ON THE CONTINUITY OF EQUILIBRIUM AND CORE CORRESPONDENCES IN ECONOMIES WITH DIFFERENTIAL INFORMATION*

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "ON THE CONTINUITY OF EQUILIBRIUM AND CORE CORRESPONDENCES IN ECONOMIES WITH DIFFERENTIAL INFORMATION*"

Transcription

1 Working Paper Economics Series 07 May 2003 Departamento de Economía Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Calle Madrid, Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) ON THE CONTINUITY OF EQUILIBRIUM ND CORE CORRESPONDENCES IN ECONOMIES WITH DIFFERENTIL INFORMTION* Ezra Einy 1, Ori Haimanko 2, Diego Moreno 3 and Benyamin Shitovitz 4 bstract We study upper semi-continuity of the private core, the coarse core, and the Radner equilibrium correspondences for economies with differential information, with Boylan (1971) topology on agents' information fields. eywords: Economies with differential information, Radner equilibrium, rational expectations, coarse core, private core, continuity. 1 Einy, Departament of Economics, Ben Gurion University of the Negev, Beer Sheva, Israel einy@bgumail.bgu.ac.il 2 Haimanko, Departament of Economics, Ben Gurion University of the Negev, Beer Sheva, Israel orih@bgumail.bgu.ac.il 3 Moreno, Departamento de Economía, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Getafe, Spain. dmoreno@eco.uc3m.es; 4 Shitovitz, Department of Economics, University of Haifa (Haifa, Israel 31905). binya@econ.haifa.ac.il *Moreno acknowledges the support of the Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología, grant BEC

2 1 Introduction We study the behavior of several notions of competitive equilibrium and core in economies with differential information. Our aim is to check whether these solution concepts respond continuously to changes in agents characteristics in the underlying economy. This is a basic problem in general equilibrium theory, that was studied by several authors in the context of economies with complete information. For instance, annai (1970) considered continuity properties of the core of a pure exchange economy, while Hildenbrand (1972) and Hildenbrand and Mertens (1972) investigated the continuity of the equilibrium-set correspondence. It turns out that both solution concepts are upper semi-continuous : when the agents characteristics converge, together with a selection from the solution of corresponding economies, then the limit of the selection belongs to the solution of the limiting economy. In an economy with differential information every agent is characterized by his initial endowment of commodities (which is a random variable, whose value is determined by the realization of the state of nature), his state-dependent utility function, and his private information represented by a σ-fieldonthespaceof states of nature (i.e., an agent can tell whether the realized state of nature is contained in any given set from the field). In measuring closeness of these economies, the only non-standard part lies in evaluating the distance between agents information endowments. We do so by means of Boylan (1971) metric, following llen (1983) who was the first to apply topologies on information fields in economies with differential information. (llen proved continuity 1 of the consumer demand and the value of information with respect to Boylan metric.) We first consider a notion of competitive equilibrium for economies with differential information introduced in Radner (1968, 1982), that imposes measurability restrictions with respect to the private information on each agent s trades. We show that if the space of random commodity bundles is L m p (where m is the number of commodities, and 1 p< ) and the prices lie in its dual, then the Radner equilibrium correspondence is upper semi-continuous, see Theorem 1. We do not consider another equilibrium concept, that of rational expectations, in the study of continuity of equilibrium correspondences. The reason is simple: the rational expectations equilibrium correspondence cannot be upper semi-continuous since the information revealed to the agents by prices may have severe discontinuities; e.g., a sequence of fully revealing price systems can converge to a constant price system which reveals no information whatsoever. In the literature there are several notions of core for economies with differential information (for a comprehensive survey see Forges, Minelli and Vohra (2002)). mong them, two notions stand out in that they are nonempty under 1 Cotter (1986, 1987) showed that continuity properties could be obtained with a weaker topology. Stinchocombe (1990) derived further results for both topologies. Van andt (2002) studied continuity of solutions to constrained maximization problems with respect to the Cotter (1986) topology on the information fields. 2

3 quite general conditions on the economy. These are Wilson (1978) coarse core, where a blocking coalition considers its interim payoffs (following the revelation of private information to agents) given a common knowledge event, and Yannelis (1991) private core, where blocking is based on ex-ante payoffs, but measurability of all allocations with respect to agents private information is required. The relation between the private core and the Radner equilibrium correspondence is analogous to that of the core and the Walrasian equilibrium correspondence in a complete information economy see Einy, Moreno and Shitovitz (2001) for an equivalence result in economies with differential information and a continuum of traders. Here we show that the private core correspondence may not be upper semi-continuous even in simple economies (see Example 1). However, the private core correspondence is upper semi-continuous for every converging sequence of economies where agents information fields approach their limiting information fields from above (which corresponds to the case of decreasing information quality; see Theorem 2). The private core correspondence is also upper semi-continuous when the limiting economy is a complete information economy (see Theorem 3). This stands in contrast to Theorem 1 of rasa and Shafer (2001), that shows discontinuity of this correspondence when the agents common prior 2 over the set of states of nature changes, in a way that the information becomes complete in the end. Here we view the common prior as an invariable characteristic of the economy 3 (together with the sets of agents, commodities, and states of nature), and not as part of the agents characteristics. ccordingly, in all our results the information fields of the agents (and their other characteristics) are allowed to vary, while the common prior stays fixed. This is precisely what allows us to obtain the positive result of Theorem 3. Finally, we examine the coarse core correspondence, and find that it is also fragile, as it may fail to be upper semi-continuous even when the private core correspondence is (see Example 2). 2 The Model We consider a pure exchange economy E with differential information. The commodity space is R m +. The set of agents is N = {1, 2,..., n}. The uncertainty in the economy is described by a probability space (, z,µ), where is the space of states of nature, which we assume to be compact and metrizable, z is a σ-fieldofsubsetsof, and µ is the common prior of the agents - a countably additive probability measure on (, z). The initial information of agent i N is given by a σ-subfield z i of z; that is, for every z i agent i knows whether the realized state of nature is contained in. 2 To interpret the model of rasa and Shafer (2001) in our setting, one has to view this common prior as defined on the product of the set of states of nature and the signals receivable by agents, rather than the set of states of nature alone (as we do here, with information fields as a device of revealing information). 3 Or, more precisely, of its information structure determined by the underlying economic data. 3

4 For any 1 p< we write L m p for the Banach space of all z-measurable functions 4 x : R m such that kxk p R kx (ω)kp dµ (ω) 1 p < (here k k stands for the Euclidean norm on R m ). It is well known that L m p L m 1 and that convergence in L m p -norm implies convergence in L m 1 -norm. Given S N, an S-assignment in economy E is an S-tuple x = x i of non-negative functions (commodity bundles) inwhichx i L m 1 for every i S. nn-assignment is simply referred to as an assignment. Thereisafixed initial assignment of commodities in the economy, e =(e 1,..., e n ); e i is referred to as the initial endowment of agent i. ns-allocation is an S-assignment x = x i that5 satisfies the feasibility constraint: X x i (ω) X e i (ω) for (µ-)almost every ω. (1) Given a subfield z 0 of z, we use the extended notion of z 0 -measurability by calling a function, which is equal µ-almost everywhere to an z 0 -measurable function, also z 0 -measurable. private S-allocation is an S-allocation x = x i such that x i is z i -measurable for every i S. n N-allocation (respectively, private N-allocation) is called an allocation (respectively, private allocation). The preferences of agent i over the commodity space are represented by a state-dependent utility function, u i : R m + R +, measurable with respect to the product field z B (where B is the σ-fieldofborelsetsinr+ m )and continuous 6. We will always assume that u i (ω, ) is concave on R m + for every ω, and non-decreasing. If x =(x 1,..., x n ) is an assignment, we denote U i x i = u i ω,x i (ω) dµ, (2) whenever the integral exists. To sum up, an economy with differential information, E, is described by the collection e i,u i, z i n. i=1 possible interpretation 7 of the above economy is the following. It extends over two periods of time. In the first period there is uncertainty about the state of nature. In this period, agents make contracts on redistribution of their initial endowments either before the state of nature is realized (ex-ante) or after receiving their private information (interim). In the second period agents carry out previously made agreements, and consumption takes place. In order to define convergence of economies with differential information, we use a pseudo-metric (introduced in Boylan (1971)) on the family z of σ- 4 Or, to be precise, their equivalence classes, where any two functions which are equal µ-almost everywhere are identified. 5 For any two vectors x =(x 1,..., x m),y =(y 1,...,y m) R m we write x y when x k y k for every k =1,...,m, and x>ywhen x y and x 6= y. 6 Continuity of u implies its z B-measurability when z is the σ-field of Borel sets in. 7 This paragraph is a quotation from llen and Yannelis (2001), p. 265, slightly modified to fit oursetting. 4

