An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation"

Transcription

1 An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation by Yongmin Chen* and David E. M. Sappington** May 2017 Abstract: Weanalyzetheoptimaldesignofdamagesforpatentinfringementinsettings where the patent of an initial innovator may be infringed by a follow-on innovator. We consider relatively simple damage rules that are linear combinations of the popular ìlost proötî (LP) and ìunjust enrichmentî (UE) rules, coupled with a lump-sum transfer between the innovators. We identify conditions under which a linear rule can induce the socially optimal levels of sequential innovation and the optimal allocation of industry output. We also show that, despite its simplicity, the optimal linear rule achieves the highest welfare among all rules that ensure a balanced budget for the industry, and often secures substantially more welfare than either the LP rule or the UE rule. Keywords: Patents, sequential innovation, infringement damages, linear rules for patent damages. *DepartmentofEconomics,UniversityofColorado;Yongmin.Chen@colorado.edu ** Department of Economics, University of Florida; sapping@uá.edu We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from Ted Bergstrom, Rich Gilbert, Michael Meurer, Michael Riordan, Marius Schwartz, Yair Tauman, John Turner, Dennis Yao, and seminar participants at Columbia University, Fudan University, Queens University, the State University of New York at Stony Brook, the University of California at Santa Barbara, the University of Georgia, the University of Groningen, the 2016 Workshop on IO and Competition Policy at the Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, and the 2016 Workshop on Industrial Organization and Management Strategy at the Hong Kong University of Science and Technology. 1

2 1 Introduction Innovation is a key driver of economic growth and prosperity. To encourage innovation, successful innovators often are awarded patents for their inventions. A patent grants an innovator exclusive rights to her invention for a speciöed period of time. An extensive literature analyzes optimal patent protection, focusing on issues such as the optimal strength and breadth of patents. 1 An important, but less developed, literature studies Önancial penalties (ìdamagesî) for patent infringement. To date, this literature has primarily analyzed the performance of individual damage rules that are employed in practice, including the lost proöt (LP) rule and the unjust enrichment (UE) rule. 2 In contrast, the purpose of this paper is to analyze the optimal design of patent damage rules under sequential innovation, where an initial innovatorís patent may be infringed by a follow-on innovator whose di erentiated product, possibly of higher quality, expands market demand. Sequential innovation is important to consider because it drives progress in many important industries. Scotchmer (1991) identiöes several products ñ including antibiotic drugs, incandescent lights, lasers, and computer operating systems ñ whose development was fueled by sequential innovation. 3 Todayís smartphones are estimated to embody innovations protected by as many as 250,000 patents that have been developed sequentially (Sparapani, 2015). 4 The design of damages for patent infringement is particularly subtle in the presence 1 Early studies of optimal patent protection include Nordhaus (1969), Gilbert and Shapiro (1990), Klemperer (1990), and Scotchmer (1991) 2 Anton and Yao (2007) examine the performance of the LP rule. Shankerman and Scotchmer (2001), Choi (2009), and Henry and Turner (2010) examine the performance of both the LP and the UE rules. (These rules are described below.) Choi and Henry and Turner also analyze the performance of the reasonable royalty damage rule, which is discussed in section 6. Schankerman and Scotchmer (2005) report that although the UE rule was commonly employed in the U.S. prior to the implementation of patent reforms in 1946, the LP rule has been employed relatively frequently since then. See Blair and Cotter (2005) for additional discussion of the use of patent damage rules in the U.S. and Reitzig et al. (2003) for corresponding discussion of international experience. 3 In addition, gene sequencing discoveries are valuable inputs in follow-on scientiöc research and in commercial applications (Sampat and Williams, 2015). Murray et al. (2016) examine the e ects of a ording academic researchers expanded access to newly discovered information about genetically engineered (transgenic) mice. The authors report that expanded access increases follow-on discoveries by new researchers and promotes diverse follow-on research methodologies without reducing the rate of innovation. 4 It has been observed that modern computing technologies like smart phones ìtightly and e ciently integrate the engineering of other companies and other earlier inventors, and are enhanced with new functions and 1

