On the Optimal Use of "Dirt Taxes" and Credit Subsidies in the Presence of Private Financing Constraints

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Optimal Use of "Dirt Taxes" and Credit Subsidies in the Presence of Private Financing Constraints"

Transcription

1 On the Optimal Use of "Dirt Taxes" an Creit Subsiies in the Presence of Private Financing Constraints Florian Ho mann Roman Inerst y Ulf Moslener z February 2011 Abstract We consier an economy where prouction generates externalities, which can be reuce by aitional expenitures. This requires to raise outsie nancing, which is "costly" ue to a stanar agency problem vis-á-vis outsie investors. Policy is constraine as agents are privately informe about their marginal cost of avoiing externalities. We rst erive the optimal linear "irt tax", which is strictly lower than the Pigou tax, as reucing externalities requires aitional, costly funing an as through reistributing resources in the economy a higher tax reuces average prouctive e ciency. We show how this can be improve through nonlinear "irt taxes", which are thus no longer equivalent to a system of traing "pollution rights". E ciency can be further improve through tying grants to creit, as is frequently observe in practice. University of Frankfurt, IMFS. fho mann@ nance.uni-frankfurt.e. y University of Frankfurt an Imperial College Lonon. Aress for corresponence: University of Frankfurt, IMFS, Grüneburgplatz 1, Frankfurt am Main, Germany. inerst@ nance.unifrankfurt.e. z Frankfurt School of Finance an Management, UNEP Center for Climate Finance.

2 1 Introuction Pigou (1920) showe that the optimal tax on a goo that generates externalities shoul be equal to the marginal external amage that arises from the consumption of that goo. For instance, to internalize potential environmental amages, rms aoption of i erent technologies shoul be steere through taxing the emission of greenhouse gasses or, more irectly, the choice of particular technologies. In practice, however, governments also employ policies that subsiize the aoption of particular, more environmentally frienly policies, either through grants or through cheaper creit. One aim of our research is to inform policymakers about the optimal mix of these instruments. We consier an economy where agents must invest to prouce. An they must invest more in orer to prouce with less negative externalities, which can be observe an thus taxe appropriately. (A version of our moel applies to the case where the aoption of more or less polluting technologies is itself contractible.) The key feature of our moel is the introuction of funing constraints. For this we enow agents with a limite amount of resources an grant them access to an external creit market ("outsie nance"). (In our basic moel, we restrict the government s role to that of transferring resources, instea of acting, in aition, as a nancial intermeiary with respect to "foreign investors".) The amount of external nancing that is raise interferes with prouctive e ciency ue a stanar moral-hazar problem, which is moele through the provision of unobservable e ort that a ects the likelihoo of realizing high instea of low nal output. In such a setting, we explore rst the optimal taxation of the externality, combine with a buget-balancing transfer, that maximizes the objective function of a utilitarian policymaker. This can be implemente also through the free istribution of a constraine amount of "pollution rights", which are then trae in a market. We then introuce nonlinear irt taxes as well as policies that are contingent on the amount of outsie nance ("creit") that is raise to (purportely) reuce pollution. Our framework may be particularly suitable to escribe policies that are aime towars rms an that inten to implement a large, costly change in their behavior. The costs of achieving the necessary aoption of i erent technologies shoul then have a non-negligible impact on rms funing requirements. We aress this in a moel where rms costs of outsie nancing are erive from rst principles. 1

3 When policy is restricte to a simple linear tax or, likewise, to the allocation of marketable "pollution rights", we n two reasons for why the tax is strictly lower than the optimal Pigou tax. First, the optimal tax - or, likewise, the aggregate amount of permissible pollution - takes into account the enogenous costs of raising nance so as to reuce negative externalities. Note that this e ect oes not hinge on the presence of heterogeneous agents with i erent marginal costs of avoiance: It is not the irt tax per se that generates a istortion, but more simply the aitional costs of higher avoiance an, consequently, the requirement to raise more outsie nance, as this increases agency costs. With a homogeneous agent, in equilibrium the agent is actually fully reimburse for his taxes, at least in expectation, an the incremental prouctive ine ciency arises only through the nee to raise aitional nance so as to cover the incremental costs of avoiance. With heterogeneous agents, there is a secon rationale for why the optimal linear tax is strictly lower than the " rst-best" Pigou tax. As tax procees are istribute back to agents in equilibrium, a higher tax shifts resources to rms that ue to lower marginal avoiance costs are alreay avantage an nee less outsie nancing. We show that this reistribution, which only arises in the presence of a policy aime at reucing externalities, reuces average prouctive e ciency. In our framework, a linear tax is, however, not the optimal mechanism. We rst explore the use of nonlinear taxes. We n that the optimal nonlinear tax rst ecreases with the externalities that an agent generates an then increases again; or, likewise, for rms the marginal bene t from avoiance is highest at relatively low levels (the " rst units") an at relatively high levels, which are only reache by rms with very low marginal costs of avoiance. As we explore, this non-linearity mirrors similar observations in the theory of optimal income taxation with private information an an utilitarian policymaker. In our framework, a key implication is that compare to such a nonlinear tax, a system of traable "pollution rights", which is akin to a linear tax, woul be ine cient. Furthermore, we show that e ciency can be further improve by linking transfers to the outsie nance that agents raise so as to (purportely) reuce externalities. In a nutshell, by combining a tax on externalities with grants that are linke to creit, the reistribution that is generate by the tax can be counteracte. Thereby, agents with lower avoiance costs n it less pro table to mimic those with higher avoiance costs, so 2

4 as to claim aitional grants. This follows simply as raising more-than-necessary outsie nance exacerbates the agency problem vis-á-vis outsie investors. As a consequence, coupling taxes on externalities with grants linke to loans - as is frequently observe in practice - may be an e cient instrument, as it allows to improve aggregate prouctive e ciency. As note above, our results with a linear tax eviate from the " rst-best" Pigou rule, which woul prescribe to set the tax so as to thereby fully internalizes the marginal social amage from pollution. It also contrasts with the notion of a "ouble ivien", which woul prescribe to set the tax still higher, as the revenues coul then be use to reuce istortions that woul arise from other taxes, e.g., on income (cf. Gaube 2005 for an exposition). However, as was recognize early on (cf. Bovenberg an e Mooij 1994; Parry 1996), the tax on externalities may itself a istortions in prouction or consumption. 1 However, recent contributions in the public nance literature have restore the " rstbest" Pigou rule, most notably through the use of nonlinear income taxes that are use to compensate for the aforementione istortions that a tax on externalities imposes on prouction an consumption in these moels (cf. on nonlinear taxes, in particular, Kaplov 2006; Jacobs an e Moij 2010). 2 Importantly, we solve in our moel for the optimal mechanism an allow the government to tax both the externality as well as observe output. Still, in the presence of outsie nancing requirements an agency problems the wege between the optimal marginal tax an the Pigou benchmark remains. Outsie the public nance literature, our paper is somewhat relate to the literature that analyzes the e ect of liability on environmental care. In some of this literature (cf. the survey in Boyer et al. 2007), compensation for amages is restricte by agents lim- 1 Goulner (1995) terme the positive e ect from lowering other istorting taxes the "revenue-recycling" e ect an the negative istortionary impact the "tax-interaction" e ect. Bovenberg an e Mooij (1994) argue that in the presence of preexisting istortionary taxes, an optimal pollution tax shoul lie below the Pigouvian tax. The intuition is that the collective goo of environmental quality competes with other collective goos, so that the marginal cost of increasing environmental quality through a public policy increases with the marginal cost of public funs. (In more etail, a pollution tax then further istorts the composition of consumption, even if tax revenues are recycle in the form of lower tax rates on labour income.) Cf. also Atkinson an Stern (1974) on the ning that the secon-best provision of public goos uner private information will be lower than the rst-best provision. 2 As pointe out in Kaplov (2006), the key is to recognize that the environmental tax will inuce, ceteris paribus, reistribution an that this a ects the relationship between the Pigouvian tax increment an social marginal amages. Cf. earlier in a similar vein Diamon an Mirrlees (1971), who state that istributional concerns o not justify violating prouction e ciency if the government can optimally ajust taxes (on consumption). 3