5 subfields of z, given by d (z 1, z 2 )= sup z 1 inf µ (4B)+ sup B z 2 B z 2 inf µ (4B), z 1 where 4B =(\B) (B\) is the symmetric difference of and B. Consider a sequence {E k } k=1 of economies E k = e i k,ui k, n k zi with differential i=1 information. We say that {E k } k=1 converges8 to an economy E = e i,u i, z i n i=1 if for every i N: i) 9 e i k Lm 1 k ei ; ii) u i k k u i uniformly on every compact subset of R+ m ; iii) z i k k z i in Boylan pseudo-metric. Finally, if X is a random variable on (, z,µ) and z 0 is a σ-subfield of z, denote by E (X z 0 ) the conditional expectation 10 of X with respect to z 0. 3 Continuity of Radner Equilibrium Correspondence Radner (1968, 1982) introduced a notion of competitive equilibrium for economies with differential information. Here we study the continuity of Radner equilibrium correspondence. In what follows we consider commodity bundles that are members of L m p, for some given p 1. Let E = e i,u i, z i n be an economy with differential i=1 information. price system π is a non-negative function in the unit sphere of L m q (i.e., kπk q =1), where q (1, ] is such that 1 p + 1 q =1. It is elementary that any price functional ϕ in the economy (which is a continuous linear functional in the dual of L m p, restricted to the cone of commodity bundles in L m p )isrepresentable by a unique price system π ϕ : for any commodity bundle x, ϕ (x) = R π ϕ xdµ. Given a price system π, the budget set of i N is given by ½ x L m p x is non-negative and zi -measurable and B i (π) = π xdµ ¾ π e i dµ. Radner equilibrium of E is a pair (x, π), where π is a price system and x =(x 1,..., x n ) is a private allocation such that for every i Nx i maximizes U i on B i (π). Denote by RE(E) the set of Radner equilibria in E. The following theorem (whose proof, together with all other proofs, is given in Section 6) establishes upper semi-continuity of the Radner equilibrium correspondence. 8 We use the language of convergence of economies only for the sake of convenience. s was mentioned in the introduction, the convergence here is actually restricted to the agents characteristics. 9 By Lm p k wedenoteconvergenceinthelm p -norm. 10 Since E (X z 0 ) is usually defined as a class of functions, we will always take a selection from it. 5

6 Theorem 1. Let {E k } k=1 be a sequence of economies E k = e i k,ui k, n k zi i=1 with differential information that converge to E = e i,u i, z i n i=1, where ei is strictly positive for every i N. If {(x k, π k )} k=1 is a sequence such that (x k, π k ) RE(E k ) for every k, and for every i N, x i k Lm p k xi, π k Lm q k π, then (x,π) RE(E). One may ask whether L m q -norm convergence of price systems can be replaced with weak* convergence 11, without affecting the result. The answer is negative, as will be made clear in Example 1 of the next section. In this example we will also show that confining attention only to Radner equilibrium allocations does not yield an upper semi-continuous correspondence. 4 Continuity of the Private Core In this section we study the continuity of the private core of an economy with differential information, introduced in Yannelis (1991). Let E = e i,u i, z i n be an economy with differential information. The i=1 private core of E consists of all private allocations x = x 1,..., x n for which there do not exist a non-empty coalition S N and a private S-allocation y = y i, such that U i y i >U i x i (3) for every i S. s was said in the introduction, in complete information economies the core correspondence is upper semi-continuous, see, e.g., anai (1970). Therefore, it is natural to ask whether upper semi-continuity continues to hold for economies with differential information. That is, if {x k } k=1 is a sequence of private core allocations in a converging sequence of economies {E k } k=1, and {x k} k=1 converges to x, doesthisimplythatx is a private core allocation for the limiting economy E? The following example shows that the answer may be negative for all converging sequences {x k } k=1, even in very simple economies. Example 1. For every ε [0, 1) let E ε be an economy in which m =1, n =2,e 1 k = e2 k 1 2, =[0, 1] [2, 3], µ is the restriction of the Lebesgue ½measure on the real line to (normalized ½ so as to satisfy µ () =1), u 1 (ω,x)= x, if ω [0, 1], 0, if ω [0, 1],, u 0, if ω [2, 3] ; 2 (ω,x) =, z x, if ω [2, 3]. 1 is the finite field generated by [0, 1] [2, 2+ε], (2 + ε, 3], and z 2 is the finite field generated by [0, 1], [2, 3]. Let x k = x 1 k k,x2 be a private core allocation 12 in the economy 11 When 1 <p,the weak* convergence is of course equivalent to the weak convergence. 12 Existenceofaprivatecoreallocationinsuchaneconomycanbeestablishedbyusing arguments of Glycopantis, Muir and Yannelis (2001) (where existence was established with no free disposal condition). lternatively, one can show nonemptiness of the private core of E ε by checking that it contains the initial endowments allocation. 6

7 E 1. Since x k is private, it has the form 2k ³ x k = a 1 (k) χ [0,1] [2,2+ 1 2k ] + a 2 (k) χ (2+ 1 2k,3],b 1 (k) χ [0,1] + b 2 (k) χ [2,3] (where χ stands for the indicator function of the set ); the equality holds almost everywhere. The feasibility constraint (1) taken for ω [0, 1] and ω [2, k ] yields a 1 (k)+b 1 (k) 1, and a 1 (k)+b 2 (k) 1. (4) Note that a 1 (k) 1 2 (5) since otherwise for S = {1} an S-allocation y = e 1 k would satisfy U 1 y 1 >U 1 x 1 k, contrary to x k being a private core allocation in the economy E 1 (that is, x k 2k would not be individually rational). Individual rationality of x k also implies From (5), (6), and (4) we deduce that b 2 (k) 1 2. (6) a 1 (k) =b 2 (k) = 1 2. Consider now a converging subsequence of {(a 1 (k),a 2 (k),b 1 (k),b 2 (k))} k=1. It exists since 0 a 1 (k),a 2 (k),b 1 (k),b 2 (k) 1 by the feasibility constraint, and w.l.o.g. we will assume that the sequence itself converges. This implies convergence of {x k } k=1 pointwise almost everywhere (and thus in Lm 1 -norm, or more generally any L m p -norm for 1 p< due to the boundedness of the sequence) to x = ³a 1 χ [0,1] + a 2 χ [2,3],b 1 χ [0,1] + b 2 χ [2,3], o with a 1 = b 2 = 1 2 ne. lso, 1 converges to E 0. However, x is not a private 2k k=1 core allocation of E 0. Indeed, take S = N and y = ³χ [0,1], χ [2,3]. y is obviously a private allocation in E 0, and U i y i >U i x i is satisfied for every i (that is, x is not Pareto-optimal). Note that this example would still work if the utility functions were slightly modified to become strictly concave and strictly increasing. The compact set could also be made connected without affecting our claim. 7