3 of sequential innovation because, although stringent damage rules can encourage early innovation, they may discourage subsequent innovation, especially when uncertainty prevails about whether follow-on innovations infringe earlier patents. 5 We consider a model in which innovation is not certain because of stochastic variation in innovation costs. Patent protection also is uncertain in our model, as it is in practice. 6 Hundreds of thousands of patents are granted annually, and patent descriptions can be vague and incomplete. 7 Therefore, in practice, it is often di cult to discern whether an innovation infringes an existing patent. 8 The parameter! 2 (0; 1] in our model denotes the probability that the patent of an initial innovator, Örm 1, is infringed by the di erentiated product of afollow-oninnovator,örm2.thevalueof! can be viewed as a measure of the strength of patent protection (e.g., Choi, 1998; and Farrell and Shapiro, 2008). We consider damage rules that are linear combinations of the LP rule and the UE rule, coupled with a lump-sum transfer between the innovators. The LP rule requires the infringer to compensate the patent holder for the reduction in proöt the latter su ers due to the infringement. 9 The UE rule requires the infringer to deliver its realized proöt to the patent features to attract consumer interest and drive demandî (Sparapani, 2015). Scotchmer (2004, p. 134) notes that although no product development Öts the basic model of sequential innovation perfectly, ìif one takes a more metaphorical view, [the model] Öts almost every important technology, including the laser and desktop software.î 5 Green and Scotchmer (1995) examine the patent length and division of surplus required to induce e cient sequential innovation. We extend their work in part by explicitly modeling competition between innovators in the presence of uncertainty about the applicability of existing patents. 6 Anton and Yao (2007), Choi (2009), and Henry and Turner (2010) also analyze probabilistic patent enforcement. 7 See, for example, Choi (1998), Lemley and Shapiro (2005), Bessen and Meurer (2008), and Farrell and Shapiro (2008). 8 The recent protracted patent infringement ligation between Apple and Samsung is a case in point (e.g., Vascellaro, 2012). In addition, Lemley and Shapiro (2005) report that the U.S. Patent and Trademark O ce issues nearly 200,000 patents annually, so the time that a patent o cer can devote to assessing the merits of any individual patent application is limited. Consequently, even after a patent is issued, its validity may be successfully contested in court. Uncertainty about prevailing patent protection also can complicate the licensing of innovations. See Kamien and Tauman (1986), Katz and Shapiro (1986), and Scotchmer (1991), for example, for analyses of the licensing of innovations. 9 U.S. patent law stipulates that the damage penalty for patent infringement must be ìadequate to compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the infringer, together with interest and costs as Öxed by the court.î Courts have interpreted this stipulation to require ìan award of lost proöts, or other compensatory damages, where the patentee can prove, and 2

4 holder. 10 Under the linear rules that we analyze, if Örm 2 is found to have infringed Örm 1ís patent, Örm 2 must deliver a damage payment (D) toörm1thathasthreecomponents: a lump sum monetary payment (m), a fraction (d 1 )oftheamountbywhichörm2ísoperation reduces Örm 1ís proöt, and a fraction (d 2 )oförm2ísproöt. Thus,linearrulesgeneralize the LP rule and the UE rule, including the former (with d 1 =1and m = d 2 =0)andthe latter (with d 2 =1and m = d 1 =0)asspecialcases. 11 These linear rules are relatively simple in nature. Nevertheless, we Önd that an optimallydesigned linear rule secures the highest welfare among all balanced damage rules (i.e., rules in which all payments are internal to the industry). The optimality of the linear rule reáects in part its links to both the (lost) proöt of the initial innovator and the (realized) proöt of the follow-on innovator. These links enable an optimally-designed linear rule to secure desired levels of industry proöt (which a ect aggregate investment incentives), distribute the proöt to foster desired levels of innovation by both Örms, and ensure desired allocations of industry output. We also show that the optimal linear rule typically di ers from both the LP rule and the UE rule, and often secures a substantial increase in welfare relative to both of these rules. Furthermore, when the maximum feasible level of industry proöt is su ciently large relative to innovation costs, the optimal linear rule can ensure the Örst-best outcome, under which each Örm innovates if and only if its innovation enhances welfare and industry output is allocated between the producers so as to maximize welfare. When the optimal linear rule achieves the Örst-best outcome, it resembles the LP rule more closely than the UE rule (so d 1 >d 2 )whenconsumersvaluetheproductoftheinitialinnovatorrelativelyhighly,while elects to prove, such damagesî (Frank and DeFranco, , p. 281). 10 The UE rule is sometimes employed when a design patent is infringed. The Supreme Court of the United States recently agreed to review a Federal Appeals Court decision that Apple is entitled to all of the proöt that Samsung earned from its sales of smartphones because Samsung ìinfringed three Apple design patents relating to a portion of the iphoneís outer shell and a single graphical-user-interface screenî (Amici Curiae Brief, 2016). 11 Linear rules also encompass proöt sharing rules, which require a patent infringer to pay the patent holder a portion of the proöt the infringer secures in the marketplace. 3

5 it resembles the UE rule more closely (so d 2 >d 1 )whenconsumersvalueörm2ísproduct relatively highly. 12 We also show how the optimal linear rule can limit the distortions in innovation incentives and output allocation when the Örst-best outcome is not attainable. The welfare-maximizing linear rule is optimal among balanced rules regardless of the strength of protection for Örm 1ís patent (i.e., for any given!>0). 13 This Önding suggests that although the appropriate strength and scope of patents can help to foster e cient levels of sequential innovation, the design of damages for patent infringement may play a particularly important role in this regard. The ensuing analysis proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 records equilibrium market outcomes. Section 4 characterizes and explains the key features of the optimal linear rule. Section 5 demonstrates that the welfare-maximizing linear rule is optimal among balanced damage rules. Section 5 also illustrates the (often substantial) welfare gains that the optimal linear rule can secure relative to popular damage rules. Section 6 summarizes our Öndings, discusses alternative modeling assumptions, and suggests directions for further research. Appendix A presents the proofs of all formal conclusions. Appendix B further illustrates the optimal linear rule and the welfare gains it can secure. 2 The Model We consider the interaction between two Örms. Firm 1 has the potential to innovate Örst and secure a patent on its product by incurring innovation cost k 1.Firm2hasthepotentialto innovate subsequently by incurring k 2,butonlyifÖrm1hasinnovatedsuccessfully. 14 These 12 As we demonstrate below, the optimal linear rule serves to shift equilibrium industry output toward the product that consumers value most highly. The linear rule a ects the equilibrium allocation of industry output by inducing the Örms to partially internalize each otherís proöt, which ináuences their pricing strategies. 13 It follows that the optimal linear rule also dominates ex ante e cient patent licensing, as we demonstrate in section Thus, we follow Chang (1995) in abstracting from stochastic innovation and from the possibility of simultaneous research and development activity by multiple Örms. We extend Changís work in part by considering product di erentiation and uncertainty about the applicability of existing patents. Bessen and Maskin (2009) allow for stochastic, simultaneous research and development by multiple Örms. They show that patent protection can reduce welfare in settings where the research activities of distinct Örms are complementary. 4