5 ite resources or the limite liability embee in the nancial structure that they use to nance prouction. Imposing an extene liability also on the proviers of outsie nance may then impact e ciency, in particular in the presence of nancial frictions an imperfect nancial markets (cf. Pitchfor 1995, Tirole 2010). Finally, the interaction between private nancial frictions an public policy has also been aresse in the literature on entrepreneurship that examines various rationales for policy intervention, in particular the possible spillover e ects create by start-ups. Boaway an Tremblay (2005) o er a broa overview, which mainly focuses on tax consierations. The rest of this paper is organize as follows. Section 2 introuces the economy. Section 3 erives some preliminary results. In Sections 4 an 5 we solve for the optimal linear an nonlinear tax on the externality. Section 6 shows that aing a tax on output oes not alter results. In Section 7 we allow the government to use, as an aitional instrument, a grant linke to the size of the loan. Section 8 summarizes our results. 2 The Economy Agents an Enowments. We consier an economy populate by a unit mass of agents inexe by i 2 I = [0; 1]. There are two points of time: t = 0 an t = 1. In our basic case, each agent is originally enowe with zero resources, but he has access to the same prouction technology that pays out in the nal perio t = 1. Abstracting rst from both the presence of a policymaker an the presence of externalities, starting prouction in t = 0 requires the investment of I 0 0 an generates in t = 1 either zero output or an output of x > 0. 3 The likelihoo of a positive outcome epens on the non-observable, real-value e ort e that the respective agent exerts. For our purpose it will be convenient to make agents utility separable in e ort cost (as well as in the consumption of externalities, in what follows). The respective e ort cost function is enote by c(e), while the likelihoo of positive output x is given by p(e). For what follows, we only nee that the functions are continuously i erentiable, so that a marginal change in contractual parameters has inee a marginal impact on e ciency through a ecting the choice of e ort. However, it is convenient to stipulate, in aition, that c 00 < 0, p 00 0, c 0 (0) = 0, an p 0 (0) > In our moel, the investment outlay an output are both measure in the same unit of "resources" or capital. 4 For instance, we coul stipulate that p(e) = e, c(e) = e 2 =(2), where is then taken to be su ciently large so as to ensure that p(e) < 1 hols in equilibrium. 4

6 Note that as presently all agents in the economy start with zero resources, they will have to raise capital from an external capital market. (To be speci c, we may think of this as raising capital abroa.) We stipulate that the agents utility is linear in the resources that they consume an that they o not iscount future consumption, which is why in our moel the only rationale for borrowing (i.e., raising outsie nance) is for prouction. In terms of contracting with outsie investors, we stipulate that the output realization is veri able an can thus be part of a nancial contract. Externalities. Prouction generates negative externalities, which can be reuce by aitional investment. Precisely, we stipulate that when the prouction of agent i creates y i 0 units of these externalities, then this a ects all other agents equally an, thereby, generates the social loss y i with > 0. Recall that we stipulate that utility is also aitively separable in externalities. That is, when in t = 2 agent i is left with w i resources for consumption an has exerte e ort e i, then his total utility is u i = w i c(e i ) y j j: (1) Note that this implies that an agent s private incentives to reuce his own externality y i are zero (given his "small size" compare to the uniform istribution of the externality over all agents). Externalities are veri able. An agent s cost of avoiing externalities epen on his type. Presently, this will be the only source of heterogeneity between agents. De ne the strictly positive real-value type by i, where we assume that i is, for all i 2 I, inepenently an ientically istribute accoring to the istribution function F (), permitting a ensity function f() > 0 for all 2 [; ]. Generating a level of externalities y, e.g., by using the respective technology mix or by running prouction with the respective safety provisions, is associate with a particular prouction cost. It is convenient, albeit this is without loss of generality, to stipulate that there is a given maximum level of externalities y (per business) an, consequently, to enote the respective avoie externalities by a = y y. Then, we capture avoiance costs by the twice continuously i erentiable function K(a; ) with K(0) = 0, K 0 (a = 0) = 0, an K 00 > 0. Further, we stipulate that j2i 2 K(a; ) a < 0: (2) 5

7 That is: Higher types have everywhere lower marginal costs of avoiance. For instance, we coul stipulate that K(a; ) = k(a)=. Note that the respective costs are incurre, together with the investment I 0, right when prouction starts in t = 0. Further, observe that the agent s economic success (x or zero) oes not irectly interact with the generation of externalities. However, as we show below, it interacts inirectly through the incurre avoiance costs an thus the nee to raise more external nance. That there is no irect interaction of prouce externalities an the likelihoo of high output allows to restrict contracts with external investors to repayments that are conitional only on realize output (as this is then a su cient statistic for e ort). Alternative Interpretation. Our chosen set-up, where the reuction in negative externalities is a function of investment, allows also for the following alternative interpretation. The following interpretation may be particularly suitable when introucing later policies that are contingent on raise outsie nance. We coul think of y or likewise a = y y as a (continuous) veri able technology choice, e.g., the "amount" of more fuel-e cient equipment that is installe or of energy-e cient builing materials that are use when setting up prouction. Though the purchase costs may be the same for all agents, agents costs of installation or, alternatively, their total opportunity costs may i er, given the builings, equipment, an technologies that they alreay own. For higher, the associate costs are lower accoring to conition (2). Note nally that a given choice of y an a coul then be associate with a i erent istribution over externalities (which, however, is no longer type-epenent). Without loss of generality, any policy coul then target irectly the aoption of a. When y an a capture the aoption of a particular, veri able technology, agents utility function (1) an thus also the policymaker s objective function coul be rewritten accoringly, namely as a function of expecte externalities, without changing results. Feasible Policies. In our main analysis we introuce a utilitarian policymaker, who maximizes the expecte utility of all agents: E R u i i (in contrast to, for instance, only implementing policies that woul lea to a Pareto improvement; cf. our iscussion below). For simplicity, we refer to the policymaker as the government. We consier various 6

8 policy instruments as we go along. In particular, we consier rst a simple, linear tax on externalities, couple with a transfer that is pai out of the receipts. This can also be implemente through a market for pollution rights. We further consier non-linear taxes an, subsequently, more general mechanisms that can also conition on rms nancial nees (i.e., the creit that they have to raise). Throughout our main analysis we also restrict the government to policies that, conitional on the generate externalities, reistribute resources only at the initial state. As we show below, we can inee ignore without loss of generality taxes that are levie on nal output. This hols even when the "rights" to these taxes coul be istribute initially an coul thus be sol to outsie investors, as to thereby reuce agents nee to raise outsie nance backe only by promises on own future output. Also, note that we o not allow the government to raise nance on behalf of agents. That is, the government is presently not allowe to itself borrow funs from outsie the economy. This coul be justi e on various grouns. For instance, in our two-stage worl outsie creitors may not n it possible to successfully ask repayment from a strategically efaulting sovereign. However, we show below that having the government acting as an intermeiary to raise nance oes by itself not a ect the outcome. It woul merely a an alternative way to implement a given outcome that woul, otherwise, be obtaine through having agents raise more funs themselves. When the government controls all ows of creit, however, then this gives rise to an aitional control variable, though we show that the same outcome is obtaine when the government oes not act as a nancial intermeiary but merely conitions taxes or grants on the amount of outsie nance that agents privately raise. 3 Preliminary Results 3.1 The Outsie Financing Problem Consier thus the problem of an agent who must raise capital L (a "loan") to start prouction. As he can only pay back in case output is positive, the contract with outsie investors can be restricte to a single variable: The repayment R in case the output equals x. Given some repayment R, the agent s uniquely optimal e ort level e is given by the 7

9 rst-orer conition p 0 (e )(x R) c 0 (e ) = 0: (3) (Recall that we assume that the externality a ects each agent only "in the aggregate".) This can then be substitute to obtain the investors break-even requirement p(e )R = L: (4) While (3) an (4) together may have multiple solutions, we pick in what follows the pair (R; e ) that has the lowest value R an, consequently, achieves the highest payo for the agent. Clearly, this is the unique equilibrium in a game where either outsie investors compete or the agent makes a take-it-or-leave-it o er. Further, it is immeiate that e is then strictly ecreasing in L while R is strictly increasing. Denote! = p(e )(x R) c(e ); which given the bining break-even constraint (4) is the total expecte surplus net of the funing expenitures. By the previous iscussion we can write this as a function of L:!(L). With L = 0 an thus R = 0, the agent woul choose a rst-best value solving p 0 (e F B )x c 0 (e F B ) = 0, thereby realizing a total surplus of!(0). Clearly, it hols that e < e F B whenever L > 0. When we thus compare the total net surplus at the benchmark with L = 0 an at any other choice L > 0, we have!(l) <!(0) L: This i erence beyon the change in funing requirements captures the crucial ine ciency that arises from the outsie nancing problem. It follows as the agent shirks when he no longer realizes the full bene ts from putting in higher e ort an, thereby, pushing up the likelihoo of success. Observe further that from the break-even constraint (4) the agent is the resiual claimant, so that it follows immeiately that!(l) is strictly ecreasing in L: As more of the output has to be promise away as repayment, the agent s incentives to exert e ort further ecline, resulting in a further reuction of e ciency. This captures the key ine ciency that arises from the agency problem ue to non-observable e ort an the nee to raise outsie nance. 8

10 So far, we restricte attention to eterministic contracts with outsie investors. Given risk neutrality of both agents an outsie investors, without loss of generality the most general, stochastic contract is escribe as follows. Note rst that (L;!(L)) escribes investors an the agent s expecte payo s once nancing is sunk (net of e ort costs, but gross of initial capital L). A contract with investors coul now prescribe the following, next to the initial provision of capital L: A istribution over values L n with E[L n ] = L so that when a particular value L n is rawn, the contract that is then implemente generates for the investor the expecte repayment of L j an, consequently, the expecte payo!(l n ) for the agent. Clearly, by optimality the chosen lottery woul maximize E[!(L n )] subject to E[L n ] = L. Denote the respective value by b!(l) = max E[!(L n )]. Importantly, while it is immeiate that also b!(l) is strictly ecreasing in L, it is also concave: b! 00 (L) 0 at points of i erentiability. (It is continuous an i erentiable almost everywhere.) The argument follows simply by contraiction: If this was not the case, then we coul n from Jensen s inequality three values L 1 < L < L 2 an two probabilities 1 an 2 so that L = L L 2 2 while b!(l) < b!(l 1 ) 1 + b!(l 2 ) 2, contraicting the construction of b!() at L. Lemma 1 If the agent nees initial nancing of L, then uner the optimal contract that lets outsie investors just break even he realizes the expecte payo (net of costs of e ort) b!(l), which is continuous, strictly ecreasing with b! 0 (L) < 1, an concave. In what follows, we n it more convenient to suppose that alreay the payo function!(l), for which we i not mae use of lotteries, is strictly concave. This clearly implies that lotteries are not optimal. Still, our subsequent results hol generally when we use, instea, b!(l). 3.2 A Secon-Best Benchmark without Reistribution The object function of a utilitarian government is to maximize the expecte utility of all agents: E[u i ] = [!(L i ) y i ] i: (This uses that!(l i ) alreay takes into account the investment costs as these are fune by outsie investors.) Suppose for a moment that the government coul control irectly 9

