A Structural Econometric Analysis of Network Formation Games

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A Structural Econometric Analysis of Network Formation Games"

Transcription

1 A Structural Econometric Analysis of Network Formation Games Shuyang Sheng June 7, 2014 Abstract The objective of this paper is to identify and estimate network formation models using observed data on network structure. We characterize network formation as a simultaneous-move game, where the utility from forming a link depends on the structure of the network, thereby generating strategic interactions between links. Because a unique equilibrium may not exist, the parameters are not point identified. We leave the equilibrium selection unrestricted and propose a partial identification approach. We derive bounds on the probability of observing a subnetwork, where a subnetwork is the restriction of a network to a subset of the individuals. Unlike the standard bounds as in Ciliberto and Tamer (2009, these subnetwork bounds are computationally tractable even for large networks. The identified set defined by these bounds can be consistently estimated following the moment inequality literature, with the bounds computed by simulation. We provide Monte Carlo evidence that the subnetwork bounds are informative. JEL Classifications: C13, C31, C57, D85 KEYWORDS: Network formation, simultaneous-move games, multiple equilibria, subnetworks, partial identification, moment inequalities, simulation. This paper is a revision of Chapter 2 of my dissertation. I am very grateful to my advisor Geert Ridder for his enormously valuable advice and guidance. I also thank Aureo de Paula, Bryan Graham, Jinyong Hahn, Matthew Jackson, Max Kasy, Rosa Matzkin, Roger Moon, Hashem Pesaran, Matthew Shum, Martin Weidner, Simon Wilkie, seminar participants at USC, UCLA, UCSD, JHU, Pittsburgh, Tilburg, CORE, California Econometrics Conference, NASM, NAWM, EMES for helpful discussions and comments. Financial support from the USC Graduate School Dissertation Completion Fellowship is acknowledged. All the errors are mine. Department of Economics, UCLA, Los Angeles, CA ssheng@econ.ucla.edu. 1

2 1 Introduction Social and economic networks influence a variety of individual behaviors and outcomes, including educational achievement (Calvó-Armengol, Patacchini, and Zenou (2009, employment (Calvó-Armengol and Jackson (2004, technology adoption (Conley and Udry (2010, consumption (Moretti (2011, and smoking (Nakajima (2007. As networks are often the result of individual decisions, understanding the formation of networks is important for the investigation of network effects. Despite that the theoretical literature on network formation has flourished in the past decades (see Jackson (2008 and Goyal (2007 for a survey, econometric studies on the identification and estimation of network formation models are still at an infant stage. The objective of this paper is to provide insight into this latter area. More precisely, assume that we observe the network structure, i.e., who is linked with whom. We propose new methods to identify and estimate the structural parameters in the model explaining how links are formed. The statistical analysis of network formation dates back to the seminal work of Erdős and Rényi (1959, who proposed a random graph model where links are formed independently with a fixed probability. Statisticians later extended the Erdős-Rényi model to allow for dependence between links and developed a large class of exponential random graph models (ERGM (e.g., Snijder (2002. While ERGMs may well fit the observed network statistics, they usually lack microfoundations which are essential for counterfactual analysis. Alternatively, economists view network formation as the optimal choices of individuals that maximize their utilities. A simple and widely used empirical approach in this spirit is to employ a pairwise regression, where the formation of a link is modeled by a binary choice model of the pair involved (e.g., Fafchamps and Gubert (2007, Mayer and Puller (2008. In order to treat links in a network as independent observations, this approach needs to assume that there is no influence from indirect friends (e.g., friends of friends, which could be restrictive in many applications given the prevalence of clustering (e.g., Jackson and Rogers (2007, Jackson, Barraquer and Tan (2012. Recognizing the weakness, econometricians have recently started to develop empirical network formation models that allow for utility externality, thereby introducing strategic interactions between links (Christakis, Fowler, Imbens, and Kalyanaraman (2010, Mele (2011, Boucher and Mourifié (2013, Miyauchi (2013, Leung (2013. A contribution of this paper is 2

3 to provide a different approach for the identification and estimation of such models. A crucial problem in the identification of network formation models with strategic interactions is the presence of multiple equilibria. Bouncher and Mourifié (2013 get around this problem by assuming there is a unique equilibrium in the observed data. Leung (2013 considers a network formation model with incomplete information. In his model, independence of private information creates conditional independence of links in a network under the assumption of a separable utility function, thereby enabling consistent estimation from a single large network. This approach does not need to make assumptions about the equilibrium selection if the interest is the parameters rather than counterfacturals. Christakis et al. (2010 and Mele (2011 circumvent the multiplicity issue by considering a sequential model where each link is formed in a random sequence and myopically. The Markov chain of networks achieved in each period would converge to a unique stationary distribution over the collection of equilibrium networks. Employing the stationary distribution to construct the data likelihood is equivalent to imposing implicitly an equilibrium selection mechanism in the corresponding static model (Young (1993, Jackson and Watts (2002. Unlike these studies, we admit multiple equilibria and do not impose any restrictions on the utility function or equilibrium selection. Since a unique equilibrium may not exist in this general case, the parameters are not necessarily point identified. We adopt the partial identification approach and examine what we can learn about the parameters from bounds on conditional choice probabilities. The study close to ours is by Miyauchi (2013, who considers partial identification as well. Miyauchi derives his bounds from a partial ordering of equilibrium networks under a nonnegative externality assumption, while our bounds hold for more general utility functions. The estimation of network formation models is computationally challenging because the number of possible networks is enormous: for n individuals the number of possible undirected networks is 2 n(n 1/2. In ERGMs, parameter estimation relies crucially on sampling networks from exponential family distributions. Given the huge space of possible networks, the sampling is typically carried out using Markov Chain Monte Carlo (MCMC methods. However, the mixing time of MCMC is O(e n unless links are approximately independent, in which case the model is not appreciably different from the Erdős-Rényi model (Bhamidi, Bresler, and Sly (2011. Chandrasekhar and Jackson (2013 provide Monte Carlo evidence that slow convergence of MCMC leads to poor performance of ERGMs. In sequential models of network 3

4 formation, likelihoods constructed using stationary distributions may be computationally intractable because such likelihoods typically include a sum over all possible networks (e.g., Mele (2011. While MCMC methods can be used to avoid computing intractable likelihoods, they need simulating networks from the stationary distributions where the mixing rate can be as slow as O(e n. Hence, sequential models suffer from the same computational problem as in ERGMs. In our model, the computation of the bounds may be intractable as well because it requires checking equilibrium conditions for all possible networks. We propose a completely new approach to tackle this computational problem. The idea is to make use of subnetworks. A subnetwork is the restriction of a network to a subset of the individuals. Under the equilibrium concept we consider (i.e., pairwise stability proposed by Jackson and Wolinsky (1996, if a network is in equilibrium, any subnetwork in it must also be in equilibrium. Thus, we can derive bounds on the probability of observing a subnetwork, taking into account only the equilibrium within the subnetwork. Under an assumption of local utility externality, these subnetwork bounds are computationally tractable no matter how large the networks are, as long as we only consider small subnetworks. This approach only needs choice probabilities within subnetworks, so it is still applicable if we do not observe an entire network, but links in subnetworks. Our paper is related to the econometric literature on static games of complete information (e.g., Bresnahan and Reiss (1991, Tamer (2003, Ciliberto and Tamer (2009, Bajari, Hong, and Ryan (2010, Bajari, Hahn, Hong, and Ridder (2011. Such games often face the identification problem due to the prevalence of multiple equilibria. To avoid imposing restrictions on equilibrium selection, econometricians have applied partial identification to such games (e.g., Andrews, Berry and Jia (2004, Pakes, Porter, Ho and Ishii (2006, Berry and Tamer (2006, Ciliberto and Tamer (2009, Beresteanu, Molchanov, and Molinari (2011. However, most studies look at simple entry games where the number of agents is small. We contribute to this literature by providing an application of partial identification to network formation games where the number of agents can be large, so standard probability bounds are computationally intractable. By trading off sharpness of bounds, we can achieve computational feasibility. This idea may shed light on the analysis of other games with a large number of agents (e.g., matching games and provide a new perspective on tackling computational problems in those models. 4

5 The estimation and inference of the identified set defined by the moment inequalities derived from the subnetwork bounds is a straightforward application of the works on partially identified models (e.g., Chernozhukov, Hong and Tamer (hereafter CHT, 2007, Andrews and Soares (2010, Romano and Shaikh (2010, Andrews and Jia (2012. While the distributions of subnetworks involved in the moment inequalities may depend on the choice of subnetworks, we demonstrate that subnetworks from a network with observationally identical individuals will follow the same distribution, so conditional on the observed characteristics it does not matter which subnetwork we choose. The bounds may not have closed forms. We propose how to compute them by simulation. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops the model. Section 3 presents the identification results. We address the multiple equilibrium problem in Section 3.1 and propose the partial identification approach in Section 3.2. The subnetwork bounds are derived in Section 3.3. Section 4 describes the estimation and inference methods. We discuss how to choose subnetworks in Section 4.1, how to estimate the identified set and construct confidence regions in Section 4.2, and how to compute the bounds in Section 4.3. Section 5 performs a Monte Carlo study, and Section 6 concludes. 2 A Model of Network Formation In this section, we develop the network formation model. Let V = {1, 2,..., N} be the set of individuals who can form links. The links are undirected in the sense that forming a link requires the consent of both individuals involved in the link, but severing a link can be unilateral. This is the natural setting in the context of friendship networks, and for that reason we call linked individuals friends. The links form a network, which we denote by G G. It is an N N binary matrix, where G ij = 1 if i and j are friends, and 0 otherwise for all i j. Since we consider undirected links, G is a symmetric matrix. We normalize G ii = 0 for all i V. Utility Each i V has a K 1 vector of observed characteristics X i (e.g., gender, age, race and an (N 1 1 vector of unobserved (to researchers preferences ε i = (ε i1,..., ε i,i 1, ε i,i+1,..., ε in, where ε ij is i s preference for link ij. Let 5