8 n Our o final observation is that there is a sequence of Radner equilibria in E 1 that does not converge to a Radner equilibrium in E 2k 0. Indeed, the k=1 notrade scenario(e, π k ), where e consists of the initial endowments of the agents and ( (4k) 1 q χ[2,2+ 1 π k = ], if q<, 2k χ [2,2+ 1 2k ], if q =, is a Radner equilibrium in E 1, but {π k} 2k k=1 clearly does not converge in the L m q -norm. It does converge weakly*, but to the zero function. This shows that Theorem 1 cannot be strengthened by assuming that {π k } k=1 converges to π weakly* (since π can be zero despite that kπ k k q =1for every k). In the limiting economy E 0, every Radner equilibrium has the form (x, π), where x = ³χ [0,1], χ [2,3] (almost everywhere) and π (ω) dµ (ω) = π (ω) dµ (ω). [0,1] This shows that the set of Radner equilibrium allocations RE is also not upper semi-continuous: e RE(E 1 2k ) for every k, but RE(E 0)={x} and x 6= e. [2,3] In the above example the limiting information field is neither included, nor includes, the information fields that converge to it. However, when this does not occur, positive results on upper semi-continuity of the private core can be obtained. Theorem 2. Let {E k } k=1 = e i k,ui k, n k i=1ª zi be a sequence of economies k=1 with differential information that converges 13 to E = e i,u i, z i n, such that i=1 z i k zi for all i N and k. If{x k } k=1 is such that x k = x 1 k,..., k xn is a private core allocation in E k, and for every i Nx i k Lm 1 k xi,thenx = x 1,..., x n is a private core allocation in E. ccording to Theorem 2, if the information fields of agents shrink when they approach the limiting information fields (which can be the case when, e.g., the level of random noise increases), then the private core is upper semicontinuous. Theorem 3 below may be viewed as a dual result, showing that the private core is also upper semi-continuous when the information of agents rises to the fullest possible extent, i.e., when the economies converge to a complete information economy. It stands in contrast to the result of rasa and Shafer 13 Convergence of information fields in Boylan pseudo-metric (which is one of the aspects of convergence of economies) is not, in fact, necessary for this theorem. 8

9 (2001), showing generic discontinuity of the private core correspondence when complete information is approached by changing the common prior of agents (rather than by expanding their information fields). Theorem 3. Let {E k } k=1 = e i k,ui k, n k i=1ª zi be a sequence of economies k=1 with differential information that converges to E = e i,u i, z i n i=1, where zi = z for every i N, z is the σ-fieldofallborelsetsin, and each e i is a continuous and strictly positive function. ssume also that for every two disjoint andclosedsubsets and B of there exist i k zi k for every i and k such that i k and i k B = for all sufficiently large k (that is, zi k can separate disjoint closed subsets for all sufficiently large k). Then, if {x k } k=1 is such that x k = x 1 k,..., k xn is a private core allocation in Ek and for every i N x i k Lm 1 k xi, x = x 1,..., x n is a private core allocation in E. 5 The Coarse Core Let E = e i,u i, z i n be an economy with differential information. The coarse i=1 core of E consists of all allocations x = x 1,..., x n for which there do not exist a non-empty coalition S N, an event V V zi with µ() > 0 (where zi stands for the finest field included in all z i,i S, and represents the common knowledge of agents in S), and an S-assignment y = y i,that satisfy the following conditions: (i) P yi (ω) P ei (ω) for almost every ω ; (ii) 14 E u,y i i ( ) z i (ω) > E u,x i i ( ) z i (ω) for almost every ω and i S. ccording to (i), y is feasible for agents in S, given the event and their initial endowments. nd (ii) means that agents in S can improve their conditional expected utility when they redistribute their endowments according to y, given that occurred. The concept of coarse core (introduced by Wilson (1978)) thus disallows existence of such S,, and y. Wilson (1978) proved that the coarse core is non-empty under standard conditions on the economy, at least when the set of states of nature is finite. The following example shows that the coarse core may not be upper semi-continuous, even when the private core is Recall that E (X z 0 ) stands for the conditional expectation of X with respect to z In this example, along the converging sequence of economies the information fields of agents 1 and 2 are fixed, while the information fields of agents 3 and 4 approximate full information. The proof of Theorem 3 can be used to show that the limit of any converging sequence of private core allocations will be a private core allocation in the limiting economy (commodity bundles y 1 and y 2, if used by a blocking coalition in E, will not even have to be approximated by a continuous function in order to show that E y 1 z i k and E y 2 z i k approximate them uniformly). 9

10 Example 2. Consider a sequence of economies E k = e i k,ui k, n k zi i=1 with m =2and n =4, where: 1) u i k is state-independent, and ui k (x 1,x 2 )=u(x 1,x 2 )= x1 + 2 x 2 for every i, k; 2) e i k is state-independent, and e1 k = e3 k =(10, 110),e2 k = e4 k =(110, 10), for every k; 3) the compact space of states is the sequence {ω j } j=0,whereω 0 =0, and ω j = 1 j for j 1; 4) µ is a measure on according to which µ ({ω 2j })=µ({ω 2j+1 }) > 0 for every j 0; n o 5) z 1 k = z2 k =, {ω 2j } j=0, {ω 2j+1} j=0, ; that is, 1 and2canonlytell whether the realized state of nature has even or odd index; 6) z 3 k = z4 k is the minimal σ-field in that contains {ω 0}, {ω 1 },..., {ω k }, and {ω j } j=k ; that is, 3 and 4 can actually know the state of nature, provided its index is less than k. It is clear that the sequence {E k } k=1 converges to an economy E = e i,u i, z i n i=1, which differs from those in {E k } k=1 only in one respect: z3 = z 4 is the field of all subsets of. Now consider an assignment x = x 1,x 2,x 3,x 4, where x 1 (ω 2j )=x 2 (ω 2j+1 )= (50, 50) and x 1 (ω 2j+1 )=x 2 (ω 2j )=(70, 70) for every j 0, and x 3 = x 4 (60, 60). It is obvious that x is an allocation for all economies in {E k } k=1, and for E. We show first that x is not a coarse core allocation for E. Indeed, S = {2, 3} can improve the conditional expected utility of both 2 and 3 given that the state of nature has an odd index. We simply take = {ω 2j+1 } j=0 (which is clearly in the common knowledge of 2 and 3 in E: z 2 z 3 ), and y = y i defined by y 2 (ω 2j+1 ) (51, 51),y 3 (ω 2j+1 ) (69, 69). Then (i) and (ii) are satisfied, and hence x is not a coarse core allocation for E. Our next step is to show that x is a coarse core allocation for every E k. (This will imply that the coarse core correspondence indeed lacks upper semicontinuity.) To this end suppose that there are k, S,, and y that satisfy (i) and (ii) in the economy E k. It is easy to see that x is individually rational (given each trader s information), and so S must contain more than one trader. Note that (ii) implies > u y i (ω) dµ (ω) = E u x i ( ) z i (ω) dµ (ω) = E u y i ( ) z i (ω) dµ (ω) u x i (ω) dµ (ω) for every i S, since is an element of every F i. Therefore X u y i (ω) dµ (ω) > X u x i (ω) dµ (ω). (7) 10

11 t the same time, from concavity and homogeneity of u and (i) it follows that: X u y i (ω) Ã X! dµ (ω) u y i (ω) dµ (ω) Ãs X = s X y i (ω) 1 dµ (ω)+ y i (ω) 2 dµ (ω) P R 2s (yi (ω) 1 + y i (ω) 2 ) dµ (ω) 2 2! 2 2 =2 X y i (ω) 1 + y i (ω) 2 dµ (ω) X e i (ω) 1 + e i (ω) 2 dµ (ω) =2 120 S dµ (ω) =240 S µ(). Thus X u y i (ω) dµ (ω) 240 S µ(). (8) If S = {1, 2} or S = {3, 4}, then for each ω P u x i (ω) =480=240 S, and so (7) and (8) are inconsistent. Since S > 1 (as was mentioned), we are left with the possibility that S {1, 2} 6= and S {3, 4} 6=. Then = since the common knowledge of all the agents in S (where belongs) contains only trivial information 16,andµ() > 0. However, clearly R u x i (ω) dµ (ω) = 240 for every i N, and therefore X u x i (ω) dµ (ω) = 240 S. Thus, (7) and (8) lead to a contradiction again. We conclude that there exist no k, S,, and y that satisfy (i) and (ii) in the economy E k, and therefore x is a coarse core allocation in every E k. 16 I.e., the field {, }. 11