11 the activities of each agent, e.g., as i was observable. Abstracting from other transfers, i.e., transfers between agents, the government woul then choose y i so as to maximize s i =!(L i ) y i with L i = I 0 + K(y y; i ): Proposition 1 If the government coul observe each agent s type an interfere only by controlling irectly the actions of any agent i, then epening on = i the agent woul choose a unique level of externalities y SB () an thus a unique level of avoiance a SB () = y y SB (). This is strictly increasing in an etermine by K 1 (a SB (); )! 0 (I 0 + K(a SB (); )) = : (5) Proof. For agent i, the erivative of s i is given by s i y i =! 0 K 1, where K 1 > 0 an! 0 < 1. Note that then 2 s i (y i ) 2 =!0 K 11 + (K 1 ) 2! 00 < 0; where we use K 11 > 0 an! 00 < 0, so that there is a unique value y SB (). By implicit i erentiation we then obtain y SB () = K 12! 0 + K 1 K 2! 00! 0 K 11 + (K 1 ) 2! 00 < 0; (6) using that K 2 < 0, as for all y > 0 we have K 12 < 0 while K(0; ) = 0. Q.E.D. When! 0 = 1, then conition (5) woul simply state that for each the costs of avoiing externalities shoul equal the marginal social bene ts,. That is: K 1 (a SB (); ) =. Note that from K 12 < 0, the level of avoiance woul then still be strictly increasing in. With external nancing, however, we have that! 0 < 1 (cf. Lemma 1), so that at the secon-best value a SB () the marginal avoiance costs are still strictly below. In light of the subsequent analysis, for which the "avoiance scheule" a SB () will serve as a benchmark, the following case istinction will be of interest. Take again the case where! 0 = Note now that 1 an enote the " rst-best value" by a F B (), which satis es K 1 (a F B (); ) =, with a F B() = K 12(a F B (); ) K 11 (a F B (); ) > 0: K(a F B(); ) > 0 if K 2 + a F B() K 1 > 0 () K 2 K 11 > K 1 K 12 : (7) 10

12 That is, when conition (7) hols, then the marginal avoiance cost avantage of a higher type is su ciently large so that in the rst-best benchmark he woul invest strictly more to reuce externalities, implying that he woul have to raise strictly more outsie nance. As is easily checke, this is, for instance, the case when 5 K(a; ) = k(a) = 1 a 2 2 : Instea, when the converse of conition (7) hols everywhere, then the irect e ect (K 2 < 0) ominates an higher types woul invest less uner the rst-best choice of externalities. These observations exten also to the secon-best benchmark. Corollary 1 When conition (7) hols everywhere, then uner the secon-best benchmark (cf. Proposition 1) the cost of avoiance K(a SB (); ) an thus the total outsie nance are strictly increasing in. When the converse hols strictly everywhere, then uner the secon-best benchmark the cost of avoiance K(a SB (); ) are strictly ecreasing in. Proof. We have which is just conition (7). Q.E.D. K(a SB(); ) > 0 if K 2 + a SB() K 1 > 0 K 12! 0 + K 1 K 2! 00 () K 2! 0 K 11 + (K 1 ) 2! K 00 1 > 0 () K 2 K 11 > K 1 K 12 ; This case istinction is now crucial when consiering the optimality conition (5). When conition (7) hols, then together with the concavity of! from Lemma 1, we have that the term! 0 > 1 is strictly increasing in. Compare to the rst-best benchmark, the nee to raise outsie nance then ampens the avoiance of externalities more for high-type than for low-type agents. The opposite is the case when conition (7) oes not hol. 3.3 A Benchmark with Reistribution Suppose now that the government can also reistribute resources. Such a reistribution is accomplishe through transfers. Precisely, suppose now that the government coul control 5 More generally, this hols when k 0 =k > k 00 =k 0. 11

13 not only y i but that it coul also stipulate a transfer T i for each agent. Consequently, the respective agent woul then have to raise the funs L i = I 0 + K(a i ; i ) + T i. Again we stipulate that the government can observe the agent s type = i. The respective Lagrangian for the government s problem is then L =E[u i ] + T i i; (8) taking into account the constraint that the integral over all transfers must sum up to zero. Recall now that for the benchmark in Proposition 1 higher-type agents always have a higher level of avoiance, a SB (). Still, conition (7) or the converse of it (provie either hols globally) etermine whether total expenitures to reuce externalities an thus the nee to raise outsie nance are increasing or ecreasing in. Recall further, that when expenitures are increasing in, then this reuces prouctive e ciency for high-type agents, while the opposite hols when expenitures are ecreasing in. In either case, as! is strictly concave by Lemma 1, the utilitarian government woul want to reistribute resources an thus ajust the nee to raise nance across agents. Conition (7) etermines the irection of the optimal reistribution. Note that in our moel this scope for e ciency-enhancing reistribution hinges entirely on the agency problem vis-á-vis outsie investors, together with the i erence in agents costs of avoiing the negative externalities. (When a = 0 hols for all agents, then also! 0 is equalize across agents, as they all raise only outsie nance equal to I 0.) Proposition 2 Suppose the government coul observe each agent s type an stipulate, next to the level of avoiance, a transfer. Then the respective type-epenent transfer T RD () woul be chosen to equalize each agent s nee to raise nance, L RD () = L, while the respective level of avoiance y RD () woul satisfy K 1 (a RD (); ) = with > 1. (9) This is everywhere strictly lower than the rst-best level of avoiance, an it compares to the secon-best benchmark (cf. Proposition 1) as follows: i) When conition (7) hols, then there is reistribution to high-type agents. With reistribution high-type agents have a strictly higher level of avoiance compare to the benchmark without reistribution (a RD () > a SB ()), while low-type agents have a strictly lower level of avoiance. 12

14 ii) If the converse of conition (7) hols, then there is reistribution to low-type agents, who then have a strictly higher level of avoiance uner reistribution, while high-type agents then have a strictly lower level compare to the benchmark without reistribution. Proof. From the Lagrangian we have for type the rst-orer conitions w.r.t. y() an T () K 1 (a(); )! 0 (I 0 + K(a(); ) + T ()) = 0; from which we obtain (9) as well as > 1 as! 0 < that L RD () = L = (! 0 ) 1 ().! 0 (I 0 + K(a(); ) + T ()) + = 0; 1. We then have also the requirement Suppose that at some we have that a SB () = a RD () an thus y SB () = y RD (). Comparing slopes at this type, using (6) an implicitly i erentiating (9), we have for the two strictly positive slopes that: a SB () < a RD() () K 12 + K 1 K 2! 00 =! 0 K 11 + (K 1 ) 2! 00 =! 0 < K 12 K 11 () K 2 K 1 K 12 K 11 > 0; when a SB () = a RD () (10) as in conition (7). It is then straightforwar to show that a SB () a RD () or the converse can not hol everywhere. Q.E.D. Clearly, absent problems of private information the utilitarian government optimally uses reistribution until prouctive e ciency is equate at each agent, i.e., until all! 0 are equalize. This is the case when the respective nees to raise nance are equalize, so that ultimately!(l RD ()) =!(L) an thus also! 0 (L RD ()) =! 0 (L) no longer epen on the agent s ientity. 4 Linear Tax So far we have assume that the government can observe i an, thus, control irectly the activities of each agent. From now on, we suppose that i is the agent s private information. 13

15 In this Section, we restrict the government to the following simple policy. Depening on the volume of prouce externalities, y i, each agent is taxe accoring to the function 6 (y) = 0 + y: (11) Here, with a slight abuse of notation, is the per-unit tax on the externality, while the xe component 0 takes into account the overall istribution that is achieve by (optimally) making the government s buget just balance: 0 + y i i = 0: (12) Without loss of generality, we stipulate that the agent must "purchase" the respective pollution rights when starting prouction in t = 0. Consequently, without resources on his own, an agent must raise outsie nance equal to L(y; ) = I 0 + K(y y; ) + (y): (13) Optimal Avoiance. Given the tax scheme (y) = 0 + y, we consier rst the program of an iniviual agent. The agent chooses y i an, consequently, has to raise L(y i ; i ), as given by (13). Dropping the subscript i, an agent of type thus chooses y to maximize! (L(y; )) with L(y; ) given by (13). Lemma 2 Suppose the government imposes a (buget-breaking) tax-cum-transfer T (y) = 0 + y. Then, an agent of type chooses the optimal level of externalities y () an thus a unique level of avoiance a () = y y () so that K 1 (a (); ) = ; (14) from which a () is strictly increasing in both an. Still, higher-type agents invest less in avoiance an thus nee to raise less outsie nance: L() = K 2 (a (); ) < 0: (15) Proof. We have! y = ( K 1(y y; ))! 0 (L(y; )) ; 6 Strictly speaking, the tax scheule is an (a ne) two-part tari. 14