6 X = (X 1,..., X N and ε = (ε 1,..., ε N. The utility of i in a network in general depends on the network configuration G, the observed characteristics X, and i s unobserved preferences ε i, i.e., U i (G, X, ε i. For any i j, we decompose G into (G ij, G ij, where G ij G ij is the network obtained from G by removing link ij. Then the marginal utility of i from forming a link with j is ij U i (G ij, X, ε i = U i (1, G ij, X, ε i U i (0, G ij, X, ε i. (1 In this paper, we consider the utility specification U i (G, X, ε i = N G ij u(x i, X j, ε ij + N j=1 j=1 N G ij G jk γ 1 + N k=1 k i j=1 k>j ( N N G ij G ik G jk γ 2 C i G ij, with u(x i, X j, ε ij = β 0 + β 1X i + β 2 X i X j + ε ij, where we assume that γ 1, γ 2 R are constants, while C i (. : R + R + can depend on X i. 1 In this specification, the first term is the utility from direct friends, where X i X j is to capture the homophily effect, which says that people tend to make friends with those who are similar to them (Currarini, Jackson and Pin (2009, Christakis et al. (2010. In addition to the direct-friend effects, (2 also allows for the effects of indirect friends. The second term in (2 captures the utility from i s friends of friends, and the third term captures the additional utility if i and i s friend have friends in common. 2 last term is the cost of direct friends. Hence, if we consider the marginal utility of i from forming a link with j, which is given by ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij = u(x i, X j, ε ij + N G jk γ 1 + N G ik G jk γ 2 C i N k=1 k i 1 In the econometric analysis we consider a linear cost function, but let C i (n = if n > b for some b < so that the number of one s direct friends is bounded by an upper limit. See Section for details. 2 The latter is motivated by the clustering hypothesis, which says that if two individuals have friends in common, they are more likely to be friends than if links are formed randomly (Jackson and Rogers (2007, Jackson (2008, Christakis et al. (2010, Jackson et al. (2012. k=1 k=1 k j j=1 G ik (2 The, (3 6

7 where C i (n = C i (n + 1 C i (n, then it consists of not only the direct utility from j, but also the indirect utility from i s other friends, j s other friends, and i, j s friends in common. This utility function follows closely the specification in Christakis et al. ( It is also related to the specifications in Mele (2011 and Goyal and Joshi (2006, but is more general than both. 4 Equilibrium Given the utilities, individuals choose friends simultaneously as in the link-announcement game (Myerson (1991, Jackson (2008. We assume that individuals observe X and ε, so it is a complete information game. Depending whether transfers are allowed for, each individual announces a set of intended links or intended transfers. Under nontransferable utility (NTU, a link is formed if both individuals intend to form it, while under transferable utility (TU a link is formed if the sum of the two transfers for it is nonnegative. The network formed is an equilibrium. The equilibrium concept we consider in this paper is pairwise stability (Jackson and Wolinsky (1996 for NTU, Bloch and Jackson (2006, 2007 for TU. We say a network is pairwise stable if no pair of individuals wants to create a new link, and no individual wants to sever an existing link. Formally, Definition 1 A network G is NTU-pairwise stable (NTU-PS if 1. for all G ij = 1, ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij 0 and ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji 0; 2. for all G ij = 0, ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij > 0 = ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji < 0. Definition 2 A network G is TU-pairwise stable (TU-PS if 1. for all G ij = 1, ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij + ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji 0; 2. for all G ij = 0, ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij + ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji 0. 3 Christakis et al. (2010 allow for nonlinear effects from friends of friends and friends in common. Our specification is a linear version of theirs. However, with linearity we can establish the existence of equilibrium (see Appendix 7.1, which is an open question for the specification they use. 4 Mele (2011 considers a linear utility function which does not allow for the effects of friends in common. Goyal and Joshi (2006 assumes that the direct-friend effects are homogeneous across individuals. 7

8 Since we allow for utility interdependence, the pairwise stability condition leads to a simultaneous discrete choice model, i.e., G ij = 1 { ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij 0, ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji 0}, i j V, (4 under NTU and G ij = 1 { ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij + ij U j (G ij, X j, X i, ε ji 0}, i j V, (5 under TU, 5 where the choice of a link G ij depends on the choices of others, G ij. This implies that we cannot treat each link as a single observation and use a pairwise regression because G ij is endogenous in the model, so could be correlated with (ε ij, ε ji. What further complicates the statistical inference of (4 and (5 is that there may be multiple equilibria, which will affect the identification of the parameters. The analysis for NTU and TU is almost identical except that the existence of equilibrium holds under weaker conditions for TU compared to NTU (see Appendix 7.1 for discussion on the existence issue. In sequel we consider TU only and abbreviate TU-PS to PS for convenience. Remark 2.1 There are other equilibrium concepts in the network literature, and they differ mainly in the coordination that individuals are assumed to have. The simplest concept is Nash equilibrium, which allows for no coordination. In the mutual-consent setting, Nash equilibrium is not appropriate because even if forming a link is beneficial for both individuals involved, it can still be optimal in the Nash sense that they do not form the link, merely due to coordination failure. 6 This is why Jackson and Wolinsky proposed pairwise stability, which allows two individuals to coordinate so they do not fail to form a link if that is beneficial for both. Pairwise stability only allows for the coordination of a pair on one link. There are other equilibrium concepts that allow for higher level coordination. For example, bilateral equilibrium allows for the coordination of a pair on more than one link (Goyal and Vega-Redondo (2007, and strong stability allows for the coordination of a coalition (Dutta and Mutuswami 5 Equations (4 and (5 differ slightly from Definitions 1 and 2 in the indifference case, but the discrepency is negligible when ε follows a continuous distribution. 6 This is because if i rejects the link, it does not matter whether or not j rejects it. Then rejection is a (weakly optimal choice for j. Moreover, given j s rejection, it is also (weakly optimal for i to reject the link. 8

9 (1997, Jackson and van den Nouweland (2005. These concepts refine pairwise stability with further restrictions. In this paper, we want to keep the assumptions as weak as possible, so we only assume pairwise stability. 3 Identification In this section, we examine the framework that we use to identify the model. We first discuss multiple equilibria, the main problem in identification. Then we show how much we can learn without imposing any restrictions on the equilibrium selection. We consider the following data generating process. Suppose there is an infinite population of individuals. We first generate an integer N from a distribution on {2, 3,...}. Given N, we then draw at random N individuals. Each individual i is associated with a vector of characteristics X i and a vector of preferences ε i. let these individuals form links, and a PS network emerges. We observe G (N and X (N = (X 1,..., X N, but not ε (N = (ε 1,..., ε N. 7 We This procedure is repeated independently T times, and we obtain a sample (G t (N t, X t (N t, N t, t = 1,..., T. Let V t = {1, 2,..., N t } and ε t (N t the preferences of the individuals in observation t. For simplicity, we suppress N in G (N, X (N, and ε (N whenever possible. Throughout the paper we make the following assumptions. Assumption 1 (Data generating process (i We have an i.i.d. sample of (G t, X t, N t, t = 1,..., T. Let T. (ii X t and ε t are independent, t = 1,..., T. (iii ε t,ij, i j V t, t = 1,..., T, are i.i.d. with an absolutely continuous distribution (with respect to the Lebesgue measure, which is known up to finite dimensional θ ε Θ ε. 8 Denote the distribution of ε t, t = 1,..., T, by F ε (ε; θ ε. Assumption 2 (Utility The marginal utility of i from forming a link with j takes the form ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij ; θ u, which is known up to finite dimensional θ u Θ u and is continuous in θ u. Moreover, the marginal utility function satisfies that for any (X, ε and θ u Θ u there exists a PS network. The parameter of interest is θ = (θ u, θ ε Θ u Θ ε = Θ. 7 Due to the sampling scheme X i are i.i.d. for i = 1,..., N. 8 The i.i.d. assumption is not crucial to our analysis. In fact, we can introduce dependence by letting ε ij = α i + ξ ij, where α i is the individual random effects, α i and ξ ij are independent, and ( ξij, ξ ji are i.i.d.. In this case, εij, j = 1,..., N are dependent through α i. 9