12 6 Proofs Lemma 1. Let {z k } k=1 be a sequence of σ-subfields of z that converges to z 0 in Boylan pseudo-metric, and let {X k } k=1 be a sequence of functions in L 1 (, z,µ) that converges to X in L 1 -norm. If X k is z k -measurable for every k, thenx is z 0 -measurable. Proof. We will show that X = E (X z 0 ) almost everywhere. Since L 1 - norm convergence implies convergence in measure, {X k } k=1 converges to X in measure. Thus, it suffices to show that {X k } k=1 converges in measure also to E (X z 0 ). From z k -measurability of X k,x k = E (X z k ) almost everywhere. Thus, almost everywhere, X k E (X z 0 ) = E (X k z k ) E (X z 0 ) (9) For every k, E (X k z k ) E (X z k ) + E (X z k ) E (X z 0 ). (10) E (X k z k ) E (X z k ) dµ = E ( X k X z k ) dµ X k (ω) X (ω) dµ (ω) =kx k Xk 1. Since kx k Xk 1 k 0, also R E (X k z k ) E (X z k ) dµ k 0, and hence the first summand in (10) converges to zero in measure. nd E (X z k ) k E (X z 0 ) in measure by Theorem 4 in Boylan (1971). Consequently, by (9)- (10), {X k } k=1 indeed converges in measure to E (X z 0). Lemma 2. Let {u k } k=1 be a sequence of continuous functions on Rm + such that for every ω the function u k (ω, ) is concave, non-negative, and non-decreasing. ssume that {u k } k=1 converges to a function u uniformly on every compact subset of R m +. If {x k} k=1 is a sequence in Lm 1 that converges to x in the L m 1 -norm, then u k (ω,x k (ω))dµ (ω) = u(ω,x(ω))dµ (ω). lim k 12

13 Proof. Due to the uniform convergence of {u k } k=1, the sequence of C k = max ω,kxk 1 u k (ω,x) is bounded from above by some C>0. Fix ε > 0. Since {x k } k=1 converges to x in Lm 1 -norm, {x k } k=1 is uniformly integrable (see Proposition II.5.4 of Neveu (1965)) and x is integrable. Consequently, we can find M>1with: and (i) sup kx k (ω)k dµ (ω) < ε k {ω kx k (ω)k>m} 9C ; (ii) {ω kx(ω)k>m} kx (ω)k dµ (ω) < ε 9C. Note that u k (ω,x k (ω))dµ (ω) u(ω,x(ω))dµ (ω) = u k (ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x k (ω)) dµ (ω) + u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) dµ (ω) u k (ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x k (ω)) χ {ω kxk (ω)k M}dµ (ω) + u k (ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x k (ω)) dµ (ω) {ω kx k (ω)k>m} + u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) χ {ω kxk (ω)k M and kx(ω)k M}dµ (ω) + u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) dµ (ω) {ω kx k (ω)k>m or kx(ω)k>m} I 1 + I 2 + I 3 + I 4. (Here χ S stands for the characteristic function of the set S). We will show that each I j is less than ε for all sufficiently large k, and this will establish the claim. 13

14 Before proceeding further, note that concavity and monotonicity of each u k (ω, ) imply that u k (ω,x) C max{kxk, 1} (11) for all k, ω, and x R l +. The uniform convergence of {u k } k=1 to u on x R m + kxk M ª immediately yields lim k I 1 =0, and thus I 1 < ε for all sufficiently large k. Inequality (11) implies that I 2 2C kx k (ω)k dµ (ω), (12) and by our choice of M, {ω kx k (ω)k>m} I 2 < ε for all k. Since x k converges to x 0 in measure (as implied by the L m 1 -norm convergence), and u(, ) is uniformly continuous on the compact set {x R m + kxk M} (being a continuous function), u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) χ {ω kxk (ω)k M and kx(ω)k M} converges in measure to zero, and thus lim k I 3 = 0 by the generalized bounded convergence theorem. Once again, for all sufficiently large k. Finally, I 4 = {ω kx k (ω)k>m or kx(ω)k>m} {ω kx k(ω)k>m} I 3 < ε u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) dµ (ω) u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) dµ (ω) + u(ω,x k (ω)) u(ω,x(ω)) dµ (ω) {ω kx(ω)k>m} C (kx k (ω)k + max(kx (ω)k, 1))dµ (ω) {ω kx k(ω)k>m} +C (max(kx k (ω)k, 1) + kx (ω)k)dµ (ω) {ω kx(ω)k>m} 14

15 C (2 kx k (ω)k + kx (ω)k)dµ (ω) {ω kx k(ω)k>m} +C (kx k (ω)k +2kx (ω)k)dµ (ω) {ω kx(ω)k>m} C (2 kx k (ω)k + kx (ω) x k (ω)k + kx k (ω)k)dµ (ω) {ω kx k (ω)k>m} +C (kx k (ω) x (ω)k + kx (ω)k +2kx (ω)k)dµ (ω) {ω kx(ω)k>m} 2C kx k (ω) x 0 (ω)k dµ (ω) +3C kx k (ω)k dµ (ω)+3c kx 0 (ω)k dµ (ω) {ω kx k (ω)k>m} {ω kx 0 (ω)k>m} 2C kx k (ω) x 0 (ω)k dµ (ω)+ 2ε (by the choice of M). 3 The first summand in the above expression is less than ε 3 for all sufficiently large k, which yields I 4 < ε. ProofofTheorem1. We have to show that (x, π) is a Radner equilibrium of E. Note first that x =(x 1,..., x n ) is a private allocation in E. Indeed, each x i is z i -measurable by Lemma 1. Moreover, each L m 1 -norm convergent xkª i k=1 has a subsequence that converges pointwise almost everywhere, and thus x also satisfies the feasibility constraint (1). Next, for every i N πk x i k π x i dµ πk x i k x i dµ + (πk π) x i dµ. (13) By Hölder inequality, πk x i k x i dµ kπk k x i q k x i p = x i k x i p 15

16 and (π k π) x i dµ kπ k πk q x i p. However, lim k kπ k πk q = lim k x i k xi p =0, and hence by (13) π k x i kdµ k π x i dµ. (14) It is also obvious that π k e i dµ k π e i dµ. (15) From (14), (15) it follows that x i B i (π) for every i N. It remains to show that for every i N, x i maximizes U i on B i (π). Indeed, if this were not true, there would exist i N and y i B i (π) with U i (y i ) >U i (x i ). Since (1 α)min(y i,m) α&0,m y i in L m 1 -norm, U i ((1 α)min(y i,m)) α&0,m U i (y i ) by Lemma 2, and thus w.l.o.g. y i is bounded and satisfies 17 π y i dµ < π e i dµ (16) (otherwise it can be replaced by some (1 α)min(y i,m)). Now define yk i E y i zk i ; it is z i k -measurable. Since yk i k y i in measure (by Theorem 4 of Boylan (1971)), yk i Lm 1 k yi because of the uniform boundedness of yk i and yi, and it can be established similarly to (14) that π k ykdµ i k π y i dµ. Together with (15) and (16) this implies that yk i Bi (π k ) for all sufficiently large k. But U i (y i ) >U i (x i ), and x i k Lm 1 k xi,yk i Lm 1 k yi. By Lemma 2, for all sufficiently large k U i k(y i k) >U i k(x i k), where U i k is defined by (2) for the utility function u k. This cannot be consistent with y i k Bi (π k ) since (x k, π k ) RE(E k ). We reached a contradiction, which leads to the conclusion that (x, π) RE(E). ProofofTheorem2. s in the proof of Theorem 1, x =(x 1,..., x n ) is a private allocation in E. ssume, however, that x is not in the private core of E. 17 We use the fact that R π ei > 0, which is due to strict positivity of e i, and positivity of the non-vanishing π. 16