6 innovation costs are the realizations of independent random variables, with continuous and strictly increasing distribution functions F (k 1 ) and G(k 2 ); respectively, on support! 0; k ' " i for i =1; 2. WeassumethatinnovationcostsaretheonlycoststheÖrmsincur. 15 AmassofQ potential consumers are distributed uniformly on a line segment of length Q. If Örm 1 innovates, it locates at point 0 on the line segment, and Q =1if Örm 1 is the only innovator. If Örm 2 innovates, it locates at point Q = L " 1 on the line segment, where L is an exogenous parameter that captures the extent to which Örm 2ís innovation expands the market. This potential expansion adds to the standard Hotelling model another dimension on which the operation of a second innovator can enhance welfare. In practice, market expansion might arise, for instance, when the follow-on innovation attracts the attention of a new consumer demographic (e.g., young consumers or consumers in a new foreign market). 16 The product supplied by Örm i delivers value v i to consumers for i =1; 2. Thenetutility aconsumerderivesfromtravelingdistances to purchase a unit of the product from Örm i at price p i is v i # p i # s. Each consumer purchases at most one unit of the product, and purchases from the supplier that o ers the highest nonnegative net utility. This formulation admits both monopoly and duopoly industry structures. The duopoly structure extends the standard Hotelling model by allowing the follow-on innovation of Örm 2 to beneöt consumers not only through (standard) horizontal product di erentiation, 17 but also through quality improvement (when v 2 >v 1 ) and market expansion (when L>1). 18 To capture relevant uncertainty about whether Örm 2ís product infringes Örm 1ís patent, we let! 2 (0; 1] denote the probability that, after serving consumers, Örm 2 is ultimately 15 Thus, we adopt Green and Scotchmer (1995)ís ìideaî approach to modeling innovation, assuming that innovators naturally acquire ideas about new products and an innovator must incur a speciöed cost to implement the innovation. 16 Compared to consumers in the market before Örm 2ís innovation, new consumers that arrive after the innovation have a stronger innate preference for Örm 2ís product relative to Örm 1ís product. 17 Henry and Turner (2010) consider price competition in a standard Hotelling model. Anton and Yao (2007) and Choi (2009) analyze (Cournot) quantity competition with a homogeneous product. 18 As we explain in section 6, our primary Öndings persist in more general models of competition with product di erentiation. We focus on this Hotelling model with potential market expansion because the closed-form solutions it admits facilitate the demonstration of our Öndings. 5

7 found to have infringed Örm 1ís patent. 19 In this event, Örm 2 is obligated to pay Örm 1 the amount D $ m + d 1 R 1 + d 2 1 2,whereR 1 is the amount by which Örm 1ís proöt is reduced by Örm 2ís operation, 1 2 is Örm 2ís proöt, and m is a lump sum monetary payment. The policy instruments, m, d 1 " 0, andd 2 " 0, arechosentomaximizeexpectedwelfare (the sum of consumer and producer surplus). We will call the damage rule associated with damage payment D the linear rule. The timing in the model is as follows. First,! is determined exogenously. Then d 1, d 2, and m are set to maximize expected welfare. Next, Örm 1 privately learns the realization of k 1 and decides whether to innovate. If Örm 1 decides not to innovate, the game ends. If Örm 1 innovates by incurring cost k 1,thenÖrm2privatelylearnstherealizationofk 2 and decides whether to incur this cost in order to secure the follow-on innovation. If Örm 2 innovates, it subsequently competes against Örm 1 for the patronage of consumers on [0;L]. If Örm 2 chooses not to innovate, then Örm 1 acts as a monopolist and serves consumers on [0; 1]. When both Örms compete in the marketplace, they set their prices simultaneously and non-cooperatively. 20 After consumers have been served, it becomes known whether Örm 2hasinfringedÖrm1íspatent.IfÖrm2isfoundtohaveinfringed1íspatent,Örm2makes the requisite payment to Örm 1. We assume throughout the ensuing analysis that consumer valuations of the two products are not too disparate, and are large relative to transportation costs. This assumption helps to ensure that all consumers purchase a unit of the product and that, under duopoly competition, both Örms serve customers in equilibrium We take as given any actions Örm 2 might undertake to avoid patent infringement. Gallini (1992) demonstrates that long patent durations can reduce welfare by encouraging Örms to ìinvent aroundî the patents of early innovators. Zhang and Hylton (2015) analyze the optimal design of infringement penalties in a setting where the potential infringer can undertake unobserved actions to limit the loss the patent holder su ers in the event of infringement. 20 Industry suppliers often can change the prices of their products relatively rapidly. Consequently, we assume that Örm 1ís potentially longer tenure in the market does not endow it with any Stackelberg leadership advantage in its retail competition with Örm 2. (Such an advantage seems unlikely to alter our key qualitative conclusions.) 21 This is the equilibrium on which we focus throughout the ensuing analysis of the optimal damage rule for patent infringement. We explain below why this focus is without loss of generality, given Assumption 1. 6