16 which is strictly quasiconcave an yiels the rst-orer conition (14). i erentiation an using (2) we have further that From implicit a () a () = = K 12 (a (); ) K 11 (a (); ) > 0; 1 K 11 (a (); ) > 0: Finally, expression (15) follows from substituting the rst-orer conition (14) into the total erivative of L(). Q.E.D. Hence, with a linear tax on externalities, each agent chooses a level of avoiance where the marginal nancial bene ts arising from a reuction in the incurre tax are equal to the marginal cost of avoiance. Importantly, prouctive e ciency, as expresse through the slope! 0, plays no role in this trae-o. Moreover, note that regarless of whether the previously iscusse conition (7) hols, uner the agent s optimal choice his nee to raise outsie nance is always strictly ecreasing in his type. In fact, as now the agent chooses his privately optimal level of avoiance, this follows immeiately from optimality, as otherwise higher-type agents coul not enjoy a higher expecte utility!(l). Optimal Tax. Given the agent s optimal ecision, using Lemma 2, the government s program is now to maximize E[u i ] = [!(L(y (); )) y ()] F () (16) subject to the buget-breaking constraint (cf. (12)) 0 + y ()F () = 0: (17) Take for a moment the benchmark without nancial constraints, so that everywhere! 0 () = 1. Then, from substitution of (17) into (16) while using the agent s rst-orer conition (cf. Lemma 2) we obtain the Pigou rule =. (This obviously then implements the rst-best outcome, espite agents private information about their marginal cost of avoiance.) The following result characterizes the optimal linear tax when agents must raise outsie nance. 15

17 Proposition 3 The optimal linear per-unit tax satis es R! 0 (L(y (); ))F () =!0 (L(y (); )) y () R which implies that is strictly smaller than. y () R y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) F () ; F () (18) Proof. We can substitute from (17) to obtain for each type the nancing requirement L(y (); ) = I 0 + K(y y (); ) + y () y ( 0 )F ( 0 ); so that E[u i] " y () equals R y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) + y () ( K 1 ()) R y ( 0 ) y () # F ( 0 )! 0 () F (): Substituting the rst-orer conition (14) for y (), = K 1, this gives rise to the rstorer conition (18). From R remains to prove that! 0 () y () y () F () < 0, given that y () is strictly ecreasing, it y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) F () < 0: (19) To see this, note rst that, next to y () < 0, we have from expression (15) an Lemma 1 that (!0 (L(y; ))) = L()!00 > 0: (20) De ne now the unique type b where y ( b ) = E[y ] = R y ( 0 )F ( 0 ), while y () > E[y ] hols for < b an y () < E[y ()] hols for > b. We can now rewrite the left-han sie of (19) as LS =! 0 () [y () E[y ]] F () + < b > b! 0 () [y () E[y )]] F (): (21) There, the terms in the rst integral are all strictly negative an the terms in the secon integral are all strictly positive. Given strict monotonicity of! 0 (), we can thus erive the upper boun LS <! 0 (L(y; b )) [y () E[y ]] F () +! 0 (L(y; b )) [y () E[y ]] F () < b < b =! 0 (L(y; b )) y () y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) F () = 0. 16

18 Q.E.D. From (18) an optimal tax is strictly lower than. for two reasons. The rst is capture by the multiplier on the left-han sie (cf. Lemma 1 for! 0 < capture by the term! 0 () y ()! 0 (L(y (); ))F () > 1 (22) 1); given R y () F () < 0, the secon is y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) F () > 0; (23) that is subtracte on the right-han sie. We iscuss both in turn. The term (22) is similar to the respective multiplier obtaine in the secon-best benchmark in expression (5). It captures the fact that to lower externalities, agents must raise outsie nance, which ue to the agency problem involves an aitional "shaow cost", namely in the form of lower e ciency as e ort becomes ine ciently low. (Formally,! 0 < 1.) Next, the term (23) captures the e ciency implications of the reistribution of resources that goes han-in-han with the applie taxation, namely from agents with higher marginal avoiance costs to agents with lower marginal avoiance costs. (Note that when = 0, then the type oes not a ect utilities as y i = y an, consequently, avoiance costs are zero.) The impact of reistribution on aggregate prouctive e ciency is negative. This follows from the following two observations: First, with a linear tax high-type agents incur, uner the optimal choice y (), strictly lower costs of avoiance; secon,! is strictly concave. As the tax on externalities shifts resources to high-type agents, this reuces the agency problem of high-type agents but increases the agency problem of low-type agents. Thus, it makes the alreay more prouctive high-type agents (enogenously) still more prouctive, while further reucing prouctivity of low-type agents. This leas to a reuction in aggregate e ciency of prouction in the economy. In what follows, we explore i erent possibilities of how the government coul improve on the linear tax. Our previous iscussion suggests, in particular, the following ways. First, to avoi the iscusse reistribution to agents with lower marginal costs of avoiance, a better policy coul try to link transfers not only to the generate externalities but also 17

19 to the nee to raise outsie nance. Secon, even when this option is not feasible so that transfers can still conition only on the generate externalities, there coul be scope for nonlinear taxes. Before exploring this option in the following Section??, we rst iscuss an alternative implementation of the optimal linear tax scheme an shortly compare the outcome uner such a scheme with the secon-best benchmark, where i is observable. Alternative Implementation. It is straightforwar to see that the government coul implement the outcome i erently as follows. It coul set a total maximum capacity for externalities Y an allocate this uniformly (an for free) across all agents. (Thus each agent receives the same capacity, which we may write as Y i = Y, as there is the measure one of agents in the economy.) These capacities or "pollution rights" are then trae in the market. When is the resulting price, we obviously have that K 1 (a (); ) =, as previously in (14), together with R a ()F () = y Y. This uniquely links to Y, an vice versa. The equivalence of the two policy instruments can then be seen immeiately from substituting into the funing retirement (13) L(y (); ) = I 0 + K(y y (); ) + (y () Y ) = I 0 + K(y y (); ) + (y () y ()F ()); which is just the same as uner the linear tax, after substituting the "break-even" constraint for taxes (17). Comparison with Secon-Best Benchmark. Before moving on, we compare the outcome with a linear tax to those obtaine in the previously erive benchmarks, where the government can control irectly agents actions, without being impee by private information. There is an interesting comparison with respect to the secon-best benchmark without reistribution. With a linear tax we have observe that high-type agents always en up raising less nance, as L() is strictly ecreasing. Moreover, the linear tax implies a strictly positive transfer to high-type agents, which further reuces their nee to raise external nance. In the secon-best benchmark without reistribution, recall that conition (7) etermines whether avoiance expenitures an thus the nee for outsie nance increase or ecrease in. In analogy to the comparative analysis in Proposition 2, we then have the following result. 18

20 Corollary 2 The outcome with a linear tax compares as follows to the secon-best benchmark without reistribution (cf. Proposition 1). i) When conition (7) hols, high-type agents have a strictly higher level of avoiance with the linear tax (a () > a SB ()), while low-type agents have a strictly higher level of avoiance in the secon-best benchmark ii) When the converse of conition (7) hols, high-type agents have a strictly higher level of avoiance in the secon-best benchmark an low-type agents with the linear tax. Proof. Using the agents rst-orer conition K 1 (a (); ) =, we have R R = K 1 (y y (); )! 0 F () +!0 y () y ( 0 )F ( 0 ) F () R : F () From this we have that a () = K 12(y y (); ) K 11 (y y (); ) : y () Hence, we have in analogy to the proof of Proposition 2 that at types where expenitures are the same (i.e., where the functions cross) a SB () < a () () K 12 + K 1 K 2! 00 =! 0 K 11 + (K 1 ) 2! 00 =! 0 < K 12 K 11 ; which is just conition (7). The claim then follows as a is not higher or lower everywhere uner either regime. Q.E.D. 5 Nonlinear Taxes Consier now a general tax function (y). As is stanar, we analyze rst a irect, incentive compatible mechanism. Then, for each type there is a tax T () as well as a prescribe level of externalities y() that must be incentive compatible. That is, for all types 2 it must hol that where! (L(y(); T (); )! L(y( b ); T ( b ); ) L(y(); T (); ) = I 0 + K(y y(); ) + T (); L(y( b ); T ( b ); ) = I 0 + K(y y( b ); ) + T ( b ): for all b 2, (24) 19