17 Then there exist a non-empty coalition S and a private S-allocation y =(y i ) such that U i y i >U i x i (17) for every i S. We will now modify y to obtain an S-allocation in E k for a certain large k. Let ε > 0 and denote by k (ε) some positive integer k for which where µ i k,ε > 1 ε for every i S, (18) i k,ε = ω e i k (ω) ei (ω) < ε ª. Such k (ε) is clearly well defined for all ε > 0, since e i k ei in measure. For this reason, we can also choose {k (ε)} ε>0 in a way that k (ε) is non-increasing in ε and lim ε&0 k (ε) =. Clearly, for almost every ω and every commodity j X y i (ω) χ i (ω) X e i k(ε),ε k(ε) (ω)+nε1, where 1=(1,...,1) R m (this inequality follows from the fact that y satisfies the feasibility constraint in E and the definition of i k(ε),ε ). Therefore, y k(ε) = (y i k(ε) ), defined by yk(ε) i (ω) j max(yi (ω) j χ i (ω) nε, 0) k(ε),ε for every ω and every commodity j, satisfies the feasibility constraint in E k(ε) : X yk(ε) i (ω) X e i k(ε) (ω) for almost every ω. (19) Note that each i k,ε is zi k -measurable (since both ei k and ei are z i k -measurable due to the inclusion z i k zi ), and so yk(ε) i is zi k(ε) -measurable. From this n o fact and (19) it follows that the sequence y k( 1 r ) is a sequence of private n o r=1 S-allocations in economies E k( 1 r ),and(18) implies that for each i S ½ ¾ r=1 y k( i converges to y 1 r ) i in measure. r=1 Since for each i S and ry i k( 1 r ) yi, the sequence ½ ¾ y k( i 1 r ) r=1 is bounded from above by an integrable function. Therefore, its convergence in measure to y i implies convergence in the L m 1 -norm as well. However, according to this and Lemma 2, for every i S lim r U i k( 1 r ) ³ y k( i 1 r ) = U i y i. 17

18 lso, since x i k Lm 1 k xi, for every i S lim r U i k( 1 r ) ³ x i k( 1 r ) = U i x i. Due to assumption (17), these two equalities yield existence of r for which ³ ³ U k( i 1 r ) y k( i 1 r ) >U k( i 1 r ) x i k( 1 r ) for every i S. This contradicts the assumption that x k( 1 allocation in E k( 1 r ). r ) is a private core Proof of Theorem 3. s in the proof of Theorem 2, if the limit allocation x =(x 1,..., x n ) is not in the private core of E, there exist a non-empty coalition S and a private S-allocation y =(y i ) such that U i y i >U i x i (20) for every i S. We can assume w.l.o.g. that each y i is bounded. (Otherwise it can be replaced by min(y i,m), which converges to y i in L m 1 -norm as M. Indeed, according to Lemma 2, U i (min(y i,m)) M U i (y i ), and thus this replacement will leave (20) intact for sufficiently large M. Clearly, the replacement also leads to a private allocation.) We will show next that it can also be assumed w.l.o.g. that each y i is continuous. By Lusin theorem, for every ε > 0 and i S there exists a continuous function yε i on, such that µ ε i < ε where i ε = n ω y i (ω) 6= yε i (ω)ª. lso denote B ε = ω there exists j with P yi ε (ω) j P o ei (ω) j + ε, B = P ω yi ε (ω) P ei (ω) ª. Since these subsets of a compact metric space are disjoint and closed (here we use continuity of both e i and yε i for every i S), they can be separated, i.e., there is a continuous function c : [0, 1] such that c 1 on B and c 0 on B ε. Thus, ey ε =(ey ε) i given by ey ε i (ω) j max(c (ω) yi ε (ω) j ε, 0) for every i S, commodityj, and ω, satisfies the feasibility constraint in E : X ey ε i (ω) X e i (ω) for every ω. Since each ey i ε is z i -measurable as a continuous function on (recall that z i = z is the σ-field of all Borel sets in ), ey ε is in fact a private S-allocation that consists of continuous functions. Moreover, for each i S and a commodity j y i ε (ω) j ε ey i ε (ω) j y i ε (ω) j (21) 18

19 for almost every ω T i c ε, since y satisfies the feasibility constraint P yi (ω) P ei (ω) for almost every ω and hence µ T i c ε \B = 0. Clearly µ T i c ε > 1 nε, and together with (21) thisimpliesthat functions in ey ε converge in measure to those in y as ε & 0. From the (obvious) uniform boundedness 18 of ey ε and y it follows that the convergence is in the L m 1 -norm as well. By Lemma 2 and (20), U i ey ε i 0 >U i x i for every i S and some sufficiently small ε 0. Thus, by replacing y in (20) by ey ε0 if necessary, we can w.l.o.g. assume that (20) holds for y that consists of continuous functions. For every k = 1, 2,... and i S define zk i = E(yi z i k ); zi k is clearly z i k-measurable and is (or can be chosen to be) bounded by the same constant as y i. We will show that a subsequence of zkª i k=1 converges to yi uniformly (almost everywhere). For every commodity j and two positive integers, l with 0 l, consider a pair of closed subsets of : ½ C l (j) = ω l 1 max ω yi j yi (ω) j l ¾ max ω yi j and ½ ec l (j) = ω l 2 max ω yi j y i (ω) j or l +1 ¾ max ω yi j y i (ω) j. Since z i k can separate disjoint closed sets for all sufficiently large k, for every there exists k = k() independent of i and j such that z i k() separates C l (j) from C e l (j) for every j and 1 l ; it can also be assumed that lim k() =. Thus for every j and 1 l there is a set D l (j) z i k() such that ½ ω l 1 max ω yi j yi (ω) j l ¾ max ω yi j D l (j) (and hence D 1 (j),d2 (j),..., D (j) cover ), and ½ D l (j) ω l 2 max ω yi j <y i (ω) j < l +1 ¾ max ω yi j. Consequently, for every j and 1 l, and almost every ω D l (j), z i k() (ω) j yi (ω) j = E(y i j z i k() )(ω) yi (ω) j (hereweusethefactthatd l (j) zi k() ) = E(y i j χ D l (j) z i k() )(ω) yi (ω) j 18 Here we use the (w.l.o.g.) assumption that the commodity bundles in y are bounded functions. 19

20 E( l +1 max ω yi j χ D l (j) z i k() )(ω) l 2 max ω yi j Similarly, = l +1 max ω yi j l 2 max ω yi j = 3 max ω yi j. z i k() (ω) j yi (ω) j 3 max ω yi j for almost every ω D l (j). We conclude that zk() i (ω) j 3 yi (ω) j max ω yi j δ (j) for almost every ω. (This means that Thus n zk() i o =1 yi uniformly (almost everywhere).) X zk() i (ω) j X y i (ω) j + nδ k() (j) X e i (ω) j + nδ k() (j) (22) for almost every ω. Now denote yk() i (ω) j max(zi k() (ω) j nδ (j), 0) for every i S, commodity j, and ω. It is clear that n yk() i o =1 to y i uniformly, and that (from (22)) the feasibility constraint X yk() i (ω) j X e i (ω) j is satisfied for every j and almost every ω. Each yk() i is also zi k() - measurable, since so is zk() i. We conclude that ª y k(), =1 where y k() = ³ yk() i, is a sequence of private S-allocations in economies ª E k(). =1 Uniform convergence of functions implies convergence in L m 1 -norm, and hence, accordingtolemma2,foreveryi S ³ lim U k() i yk() i = U i y i and lim U k() i Due to (20), there exists such that ³ Uk() i yk() i >Uk() i ³ x i k() ³ x i k() = U i x i. for every i S. This contradicts the assumption that x k() is a private core allocation in E k(). 20

