September 2010 Abstract In this work I revisit the paper by Galí et al. (2003), which explains how the changes over time in the

More information

Endogenous information acquisition

Endogenous information acquisition Endogenous information acquisition ECON 101 Benhabib, Liu, Wang (2008) Endogenous information acquisition Benhabib, Liu, Wang 1 / 55 The Baseline Mode l The economy is populated by a large representative

More information

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes David L. Kelly Department of Economics University of Miami Box 248126 Coral Gables, FL 33134 dkelly@miami.edu Current Version: Fall 2013/Spring 2013 I Introduction A

More information

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t ) 6. Economic growth Let us recall the main facts on growth examined in the first chapter and add some additional ones. (1) Real output (per-worker) roughly grows at a constant rate (i.e. labor productivity

More information

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE James Bullard President and CEO 2018 ECB Forum on Central Banking Macroeconomics of Price- and Wage-Setting June 19, 2018 Sintra, Portugal Any opinions expressed

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

1 The Basic RBC Model

1 The Basic RBC Model IHS 2016, Macroeconomics III Michael Reiter Ch. 1: Notes on RBC Model 1 1 The Basic RBC Model 1.1 Description of Model Variables y z k L c I w r output level of technology (exogenous) capital at end of

More information

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy Jonathan Heathcote Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Kjetil Storesletten Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and CEPR Gianluca Violante

More information

INFORMATION AND INTERACTION. Dirk Bergemann, Tibor Heumann, and Stephen Morris. May 2017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO.

INFORMATION AND INTERACTION. Dirk Bergemann, Tibor Heumann, and Stephen Morris. May 2017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. INFORMATION AND INTERACTION By Dirk Bergemann, Tibor Heumann, and Stephen Morris May 2017 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO 2088 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY Box 208281

More information

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari) University of Minnesota 8107 Macroeconomic Theory, Spring 2012, Mini 1 Fabrizio Perri Stationary equilibria in economies with Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets We are now at the point in which

More information

Problem 1 (30 points)

Problem 1 (30 points) Problem (30 points) Prof. Robert King Consider an economy in which there is one period and there are many, identical households. Each household derives utility from consumption (c), leisure (l) and a public

More information

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE James Bullard President and CEO 2018 BOJ-IMES Conference Central Banking in a Changing World May 31, 2018 Tokyo, Japan Any opinions expressed here are my own

More information

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013) The Ramsey Model (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 213) 1 Introduction The Ramsey model (or neoclassical growth model) is one of the prototype models in dynamic macroeconomics.

More information

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation Minseong Kim 30 April 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/71072/ MPRA Paper No. 71072, posted 5 May 2016 16:21

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018 Advanced Macroeconomics II Real Business Cycle Models Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018 Assumptions Optimization by consumers and rms Perfect competition General equilibrium Absence of a

More information

Endogenous Information Choice

Endogenous Information Choice Endogenous Information Choice Lecture 7 February 11, 2015 An optimizing trader will process those prices of most importance to his decision problem most frequently and carefully, those of less importance

More information