10 3.1 Multiple Equilibria and No Point Identification For a given X and ε, the model yields a collection of PS networks, denoted by PS ( U (X, ε, where U (X, ε = {{ ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij } G ij G ij } i,j V,i j R N(N 1 G /2 is the marginal-utility profile. To complete the model, suppose there is an equilibrium selection mechanism that picks one network from the collection of PS networks. Denote by Pr (G PS ( U (X, ε, X, ε the selection probability. Then the probability that we observe network G conditional on X is Pr (G X = Pr (G PS ( U (X, ε, X, ε df ε (ε, (6 Equation (6 is similar to what Ciliberto and Tamer (2009 establish in entry games and Bajari, Hong, and Ryan (2010 in discrete games with complete information. Since the equilibrium selection probability in (6 is unknown when there are multiple equilibria (i.e., PS ( U (X, ε 2, whether the true parameter value θ 0 can be point identified from condition (6 depends on whether there is an unique equilibrium (i.e., PS ( U (X, ε = 1. If for any θ Θ there is a network that can only be a unique equilibrium, then under certain conditions the unique equilibrium may provide moment restrictions to point identify θ 0. However, if for some θ Θ all the networks are part of multiple equilibria, then θ 0 cannot be point identified without additional restrictions on the equilibrium selection. In this case, we encounter the incoherency problem addressed in the literature (Bresnahan and Reiss (1991, Tamer (2003. For the game described in Section 2, the presence of multiple equilibria is prevalent because of the interdependence of marginal utilities across links. 9 multiple equilibria in the example below. We illustrate Example 1 Consider networks of N = 3. Suppose the utility function is as in (2 with u ij = ε ij, γ 1 < 0, γ 2 > 0, γ 1 + γ 2 > 0, C i ( = 0. For simplicity we assume ε ij = ε ji, i, j = 1, 2, 3, so ε = (ε 12, ε 23, ε 13. Figure 1 shows the 8 possible networks. Given the utility specification, we can calculate all possible collections of PS networks and the corresponding regions of (ε 12, ε 23, ε 13, as collected in Table 1, where θ 1 = γ 1 γ 2, θ 2 = γ Under the assumed parameter values, we find both multiple 9 If there is no utility interdependence, i.e., ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij = ij U i (X i, X j, ε ij, then a PS network must be unique. 10 Note that a collection of PS networks must contain only nonadjacent networks, i.e., networks 10

11 Figure 1: Networks of Three Individuals equilibria and unique equilibria. The regions of (ε 12, ε 23, ε 13 corresponding to these equilibrium collections form a partition of R In Example 1, there are networks that can only be a unique equilibrium (i.e., g 5, g 6, g 7 under the assumed parameter values. For other parameter values, however, an unique equilibrium may not exist, as illustrated in Example 2. This implies that the existence of an unique equilibrium is not guaranteed. Hence, the true parameter value is generally not point identified unless we make additional assumptions about the equilibrium selection rule. Example 2 Consider the same setting as in Example 1 except that γ 1 > 0, γ 2 > 0. Then no network can be a unique equilibrium. All the eight networks belong to certain multiple equilibria. 3.2 Partial Identification One can achieve point identification by making certain assumptions about the equilibrium selection. See Remark 3.1 for detailed discussion. In this paper, we do not want to impose any restrictions on the equilibrium selection, so we get around the non-identifiability issue using partial identification. This approach has been widely that differ by at least two links. This is because if two networks differ by only one link, the pair involved in the link must prefer one network over the other, and the latter cannot be PS. Hence, to find all possible equilibria, we only need to look at the collections of nonadjacent networks. 11 They form a partition of R 3 because a PS network exists for any ε. 11

12 Table 1: All Possible Equilibria and the Partition of the ɛ space Equilibrium collections Regions of (ε 12, ε 23, ε 13 Multiple equilibria {g 1, g 8 } [θ 1, 0 [θ 1, 0 [θ 1, 0 {g 2, g 3 } [0, θ 2 (, θ 1 [0, θ 2 {g 2, g 4 } (, θ 1 [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 {g 3, g 4 } [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 (, θ 1 {g 2, g 8 } {[θ 1, 0 [θ 1, 0 [0, θ 2 } {[θ 1, θ 2 [θ 1, θ 2 [θ 2, } {g 3, g 8 } {[0, θ 2 [θ 1, 0 [θ 1, 0} {[θ 2, [θ 1, θ 2 [θ 1, θ 2 } {g 4, g 8 } {[θ 1, 0 [0, θ 2 [θ 1, 0} {[θ 1, θ 2 [θ 2, [θ 1, θ 2 } {g 2, g 3, g 8 } [0, θ 2 [θ 1, 0 [0, θ 2 {g 3, g 4, g 8 } [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 [θ 1, 0 {g 2, g 4, g 8 } [θ 1, 0 [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 {g 2, g 3, g 4, g 8 } [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 [0, θ 2 Unique equilibria {g 1 } {(, 0 (, θ 1 [θ 1, 0} {[θ 1, 0 (, 0 (, θ 1 } {(, θ 1 [θ 1, 0 (, 0} {(, θ 1 (, θ 1 (, θ 1 } {g 2 } {(, θ 1 (, 0 [0, θ 2 } {(, θ 1 (, θ 2 [θ 2, } {[θ 1, 0 (, θ 1 [0, θ 2 } {[θ 1, θ 2 (, θ 1 [θ 2, } {g 3 } {[0, θ 2 (, 0 (, θ 1 } {[θ 2, (, θ 2 (, θ 1 } {[0, θ 2 (, θ 1 [θ 1, 0} {[θ 2, (, θ 1 [θ 1, θ 2 } {g 4 } {(, 0 [0, θ 2 (, θ 1 } {(, θ 2 [θ 2, (, θ 1 } {(, θ 1 [0, θ 2 [θ 1, 0} {(, θ 1 [θ 2, [θ 1, θ 2 } {g 5 } [θ 2, (, θ 1 [θ 2, {g 6 } (, θ 1 [θ 2, [θ 2, {g 7 } [θ 2, [θ 2, (, θ 1 {g 8 } {[θ 2, [θ 1, [θ 2, } {[θ 2, [θ 2, [θ 1, θ 2 } {[θ 1, θ 2 [θ 2, [θ 2, } 12

13 applied to game-theoretic models with multiple equilibria (Andrews, Berry and Jia (2004, Pakes, Porter, Ho and Ishii (2006, Berry and Tamer (2006, Ciliberto and Tamer (2009. Following closely Ciliberto and Tamer (2009, we divide the integral in (6 into two parts Pr (G X = + G PS( U(X,ε& PS( U(X,ε =1 G PS( U(X,ε& PS( U(X,ε 2 df ε (ε Pr (G PS ( U (X, ε, X, ε df ε (ε, (7 depending on whether there is a unique equilibrium or multiple equilibria. Note that the selection probability is trivially 1 when a network is a unique equilibrium. When there are multiple equilibria, the selection probability, though unknown, lies between 0 and 1. Replacing the selection probability with these bounds, we derive an upper and lower bound for Pr(G X, i.e., and Pr (G X Pr (G X G PS( U(X,ε G PS( U(X,ε& PS( U(X,ε =1 df ε (ε, (8 df ε (ε. (9 The upper bound is the probability that network G is PS, and the lower bound is the probability that G is uniquely PS. These are the best possible bounds because the selection probability in (7 can be any number between 0 and 1. Unfortunately, the lower bound in (9 is computationally infeasible if the network size N is large. This is because to compute the lower bound, we need to check pairwise stability for 2 N(N 1/2 possible networks. 12 This is computationally intractable even for a moderate value N. For example, in the case of 20 people, the number of possible networks is Remark 3.1 An alternative approach is to achieve point identification by making additional assumptions about the equilibrium selection. In network formation, one way to do this is to consider a sequential model as in Jackson and Watts (2002 (see 12 Unlike the upper bound, the lower bound has no closed form and needs to be computed by simulation. For each simulated ε, we need to check whether a network is uniquely pairwise stable, which amounts to checking pairwise stability for all possible networks. 13

14 also Christakis et al. (2010 and Mele (2011. This sequential model assumes that individuals are myopic and form links in a random sequence: in each period only pair of individuals is randomly selected and only that pair can update their relationship. The sequence of networks realized in each period form a Markov chain with states corresponding to the networks. Under certain conditions 13 the Markov chain converges to a unique stationary distribution, which typically assigns probability one to a single PS network. 14 Hence the stationary distribution amounts to a particular selection rule. Alternatively, one can assume a more general equilibrium selection mechanism, for example, by specifying a parametric form (Bajari, Hong, and Ryan (2010 or considering a nonparametric equilibrium selection (Bajari, Hahn, Hong, and Ridder (2011. Note that in the game we consider a fully nonparametric equilibrium selection is not identified. Certain restrictions must be imposed on it (e.g., independence of ε in order to achieve identification. 3.3 Subnetworks We propose a novel method to tackle the computational problem. The idea is to use the pairwise stability of certain parts of a network, called subnetworks. A subnetwork is the restriction of a network to a subset of the individuals. To be precise, denote a network by G = (V, E, where V is the vertex set and E is the edge set. For A V, we say G A = (A, E A is the subnetwork of G in A if E A E contains the links in G that connect two individuals in A. Moreover, let G A = (V, E\E A be the complement of G A in G, i.e., the remainder of G after the links in E A are deleted. It contains links in G that connect either two individuals in V \A or an individual in A to an individual in V \A. The former type of links form the subnetwork in V \A, G V \A, and the latter type of links form the neighborhood of A in G, denoted by B A (G = (V, E\ ( E A E V \A. Clearly, we have the decomposition G = (G A, G A = ( G A, B A (G, G V \A. These definitions are based on graph notation. In matrix notation, subnetwork G A (neighborhood B A corresponds to the submatrix of G with rows and columns in A (rows in A and columns in V \A. For 13 An example of such conditions would be (i the individuals are assumed to make mistakes (i.e., forming or deleting a link randomly rather than based on utility maximization and (ii the probability of making a mistake is suffi ciently small. 14 This network is essentially the most "stable" one among all the PS networks, or more precisely, the network that has the minimum resistance (Young (1993, Jackson and Watts (