21 References 1. llen, B. (1983) Neighboring Information and Distribution of gent Characteristics under Uncertainty, Journal of Mathematical Economics 12, pp llen, B. and N.C. Yannelis (2001) Differential Information Economies: Introduction, Economic Theory 18, pp Boylan, E. (1971) Equiconvergence of Martingales, nnals of Mathematical Statistics 42, pp Cotter,.D. (1986) Similarity of Information and Behavior with Pointwise Convergence Topology, Journal of Mathematical Economics 15, pp Cotter,.D. (1987) Convergence of Information, Random Variable and Noise, Journal of Mathematical Economics 16, pp Einy E., D. Moreno and B. Shitovitz (2001) Competitive and Core llocations of Large Economies with Differential Information, Economic Theory 18, pp Forges F., E. Minelli and R. Vohra (2002) Incentive and the Core of an Exchange Economy: a Survey, Journal of Mathematical Economics 38, pp Glycopantis D.,. Muir, and N.C. Yannelis (2001) n Extensive Form Interpretation of the Private Core, Economic Theory 18, pp Hildenbrand,. (1972) Continuity of the Equilibrium Set Correspondence, Journal of Economic Theory 5, pp Hildenbrand W. and J.F. Mertens (1972) Upper Hemi-Continuity of the Equilibrium Set Correspondence for Pure Exchange Economies, Econometrica 40, pp annai, Y. (1970) Continuity Properties of the Core of a Market, Econometrica 38, pp rasa, S. and W. Shafer (2001) Core Concepts in Economies where Information is lmost Complete, Economic Theory 18, pp Neveu, J. (1965) Mathematical Foundations of the Calculus of Probability, Holden Day Inc., San Francisco. 14. Radner, R. (1968) Competitive Equilibrium under Uncertainty, Econometrica 36, pp

22 15. Radner, R. (1982) Equilibrium Under Uncertainty, in.j. rrow, Intrilligator, M. D. (eds.) Handbook of Mathematical Economics, vol. II, North Holland, msterdam. 16. Stinchocombe, M. (1990) Bayesian Information Topologies, Journal of Mathematical Economics 19, pp Van andt, T. (2002) Information, Measurability, and Continuous Behavior, Journal of Mathematical Economics 38, pp Wilson, R. (1978) Information, Efficiency, and the Core of an Economy, Econometrica 46, pp Yannelis, N.C. (1991) The Core of an Economy with Differential Information, Economic Theory 1, pp

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Existence, ncentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Yeneng Sun, Lei Wu and Nicholas C. Yannelis Abstract The rational expectations equilibrium (REE), as introduced

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Rational Expectations Equilibria: Existence and Representation

Rational Expectations Equilibria: Existence and Representation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Rational Expectations Equilibria: Existence and Representation Anuj Bhowmik and Jiling Cao Indian Statistical Institute, Auckland University of Technology 24. March 2015

More information

Equilibrium Theory under Ambiguity

Equilibrium Theory under Ambiguity Equilibrium Theory under Ambiguity Wei He and Nicholas C. Yannelis July 3, 2015 Abstract We extend the classical results on the Walras-core existence and equivalence to an ambiguous asymmetric information

More information

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad

Unlinked Allocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One Bad Unlinked llocations in an Exchange Economy with One Good and One ad Chiaki Hara Faculty of Economics and Politics, University of Cambridge Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University pril 16,

More information

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery João Correia-da-Silva Faculdade de Economia. Universidade do Porto. PORTUGAL. Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Facultad de Económicas. Universidad

More information

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Existence, Incentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Existence, ncentive Compatibility and Efficiency of the Rational Expectations Equilibrium Yeneng Sun, Lei Wu and Nicholas C. Yannelis Abstract The rational expectations equilibrium (REE), as introduced

More information

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1 David Pérez-Castrillo 2 Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona David Wettstein 3 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev April 2005 1 We gratefully

More information

On extensive form implementation of contracts in differential information economies

On extensive form implementation of contracts in differential information economies Economic Theory 21, 495 526 (2003) On extensive form implementation of contracts in differential information economies Dionysius Glycopantis 1, Allan Muir 2, and Nicholas C. Yannelis 3 1 Department of

More information

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies

Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Working Papers Institute of Mathematical Economics 430 April 2010 Representation of TU games by coalition production economies Tomoki Inoue IMW Bielefeld University Postfach 100131 33501 Bielefeld Germany

More information

Lecture Notes MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS

Lecture Notes MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS Lecture Notes MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS A. Neyman Fall 2006, Jerusalem The notes may/will be updated in few days. Please revisit to check for the updated version. Please email comments to aneyman@math.huji.ac.il

More information

Equilibrium theory with asymmetric information and with infinitely many commodities

Equilibrium theory with asymmetric information and with infinitely many commodities Journal of Economic Theory 141 (2008) 152 183 www.elsevier.com/locate/jet Equilibrium theory with asymmetric information and with infinitely many commodities Konrad Podczeck a, Nicholas C. Yannelis b,

More information

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery

Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery Rational Expectations Equilibrium in Economies with Uncertain Delivery João Correia-da-Silva Faculdade de Economia. Universidade do Porto. PORTUGAL. Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Facultad de Económicas. Universidad

More information

On non-revealing rational expectations equilibrium

On non-revealing rational expectations equilibrium Econ Theory (009) 38:35 369 DOI 0.007/s0099-008-033- SYMPOSIUM On non-revealing rational expectations equilibrium Dionysius Glycopantis Allan Muir Nicholas C. Yannelis Received: 5 July 007 / Accepted:

More information

Continuity properties of the private core

Continuity properties of the private core Economic Theory (2006) 29: 453 464 DOI 10.1007/s00199-005-0001-6 SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE Erik J. Balder Nicholas C. Yannelis Continuity properties of the private core Received: 2 September 2004 / Accepted:

More information

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University February 7, 2007 2 Contents 1 Metric Spaces 1 1.1 Basic definitions...........................

More information

Core. Ichiro Obara. December 3, 2008 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, / 22

Core. Ichiro Obara. December 3, 2008 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, / 22 Ichiro Obara UCLA December 3, 2008 Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, 2008 1 / 22 in Edgeworth Box Core in Edgeworth Box Obara (UCLA) Core December 3, 2008 2 / 22 in Edgeworth Box Motivation How should we interpret

More information

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods Michael Florig Jorge Rivera Cayupi First version November 2001, this version May 2005 Abstract We study an economy where all goods entering

More information

A new perspective to rational expectations: maximin rational expectations equilibrium

A new perspective to rational expectations: maximin rational expectations equilibrium A new perspective to rational expectations: maximin rational expectations equilibrium Luciano I. de Castro 1 Marialaura Pesce 2 and Nicholas C. Yannelis 3 First Draft: October, 2010 Current Draft: April

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions Chapter 1 Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions 1.1 Arrow-Debreu model of an economy via Walras equilibrium problem. Let us consider first the so-called Arrow-Debreu model. The presentation

More information

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of Economics 201B Second Half Lecture 12-4/22/10 Justifying (or Undermining) the Price-Taking Assumption Many formulations: Core, Ostroy s No Surplus Condition, Bargaining Set, Shapley-Shubik Market Games

More information

1 General Equilibrium

1 General Equilibrium 1 General Equilibrium 1.1 Pure Exchange Economy goods, consumers agent : preferences < or utility : R + R initial endowments, R + consumption bundle, =( 1 ) R + Definition 1 An allocation, =( 1 ) is feasible

More information

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata General Equilibrium Equilibrium in Consumption GE begins (1/3) 2-Individual/ 2-good Exchange economy (No production, no transaction costs, full information..) Endowment (Nature): e Private property/ NO

More information

4 Lecture Applications

4 Lecture Applications 4 Lecture 4 4.1 Applications We now will look at some of the applications of the convex analysis we have learned. First, we shall us a separation theorem to prove the second fundamental theorem of welfare

More information

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA WORKING PAPERS Konrad Podczeck Note on the Core-Walras Equivalence Problem when the Commodity Space is a Banach Lattice March 2003 Working Paper No: 0307 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA All

More information

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller Real Analysis Notes Thomas Goller September 4, 2011 Contents 1 Abstract Measure Spaces 2 1.1 Basic Definitions........................... 2 1.2 Measurable Functions........................ 2 1.3 Integration..............................