21 (In wors, type must not strictly prefer to preten to be any other type b.) It is convenient to express the following optimization problem purely in terms of (permitte) externalities y(), rather than optimal avoiance a(). For ease of exposition only we presently assume that the menu f(y(); T ())g is continuously i erentiable. In this case, the incentive constraint (24) woul hol locally if! L(y( b ); ) b = T 0 () y 0 ()K 1 (y y(); ) = 0: (25) b= Further, we presently assume that the " rst-orer approach" is vali such that (25) is suf- cient to ensure global incentive compatibility. As is immeiate from the single-crossing property (2), note that this requires also that the characterize function y() be nonincreasing. De ne now (with some abuse of notation) the payo function uner truthtelling 7 u() =! (L(y(); T (); )) : We know that by incentive compatibility u() is nonecreasing an continuous an thus a.e. continuously i erentiable with L(y( b ); T ( b ); ) =! 0 K 2 (y b= y(); ) > 0 when y() > 0. (26) Control Problem. To solve for the optimal menu we set up the government s optimal control problem. For this we make the following choices. With some abuse of notation e ne L() = I 0 + K(y y(); ) + T (); which we take as the state variable. As thus u() =!(L()), we have from (26) that L() = K 2 (y y(); ) < 0: (27) Further, from T () = L() [I 0 + K(y y(); )] 7 This still presumes that taxes an subsiies are fully "use" to increase or reuce the amount of funs that must be raise externally (instea of being immeiately consume or save for consumption in the nal perio). It can be shown that this restriction is without loss of generality. 20

22 we can substitute pointwise for T (), which leaves us with the single control variable y(). The objective is thus to maximize [!(L()) y()] F () subject to the "law of motion" (27) an the buget balance conition [L() K(y y(); ) I 0 ] F () = 0: With the Hamiltonian then given by H = [!(L()) y()] f() + [L() K(y y(); ) I 0 ] f() + ()K 2 (y y(); ); an optimal solution must satisfy the rst-orer conition for y() an for the costate variable f() [ + K 1 (y y(); )] ()K 12 (y y(); ) = = 0 (), f() [! 0 (L()) + ] + 0 () = 0: (29) There are no terminal conitions, an the transversality conitions are given by lim () = 0; (30)! () = 0: (31) lim! Using (30) an (31), we thus obtain from integrating (29) an () = (! 0 (L(#)) + ) f(#)# = = (! 0 (L(#)) + ) f(#)#! 0 (L(#))F (#) > 1: (32) Note that expresses the marginal bene ts when the economy s resource constraint was marginally relaxe (e.g., by some initial enowment that coul be allocate by the government). Now, from (27) an the concavity of!(l()), we have that! 0 (L()) is increasing in. Thus, making use of (32), 0 () = f() (! 0 (L(#))! 0 (L())) F (#) 21

23 is rst positive an then negative, i.e., () is rst increasing an then ecreasing. Clearly the transversality conitions then imply that () 0 hols everywhere. Rearranging now the rst-orer conition for the control y() in (28), we have 8 K 1 (y y(); ) = + () f() K 12(y y(); ); (33) which, using K 12 < 0, 0 an > 1, shows rst that K 1 () <, i.e., also with nonlinear taxes externalities are for all types higher than uner the ( rst-best) Pigou tax. Moreover, note that it hols only at the bounaries an (when they are nite) that () = 0 an thus K 1 (y y(); ) = an K 1 (y y(); ) = ; while K 1 (y y(); ) < for all 2 (; ): Recall that we substitute out the tax T (). We obtain the slope from T 0 () = L 0 () K 2 () + y 0 ()K 1 () = y 0 ()K 1 () 0: That is, as in the case of linear taxes, the nonlinear tax on the externality still involves a transfer from low-type agents to high-type agents, given that T 0 () 0 (an strictly so where y 0 () < 0). 9 8 Presently, we assume that the rst-orer approach applies an that y(), as characterize by (33) is nonincreasing. Di erentiating (33) wrt we obtain (K 12 (y y(); ) y 0 ()K 1 (y y(); )) = () K 12 (y y(); ) + () f() f() (K 122(y y(); ) y 0 ()K 112 (y y(); )) an thus y 0 () = () 1 f() K 112() () f() K 1 () K 12 () + () f() K 122() K 12 () : 9 In fact, incentive compatibility implies that in both cases, i.e., with linear an nonlinear taxes, the marginal tax w.r.t. the agent s type is given by y 0 ()K 1 (). (For the linear tax we can use that T 0 () = y 0 () an that K 1 () =.) 22

24 Implementation. (y) = T ((y)), then If we were to implement the prescribe menu with a nonlinear tax 0 (y) = T 0 () y = T 0 () y 0 () = K 1(y y; (y)) (34) = 1 + ((y)) f((y)) K 12(y y; (y)) where when y 0 < 0 hols strictly we use (y) = y 1 (y()). This yiels next 00 (y) = () f() K () y f() K () K 12 : (35) f() Recall now from the transversality conitions (30)-(31) that at the bounaries an (when they are nite) we have () = 0. Denote now the lowest an highest realize level of externalities by y l = y() < y h = y(): Further, recall that 0 > 0 for low an 0 < 1 for high, while y bunching). Using then we have () = 1 f() f 2 () [f()0 () + f 0 ()()] 00 (y l ) = y K 0 () 12 f() < 0; 00 (y h ) = y K 0 () 12 f() > 0: < 0 (when there is no In wors, uner the optimal nonlinear tax (y), at very high levels of y the marginal tax 0 (y) > 0 becomes strictly ecreasing, while at very low levels of y the marginal tax is strictly increasing. In terms of the achieve avoiance a this result reas as follows. For the rst "units" of avoiance the marginal bene ts are strictly ecreasing, while when avoiance is alreay very high, the marginal bene ts of further avoiance are strictly increasing. Proposition 4 Uner the optimal nonlinear tax (y) the marginal tax rate is highest at the two extremes, y l an y h. This implies that when the generate externality is still high, then the marginal tax is strictly increasing. Instea, when the generate externality is alreay low, then the marginal bene ts from further reucing pollution are strictly increasing. 23

25 Put i erently, by Proposition 4 the optimal nonlinear tax rewars a reuction of externalities in particular at very high an very low realizations, i.e., the " rst units" an the "last units". The intuition for this result is as follows. At the heart is the attempt to restrict the reistribution that is mae to high-type agents. Recall that reistribution is higher when the marginal tax is higher. Note, further, that () is the marginal increase in social welfare resulting from shifting one unit of require nancing from types below to types above, i.e., from ampening reistribution to higher types. Hence, the marginal tax rate shoul be lower the higher (), as can be seen from expression (34). Obviously, at the lower bounary, there is no nee to istort the implemente choice of externalities (away from the rule K 1 = ) as there is no one bene tting from reistribution below. At the other extreme, when =, there is clearly no longer a bene t from "istorting" the marginal tax since there is noboy contributing to reistribution above. 6 Taxes on Output As we explore in etail in the preceing two sections, the government s problem is that it has only a single instrument for its two goals of, rst, a ecting the generation of externalities an, secon, limiting the amount of resources that are thereby reistribute to high-type agents. This reistribution lowers prouctive e ciency. It coul now be aske whether the government coul not improve overall e ciency through taxing the nal output, which is zero or x for all agents. For instance, one coul imagine that the government coul then reistribute to agents these rights to future taxes, which agents coul then plege to outsie investors so as to, thereby, reuce their own nee to raise nance. It is, however, straightforwar to see that such a policy is of little use. For brevity s sake we restrict ourselves to a somewhat informal argument. Suppose thus that the mechanism woul also specify a tax on positive outcome z() < x. 10 Taking this as well as the resulting nancial nee L() into account, this gives rise to a level of e ort an, thereby, to some expecte probability of success p(). Denote by () = z()p() the resulting expecte levy on output. As these can be istribute among agents, who can 10 Importantly, this can not conition on the subsequently agree repayment R with the respective investors, which woul proxy for a making the mechanism contingent on the size of external nance (cf., however, the following section). 24

26 then plege it to outsie investors, we now have the aggregate resource constraint [T () + ()] F () = 0: The key observation is now the following. For a given agent, the respective total tax payments over the two perios can be lumpe into the rst perio without a ecting the outcome. Precisely, the agent then faces the transfer e T () = T ()+() up-front an thus has to increase his external nance by the amount (). This, however, leaves both the agent s utility an total prouctive e ciency completely unchange as it oes not a ect p(). 7 Loan-Base Grants So far, we have consiere a class of policy interventions with transfers that conition only on the generate externalities. A more general policy coul link transfers also to the amount of outsie nance raise, thus, trying to limit the reistribution to agents with lower marginal costs of avoiance. Hence, in this section, we allow the government to set, apart from the optimal (linear or nonlinear) tax on externalities, also a creit subsiy epening on the size of the loan raise by a particular rm. Such a policy can realistically only conition on whether a loan of a certain size is raise, however, not on whether this is really spent on avoiance, as the concrete usage of the funs within the rm is usually unobservable. Neither can the government restrict the rm to raise, apart from the subsiize loan, aitional outsie nancing elsewhere. Within this basic framework, we erive in the following two sections the optimal creit subsiy complementing, rst, a linear an, secon, a nonlinear tax on externalities. Presently, the focus is solely on showing how loan-base grants allow to improve e ciency through reucing the reistribution to high-type agents that is implie by a tax on externalities. Linear Tax with Subsiize Loans. We rst consier the case where the government is restricte to a linear tax on externalities or, likewise, a system of traable rights. In aition, the government can now specify a transfer t() that can be i erent from a xe, type-epenent istribution t() = 0. For what follows we take it as given that, 25