15 Figure 2: An Example of a Subnetwork brevity, we suppress G in B A (G whenever possible and abbreviate G {i,j}, G {i,j} and B {i,j} to G ij, G ij, and B ij. The sets of all possible G A, G A and B A are denoted by G A, G A and B A. Figure 2 illustrates a subnetwork. From G = (G A, G A, the distribution of subnetwork G A is simply a marginal distribution of the distribution of G, i.e., Pr (G A X = Pr (G A, G A X G A = G A Pr (G A, G A PS ( U (X, ε, X, ε df ε (ε. (10 The summed equilibrium selection probability in (10 is unknown unless all the networks in PS ( U (X, ε have the same subnetwork in A. Following the same idea as in (6, we can derive an upper and lower bound for Pr (G A X. Specifically, divide the integral in (10 into two parts Pr (G A X = df ε (ε + G A PS A ( U(X,ε & PS A ( U(X,ε =1 G A PS A ( U(X,ε & PS A ( U(X,ε 2 G A Pr (G A, G A PS ( U (X, ε, X, ε df ε (ε, (11 { where PS A ( U (X, ε = GA G A : G A G A, ( G A, G A PS ( U (X, ε} 15

16 is the set of subnetworks in A that are part of a network in PS ( U (X, ε. Replacing the sum term in (11 by 0 and 1 yields and Pr (G A X Pr (G A X G A PS A ( U(X,ε G A PS A ( U(X,ε& PS A ( U(X,ε =1 df ε (ε, (12 df ε (ε, (13 The bounds are analogous to those in (8 and (9: the upper bound is the probability that G A is part of a PS network, and the lower bound is the probability that only G A can be part of a PS network. These bounds are the best possible because the sum term in (11 can be any number between 0 and 1. However, they are still infeasible: the upper bound requires checking the pairwise stability of (G A, G A for all G A and the lower bound requires checking that of (G A, G A for all G A and all G A G A, so the computational complexity of them is exactly the same as that of the lower bound in (9. In the next step, we will derive from these bounds inequalities that are tractable Main idea The main idea is to use the pairwise stability of subnetworks rather than networks. We say a subnetwork G A is pairwise stable (PS for a given G A if condition (5 is satisfied for all i j A. More generally, we say a collection of links is pairwise stable for a given complement of the collection if all the links in the collection satisfy condition (5. 15 By definition, if network G is pairwise stable, subnetwork G A is pairwise stable for G A. From this simple property, we can derive inequalities that involve only the pairwise stability of subnetworks. To proceed, for i j A write G A = (G ij, G A ij, where G A ij G A ij is the remainder of G A after link ij is deleted. It is clear that G ij = (G A ij, G A. Let X A = (X i i A and ε A = (ε ij i j A be the vectors of observed characteristics and unobserved preferences of the individuals in A. Denote the distribution of ε A by F εa (ε A. For a given (G A, X A, ε A, there is a collection of PS subnetworks in A, denoted by PS ( U A (G A, X A, ε A, where U A (G A, X A, ε A = {{ ij U i (G A ij, G A, X i, X j, ε ij } GA ij G A ij } i j is the marginal-utility profile of the individuals in A. Then the aforementioned prop- 15 This definition is useful when we consider the pairwise stability of G A for a given G A. 16

17 erty yields the lemma below. Lemma 3.1 Under Assumptions 1-2, for any A V, Pr (G A X A df εa (ε A, (14 G A,G A PS( U A (G A,X A,ε A and Pr (G A X A df εa (ε A. (15 G A,G A PS( U A (G A,X A,ε A & PS( U A (G A,X A,ε A =1 Proof. See the appendix. The upper bound for Pr (G A X A is the probability that subnetwork G A is PS for some G A, and the lower bound is the probability that for any G A only subnetwork G A can be PS. These bounds are wider than those in (12 and (13 and thus not sharp, but the loss of sharpness is exactly the source from which we reduce the computational burden. Because the new bounds take into account only the pairwise stability of subnetworks, ignoring the pairwise stability of the rest of the networks, we only need to check pairwise stability for all possible subnetworks rather than all possible networks. The bounds in (12 and (13 also make use of subnetworks, but because the links inside a subnetwork are generally correlated with the links outside, while those bounds take into consideration the correlation and internalize it by employing the pairwise stability of the entire network, their computational complexity is not reduced. In contrast, the bounds in Lemma 3.1 only consider the maximum and minimum of the correlation, so their computational complexity can be lower. In fact, this computational problem arises in many applications where there is a intractably large set of choices/agents. Researchers tend to use a subset of the choices/agents to reduce the computational complexity, but how to handle the correlation between choices inside the subset and choices outside is essential. In multinomial choice models, for example, people assume that the choices follow a block-additive GEV model, so using random subsets of the full choice set would yield consistent estimates (Bierlaire, Bolduc and McFadden, Our approach is different in the sense that we do not need additional assumptions to restrict the correlation, but use bounds for it. In practice, because G A is large even for a moderate N, the computation of the bounds in Lemma 3.1 is still intractable. However, because G A plays a role only 17

18 through U A (G A, X A, ε A, if we can restrict the effect of G A in the utility function, we may avoid checking for all G A. In particular, we assume that the marginal utility ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij depends on G ij only through the neighborhood of i and j, B ij. This local externality property holds for the utility function in (2. Assumption 3 (Local externality For any i j V, ij U i (G ij, X i, X j, ε ij ; θ u = ij U i (B ij, X i, X j, ε ij ; θ u. Because B ij is determined by G A ij and B A, local externality implies that for A V, the marginal-utility profile in A satisfies U A (G A, X A, ε A = U A (B A, X A, ε A = {{ ij U i (B ij (G A ij, B A, X i, X j, ε ij } GA ij G A ij } i j A. Hence, Proposition 3.1 Under Assumptions 1-3, for any A V, Pr (G A X A df εa (ε A, (16 B A,G A PS( U A (B A,X A,ε A and Pr (G A X A df εa (ε A. (17 B A,G A PS( U A (B A,X A,ε A & PS( U A (B A,X A,ε A =1 The bounds in Proposition 3.1 consider all possible B A. There is an upper bound for Pr (G A, B A X A that considers the realized B A. Proposition 3.2 Under Assumptions 1-3, for any A V, Pr (G A, B A X A df εa (ε A. (18 G A PS( U A (B A,X A,ε A Proof. See the appendix. When we compute the bounds in (16 and (17, the total number of subnetworks that need to be checked for pairwise stability is equal to 2 A ( A 1/2 times the number of B A B A that yield distinct U A (B A. The latter number could still be large because B A increases exponentially in N. In practice, we need additional restrictions on the utility specification to keep that number at a tractable level. In this paper, we consider the utility function as in (2, which implicitly impose several assumptions to reduce the number of distinct U A (B A. First, the effects of each link in B ij are 18

19 Table 2: Regions of ɛ 13 B 13 = (0, 0 B 13 = (1, 0 B 13 = (0, 1 B 13 = (1, 1 G 13 = 1 [0, [ γ 1, [ γ 1, [ γ 1 γ 2, G 13 = 0 (, 0 (, γ 1 (, γ 1 (, γ 1 γ 2 assumed to be identical, i.e., they do not depend on the characteristics of k i, j, so B A can be captured by numbers of friends. 16 Second, (2 only consider two types of friends, i.e., friends of each individual and common friends of each pair. Third, we choose a cost function C i (n such that C i (n = if n > b for some integer b, so in equilibrium nobody has more than b friends. Under these assumptions, B A can be captured by ( ( A 1 + A { 2 integers, whose values are in 0, 1,..., b}. Thus, the number of distinct U A (B A is bounded above by ( b A ( A +1/2, + 1 which is independent of N. 17 Therefore, the computation of the bounds in (16 and (17 is tractable no 18 matter how large N is, provided that we choose small A and b. As for the upper bound in (18, it is easy to compute because it only needs the realized B A. Example 3 (Example 1 continued Assume the same setting as in Example 1. We want to derive (16 and (17 for subnetwork G 13 = 1. In this case, B 13 = (G 12, G 23 takes four possible values, i.e., B 13 = {(0, 0, (1, 0, (0, 1, (1, 1}. Because the pairwise stability of G 13 for a given B 13 is affected by ε only through ε 13, we find the regions of ε 13 in which G 13 = 1 or 0 is PS for each B 13 B 13. All the regions are collected in Table 2. By taking the union of the regions in the first row and in the second row respectively, we obtain (16 and (17 as follows: Pr (G 13 = 1 [ γ 1 γ 2, df ε13 (ε 13, (19 16 To be specific, B A can be captured by a vector of integers, whose components are the numbers of friends in V \A that each i in A has, that each pair (i, j in A has in common, that each triplet (i, j, k in A has in common,..., and that all individuals in A have in common. 17 In fact, the number of distinct U A (B A is substantially smaller than ( b + 1 A ( A +1/2 because the upper limit b is imposed on the total number of i s own friends and the friends that i shares with others. 18 The computational complexity will not increase for other utility specifications that satisfy Assumption 3, provided that the number of friends is bounded above by b and only pairs friends in common are considered. In particular, the computational complexity remains the same if the effects of own s friends or common friends are allowed to be nonlinear or interact with the characteristics. 19