More information

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Market Equilibrium and the Core Market Equilibrium and the Core Ram Singh Lecture 3-4 September 22/25, 2017 Ram Singh (DSE) Market Equilibrium September 22/25, 2017 1 / 19 Market Exchange: Basics Let us introduce price in our pure exchange

More information

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix

Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Bayesian Persuasion Online Appendix Emir Kamenica and Matthew Gentzkow University of Chicago June 2010 1 Persuasion mechanisms In this paper we study a particular game where Sender chooses a signal π whose

More information

On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y

On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y On the Existence of a Bayesian Nash Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information y E. Einy z, O. Haimanko z, D. Moreno x, A. Sela z, and B. Shitovitz { December 2014 Abstract We show that

More information

A remark on discontinuous games with asymmetric information and ambiguity

A remark on discontinuous games with asymmetric information and ambiguity Econ Theory Bull DOI 10.1007/s40505-016-0100-5 RESEARCH ARTICLE A remark on discontinuous games with asymmetric information and ambiguity Wei He 1 Nicholas C. Yannelis 1 Received: 7 February 2016 / Accepted:

More information

Information Advantage in Cournot Ol Title Separable Information, or Nondiffer.

Information Advantage in Cournot Ol Title Separable Information, or Nondiffer. Information Advantage in Cournot Ol Title Separable Information, or Nondiffer Author(s) Haimanko, Ori Citation Issue 2009-09 Date Type Technical Report Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/17650

More information

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses

General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses General equilibrium with externalities and tradable licenses Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Universidad de Vigo. e-mail: cherves@uvigo.es Emma Moreno-García Universidad de Salamanca. e-mail: emmam@usal.es

More information

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. Minimization Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping. 1 Minimization A Topological Result. Let S be a topological

More information

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 41, No. 2, May 2000 SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1 Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel In this article we consider

More information

On the Maximal Domain Theorem

On the Maximal Domain Theorem On the Maximal Domain Theorem Yi-You Yang April 28, 2016 Abstract The maximal domain theorem by Gul and Stacchetti (J. Econ. Theory 87 (1999), 95-124) shows that for markets with indivisible objects and

More information

Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information

Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information Existence of Equilibrium in Tullock Contests with Incomplete Information E. Einy y, O. Haimanko y, D. Moreno z, A. Sela y, and B. Shitovitz x December 2014 Abstract We show that under general assumptions

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium Introduction to General Equilibrium Juan Manuel Puerta November 6, 2009 Introduction So far we discussed markets in isolation. We studied the quantities and welfare that results under different assumptions

More information

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations We ve shown that any Walrasian equilibrium allocation (any WEA) is in the core, but it s obvious that the converse is far from

More information

Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models

Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models Bernard CORNET, Lionel DE BOISDEFFRE Abstract In a financial economy with asymmetric information and incomplete markets, we study how agents,

More information

Second Welfare Theorem

Second Welfare Theorem Second Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2015 Lecture 18, November 2 Outline 1 Second Welfare Theorem From Last Class We want to state a prove a theorem that says that any Pareto optimal allocation is (part

More information

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties In this lecture we consider a general model of a private ownership economy, i.e., a market economy in which a consumer s wealth is derived from endowments

More information

First Welfare Theorem

First Welfare Theorem First Welfare Theorem Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 17, October 31 Outline 1 First Welfare Theorem 2 Preliminaries to Second Welfare Theorem Past Definitions A feasible allocation (ˆx, ŷ) is Pareto optimal

More information

Strictly monotonic preferences on continuum of goods commodity spaces

Strictly monotonic preferences on continuum of goods commodity spaces Strictly monotonic preferences on continuum of goods commodity spaces Carlos Hervés-Beloso RGEA. Universidad de Vigo. Paulo K. Monteiro Fundação Getúlio Vargas. VI Encuentro de Análisis Funcional y Aplicaciones

More information

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract Pure strategy dominance with quasiconcave utility functions Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam Abstract By a result of Pearce (1984), in a finite strategic form game, the set of a player's serially

More information

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions Guoqiang Tian Abstract This paper provides a price equilibrium existence theorem in economies where commodities may be indivisible

More information

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples*

No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 34, 180-186 (1984) No Equilibrium in Infinite Economies: Two Examples* AHMET ALKAN Bogaripi Universitesi, Istanbul, Turkey Received December 20, 1982; revised October 14. 1983

More information

Topological properties

Topological properties CHAPTER 4 Topological properties 1. Connectedness Definitions and examples Basic properties Connected components Connected versus path connected, again 2. Compactness Definition and first examples Topological

More information

WORKING PAPER NO. 443

WORKING PAPER NO. 443 WORKING PAPER NO. 443 Cones with Semi-interior Points and Equilibrium Achille Basile, Maria Gabriella Graziano Maria Papadaki and Ioannis A. Polyrakis May 2016 University of Naples Federico II University

More information

Incentive compatibility of rational expectations equilibrium in large economies: a counterexample

Incentive compatibility of rational expectations equilibrium in large economies: a counterexample Econ Theory Bull (203) :3 0 DOI 0.007/s40505-03-000-8 SHORT PAPER Incentive compatibility of rational expectations equilibrium in large economies: a counterexample Yeneng Sun Lei Wu Nicholas C. Yannelis

More information

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses. Microeconomic Theory Summer 206-7 Mid-semester Exam 2 There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.. Consider the following 2 2 economy. The utility functions are: u (.) = x x 2

More information

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 207 Pareto Efficient Allocation Recall the following result: Result An allocation x is Pareto-efficient if and only

More information

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits

02. Measure and integral. 1. Borel-measurable functions and pointwise limits (October 3, 2017) 02. Measure and integral Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/real/notes 2017-18/02 measure and integral.pdf]

More information

Incentives and the core of an exchange economy: a survey

Incentives and the core of an exchange economy: a survey Journal of Mathematical Economics 38 (2002) 1 41 Incentives and the core of an exchange economy: a survey Françoise Forges a, Enrico Minelli b, Rajiv Vohra c, a THEMA, Université de Cergy-Pontoise, 33

More information

Normed Vector Spaces and Double Duals

Normed Vector Spaces and Double Duals Normed Vector Spaces and Double Duals Mathematics 481/525 In this note we look at a number of infinite-dimensional R-vector spaces that arise in analysis, and we consider their dual and double dual spaces

More information

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom

Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Title: The existence of equilibrium when excess demand obeys the weak axiom Abstract: This paper gives a non-fixed point theoretic proof of equilibrium existence when the excess demand function of an exchange

More information

Exercise Solutions to Functional Analysis

Exercise Solutions to Functional Analysis Exercise Solutions to Functional Analysis Note: References refer to M. Schechter, Principles of Functional Analysis Exersize that. Let φ,..., φ n be an orthonormal set in a Hilbert space H. Show n f n

More information

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness

CHAPTER 7. Connectedness CHAPTER 7 Connectedness 7.1. Connected topological spaces Definition 7.1. A topological space (X, T X ) is said to be connected if there is no continuous surjection f : X {0, 1} where the two point set

More information

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem

Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem 56 Chapter 7 Locally convex spaces, the hyperplane separation theorem, and the Krein-Milman theorem Recall that C(X) is not a normed linear space when X is not compact. On the other hand we could use semi

More information

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces Chapter 4. Measure Theory 1. Measure Spaces Let X be a nonempty set. A collection S of subsets of X is said to be an algebra on X if S has the following properties: 1. X S; 2. if A S, then A c S; 3. if

More information

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces Part III 10 Topological Space Basics Topological Spaces Using the metric space results above as motivation we will axiomatize the notion of being an open set to more general settings. Definition 10.1.

More information

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, 2014 1 Introduction Definition. If A, B are sets and there exists a bijection A B, they have the same cardinality, which we write as A, #A. If there exists

More information

On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods

On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods On the Shapley-Scarf Economy: The Case of Multiple Types of Indivisible Goods Hideo Konishi Thomas Quint Jun Wako April, 1997 (first version) October 1997 (revised) July 20, 2000 (second revision) file

More information

Notions such as convergent sequence and Cauchy sequence make sense for any metric space. Convergent Sequences are Cauchy

Notions such as convergent sequence and Cauchy sequence make sense for any metric space. Convergent Sequences are Cauchy Banach Spaces These notes provide an introduction to Banach spaces, which are complete normed vector spaces. For the purposes of these notes, all vector spaces are assumed to be over the real numbers.