Web-Based Technical Appendix: Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization

Web-Based Technical Appendix: Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization Web-Base Technical Appeni: Multi-Prouct Firms an Trae Liberalization Anrew B. Bernar Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth & NBER Stephen J. Reing LSE, Yale School of Management & CEPR Peter K. Schott Yale

More information

How to Minimize Maximum Regret in Repeated Decision-Making

How to Minimize Maximum Regret in Repeated Decision-Making How to Minimize Maximum Regret in Repeate Decision-Making Karl H. Schlag July 3 2003 Economics Department, European University Institute, Via ella Piazzuola 43, 033 Florence, Italy, Tel: 0039-0-4689, email:

More information

Online Appendix for Trade Policy under Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection

Online Appendix for Trade Policy under Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection Online Appenix for Trae Policy uner Monopolistic Competition with Firm Selection Kyle Bagwell Stanfor University an NBER Seung Hoon Lee Georgia Institute of Technology September 6, 2018 In this Online

More information

Calculus and optimization

Calculus and optimization Calculus an optimization These notes essentially correspon to mathematical appenix 2 in the text. 1 Functions of a single variable Now that we have e ne functions we turn our attention to calculus. A function

More information

Web Appendix to Firm Heterogeneity and Aggregate Welfare (Not for Publication)

Web Appendix to Firm Heterogeneity and Aggregate Welfare (Not for Publication) Web ppeni to Firm Heterogeneity an ggregate Welfare Not for Publication Marc J. Melitz Harvar University, NBER, an CEPR Stephen J. Reing Princeton University, NBER, an CEPR March 6, 203 Introuction his

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Survey Sampling. 1 Design-based Inference. Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University. February 19, 2013

Survey Sampling. 1 Design-based Inference. Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University. February 19, 2013 Survey Sampling Kosuke Imai Department of Politics, Princeton University February 19, 2013 Survey sampling is one of the most commonly use ata collection methos for social scientists. We begin by escribing

More information

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Model with Endogenous Participation

Efficiency in a Search and Matching Model with Endogenous Participation Efficienc in a Search an Matching Moel with Enogenous Participation James Albrecht a Department of Economics, Georgetown Universit an IZA Lucas Navarro Department of Economics, ILADES-Universia Alberto

More information

TMA 4195 Matematisk modellering Exam Tuesday December 16, :00 13:00 Problems and solution with additional comments

TMA 4195 Matematisk modellering Exam Tuesday December 16, :00 13:00 Problems and solution with additional comments Problem F U L W D g m 3 2 s 2 0 0 0 0 2 kg 0 0 0 0 0 0 Table : Dimension matrix TMA 495 Matematisk moellering Exam Tuesay December 6, 2008 09:00 3:00 Problems an solution with aitional comments The necessary

More information

Lecture 6: Calculus. In Song Kim. September 7, 2011

Lecture 6: Calculus. In Song Kim. September 7, 2011 Lecture 6: Calculus In Song Kim September 7, 20 Introuction to Differential Calculus In our previous lecture we came up with several ways to analyze functions. We saw previously that the slope of a linear

More information

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec56

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec pp. ec1 ec56 MANAGEMENT SCIENCE oi 0.287/mnsc.080.0970ec pp. ec ec56 e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM inorms 2009 INFORMS Electronic Companion Eects o E-Waste Regulation on New Prouct Introuction by Erica

More information

Patent Quality and a Two-Tiered Patent System

Patent Quality and a Two-Tiered Patent System Patent Quality an a Two-Tiere Patent System Viya Atal y an Talia Bar z October 2, 200 Abstract We stuy the eterminants of patent quality an the volume of patent applications in a moel where innovators

More information

Separation of Variables

Separation of Variables Physics 342 Lecture 1 Separation of Variables Lecture 1 Physics 342 Quantum Mechanics I Monay, January 25th, 2010 There are three basic mathematical tools we nee, an then we can begin working on the physical

More information

Linear First-Order Equations

Linear First-Order Equations 5 Linear First-Orer Equations Linear first-orer ifferential equations make up another important class of ifferential equations that commonly arise in applications an are relatively easy to solve (in theory)

More information

IERCU. Institute of Economic Research, Chuo University 50th Anniversary Special Issues. Discussion Paper No.210

IERCU. Institute of Economic Research, Chuo University 50th Anniversary Special Issues. Discussion Paper No.210 IERCU Institute of Economic Research, Chuo University 50th Anniversary Special Issues Discussion Paper No.210 Discrete an Continuous Dynamics in Nonlinear Monopolies Akio Matsumoto Chuo University Ferenc

More information

Dynamics of Knowledge Creation and Transfer: The Two Person Case

Dynamics of Knowledge Creation and Transfer: The Two Person Case Dynamics of Knowlege Creation an Transfer: The Two Person Case Marcus Berliant an Masahisa Fujita June 8, 2006 Abstract This paper presents a micro-moel of knowlege creation an transfer for a couple. Our

More information

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard Simon Board and Moritz Meyer-ter-Vehn October 23, 2012 1 Dynamic Moral Hazard E ects Consumption smoothing Statistical inference More strategies Renegotiation Non-separable

More information

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics"

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics 1/21 "A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics" G.L. Clementi and H.A. Hopenhayn (QJE, 2006) Cesar E. Tamayo Econ612- Economics - Rutgers April 30, 2012 2/21 Program I Summary I Physical environment

More information

Lower Bounds for the Smoothed Number of Pareto optimal Solutions

Lower Bounds for the Smoothed Number of Pareto optimal Solutions Lower Bouns for the Smoothe Number of Pareto optimal Solutions Tobias Brunsch an Heiko Röglin Department of Computer Science, University of Bonn, Germany brunsch@cs.uni-bonn.e, heiko@roeglin.org Abstract.

More information

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard Simon Board and Moritz Meyer-ter-Vehn October 27, 2011 1 Marginal Cost of Providing Utility is Martingale (Rogerson 85) 1.1 Setup Two periods, no discounting Actions

More information

Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors

Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors 49 Chapter 6: Energy-Momentum Tensors This chapter outlines the general theory of energy an momentum conservation in terms of energy-momentum tensors, then applies these ieas to the case of Bohm's moel.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE. Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE. Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FACTOR PRICES AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE: A UNIFYING PERSPECTIVE Ariel Burstein Jonathan Vogel Working Paper 6904 http://www.nber.org/papers/w6904 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

More information

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Matthias Kräkel y Anja Schöttner z Abstract It is well-known that, in static models, minimum wages generate positive worker rents and, consequently, ine ciently

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan

Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan Math 342 Partial Differential Equations «Viktor Grigoryan 6 Wave equation: solution In this lecture we will solve the wave equation on the entire real line x R. This correspons to a string of infinite

More information

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Labor Economics, 14.661. Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search Daron Acemoglu MIT December 6, 2011. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Sequential Search December 6, 2011. 1 / 43 Introduction Introduction

More information

Topic 7: Convergence of Random Variables

Topic 7: Convergence of Random Variables Topic 7: Convergence of Ranom Variables Course 003, 2016 Page 0 The Inference Problem So far, our starting point has been a given probability space (S, F, P). We now look at how to generate information

More information

Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments

Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments 2 Conference on Information Sciences an Systems, The Johns Hopkins University, March 2, 2 Time-of-Arrival Estimation in Non-Line-Of-Sight Environments Sinan Gezici, Hisashi Kobayashi an H. Vincent Poor

More information

Schrödinger s equation.

Schrödinger s equation. Physics 342 Lecture 5 Schröinger s Equation Lecture 5 Physics 342 Quantum Mechanics I Wenesay, February 3r, 2010 Toay we iscuss Schröinger s equation an show that it supports the basic interpretation of

More information

1 dx. where is a large constant, i.e., 1, (7.6) and Px is of the order of unity. Indeed, if px is given by (7.5), the inequality (7.

1 dx. where is a large constant, i.e., 1, (7.6) and Px is of the order of unity. Indeed, if px is given by (7.5), the inequality (7. Lectures Nine an Ten The WKB Approximation The WKB metho is a powerful tool to obtain solutions for many physical problems It is generally applicable to problems of wave propagation in which the frequency

More information

New Technology, Human Capital and Growth for Developing Countries.