20 and Pr (G 13 = 1 df ε13 (ε 13. (20 [ γ 1, The identified set is defined as the collection of θ Θ that satisfy inequalities (16-(18. Definition 3 The identified set is Θ I = {θ Θ : (16-(18 hold, A s.t. 2 A ā, X A } (21 for some integer ā. The trade-off in choosing ā is between the computational complexity and the tightness of the bounds. Bounds from smaller subnetworks are easier to compute, but they are also wider. We suggest to start with the smallest subnetworks, i.e., pairs, and choose the maximum size ā based on the computational capability. Note that if the networks in data happen to be small and we are able to choose ā = N, then the bounds in (16 and (17 reduce to those in (8 and (9. 4 Estimation and Inference In this section, we discuss the estimation and inference of the identified set in (21. This set is defined by conditional moment inequalities (16-(18. We assume that X is discrete and transform the conditional moment inequalities into their unconditional counterparts Pr (G A = g A, X A = x A H 1 (g A, x A ; θ Pr (X A = x A 0 H 2 (g A, x A ; θ Pr (X A = x A Pr (G A = g A, X A = x A 0 Pr (G A = g A, B A = b A, X A = x A H 3 (g A, b A, x A ; θ Pr (X A = x A 0, (22 where H 1 (g A, x A ; θ = H 2 (g A, x A ; θ = max 1 {g A PS ( U A (b A, x A, ε A ; θ u } df εa (ε A θ ε b A { } g A PS ( U A (b A, x A, ε A ; θ u & min 1 df εa (ε A θ ε b A PS ( U A (b A, x A, ε A ; θ u = 1 20

21 Figure 3: An Example of Multiple Subnetworks H 3 (g A, b A, x A ; θ = 1 {g A PS ( U A (b A, x A, ε A ; θ u } df εa (ε A θ ε. (23 What we need is to estimate the probabilities in (22 and compute the bounds in (23. The former is discussed in Section 4.1. We then discuss in Section 4.2 the estimation and inference of the identified set, assuming that the bounds are known. The computation of the bounds is discussed in Section Estimation of the Probabilities To estimate the probabilities in (22, we need to pick subnetworks in A with certain characteristics. In most network data (such as Add Health individuals do not have identities, so those individuals with the same characteristics are viewed as identical and labeled arbitrarily. 19 This implies that subset A may not be uniquely determined and there may be more than one way to choose a subnetwork in A with certain characteristics. For example, if we consider the subnetworks of a boy and a girl in the network in Figure 3, we will find four such subnetworks. For discrete X, this indeterminacy occurs with positive probability. Nevertheless, because pairwise stability and equilibrium selection do not depend on how we label the individuals, we can show that subnetworks with the same characteristics follow the same distribution, so it does not matter which one we choose. To see this, fix n and let π be a permutation over V = {1,..., n}. Express the characteristics explicitly, and write a subnetwork as (g A, x A and a subnetwork with 19 Network data with identities are those that consist of repeated observations for a given group of individuals. In such data, each individual is labeled by a fixed number across networks. The difference between with and without identities is analogous to the difference between panel data and repeated cross-sectional data. 21

22 a neighborhood as (g A, b A, x A. We define two subnetworks (or subnetworks with neighborhoods to be isomorphic if they are identical except for the labels. Definition 4 (i For A, A V and subnetworks (g A, x A and (g A, x A, if there is a permutation π over V with π (A = A such that (a g ij = g π(iπ(j, i, j A, i j, and (b x i = x π(i, i A, then (g A, x A and (g A, x A are isomorphic, and we write (g A, x A = (g A, x A. (ii For A, A V and subnetworks with neighborhoods (g A, b A, x A and (g A, b A, x A, if there is a permutation π over V with π (A = A such that (a g ij = g π(iπ(j, i A, j V, i j, and (b x i = x π(i, i A, then (g A, b A, x A and (g A, b A, x A are isomorphic, and we write (g A, b A, x A = (g A, b A, x A. Proposition 4.1 Suppose Assumptions 1-3 are satisfied. (i For A, A subnetworks (g A, x A and (g A, x A, if (g A, x A = (g A, x A, then V and Pr (G A = g A, X A = x A = Pr (G A = g A, X A = x A, (24 H 1 (g A, x A ; θ = H 1 (g A, x A ; θ, (25 H 2 (g A, x A ; θ = H 2 (g A, x A ; θ. (26 (ii For A, A V and subnetworks with neighborhoods (g A, b A, x A and (g A, b A, x A, if (g A, b A, x A = (g A, b A, x A, then Pr (G A = g A, B A = b A, X A = x A = Pr (G A = g A, B A = b A, X A = x A, (27 Proof. See the appendix. H 3 (g A, b A, x A ; θ = H 3 (g A, b A, x A ; θ. (28 Proposition 4.1 shows that if we treat isomorphic subnetworks (g A, x A and (g A, x A as identical realizations, (G A, X A and (G A, X A follow the same distribution. This can be satisfied for any A, A V such that A = A, so we can choose any subnetworks of size A to estimate Pr (G A = g A, X A = x A and similar for Pr(G A = g A, B A = b A, X A = x A. Another implication of Proposition 4.1 is that, letting A = A, we can treat isomorphic subnetworks (g A, x A and (g A, x A as the same realization of (G A, X A. Therefore, the distribution of (G A, X A is considered as over the equivalence classes of subnetworks, defined by the isomorphism. This resolves the problem that different labeling may lead to different matrix representations of 22

23 subnetworks. 20 Although picking from each network any subnetwork of size A provides consistent estimators as the number of networks goes to infinity, we exploit the data more effi ciently by picking from each network all subnetworks of size A and taking the average over them. 21 To be precise, let a = A and A 1,..., A ( n be the subsets of a {1,..., n} that have a elements. Denote by (g a, x a and (g a, b a, x a the realizations of (G A, X A and (G A, B A, X A. Then the moment functions for observation t in (22 take the form where m 1t (g a, x a ; θ = p t (g a, x a H 1t (g a, x a ; θ p t (x a, m 2t (g a, x a ; θ = H 2t (g a, x a ; θ p t (x a p t (g a, x a, m 3t (g a, b a, x a ; θ = p t (g a, b a, x a H 3t (g a, b a, x a ; θ p t (x a, (29 p t (g a, b a, x a = 1 1 { } G t,aj = g a, B t,aj = b a, X t,aj = x a, ( nt a ( n t a j=1 p t (g a, x a = 1 1 { } G t,aj = g a, X t,aj = x a, ( nt a ( n t a j=1 p t (x a = 1 1 { } X t,aj = x a. (30 ( nt a ( n t a j=1 and the bounds are those in (23 multiplied by ( n t a, e.g., H1t (g a, x a ; θ = ( n t a H 1 (g A, x A ; θ. Clearly, E p t (g a, x a = Pr (G A = g a, X A = x a, and V p t (g a, x a < V (1 {G t,a1 = g a, X t,a1 = x a }. 22 Thus taking the average over all eligible subnetworks would lower the variance of the estimator of the identified set. 20 In practice, we need a graph isomorphism algorithm to find which subnetworks are isomorphic. In the Monte Carlo study we use the algorithm Nauty ( More details about the implementation of Nauty can be found in the appendix. 21 It is true that subnetworks from the same network are dependent because they are part of a single PS network. However, the dependence does not cause any additional problems if we consider the asymptotics as the number of networks goes to infinity. 22 This is from the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and Pr ( G Aj = G Ak, X Aj = X Ak, N = n 1, j k. 23

24 4.2 Estimation and Inference of the Identified Set Now we discuss the estimation and inference of the identified set, assuming the bounds in (23 are known. Suppose (g a, x a and (g a, b a, x a take κ g and κ b distinct values respectively, denoted by (g a, x a 1,..., (g a, x a κg, and (g a, b a, x a 1,..., (g a, b a, x a κ b. 23 Stack the moment functions in (29 into a vector m t (θ = ( m 2 t (θ,, māt (θ where m a t (θ = (m a 1t (θ, m a 2t (θ, m a 3t (θ, a = 2,..., ā, m a jt (θ = ( m jt ((g a, x a 1 ; θ,..., m jt ((g a, x a κg ; θ, j = 1, 2, m a 3t (θ = ( m 3t ((g a, b a, x a 1 ; θ,..., m 3t ((g a, b a, x a κ b ; θ. Then the moment inequalities in (22 can be written as Em t (θ 0. (31 Following the set inference literature (CHT (2007, Romano and Shaikh (2010, Andrews and Soares (2010 among others, we estimate the identified set by minimizing the sample analog of a criterion function based on (31. We use the criterion function as in CHT (2007, Q (θ = (Em t (θ 2 +, where (x+ = max (x, 0 and is the Euclidean norm. The identified set is given by Θ I = {θ Θ : Q (θ = 0}. (32 Let Q T (θ = (ET m t (θ + 2 be the sample analog of Q (θ, where ET m t (θ = 1 T T t=1 m t (θ. In practice we use the normalized sample criterion Q T (θ = Q T (θ inf θ Θ Q T (θ to account for misspecification (CHT (2007, Ciliberto and Tamer (2009 and propose the estimator ˆΘ I = {θ Θ : T Q T (θ c T }, (33 23 That is, each (g a, x a i represents an equivalence class of subnetworks, i = 1,..., κ g, so do (g a, b a, x a j, j = 1,..., κ b. The numbers κ g and κ b are determined by a and the cardinality of the support of X. 24