8 Assumption 1. min fv 1 ;v 2 g > 2 L and j. j <L,where. $ v 2 # v 1. 3 Market Equilibrium Having identiöed the key elements of the model, we now characterize equilibrium outcomes. To begin, consider the setting where only Örm 1 innovates and so operates as the monopoly supplier of the product. Because v 1 > 2 by assumption, Örm 1 maximizes its proöt p 1 min fv 1 # p 1 ; 1g by selling one unit to all potential customers at price p 1 = v 1 # 1. Firm 1ís monopoly proöt in this case is: 1 M 1 = v 1 # 1. (1) Now suppose both Örms innovate. Let p i denote the price that Örm i 2f1; 2g charges for its product. Then the location of the consumer on (0;L) who is indi erent between purchasing from Örm 1 and from Örm 2 is l = 1 [ L + v 2 1 # v 2 + p 2 # p 1 ]. Therefore, the demand functions facing Örms 1 and 2 when they both serve customers and all consumers purchase one unit of a product are, respectively: q 1 (p 1 ;p 2 ) = 1 2 [ L #.+p 2 # p 1 ] and q 2 (p 2 ;p 1 ) = 1 2 [ L +.+p 1 # p 2 ]. (2) In the absence of patent infringement, the proöts (not counting innovation costs) of Örms 1and2are,respectively: 1 N 1 = p 1 q 1 (p 1 ;p 2 ) and 1 N 2 = p 2 q 2 (p 2 ;p 1 ). (3) Firm 2ís operation reduces Örm 1ís equilibrium proöt by R 1 = 1 M 1 # 1 N 1. Therefore, because Örm 2 is required to pay D = m + d 1 R 1 + d 2 1 N 2 to Örm 1 if Örm 2 is found to have infringed Örm 1ís patent, the proöts of Örm 1 and Örm 2 in the event of infringement (excluding m) are,respectively: 1 I 1 = 1 N 1 + d 1! 1 M 1 # 1 N 1 " + d2 1 N 2 and 1 I 2 = 1 N 2 # d 1! 1 M 1 # 1 N 1 " # d2 1 N 2. (4) The Örmsí ex ante expected proöts (not counting innovation costs and m) whenthey both innovate are, respectively: 1 e 1 = [1#! ] 1 N 1 +!1 I 1 and 1 e 2 = [1#! ] 1 N 2 +!1 I 2. (5) 7

9 In equilibrium, Örm i 2f1; 2g chooses p i to maximize 1 e i,takingitsrivalíspriceasgiven. Letting! ís denote equilibrium outcomes, standard calculations reveal that equilibrium prices and quantities are as speciöed in Lemma 1. Lemma 1. Suppose both Örms innovate, all consumers purchase a unit of the product, and each Örm supplies a strictly positive level of output. Then, given d 1 and d 2 with! [ d 1 + d 2 ] < 1, equilibriumpricesandquantitiesare,for i; j =1; 2 (j 6= i): p! i = [1#!d j ] L [3#! (3 d i # d j )]+[v i # v j ][1#! (d 1 + d 2 )] [1#! (d 1 + d 2 )][3#! (d 1 + d 2 )], and (6) q! i = L [3# 2!d j ]+v i # v j 2[3#! (d 1 + d 2 )] 2 (0;L). (7) Furthermore, p! 2 R p! 1 as. R L([ d 2 " d 1 ] 2 " ( [ d 1 + d 2 ],andallconsumerswillindeedpurchaseaunit of the product in equilibrium if d 1 " 0 and d 2 " 0 are su ciently small. Additionally, any prices p! 1 and p! 2 in (6) can be induced by some d 1 and d 2 : Lemma 1 speciöes how d 1 and d 2 a ect equilibrium prices and outputs. The lemma implies that if d 1 = d 2 ; then Örm i will charge a higher price than Örm j in equilibrium (p! i >p! j)ifconsumersvalueörmiís product more highly than Örm jís product (i.e., if v i >v j ). Proposition 1 examines the impact of changes in d 1 and d 2 on equilibrium outcomes, including 1! i,theequilibriumexpectedproötoförmi 2f1; 2g. 22 Proposition 1. Under duopoly competition: (i) p! 1 and p! 2 both increase in d 1 and in d 2 ; (ii) p! 2#p! 1 and q! 1 increase in d 1 ; while p! 1#p! 2 and q! 2 increase in d 2 ; (iii) 1! $ 1! 1+1! 2 increases in d 1 if. ) L([ d 2 " d 1 ] 2 " ( [ d 1 + d 2 ] (so p! 1 " p! 2), while 1! increases in d 2 if. " L([ d 2 " d 1 ] 2 " ( [ d 1 + d 2 ] (so p! 2 " p! 1). Proposition 1 reáects the following considerations. As d 1 increases, Örm 2 is penalized 22!! i is obtained by substituting p! i and q! i from equations (6) and (7) into equation (5). 8