New Technology, Human Capital and Growth for Developing Countries. New Technology, Human Capital an Growth for Developing Countries Cuong Le Van, Manh-Hung Nguyen an Thai Bao Luong Centre Economie e la Sorbonne, Université Paris-1, Pantheon-Sorbonne 106-112 B e l Hôpital,

More information

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 14.454 - Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I 04/02/2011 Due: Monday 4/11/2011 1 Question 1 - Kocherlakota (2000) Take an economy with a representative, in nitely-lived consumer. The consumer owns a technology

More information

Balancing Expected and Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Models with Asymmetric Information and Pooling

Balancing Expected and Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Models with Asymmetric Information and Pooling Balancing Expecte an Worst-Case Utility in Contracting Moels with Asymmetric Information an Pooling R.B.O. erkkamp & W. van en Heuvel & A.P.M. Wagelmans Econometric Institute Report EI2018-01 9th January

More information

6. Friction and viscosity in gasses

6. Friction and viscosity in gasses IR2 6. Friction an viscosity in gasses 6.1 Introuction Similar to fluis, also for laminar flowing gases Newtons s friction law hols true (see experiment IR1). Using Newton s law the viscosity of air uner

More information

COSTLY STATE VERIFICATION - DRAFT

COSTLY STATE VERIFICATION - DRAFT COSTLY STTE VERIFICTION - DRFT SIMCH BRKI I am writing this note in order to explain under what circumstances debt contracts are optimal; more importantly, to explain why debt contracts are optimal. For

More information

Quantum mechanical approaches to the virial

Quantum mechanical approaches to the virial Quantum mechanical approaches to the virial S.LeBohec Department of Physics an Astronomy, University of Utah, Salt Lae City, UT 84112, USA Date: June 30 th 2015 In this note, we approach the virial from

More information

Sources and Sinks of Available Potential Energy in a Moist Atmosphere. Olivier Pauluis 1. Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences

Sources and Sinks of Available Potential Energy in a Moist Atmosphere. Olivier Pauluis 1. Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences Sources an Sinks of Available Potential Energy in a Moist Atmosphere Olivier Pauluis 1 Courant Institute of Mathematical Sciences New York University Submitte to the Journal of the Atmospheric Sciences

More information

The Exact Form and General Integrating Factors

The Exact Form and General Integrating Factors 7 The Exact Form an General Integrating Factors In the previous chapters, we ve seen how separable an linear ifferential equations can be solve using methos for converting them to forms that can be easily

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FIRM HETEROGENEITY AND AGGREGATE WELFARE. Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FIRM HETEROGENEITY AND AGGREGATE WELFARE. Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Redding NBER WORKING PPER SERIES FIRM HEEROGENEIY ND GGREGE WELFRE Marc J. Melitz Stephen J. Reing Working Paper 899 http://www.nber.org/papers/w899 NIONL BUREU OF ECONOMIC RESERCH 050 Massachusetts venue Cambrige,

More information

Introduction to the Vlasov-Poisson system

Introduction to the Vlasov-Poisson system Introuction to the Vlasov-Poisson system Simone Calogero 1 The Vlasov equation Consier a particle with mass m > 0. Let x(t) R 3 enote the position of the particle at time t R an v(t) = ẋ(t) = x(t)/t its

More information

Some Notes on Moral Hazard

Some Notes on Moral Hazard Some Notes on Moral Hazard John Morgan University of California at Berkeley Preliminaries Up until this point, we have been concerned mainly with the problem of private information on the part of the agent,

More information

d dx But have you ever seen a derivation of these results? We ll prove the first result below. cos h 1

d dx But have you ever seen a derivation of these results? We ll prove the first result below. cos h 1 Lecture 5 Some ifferentiation rules Trigonometric functions (Relevant section from Stewart, Seventh Eition: Section 3.3) You all know that sin = cos cos = sin. () But have you ever seen a erivation of

More information

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP Prof. Olivier Bochet Room A.34 Phone 3 63 476 E-mail olivier.bochet@vwi.unibe.ch Webpage http//sta.vwi.unibe.ch/bochet Advanced Microeconomics Fall 2 Lecture Note Choice-Based Approach Price e ects, Wealth

More information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Alain Delacroix (UQAM) and Etienne Wasmer (Sciences-Po) September 4, 2009 Abstract Wage determination under asymmetric information generates ine ciencies

More information

OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A PRODUCTION SYSTEM WITH INVENTORY-LEVEL-DEPENDENT DEMAND

OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A PRODUCTION SYSTEM WITH INVENTORY-LEVEL-DEPENDENT DEMAND Applie Mathematics E-Notes, 5(005), 36-43 c ISSN 1607-510 Available free at mirror sites of http://www.math.nthu.eu.tw/ amen/ OPTIMAL CONTROL OF A PRODUCTION SYSTEM WITH INVENTORY-LEVEL-DEPENDENT DEMAND

More information

Quantum Mechanics in Three Dimensions

Quantum Mechanics in Three Dimensions Physics 342 Lecture 20 Quantum Mechanics in Three Dimensions Lecture 20 Physics 342 Quantum Mechanics I Monay, March 24th, 2008 We begin our spherical solutions with the simplest possible case zero potential.

More information

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Matteo Paradisi November 1, 2016 In this Section we develop a theoretical analysis of optimal minimum

More information

inflow outflow Part I. Regular tasks for MAE598/494 Task 1

inflow outflow Part I. Regular tasks for MAE598/494 Task 1 MAE 494/598, Fall 2016 Project #1 (Regular tasks = 20 points) Har copy of report is ue at the start of class on the ue ate. The rules on collaboration will be release separately. Please always follow the

More information

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010 Session 4: Jean November 2010 I So far, focused on real economy. Real quantities consumed, produced, invested. No money, no nominal in uences. I Now, introduce nominal dimension in the economy. First and

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Robust Forward Algorithms via PAC-Bayes and Laplace Distributions. ω Q. Pr (y(ω x) < 0) = Pr A k

Robust Forward Algorithms via PAC-Bayes and Laplace Distributions. ω Q. Pr (y(ω x) < 0) = Pr A k A Proof of Lemma 2 B Proof of Lemma 3 Proof: Since the support of LL istributions is R, two such istributions are equivalent absolutely continuous with respect to each other an the ivergence is well-efine

More information

Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, and knowledge diffusion from FDI

Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, and knowledge diffusion from FDI NiCE Working Paper 08-110 November 2008 Multinational ownership, intellectual property rights, an knowlege iffusion from FDI Roger Smeets Albert e Vaal Nijmegen Center for Economics (NiCE) Institute for

More information

1 Introuction In the past few years there has been renewe interest in the nerson impurity moel. This moel was originally propose by nerson [2], for a

1 Introuction In the past few years there has been renewe interest in the nerson impurity moel. This moel was originally propose by nerson [2], for a Theory of the nerson impurity moel: The Schrieer{Wol transformation re{examine Stefan K. Kehrein 1 an nreas Mielke 2 Institut fur Theoretische Physik, uprecht{karls{universitat, D{69120 Heielberg, F..

More information

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Nonlinear Programming (NLP) Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 6: Nonlinear Programming - Unconstrained Optimization Note 6 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7), Madden (1986, Ch. 3 and 5) and Simon and Blume

More information

Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good

Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 29/12 Utilitarian Mechanism Design for an Excludable Public Good Martin Hellwig M A X P L A N C K S O C I E T Y Preprints of

More information

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801 Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 880 Larry E. Jones Introduction The basic reference for these notes is: Thomas, J. and T. Worrall (990): Income Fluctuation and Asymmetric Information: An Example

More information

05 The Continuum Limit and the Wave Equation

05 The Continuum Limit and the Wave Equation Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU Founations of Wave Phenomena Physics, Department of 1-1-2004 05 The Continuum Limit an the Wave Equation Charles G. Torre Department of Physics, Utah State University,

More information

ensembles When working with density operators, we can use this connection to define a generalized Bloch vector: v x Tr x, v y Tr y

ensembles When working with density operators, we can use this connection to define a generalized Bloch vector: v x Tr x, v y Tr y Ph195a lecture notes, 1/3/01 Density operators for spin- 1 ensembles So far in our iscussion of spin- 1 systems, we have restricte our attention to the case of pure states an Hamiltonian evolution. Toay

More information

Learning in Monopolies with Delayed Price Information

Learning in Monopolies with Delayed Price Information Learning in Monopolies with Delaye Price Information Akio Matsumoto y Chuo University Ferenc Sziarovszky z University of Pécs February 28, 2013 Abstract We call the intercept of the price function with

More information

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model Yu (Larry) Chen School of Economics, Nanjing University Fall 2015 Principal-Agent Relationship Principal-agent relationship

More information

The total derivative. Chapter Lagrangian and Eulerian approaches

The total derivative. Chapter Lagrangian and Eulerian approaches Chapter 5 The total erivative 51 Lagrangian an Eulerian approaches The representation of a flui through scalar or vector fiels means that each physical quantity uner consieration is escribe as a function

More information

Patent Quality and a Two-Tiered Patent System

Patent Quality and a Two-Tiered Patent System Patent Quality an a Two-Tiere Patent System Viya Atal y an Talia Bar z March 4, 2013 Abstract We stuy the eterminants of patent quality an the volume of patent applications when inventors care about perceive

More information

Lecture 10 Notes, Electromagnetic Theory II Dr. Christopher S. Baird, faculty.uml.edu/cbaird University of Massachusetts Lowell

Lecture 10 Notes, Electromagnetic Theory II Dr. Christopher S. Baird, faculty.uml.edu/cbaird University of Massachusetts Lowell Lecture 10 Notes, Electromagnetic Theory II Dr. Christopher S. Bair, faculty.uml.eu/cbair University of Massachusetts Lowell 1. Pre-Einstein Relativity - Einstein i not invent the concept of relativity,

More information

Thermal runaway during blocking

Thermal runaway during blocking Thermal runaway uring blocking CES_stable CES ICES_stable ICES k 6.5 ma 13 6. 12 5.5 11 5. 1 4.5 9 4. 8 3.5 7 3. 6 2.5 5 2. 4 1.5 3 1. 2.5 1. 6 12 18 24 3 36 s Thermal runaway uring blocking Application

More information

Prep 1. Oregon State University PH 213 Spring Term Suggested finish date: Monday, April 9