25 where c T is chosen to be c T and c T /T 0, e.g. c T ln T. Let d (A, B = max {sup a A d (a, B, sup b B d (b, A} be the Hausdorff distance between sets A and B, where d (a, B = inf b B a b. It can be shown that ˆΘ I is consistent under Hausdorff distance, i.e., d ( ˆΘI, Θ I p 0 as T. Theorem 4.1 Assume Θ is a compact set. (a If Q (θ and Q T (θ defined as above satisfy (i Q (θ is continuous in θ, (ii sup θ Θ Q (θ Q T (θ = O p (1/ T, and (iii sup θ ΘI Q T (θ = O p (1/T, then ˆΘ I in (33 is a consistent estimator of Θ I, i.e., d ( ˆΘI, Θ I p 0, as T. (b Under Assumptions 1-3, Conditions (i-(iii in part (a hold. Proof. See the appendix. The confidence region for the true θ 0 can be constructed by inverting the acceptance region of a test (e.g. CHT (2007, Andrews and Soares (2010, Andrews and Jia (2012. We use the confidence region proposed by CHT (2007 C T = {θ Θ : T Q T (θ c 1 α (θ}, (34 where c 1 α (θ = min (ĉ 1 α (θ, ĉ 1 α, ĉ 1 α (θ is a consistent estimator of c 1 α (θ, the 1 α quantile of the limiting distribution of T Q T (θ, and ĉ 1 α is a data-dependent variable that is O p (1 and larger than sup θ ΘI c 1 α (θ. It can be shown that for any θ Θ I, C T is asymptotically correct, i.e., lim inf Pr (θ C T 1 α. The limiting T distribution of T Q T (θ is data dependent. We can use the subsampling method in CHT (2007 to obtain c 1 α (θ. 4.3 Computation of the Bounds The discussion in the last section assumes that the bounds in (23 are known. In practice, we need to compute the unknown bounds first. The bound H 3 has a closed form H 3 (g A, b A, x A = i,j A g ij =1 Pr ( ij U i (b ij, x i, x j, ε ij + ij U j (b ij, x j, x i, ε ji 0 25

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Geert Ridder Shuyang Sheng February 8, 207 Preliminary Abstract This paper develops estimation methods for network formation using observed data from a single

More information

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games

Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Estimation of Large Network Formation Games Geert Ridder Shuyang Sheng Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract This paper provides estimation methods for network formation models using observed data of a single

More information

Econometric Analysis of Games 1

Econometric Analysis of Games 1 Econometric Analysis of Games 1 HT 2017 Recap Aim: provide an introduction to incomplete models and partial identification in the context of discrete games 1. Coherence & Completeness 2. Basic Framework

More information

Identification of preferences in network formation games

Identification of preferences in network formation games Identification of preferences in network formation games Áureo de Paula Seth Richards-Shubik Elie Tamer The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP29/15 Identification

More information

Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models

Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models Inequality Testing In the previous lecture, we discussed how to test the nonlinear hypothesis H 0 : h(θ 0 ) 0 when the sample information comes

More information

Partial Identification and Confidence Intervals

Partial Identification and Confidence Intervals Partial Identification and Confidence Intervals Jinyong Hahn Department of Economics, UCLA Geert Ridder Department of Economics, USC September 17, 009 Abstract We consider statistical inference on a single

More information

Sharp identification regions in models with convex moment predictions

Sharp identification regions in models with convex moment predictions Sharp identification regions in models with convex moment predictions Arie Beresteanu Ilya Molchanov Francesca Molinari The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper

More information

Selecting Equilibria using Best-Response Dynamics

Selecting Equilibria using Best-Response Dynamics 2017-09 Selecting Equilibria using Best-Response Dynamics Vincent Boucher Septembre / September 2017 Centre de recherche sur les risques les enjeux économiques et les politiques publiques www.crrep.ca

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari a, Mohsen Mosleh a, Kia Dalili b arxiv:1504.06634v3 [q-fin.ec] 11 Dec 2015 a School of Systems and Enterprises,

More information

A Course in Applied Econometrics. Lecture 10. Partial Identification. Outline. 1. Introduction. 2. Example I: Missing Data

A Course in Applied Econometrics. Lecture 10. Partial Identification. Outline. 1. Introduction. 2. Example I: Missing Data Outline A Course in Applied Econometrics Lecture 10 1. Introduction 2. Example I: Missing Data Partial Identification 3. Example II: Returns to Schooling 4. Example III: Initial Conditions Problems in

More information

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters

Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Flexible Estimation of Treatment Effect Parameters Thomas MaCurdy a and Xiaohong Chen b and Han Hong c Introduction Many empirical studies of program evaluations are complicated by the presence of both

More information

A Semiparametric Network Formation Model with Multiple Linear Fixed Effects

A Semiparametric Network Formation Model with Multiple Linear Fixed Effects A Semiparametric Network Formation Model with Multiple Linear Fixed Effects Luis E. Candelaria University of Warwick January 7, 2018 Overview This paper is the first to analyze a static network formation

More information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Sridhar Narayanan May 30, 2011 Discrete games of complete information have been used to analyze a variety of contexts such as market entry,

More information

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs

Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Efficient Network Structures with Separable Heterogeneous Connection Costs Babak Heydari and Mohsen Mosleh and Kia Dalili School of Systems and Enterprises, Stevens Institute

More information

A Structural Model of Multigraph Formation: Favor Exchange and Social Networks in Villages

A Structural Model of Multigraph Formation: Favor Exchange and Social Networks in Villages A Structural Model of Multigraph Formation: Favor Exchange and Social Networks in Villages Jun Sung Kim Cornell University Job Market Paper November 14, 2013 Abstract This paper proposes a structural model

More information

Inference for Subsets of Parameters in Partially Identified Models

Inference for Subsets of Parameters in Partially Identified Models Inference for Subsets of Parameters in Partially Identified Models Kyoo il Kim University of Minnesota June 2009, updated November 2010 Preliminary and Incomplete Abstract We propose a confidence set for

More information

Partial Identification and Inference in Binary Choice and Duration Panel Data Models

Partial Identification and Inference in Binary Choice and Duration Panel Data Models Partial Identification and Inference in Binary Choice and Duration Panel Data Models JASON R. BLEVINS The Ohio State University July 20, 2010 Abstract. Many semiparametric fixed effects panel data models,

More information

Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability

Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability Comparison of inferential methods in partially identified models in terms of error in coverage probability Federico A. Bugni Department of Economics Duke University federico.bugni@duke.edu. September 22,

More information

ON THE CONSISTENCY OF NETWORK DATA WITH PAIRWISE STABILITY

ON THE CONSISTENCY OF NETWORK DATA WITH PAIRWISE STABILITY ON THE CONSISTENCY OF NETWORK DATA WITH PAIRWISE STABILITY KHAI XIANG CHIONG 1 This paper characterizes the consistency of social network data with pairwise stability, which is a solution concept that

More information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information

Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Bayesian Estimation of Discrete Games of Complete Information Sridhar Narayanan August 2012 (First Version: May 2011) Abstract Estimation of discrete games of complete information, which have been applied

More information

STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS

STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS KONRAD MENZEL NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Abstract. We consider a random utility model of strategic network formation, where we derive a tractable approximation to

More information

Semiparametric Identification in Panel Data Discrete Response Models

Semiparametric Identification in Panel Data Discrete Response Models Semiparametric Identification in Panel Data Discrete Response Models Eleni Aristodemou UCL March 8, 2016 Please click here for the latest version. Abstract This paper studies partial identification in

More information

IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY

IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY IDENTIFICATION OF INCOMPLETE INFORMATION GAMES WITH MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA AND UNOBSERVED HETEROGENEITY by Ruli Xiao A dissertation submitted to The Johns Hopkins University in conformity with the requirements

More information

Weak Stochastic Increasingness, Rank Exchangeability, and Partial Identification of The Distribution of Treatment Effects

Weak Stochastic Increasingness, Rank Exchangeability, and Partial Identification of The Distribution of Treatment Effects Weak Stochastic Increasingness, Rank Exchangeability, and Partial Identification of The Distribution of Treatment Effects Brigham R. Frandsen Lars J. Lefgren December 16, 2015 Abstract This article develops

More information

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS. 1. Introduction

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS. 1. Introduction ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF MODELS WITH SOCIAL INTERACTIONS BRENDAN KLINE AND ELIE TAMER 1. Introduction Models with social interactions accommodate the possibility that an individual s outcome may be related

More information

STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS

STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS STRATEGIC NETWORK FORMATION WITH MANY AGENTS KONRAD MENZEL NEW YORK UNIVERSITY Abstract. We consider a random utility model of strategic network formation, where we derive a tractable approximation to

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IDENTIFICATION OF POTENTIAL GAMES AND DEMAND MODELS FOR BUNDLES. Jeremy T. Fox Natalia Lazzati

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IDENTIFICATION OF POTENTIAL GAMES AND DEMAND MODELS FOR BUNDLES. Jeremy T. Fox Natalia Lazzati NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IDENTIFICATION OF POTENTIAL GAMES AND DEMAND MODELS FOR BUNDLES Jeremy T. Fox Natalia Lazzati Working Paper 18155 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18155 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC

More information

Inference for Identifiable Parameters in Partially Identified Econometric Models

Inference for Identifiable Parameters in Partially Identified Econometric Models Inference for Identifiable Parameters in Partially Identified Econometric Models Joseph P. Romano Department of Statistics Stanford University romano@stat.stanford.edu Azeem M. Shaikh Department of Economics

More information

A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks

A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks Angelo Mele, November 1, 2011 Abstract The main challenges in estimating strategic network formation models are the presence of multiple equilibria,

More information

An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks. Lecture 4, Part II

An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks. Lecture 4, Part II An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks Lecture 4, Part II Michael D Ko nig University of Zurich Department of Economics 12 13 June 2017 Outline Strategic Network Formation Pairwise Stability Nash

More information

A New Random Graph Model with Self-Optimizing Nodes: Connectivity and Diameter

A New Random Graph Model with Self-Optimizing Nodes: Connectivity and Diameter A New Random Graph Model with Self-Optimizing Nodes: Connectivity and Diameter Richard J. La and Maya Kabkab Abstract We introduce a new random graph model. In our model, n, n 2, vertices choose a subset

More information

Moment Inequalities and Their Application

Moment Inequalities and Their Application Moment Inequalities and Their Application A. Pakes J. Porter Kate Ho Joy Ishii The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP16/07 Moment Inequalities and Their

More information

Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix)

Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix) Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix Flavio Cunha The University of Pennsylvania James Heckman The University

More information

Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation

Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation Revisiting the Nested Fixed-Point Algorithm in BLP Random Coeffi cients Demand Estimation Jinhyuk Lee Kyoungwon Seo September 9, 016 Abstract This paper examines the numerical properties of the nested

More information

Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model

Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model Omid Atabati 1 and Babak Farzad 2 1 Department of Economics, University of Calgary, Calgary, AB T2N 1N4, Canada oatabati@ucalgary.ca 2 Department

More information

Structural Estimation of Sequential Games of Complete Information

Structural Estimation of Sequential Games of Complete Information Structural Estimation of Sequential Games of Complete Information JASON R. BLEVINS Department of Economics, The Ohio State University November, 204 Forthcoming in Economic Inquiry Abstract. In models of

More information

Networks: Theory and Applications. by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University)

Networks: Theory and Applications. by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University) Networks: Theory and Applications by Yves Zenou (Stockholm University) General description It has been recognized for a long time that non-market interactions, i.e. interactions between agents that are

More information

Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games

Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games Identification of Discrete Choice Models for Bundles and Binary Games Jeremy T. Fox University of Michigan and NBER Natalia Lazzati University of Michigan February 2013 Abstract We study nonparametric

More information

Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information.

Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information. Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information. Andres Aradillas-Lopez Adam M. Rosen The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP36/14 Inference

More information

Specification Test on Mixed Logit Models

Specification Test on Mixed Logit Models Specification est on Mixed Logit Models Jinyong Hahn UCLA Jerry Hausman MI December 1, 217 Josh Lustig CRA Abstract his paper proposes a specification test of the mixed logit models, by generalizing Hausman

More information

A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks,

A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks, A Structural Model of Segregation in Social Networks, Angelo Mele Job Market Paper November 1, 2010 Abstract In this paper, I develop and estimate a dynamic model of strategic network formation with heterogeneous

More information

Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information.

Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information. Inference in Ordered Response Games with Complete Information. Andres Aradillas-Lopez Pennsylvania State University Adam M. Rosen Duke University and CeMMAP October 18, 2016 Abstract We study econometric

More information

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games

Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Oblivious Equilibrium: A Mean Field Approximation for Large-Scale Dynamic Games Gabriel Y. Weintraub, Lanier Benkard, and Benjamin Van Roy Stanford University {gweintra,lanierb,bvr}@stanford.edu Abstract

More information

1. Introduction. 2. A Simple Model

1. Introduction. 2. A Simple Model . Introduction In the last years, evolutionary-game theory has provided robust solutions to the problem of selection among multiple Nash equilibria in symmetric coordination games (Samuelson, 997). More

More information

Bayesian Learning in Social Networks

Bayesian Learning in Social Networks Bayesian Learning in Social Networks Asu Ozdaglar Joint work with Daron Acemoglu, Munther Dahleh, Ilan Lobel Department of Electrical Engineering and Computer Science, Department of Economics, Operations

More information

large number of i.i.d. observations from P. For concreteness, suppose

large number of i.i.d. observations from P. For concreteness, suppose 1 Subsampling Suppose X i, i = 1,..., n is an i.i.d. sequence of random variables with distribution P. Let θ(p ) be some real-valued parameter of interest, and let ˆθ n = ˆθ n (X 1,..., X n ) be some estimate

More information

6 Evolution of Networks

6 Evolution of Networks last revised: March 2008 WARNING for Soc 376 students: This draft adopts the demography convention for transition matrices (i.e., transitions from column to row). 6 Evolution of Networks 6. Strategic network

More information

Inference in ordered response games with complete information

Inference in ordered response games with complete information Inference in ordered response games with complete information Andres Aradillas-Lopez Adam Rosen The Institute for Fiscal Studies Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP33/13 Inference in

More information

Economics of Networks Social Learning

Economics of Networks Social Learning Economics of Networks Social Learning Evan Sadler Massachusetts Institute of Technology Evan Sadler Social Learning 1/38 Agenda Recap of rational herding Observational learning in a network DeGroot learning

More information

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden 1 Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning Jason R. Marden Abstract A learning rule is completely uncoupled if each player s behavior is conditioned only on his own realized

More information

Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry

Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry Andres Aradillas-Lopez and Amit Gandhi Pennsylvania State University and University of Wisconsin-Madison December 3, 2015 Abstract

More information

MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS

MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS MAKING FRIENDS MEET NETWORK FORMATION WITH INTRODUCTIONS JAN-PETER SIEDLAREK ABSTRACT. Economic and social networks often combine high levels of clustering with short distances between pairs of agents.

More information

Econometric analysis of models with social interactions

Econometric analysis of models with social interactions Brendan Kline (UT-Austin, Econ) and Elie Tamer (Harvard, Econ) 2017 - Please see the paper for more details, citations, etc. The setting Social interactions or peer effects, or spillovers, or...: My outcome/choice

More information

Notes 6 : First and second moment methods

Notes 6 : First and second moment methods Notes 6 : First and second moment methods Math 733-734: Theory of Probability Lecturer: Sebastien Roch References: [Roc, Sections 2.1-2.3]. Recall: THM 6.1 (Markov s inequality) Let X be a non-negative

More information

Structural Homophily

Structural Homophily Structural Homophily Vincent Boucher * October 2012 Abstract Homophily, or the fact that similar individuals tend to interact with each other, is a prominent feature of economic and social networks. Most

More information

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables

Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Consistency and Asymptotic Normality for Equilibrium Models with Partially Observed Outcome Variables Nathan H. Miller Georgetown University Matthew Osborne University of Toronto November 25, 2013 Abstract

More information

Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation

Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation Social Learning with Endogenous Network Formation Yangbo Song November 10, 2014 Abstract I study the problem of social learning in a model where agents move sequentially. Each agent receives a private

More information

STA 4273H: Statistical Machine Learning

STA 4273H: Statistical Machine Learning STA 4273H: Statistical Machine Learning Russ Salakhutdinov Department of Computer Science! Department of Statistical Sciences! rsalakhu@cs.toronto.edu! h0p://www.cs.utoronto.ca/~rsalakhu/ Lecture 7 Approximate

More information

An Empirical Model for Strategic Network Formation

An Empirical Model for Strategic Network Formation An Empirical Model for Strategic Network Formation Nicholas A. Christakis James H. Fowler Guido W. Imbens Karthik Kalyanaraman September 2010 Abstract We develop and analyze a tractable empirical model

More information

The Influence Function of Semiparametric Estimators

The Influence Function of Semiparametric Estimators The Influence Function of Semiparametric Estimators Hidehiko Ichimura University of Tokyo Whitney K. Newey MIT July 2015 Revised January 2017 Abstract There are many economic parameters that depend on

More information

Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria

Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria Identification and Estimation of Incomplete Information Games with Multiple Equilibria Ruli Xiao Johns Hopkins University November 20, 2013 Job Market Paper Abstract The presence of multiple equilibria

More information

The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games

The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games Andres ARADILLAS-LOPEZ Department of Economics, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544 Elie TAMER Department of Economics, Northwestern University,

More information

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models

Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Robust Backtesting Tests for Value-at-Risk Models Jose Olmo City University London (joint work with Juan Carlos Escanciano, Indiana University) Far East and South Asia Meeting of the Econometric Society

More information

Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models

Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models Information Structure and Statistical Information in Discrete Response Models Shakeeb Khan a and Denis Nekipelov b This version: January 2012 Abstract Strategic interaction parameters characterize the

More information

On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks

On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks Philippe Bich and Lisa Morhaim Monday 4 th July, 017 Abstract We provide the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks under assumptions similar

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo September 6, 2011 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games

The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games The Identification Power of Equilibrium in Simple Games Andres Aradillas-Lopez Princeton University Elie Tamer Northwestern University February 2008 Abstract We examine the identification power that Nash)

More information

Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend?

Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend? Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Building socio-economic Networks: How many conferences should you attend? Antonio Cabrales, Antoni Calvó-Armengol, Yves Zenou January 06 Summary Introduction The game Equilibrium

More information

Semi and Nonparametric Models in Econometrics

Semi and Nonparametric Models in Econometrics Semi and Nonparametric Models in Econometrics Part 4: partial identification Xavier d Haultfoeuille CREST-INSEE Outline Introduction First examples: missing data Second example: incomplete models Inference

More information

Why experimenters should not randomize, and what they should do instead

Why experimenters should not randomize, and what they should do instead Why experimenters should not randomize, and what they should do instead Maximilian Kasy Department of Economics, Harvard University Maximilian Kasy (Harvard) Experimental design 1 / 42 project STAR Introduction

More information

Lecture Notes: Entry and Product Positioning

Lecture Notes: Entry and Product Positioning Lecture Notes: Entry and Product Positioning Jean-François Houde Cornell University & NBER November 21, 2016 1 Motivation: Models of entry and product positioning Static demand and supply analyses treat

More information

SEQUENTIAL ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC DISCRETE GAMES. Victor Aguirregabiria (Boston University) and. Pedro Mira (CEMFI) Applied Micro Workshop at Minnesota

SEQUENTIAL ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC DISCRETE GAMES. Victor Aguirregabiria (Boston University) and. Pedro Mira (CEMFI) Applied Micro Workshop at Minnesota SEQUENTIAL ESTIMATION OF DYNAMIC DISCRETE GAMES Victor Aguirregabiria (Boston University) and Pedro Mira (CEMFI) Applied Micro Workshop at Minnesota February 16, 2006 CONTEXT AND MOTIVATION Many interesting

More information

A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data

A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data A nonparametric test for path dependence in discrete panel data Maximilian Kasy Department of Economics, University of California - Los Angeles, 8283 Bunche Hall, Mail Stop: 147703, Los Angeles, CA 90095,

More information

Distributions of Centrality on Networks

Distributions of Centrality on Networks Distributions of Centrality on Networks Krishna Dasaratha arxiv:1709.10402v2 [cs.si] 25 Jan 2018 January 26, 2018 Abstract We provide a framework for determining the centralities of agents in a broad family

More information

Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games

Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games Mini Course on Structural Estimation of Static and Dynamic Games Junichi Suzuki University of Toronto June 1st, 2009 1 Part : Estimation of Dynamic Games 2 ntroduction Firms often compete each other overtime

More information

No THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION. By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi. May 2003 ISSN

No THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION. By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi. May 2003 ISSN No. 2003 53 THE ROLE OF TRUST IN COSTLY NETWORK FORMATION By Robert P. Gilles and Sudipta Sarangi May 2003 ISSN 0924-7815 The Role of Trust in Costly Network Formation Robert P. Gilles Sudipta Sarangi

More information

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO

Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Dynamic Discrete Choice Structural Models in Empirical IO Lecture 4: Euler Equations and Finite Dependence in Dynamic Discrete Choice Models Victor Aguirregabiria (University of Toronto) Carlos III, Madrid

More information

Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games

Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games Monotonic ɛ-equilibria in strongly symmetric games Shiran Rachmilevitch April 22, 2016 Abstract ɛ-equilibrium allows for worse actions to be played with higher probability than better actions. I introduce

More information

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics Ozan Candogan, Asuman Ozdaglar and Pablo A. Parrilo January 29, 2012 Abstract Potential games are a special class of games for which many adaptive user dynamics

More information

BAYESIAN INFERENCE IN A CLASS OF PARTIALLY IDENTIFIED MODELS

BAYESIAN INFERENCE IN A CLASS OF PARTIALLY IDENTIFIED MODELS BAYESIAN INFERENCE IN A CLASS OF PARTIALLY IDENTIFIED MODELS BRENDAN KLINE AND ELIE TAMER UNIVERSITY OF TEXAS AT AUSTIN AND HARVARD UNIVERSITY Abstract. This paper develops a Bayesian approach to inference

More information

Methods of Identification in Social Networks

Methods of Identification in Social Networks Methods of Identification in Social Networks Bryan S. Graham January 15, 2015 Abstract Social and economic networks are ubiquitous, serving as contexts for job search, technology diffusion, the accumulation

More information

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models pascal billand a, christophe bravard a, sudipta sarangi b a CREUSET, Jean Monnet University, Saint-Etienne, France. email: pascal.billand@univ-st-etienne.fr

More information

and Level Sets First version: August 16, This version: February 15, Abstract

and Level Sets First version: August 16, This version: February 15, Abstract Consistency of Plug-In Estimators of Upper Contour and Level Sets Neşe Yıldız First version: August 16, 2004. This version: February 15, 2008. Abstract This note studies the problem of estimating the set

More information

Szemerédi s regularity lemma revisited. Lewis Memorial Lecture March 14, Terence Tao (UCLA)

Szemerédi s regularity lemma revisited. Lewis Memorial Lecture March 14, Terence Tao (UCLA) Szemerédi s regularity lemma revisited Lewis Memorial Lecture March 14, 2008 Terence Tao (UCLA) 1 Finding models of large dense graphs Suppose we are given a large dense graph G = (V, E), where V is a

More information

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions

Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK. Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions Economics Division University of Southampton Southampton SO17 1BJ, UK Discussion Papers in Economics and Econometrics Title Overlapping Sub-sampling and invariance to initial conditions By Maria Kyriacou

More information

Identification and Estimation of Marginal Effects in Nonlinear Panel Models 1

Identification and Estimation of Marginal Effects in Nonlinear Panel Models 1 Identification and Estimation of Marginal Effects in Nonlinear Panel Models 1 Victor Chernozhukov Iván Fernández-Val Jinyong Hahn Whitney Newey MIT BU UCLA MIT February 4, 2009 1 First version of May 2007.

More information

Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games

Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games Robustness of Equilibria in Anonymous Local Games Willemien Kets October 12, 2010 Abstract This paper studies the robustness of symmetric equilibria in anonymous local games to perturbations of prior beliefs.

More information

First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit. Game Theory. Giorgio Fagiolo

First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit. Game Theory. Giorgio Fagiolo Game Theory Giorgio Fagiolo giorgio.fagiolo@univr.it https://mail.sssup.it/ fagiolo/welcome.html Academic Year 2005-2006 University of Verona Summary 1. Why Game Theory? 2. Cooperative vs. Noncooperative

More information

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency Subhadip Chakrabarti and Supanit Tangsangasaksri Queen s University Management School, Queen s University

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

Probability Models of Information Exchange on Networks Lecture 5

Probability Models of Information Exchange on Networks Lecture 5 Probability Models of Information Exchange on Networks Lecture 5 Elchanan Mossel (UC Berkeley) July 25, 2013 1 / 22 Informational Framework Each agent receives a private signal X i which depends on S.

More information

Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models

Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models Nabil I. Al-Najjar & Northwestern University Eran Shmaya Tel Aviv University RUD, Warwick, June 2014 Forthcoming: Journal of Political Economy Motivation

More information

INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS

INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS INDISTINGUISHABILITY OF ABSOLUTELY CONTINUOUS AND SINGULAR DISTRIBUTIONS STEVEN P. LALLEY AND ANDREW NOBEL Abstract. It is shown that there are no consistent decision rules for the hypothesis testing problem

More information

Networks and Favor Exchange Norms under Stochastic Costs

Networks and Favor Exchange Norms under Stochastic Costs The University of Adelaide School of Economics Research Paper No. 203-04 April 203 Networks and Favor Exchange Norms under Stochastic Costs Seungmoon Choi, Virginie Masson, Angus Moore and Mandar Oak Networks

More information

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis

Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Simultaneous Choice Models: The Sandwich Approach to Nonparametric Analysis Natalia Lazzati y November 09, 2013 Abstract We study collective choice models from a revealed preference approach given limited

More information

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011 SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER By Donald W. K. Andrews August 2011 COWLES FOUNDATION DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 1815 COWLES FOUNDATION FOR RESEARCH IN ECONOMICS

More information

Approximating High-Dimensional Dynamic Models: Sieve Value Function Iteration

Approximating High-Dimensional Dynamic Models: Sieve Value Function Iteration Approximating High-Dimensional Dynamic Models: Sieve Value Function Iteration Peter Arcidiacono Patrick Bayer Federico Bugni Jon James Duke University Duke University Duke University Duke University January

More information

Building Social Networks

Building Social Networks Building Social Networks Robert P. Gilles Sudipta Sarangi May 2006 Abstract We examine the process of building social relationships as a non-cooperative game that requires mutual consent and involves reaching

More information

A NETWORK FORMATION MODEL BASED ON SUBGRAPHS

A NETWORK FORMATION MODEL BASED ON SUBGRAPHS A NETWORK FORMATION MODEL BASED ON SUBGRAPHS ARUN G. CHANDRASEKHAR AND MATTHEW O. JACKSON Abstract. We develop a new class of random-graph models for the statistical estimation of network formation that

More information

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Hypothesis Testing for Arbitrary Bounds. Jeffrey Penney Queen s University

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Hypothesis Testing for Arbitrary Bounds. Jeffrey Penney Queen s University QED Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1319 Hypothesis Testing for Arbitrary Bounds Jeffrey Penney Queen s University Department of Economics Queen s University 94 University Avenue Kingston,

More information