10 alargerportionoförm1íslostproöt(1 M 1 # 1 N 1 )iförm2isultimatelyfoundtohave infringed Örm 1ís patent. Firm 2 recognizes that it can reduce this penalty by competing less aggressively, thereby allowing Örm 1ís duopoly proöt (1 N 1 )toincrease. Thereduced aggression leads to higher equilibrium prices for both Örms. The increased congruence of the Örmsí preferences regarding higher proöt for Örm 1 results in expanded output for Örm 1, secured by a reduction in Örm 1ís price relative to Örm 2ís price. As d 2 increases, Örm 2 forfeits a larger portion of its proöt (1 N 2 )ifitisultimatelyfound to have infringed Örm 1ís patent. Firm 1 recognizes that it can secure a larger expected penalty payment from Örm 2 by competing less aggressively, thereby allowing 1 N 2 to increase. The reduced aggression leads to higher equilibrium prices for both Örms. The increased congruence of the Örmsí preferences regarding higher proöt for Örm 2 results in expanded output for Örm 2, secured by a reduction in Örm 2ís price relative to Örm 1ís price. 23 The increase in Örm 1ís equilibrium output (q! 1)andthecorrespondingreductioninÖrm 2ís output (q! 2)inducedbyanincreaseind 1 increase equilibrium industry proöt (1! $ 1! 1 + 1! 2)whenÖrm1ísproÖtmarginexceedsÖrm2ísmargin(i.e.,whenp! 1 >p! 2). Similarly, the increase in q! 2 and the reduction in q! 1 induced by an increase in d 2 increase 1! when p! 2 exceeds p! 1. Before proceeding to characterize the optimal linear damage rule, it is helpful to consider the policy that maximizes welfare and the policy that maximizes industry proöt following innovation by both Örms. These policies are characterized in Lemmas 2 and 3, respectively. Lemma 2 refers to equilibrium welfare in the duopoly setting: fw 12 = v 1 q! 1 # Z q! 1 0 y dy + v 2 q! 2 # Z q! 2 0 y dy = v 1 q! 1 # 1 2 q!2 1 + v 2 q! 2 # 1 2 q!2 2. (8) Lemma 2 also refers to d w 1,whichisdeÖnedinexpression(41)inAppendixA. Lemma 2. Suppose: d 2 = d w 2 (d 1 ) $ d [1#!d 1 ]! [ L +.]. (9) 23 See Anton and Yao (2007), Choi (2009), and Henry and Turner (2010) for related observations. 9

11 Then when both Örms innovate, the maximum feasible level of welfare (excluding innovation costs), v 2 L # 1 4 [2L. #.2 + L 2 ],isinduced,andequilibriumpricesare p! 1 = p! 2 = [1" (d 1 ][L 2 " ( 2 ] L [1" 2 (d 1 ] " (.EquilibriumindustryproÖt,1! = p! 1 L, increasesasd 1 or d w 2 (d 1 ) increases, reaching its maximum 1 w = p w L at d 1 = d w 1 < 1 2 ( with p! 1 = p! 2 = p w $ v 1 # 1 2 [ L #.]. Lemma 3 refers to ' d 1 and ' d 2,whicharedeÖnedinexpression(48)inAppendixA. Lemma 3. When d 1 = ' d 1 and d 2 = ' d 2, the maximum feasible level of duopoly proöt, 1=1 w + (2,isinduced.Furthermore,equilibriumpricesare 8 p 1 $ v 1 # 1 % L #. & and p $ v 2 # 1 2 with corresponding outputs q 1 2 (0;L) and q 2 = L # q % L +. & ; (10) 2 Lemmas 2 and 3 report that the welfare-maximizing duopoly prices typically di er from the prices that maximize industry proöt. (They coincide only when v 1 = v 2.) Duopoly welfare is maximized when the two Örms charge identical prices. In this event, consumers purchase from the Örm that o ers the largest di erence between product value and transportation cost, which ensures that welfare is maximized. In contrast, industry proöt is maximized when the Örm with the most highly-valued product charges a higher price than its competitor. Relative to the identical welfare-maximizing prices, this price structure results in greater extraction of consumer surplus. It can also be veriöed that the values of d 1 and d 2 that induce welfare-maximizing or proöt-maximizing duopoly prices decline as! increases. Thus, less stringent damages are required to secure key industry outcomes when stronger patent protection prevails. 4 Characterizing the Optimal Linear Rule Lemma 2 identiöes the welfare-maximizing allocation of industry output following innovation by both Örms. To characterize the welfare-maximizing damage rule for patent infringement, one must also consider the Örmsí innovation incentives. To do so, observe Örst 24 These outputs are derived by substituting p 1 and p 2 into the expressions identiöed in equation (2). 10