Prep 1. Oregon State University PH 213 Spring Term Suggested finish date: Monday, April 9 Oregon State University PH 213 Spring Term 2018 Prep 1 Suggeste finish ate: Monay, April 9 The formats (type, length, scope) of these Prep problems have been purposely create to closely parallel those

More information

Lectures - Week 10 Introduction to Ordinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Order Linear ODEs

Lectures - Week 10 Introduction to Ordinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Order Linear ODEs Lectures - Week 10 Introuction to Orinary Differential Equations (ODES) First Orer Linear ODEs When stuying ODEs we are consiering functions of one inepenent variable, e.g., f(x), where x is the inepenent

More information

Convergence of Random Walks

Convergence of Random Walks Chapter 16 Convergence of Ranom Walks This lecture examines the convergence of ranom walks to the Wiener process. This is very important both physically an statistically, an illustrates the utility of

More information

Assignment 1. g i (x 1,..., x n ) dx i = 0. i=1

Assignment 1. g i (x 1,..., x n ) dx i = 0. i=1 Assignment 1 Golstein 1.4 The equations of motion for the rolling isk are special cases of general linear ifferential equations of constraint of the form g i (x 1,..., x n x i = 0. i=1 A constraint conition

More information

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem

The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Natalia Lazzati Mathematics for Economics (Part I) Note 8: Nonlinear Programming - The Kuhn-Tucker Problem Note 8 is based on de la Fuente (2000, Ch. 7) and Simon and Blume (1994, Ch. 18 and 19). The Kuhn-Tucker

More information

Implicit Differentiation

Implicit Differentiation Implicit Differentiation Thus far, the functions we have been concerne with have been efine explicitly. A function is efine explicitly if the output is given irectly in terms of the input. For instance,

More information

Transmission Line Matrix (TLM) network analogues of reversible trapping processes Part B: scaling and consistency

Transmission Line Matrix (TLM) network analogues of reversible trapping processes Part B: scaling and consistency Transmission Line Matrix (TLM network analogues of reversible trapping processes Part B: scaling an consistency Donar e Cogan * ANC Eucation, 308-310.A. De Mel Mawatha, Colombo 3, Sri Lanka * onarecogan@gmail.com

More information

A Contribution to the Theory of Optimal Utilitarian Income Taxation

A Contribution to the Theory of Optimal Utilitarian Income Taxation Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bonn 2007/2 A Contribution to the Theory of Optimal Utilitarian Income Taxation Martin Hellwig M A X P L A N C K S O C I E T Y Preprints

More information

Heteroscedasticityinstochastic frontier models: A Monte Carlo Analysis

Heteroscedasticityinstochastic frontier models: A Monte Carlo Analysis Heterosceasticityinstochastic frontier moels: A Monte Carlo Analysis by C. Guermat University of Exeter, Exeter EX4 4RJ, UK an K. Hari City University, Northampton Square, Lonon EC1V 0HB, UK First version:

More information

Screening. Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1

Screening. Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1 Screening Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1 The Agency Problem with Adverse Selection A risk neutral principal wants to o er a menu of contracts to be o ered

More information

Calculus of Variations

Calculus of Variations Calculus of Variations Lagrangian formalism is the main tool of theoretical classical mechanics. Calculus of Variations is a part of Mathematics which Lagrangian formalism is base on. In this section,

More information

Math 1B, lecture 8: Integration by parts

Math 1B, lecture 8: Integration by parts Math B, lecture 8: Integration by parts Nathan Pflueger 23 September 2 Introuction Integration by parts, similarly to integration by substitution, reverses a well-known technique of ifferentiation an explores

More information

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions) TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions) Q: Ramsey Model: Exponential Utility Assume that in nite-horizon households maximize a utility function of the exponential form 1R max U = e (n )t (1=)e

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

Markov Chains in Continuous Time

Markov Chains in Continuous Time Chapter 23 Markov Chains in Continuous Time Previously we looke at Markov chains, where the transitions betweenstatesoccurreatspecifietime- steps. That it, we mae time (a continuous variable) avance in

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

Math Notes on differentials, the Chain Rule, gradients, directional derivative, and normal vectors

Math Notes on differentials, the Chain Rule, gradients, directional derivative, and normal vectors Math 18.02 Notes on ifferentials, the Chain Rule, graients, irectional erivative, an normal vectors Tangent plane an linear approximation We efine the partial erivatives of f( xy, ) as follows: f f( x+

More information

Crowdsourced Judgement Elicitation with Endogenous Proficiency

Crowdsourced Judgement Elicitation with Endogenous Proficiency Crowsource Jugement Elicitation with Enogenous Proficiency Anirban Dasgupta Arpita Ghosh Abstract Crowsourcing is now wiely use to replace jugement or evaluation by an expert authority with an aggregate

More information

Prof. Dr. Ibraheem Nasser electric_charhe 9/22/2017 ELECTRIC CHARGE

Prof. Dr. Ibraheem Nasser electric_charhe 9/22/2017 ELECTRIC CHARGE ELECTRIC CHARGE Introuction: Orinary matter consists of atoms. Each atom consists of a nucleus, consisting of protons an neutrons, surroune by a number of electrons. In electricity, the electric charge

More information

6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first order ODE

6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first order ODE 6 General properties of an autonomous system of two first orer ODE Here we embark on stuying the autonomous system of two first orer ifferential equations of the form ẋ 1 = f 1 (, x 2 ), ẋ 2 = f 2 (, x

More information

Extreme Values by Resnick

Extreme Values by Resnick 1 Extreme Values by Resnick 1 Preliminaries 1.1 Uniform Convergence We will evelop the iea of something calle continuous convergence which will be useful to us later on. Denition 1. Let X an Y be metric

More information

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers Econ 4808 Review Set 2 - Answers EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS 1. De ne the concept of equilibrium within the con nes of an economic model. Provide an example of an economic equilibrium. Economic models contain

More information

Equilibrium in Queues Under Unknown Service Times and Service Value

Equilibrium in Queues Under Unknown Service Times and Service Value University of Pennsylvania ScholarlyCommons Finance Papers Wharton Faculty Research 1-2014 Equilibrium in Queues Uner Unknown Service Times an Service Value Laurens Debo Senthil K. Veeraraghavan University

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models Daron Acemoglu MIT September 12, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 3 September 12, 2007 1 / 40 Introduction

More information

Moral Hazard and Persistence

Moral Hazard and Persistence Moral Hazard and Persistence Hugo Hopenhayn Department of Economics UCLA Arantxa Jarque Department of Economics U. of Alicante PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract We study a multiperiod principal-agent

More information

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition Leslie J. Reinhorn Economics Department University of Durham 23-26 Old Elvet Durham DH1 3HY United Kingdom phone +44 191 334 6365 fax +44 191 334 6341 reinhorn@hotmail.com

More information

Calculus of Variations

Calculus of Variations 16.323 Lecture 5 Calculus of Variations Calculus of Variations Most books cover this material well, but Kirk Chapter 4 oes a particularly nice job. x(t) x* x*+ αδx (1) x*- αδx (1) αδx (1) αδx (1) t f t

More information

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics BEE020 { Basic Mathematical Economics Week 2, Lecture Thursday 2.0.0 Constrained optimization Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics University of Exeter Objective We give the \ rst order conditions"

More information

Lecture 10: Logistic growth models #2

Lecture 10: Logistic growth models #2 Lecture 1: Logistic growth moels #2 Fugo Takasu Dept. Information an Computer Sciences Nara Women s University takasu@ics.nara-wu.ac.jp 6 July 29 1 Analysis of the stochastic process of logistic growth

More information

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo Economics, HKU September 17, 2018 Luo, Y. (Economics, HKU) ME September 17, 2018 1 / 46 Static Optimization and Extreme Values In this topic, we will study goal

More information

Closed and Open Loop Optimal Control of Buffer and Energy of a Wireless Device

Closed and Open Loop Optimal Control of Buffer and Energy of a Wireless Device Close an Open Loop Optimal Control of Buffer an Energy of a Wireless Device V. S. Borkar School of Technology an Computer Science TIFR, umbai, Inia. borkar@tifr.res.in A. A. Kherani B. J. Prabhu INRIA

More information

Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games

Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games John Morgan University of California at Berkeley Preliminaries Our running example is that of a decision maker (DM) consulting a knowledgeable expert for advice about

More information

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4 Solow Growth Model Michael Bar February 28, 208 Contents Introduction 2. Some facts about modern growth........................ 3.2 Questions..................................... 4 2 The Solow Model 5

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

A representation theory for a class of vector autoregressive models for fractional processes

A representation theory for a class of vector autoregressive models for fractional processes A representation theory for a class of vector autoregressive moels for fractional processes Søren Johansen Department of Applie Mathematics an Statistics, University of Copenhagen November 2006 Abstract

More information

Designing Information Devices and Systems II Fall 2017 Note Theorem: Existence and Uniqueness of Solutions to Differential Equations

Designing Information Devices and Systems II Fall 2017 Note Theorem: Existence and Uniqueness of Solutions to Differential Equations EECS 6B Designing Information Devices an Systems II Fall 07 Note 3 Secon Orer Differential Equations Secon orer ifferential equations appear everywhere in the real worl. In this note, we will walk through

More information