More information

Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers

Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers Walras and dividends equilibrium with possibly satiated consumers Nizar Allouch Department of Economics Queen Mary, University of London Mile End Rd, E1 4NS London, United Kingdom n.allouch@qmul.ac.uk

More information

3 Measurable Functions

3 Measurable Functions 3 Measurable Functions Notation A pair (X, F) where F is a σ-field of subsets of X is a measurable space. If µ is a measure on F then (X, F, µ) is a measure space. If µ(x) < then (X, F, µ) is a probability

More information

Equilibrium Blocking in Large Quasilinear Economies Yusuke Kamishiro and Roberto Serrano

Equilibrium Blocking in Large Quasilinear Economies Yusuke Kamishiro and Roberto Serrano Equilibrium Blocking in Large Quasilinear Economies Yusuke Kamishiro and Roberto Serrano This version: May 2011 Abstract. We study information transmission in large interim quasilinear economies using

More information

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Summary of Real Analysis by Royden Dan Hathaway May 2010 This document is a summary of the theorems and definitions and theorems from Part 1 of the book Real Analysis by Royden. In some areas, such as

More information

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households Volume 29, Issue 3 Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies wit multi-member ouseolds Noriisa Sato Graduate Scool of Economics, Waseda University Abstract Tis paper focuses on te existence of

More information

Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies

Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies Assortative Matching in Two-sided Continuum Economies Patrick Legros and Andrew Newman February 2006 (revised March 2007) Abstract We consider two-sided markets with a continuum of agents and a finite

More information

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 Christopher Heil Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces Last Updated: March 10, 2018 c 2018 by Christopher Heil Chapter 1 A Primer on Norms and Banach Spaces

More information

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis Stephen Semmes Rice University Abstract These informal notes deal with some very basic objects in functional analysis, including norms and seminorms

More information

Integration on Measure Spaces

Integration on Measure Spaces Chapter 3 Integration on Measure Spaces In this chapter we introduce the general notion of a measure on a space X, define the class of measurable functions, and define the integral, first on a class of

More information

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS This exam is take-home, open-book, open-notes. You may consult any published source (cite

More information

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER

BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER BROUWER S FIXED POINT THEOREM: THE WALRASIAN AUCTIONEER SCARLETT LI Abstract. The focus of this paper is proving Brouwer s fixed point theorem, which primarily relies on the fixed point property of the

More information

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Duality for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume Headwords: CONVEXITY, DUALITY, LAGRANGE MULTIPLIERS, PARETO EFFICIENCY, QUASI-CONCAVITY 1 Introduction The word duality is

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III The Existence of Equilibrium in Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples John H. Boyd III April 1989; Updated June 1995 Abstract. This paper presents some examples that clarify certain topological and

More information

l(y j ) = 0 for all y j (1)

l(y j ) = 0 for all y j (1) Problem 1. The closed linear span of a subset {y j } of a normed vector space is defined as the intersection of all closed subspaces containing all y j and thus the smallest such subspace. 1 Show that

More information

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control Vasile Staicu University of Aveiro UNICA, May 2018 Vasile Staicu (University of Aveiro) An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control UNICA, May 2018

More information

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: WEAK AND WEAK* CONVERGENCE

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: WEAK AND WEAK* CONVERGENCE FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: WEAK AND WEAK* CONVERGENCE CHRISTOPHER HEIL 1. Weak and Weak* Convergence of Vectors Definition 1.1. Let X be a normed linear space, and let x n, x X. a. We say that

More information

20 GUOQIANG TIAN may cooperate and in others they may not, and such information is unknown to the designer. (2) This combining solution concept, which

20 GUOQIANG TIAN may cooperate and in others they may not, and such information is unknown to the designer. (2) This combining solution concept, which ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 1, 19 32 (2000) Feasible and Continuous Double Implementation of Constrained Walrasian Allocations * Guoqiang Tian Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, College

More information

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989),

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989), Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 April 26, 2005 1 Real Analysis 2, Math 651, Spring 2005 Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski 1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer

More information

Existence of Equilibria with a Tight Marginal Pricing Rule

Existence of Equilibria with a Tight Marginal Pricing Rule Existence of Equilibria with a Tight Marginal Pricing Rule J.-M. Bonnisseau and B. Cornet December 1, 2009 Abstract This paper deals with the existence of marginal pricing equilibria when it is defined

More information

Fixed Point Theorems

Fixed Point Theorems Fixed Point Theorems Definition: Let X be a set and let f : X X be a function that maps X into itself. (Such a function is often called an operator, a transformation, or a transform on X, and the notation

More information

Competitive Equilibrium

Competitive Equilibrium Competitive Equilibrium Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 16, October 26 Outline 1 Pareto Effi ciency 2 The Core 3 Planner s Problem(s) 4 Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium Decentralized vs. Centralized Economic

More information

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures

Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Competitive Market Mechanisms as Social Choice Procedures Peter J. Hammond 1 Department of Economics, Stanford University, CA 94305-6072, U.S.A. 1 Introduction and outline 1.1 Markets and social choice

More information

MORE ON CONTINUOUS FUNCTIONS AND SETS

MORE ON CONTINUOUS FUNCTIONS AND SETS Chapter 6 MORE ON CONTINUOUS FUNCTIONS AND SETS This chapter can be considered enrichment material containing also several more advanced topics and may be skipped in its entirety. You can proceed directly

More information

The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete. Resources

The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete. Resources The Bargaining Set of an Exchange Economy with Discrete Resources Murat Yılmaz and Özgür Yılmaz November 17, 2016 Abstract A central notion for allocation problems when there are private endowments is

More information

Sequences. Limits of Sequences. Definition. A real-valued sequence s is any function s : N R.

Sequences. Limits of Sequences. Definition. A real-valued sequence s is any function s : N R. Sequences Limits of Sequences. Definition. A real-valued sequence s is any function s : N R. Usually, instead of using the notation s(n), we write s n for the value of this function calculated at n. We

More information

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions vanrooijschikhof.tex April 25, 2018 van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions Notes from [vrs]. Introduction A monotone function is Riemann integrable. A continuous function is Riemann integrable.

More information

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ. 805 Winter 00 Prof. James Peck Homework Set Questions and Answers. Consider the following pure exchange economy with two consumers and two goods.

More information

EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIA FOR ECONOMIES WITH EXTERNALITIES AND A MEASURE SPACE OF CONSUMERS

EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRIA FOR ECONOMIES WITH EXTERNALITIES AND A MEASURE SPACE OF CONSUMERS THE UNIVERSITY OF KNSS WORKING PPERS SERIES IN THEORETICL ND PPLIED ECONOMICS EXISTENCE OF EQUILIBRI FOR ECONOMIES WITH EXTERNLITIES ND MESURE SPCE OF CONSUMERS Bernard Cornet Department of Economics,

More information

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory Part V 7 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets Lebesgue Integration Theory Definition 7. (Preliminary). A measure on a set is a function :2 [ ] such that. () = 2. If { } = is a finite

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo January 29, 2012 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

P-adic Functions - Part 1

P-adic Functions - Part 1 P-adic Functions - Part 1 Nicolae Ciocan 22.11.2011 1 Locally constant functions Motivation: Another big difference between p-adic analysis and real analysis is the existence of nontrivial locally constant

More information

Product metrics and boundedness

Product metrics and boundedness @ Applied General Topology c Universidad Politécnica de Valencia Volume 9, No. 1, 2008 pp. 133-142 Product metrics and boundedness Gerald Beer Abstract. This paper looks at some possible ways of equipping

More information

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The Fundamental Welfare Theorems The so-called Fundamental Welfare Theorems of Economics tell us about the relation between market equilibrium and Pareto efficiency. The First Welfare Theorem: Every Walrasian

More information

Competitive Markets with Externalities

Competitive Markets with Externalities Competitive Markets with Externalities Mitsunori Noguchi Department of Economics Meijo University noguchi@ccmfs.meijo-u.ac.jp William R. Zame Department of Economics University of California, Los Angeles

More information