12 that welfare when only Örm 1 innovates is: W 1 = W f 1 # k 1 where W f 1 = v 1 # Z 1 0 y dy = v 1 # 1 2. (11) Let b k i denote the realization of Örm iís innovation cost (k i )forwhichtheörmwillinnovate if and only if k i ) b k i.if b k 1 ) k ' 1 and b k 2 ) k ' 2 ; then b k1 = G( b k 2 )[1! 1 +!m]+[1# G( b k 2 )]1 M 1 and b k 2 = 1! 2 #!m. (12) Equations (8), (11), and (12) imply that ex ante expected welfare (i.e., the level of welfare that is anticipated before innovation costs are realized) is W = F ( b k 1 ) G( b k 2 ) f W 12 + F ( b k 1 )[1# G( b k 2 )] f W 1 Z b k2 Z b k1 # F ( b k 1 ) k 2 dg(k 2 ) # k 1 df (k 1 ). (13) To examine Örm 2ís innovation incentives, let k w denote the increase in welfare secured by Örm 2ís innovation (not counting innovation costs). From equations (8) and (11): k w 2 $ f W 12 # f W 1 = v 1 q! 1 # 1 2 q!2 1 + v 2 q! 2 # 1 2 q!2 2 # ( v 1 # 1 2 ). (14) Incremental welfare is maximized when Örm 2 innovates if and only if its innovation cost (k 2 ) does not exceed k w 2.Intheensuinganalysis,k w! 2 will denote the increase in welfare secured by Örm 2ís innovation when d 2 is set (given d 1 )toensurethewelfare-maximizingallocation of industry output. To assess whether Örm 1ís innovation increases expected welfare, one must account for Örm 2ís subsequent innovation activity. Let k w 1 ( b k 2 ) denote the increase in expected welfare secured by Örm 1ís innovation, given that Örm 2 innovates if and only if k 2 ) b k 2.Formally: k w 1 ( b k 2 ) $ G( b k 2 ) f W 12 +[1# G( b k 2 )] f W 1 # Z b k2 0 k 2 dg(k 2 ). (15) Given Örm 2ís innovation activity, incremental welfare is maximized when Örm 1 innovates if and only if its innovation cost (k 1 )doesnotexceed k w 1 ( b k 2 ). These observations imply that the optimal linear rule is the solution to problem [P], 11

13 which is deöned to be: M aximize W; where W is speciöed in equation (13), prices and d 1 ;d 2 ;m quantities are speciöed in Lemma 1, and b k i is speciöed in equation (12) for i =1; 2. In the Örst-best outcome, each Örm innovates if and only if the associated increase in expected welfare exceeds the realized innovation cost, and industry output is allocated among the active producers to maximize welfare. Formally, in the Örst-best outcome: (i) Örm 2innovatesifandonlyif k 2 ) k o 2 $ minfk w! 2 ; k 2 g;(ii)örm1innovatesifandonlyif k 1 ) k o 1 $ minfk w 1 (k o 2); k 1 g;and(fromlemma2)(iii) q! 1 = 1 2 [ L #.]and q! 2 = 1 2 [ L +.] when both Örms innovate. Observation 1 considers the setting where b k 1 < k 1,soÖrm1doesnotalwaysinnovate because its maximum innovation cost is relatively large. The Observation reports that the penalty for patent infringement must include a lump sum payment (m >0) iftheörst-best outcome is to be achieved in this setting. Observation 1. Suppose b k 1 < k 1 and m = 0. Then Örm 1ís innovation incentive is ine ciently low (i.e., b k 1 <k w 1 ( b k 2 )). When Örm 1 innovates, it creates consumer surplus that it does not fully capture, regardless of whether Örm 2 innovates. Therefore, W1 f >1 M 1 and W f 12 >1! 2 + 1! 1,soaggregate welfare from Örm 1ís innovation always exceeds aggregate industry proöt. From expression (12), when m =0; Örm 2 innovates if and only if k 2 ) 1! 2 = b k 2,andÖrm1innovatesif and only if k 1 ) b k 1 = G( b k 2 ) 1! 1 +[1# G( b k 2 )]1 M 1 : Therefore, Örm 1 has ine ciently limited incentive to innovate when the penalty for patent infringement does not include a lump sum payment between the Örms. Although Örm 1ís innovation incentive is always ine ciently low when m =0,Örm2ís incentive can be excessive. If Örm 2ís innovation does not expand the market (so L =1), then Örm 2ís innovation reduces Örm 1ís proöt in the absence of patent infringement penalties. Consequently, Örm 2ís private beneöt from innovation can exceed the corresponding social beneöt (i.e., b k 2 >k2 w ). In contrast, Örm 2ís innovation incentive can be ine ciently low (i.e., 12

14 b k2 <k w 2 )ifl is su ciently large. Observation 2. Suppose v 1 = v 2 $ v and d 1 = d 2 = m = 0. Then: (i) k2 w < b k 2 if L =1;and (ii) k2 w > b h i k 2 if L>1 and v> 1 3 L 2 " 2. 4 L " 1 Despite the potential conáict between the social and private incentives for innovation, the optimal linear rule can sometimes fully align these incentives while inducing the welfaremaximizing allocation of industry output. As Proposition 2 and Corollary 1 report, the optimal linear rule secures the Örst-best outcome if innovation costs are su ciently small relative to the maximum feasible level of industry proöt, so inequality (16) holds. 1 w " ko 1 # 1 M 1 G(k o 2) + 1 M 1 + k o 2, G(k o 2)[1 w # k o 2 ]+[1# G(k o 2)]1 M 1 " k o 1. (16) Proposition 2. Suppose inequality (16) holds. Then ( d 1 ;d 2 ;m) can be chosen to induce the Örst-best outcome, with d 2 = d w 2 (d 1 ) and m = 1 ( [ 1! 2 # k o 2 ]. Underthis(optimal)linear rule, d 2 R d 1 as. R 0. Corollary 1. If v 1, v 2,andL are su ciently large to ensure k o 2 = k 2,thentheoptimal linear rule secures the Örst-best outcome if k 1 + k 2 ) L 2 [ v 1 + v 2 # L ]. This inequality is more likely to hold if k 1 and k 2 are small and if v 1, v 2,andL are large, ceteris paribus. Proposition 2 and Corollary 1 consider settings where innovations are highly valued, Örm 2ís innovation expands the market considerably, and/or innovation costs are low. In such settings, the substantial industry proöt that is potentially available can be divided between the suppliers to induce them both to always innovate even when damages are structured to induce the Örms to set the same prices and thereby maximize duopoly welfare. Proposition 2 reports that if v 1 >v 2,thentheinitialinnovatoríslostproÖtreceives more weight than the second innovatorís proöt in the optimal linear rule (i.e., d 1 >d 2 ).In contrast, if v 2 >v 1,thenthesecondinnovatorísproÖtreceivesmoreweightthantheÖrst innovatorís lost proöt (i.e., d 2 >d 2 ). In this sense, the optimal linear rule resembles the lost 13

15 proöt (LP) rule more than the unjust enrichment (UE) rule when the (vertical dimension of) quality of the initial innovation is relatively pronounced. In contrast, the optimal linear rule resembles the UE rule more than the LP rule when the quality of the follow-on innovation is relatively pronounced. To understand the rationale for this penalty structure, recall from Proposition 1 that under duopoly competition, the relative price of Örm 1ís product declines and its output increases as d 1 increases, whereas the relative price of Örm 2ís product declines and its output increases as d 2 increases. Therefore, the identiöed penalty structure helps to reduce the relative price of, and thereby shift equilibrium consumption toward, the product that consumers value most highly. Doing so ensures the welfare-maximizing allocation of industry output between the two suppliers. Corollary 2. If inequality (16) does not hold, then the optimal linear rule does not secure the Örst-best outcome. Corollary 2 reports that when inequality (16) does not hold, so the maximum feasible industry proöt (given the welfare-maximizing output allocation) is not su ciently large relative to innovation costs, then the optimal linear rule cannot induce welfare-maximizing innovation decisions while ensuring welfare-maximizing output allocations. The values of d 1 and d 2 required to induce the welfare-maximizing allocation of duopoly output do not generate the level of industry proöt required to induce both Örms to innovate whenever the social beneöt of innovation exceeds the private cost of innovation. 25 In this case, the optimal linear rule will increase industry proöt by eliminating the surplus of the marginal consumer. Formally, from equation (2): v 1 # p 1 # 1 2 [ L + v 1 # v 2 + p 2 # p 1 ] = 0 ) p 2 = v 1 + v 2 # p 1 # L: (17) 25 When the optimal linear rule cannot secure the Örst-best outcome, the critical problem is to induce both Örms to innovate more often. m can be adjusted to avoid settings where one Örm innovates too seldom and one Örm innovates too often relative to the Örst-best outcome. Furthermore, the logic that underlies Observation 1 explains why the critical problem is not to induce both Örms to innovate less often. 14

16 If v 1 = v 2 = v; then the maximum level of industry proöt that can be secured is 1 w = 1. From expression (48), the optimal linear rule sets d 1 = d 2 = 2 v " 3 L to induce the welfare- 4 ( [ v " L ] maximizing prices p 1 = p 2 = p = v # L,and m is set to distribute 1 between the two 2 Örms to maximize W.Ifv 1 6= v 2 ; then industry proöt can be increased above 1 w by allowing p 1 and p 2 = v 1 + v 2 # p 1 # L to diverge in order to ensure 1! = 1. Now consider how the optimal linear rule is structured when it cannot secure the Örstbest outcome. Initially, the values of p 1 and b k 2 that maximize expected welfare when p 2 is set to leave the marginal consumer with zero surplus in the duopoly setting are identiöed (see equations (18) and (19) below), and the values of d 1 and d 2 that induce these prices are determined. m is then set to induce the identiöed value of b k 2. (From equation (12), m = 1 ( [ 1 2 # b k 2 ].) The properties of the optimal balanced rule then depend upon whether the identiöed rule generates more or less than the maximum feasible industry proöt, as Proposition 3 indicates. The proposition refers to 1 2,whichisÖrm2ís expected proöt (not counting innovation costs) at the equilibrium identiöed in Lemma 3, where duopoly industry proöt is maximized. Proposition 3. Suppose inequality (16) does not hold. Also suppose ep 2 = v 1 + v 2 # ep 1 # L, and ep 1 and e k 2 2! k 2 ; k 2 " are the values of p1 and b k 2 that solve [ k w 1 ( b k 2 ) # b k 1 k F ( b k 1 )[k o 2 # b k 2 k F ( b k 1 ) G( b k 2 f W 1 = 0,and (18) [ k w 1 ( b k 2 ) # b k 1 k 1 b k 2 + F ( b k 1 )[k o 2 # b k 2 k 2 b k 2 = 0. (19) (i) If e 1=ep1 [ v 1 # ep 1 ]+[v 1 + v 2 # ep 1 # L ][L + ep 1 # v 1 ] < 1; then the optimal linear rule is ( e d 1 ; e d 2 ; em), where e d 1 and e d 2 are the values of d 1 and d 2 that induce ep 1 and ep 2, 26 and em = 1 ( [ e1 2 # e k 2 ],where e1 2 = ~p 2 q 2 (~p 1 ; ~p 2 ) is Örm 2ís equilibrium proöt. (ii) If e 1 " 1 for the identiöed ep1 and ep 2,thentheoptimallinearruleis (d 1 ; d 2 ; m), where 26 These values are identiöed in the proof of Lemma 1 in Appendix A. 15

17 d 1 and d 2 are speciöed in expression (48), e k 2 solves equation (19), and m = 1 ( [ 1 2 # e k 2 ]. Proposition 3 reáects the fundamental trade-o that arises when the optimal linear rule cannot secure the Örst-best outcome. When v 1 6= v 2 ; setting d 1 and d 2 to induce distinct duopoly prices (p 1 6= p 2 )canraiseindustryproöt,whichcanbeemployedtoenhanceinnovation incentives. However, the distinct prices induce outputs that do not maximize welfare. Proposition 3 reports that, in e ect, p 1 is optimally set to balance these two considerations (where, given p 1, p 2 ensures that the marginal consumer receives zero surplus) as long as the resulting duopoly industry proöt ( 1)doesnotexceedthemaximumfeasibleindustryproÖt e (1). 27 When 1 e " 1, proötcannotbeincreasedfurtherbyalteringequilibriumprices,so the maximum industry proöt constraint binds. The optimal prices maximize industry proöt in this case (i.e., p 1 = p 1 and p 2 = p 2 ). 28 k w 1 # b k 1 > 0 can be viewed as a measure of the extent to which Örm 1 has insu cient incentive to innovate. F ( b k 1 )[k2 w # b k 2 ] can be viewed as a measure of the extent to which Örm 2 is expected to have insu cient incentive to innovate, where the expectation reáects the probability that Örm 2 will have an opportunity to innovate (because Örm 1 has innovated). Equation (19) implies that the patent infringement penalty is optimally increased to the point where the marginal reduction in Örm 1ís innovation deöciency is equal to the increase in Örm 2ís expected innovation deöciency, taking into account the rate at which b k 1 declines and b k 2 increases as the penalty increases. 5 The Optimality of the Linear Rule We now demonstrate that the optimal linear rule achieves the highest expected welfare among all balanced patent infringement damage rules. A balanced damage rule can specify 27 Notice that if v 1 = v 2 ; then ep 1 = ep 2 = p w and e "="=" W, so only equation (19) is relevant. 28 Assumption 1 ensures that all consumers purchase a unit of the product and each Örm serves some customers in both the welfare-maximizing and proöt-maximizing outcomes. Consequently, Proposition 3 implies that when characterizing the optimal linear rule, there is no loss of generality in focusing on the duopoly equilibrium in which all consumers purchase a unit of the product and both Örms serve some customers. 16

18 the prices the Örms set, a transfer payment from Örm 2 to Örm 1 following innovation by both Örms, the probability that Örm 1 innovates, and the probability that Örm 2 innovates, following innovation by Örm By the revelation principle (e.g., Myerson, 1979), it is without loss of generality to consider truthful direct mechanisms, where Örms are induced to truthfully report their privately-observed innovation costs. Let? 1 (k 0 1) 2 [0; 1] denote the probability that Örm 1 is required to innovate when it reports its innovation cost to be k 0 1.Alsolet? 2 (k 0 1;k 0 2) 2 [0; 1] denote the probability that Örm 2 is required to innovate following innovation by Örm 1 when Örm i reports its innovation cost to be k 0 i,fori =1; 2. p i (k 0 1;k 0 2) will denote the corresponding price that Örm i 2f1; 2g must set and T (k 0 2;k 0 2) will denote the corresponding payment that Örm 2 must make to Örm 1whenbothÖrmsinnovate. p M 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2) will denote the corresponding price that Örm 1 must set when it is the sole innovator. Denote this vector of policy instruments by: Z(k 0 1;k 0 2) $ +? 1 (k 0 1);? 2 (k 0 1;k 0 2); p 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2); p 2 (k 0 1;k 0 2); p M 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2); T(k 0 1;k 0 2),. In addition, let q z i (k 0 1;k 0 2) denote the demand for Örm iís product following innovation by both Örms, given that Örm i 2f1; 2g sets price p i (k 0 1;k 0 2). Furthermore,let1 z i (k 0 1;k 0 2)= p i (k 0 1;k 0 2) q z i (k 0 1;k 0 2) denote the corresponding proöt of Örm i (not counting innovation costs). q Mz 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2) will denote the demand for Örm 1ís product when it is the monopoly supplier and it sets price p M 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2). 1 Mz 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2)=p M 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2) q Mz 1 (k 0 1;k 0 2) will denote Örm 1ís corresponding monopoly proöt (not counting innovation costs). Total welfare in this setting when innovation costs (k 1 ;k 2 ) are reported truthfully is: W Z = Z k1 0? 1 (k 1 ) f Z k2 0 f? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )[ f W z 12(k 1 ;k 2 ) # k 2 ] +[1#? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )] f W z 1 (k 1 ;k 2 ) g dg(k 2 ) # k 1 g df (k 1 ) where W fz 1 (k 1 ;k 2 ) = v 1 q1 Mz (k 1 ;k 2 ) # 1! q Mz 1 (k 1 ;k 2 ) " 2 2 and 29 The balanced damage rules that we analyze permit the speciöcation of prices, not quantities. However, the speciöcation of a su ciently high price for Örm 2ís product can e ectively preclude the sale of the product, thereby functioning like an injunction (e.g., Shapiro, 2016). 17

19 fw z 12(k 1 ;k 2 ) = v 1 q z 1(k 1 ;k 2 ) # 1 2 [ qz 1(k 1 ;k 2 )] 2 + v 2 q z 2(k 1 ;k 2 ) # 1 2 [ qz 2(k 1 ;k 2 )] 2. Firm 1ís expected payo when its innovation cost is k 1,itreportsthiscosttobek 0 1,and it anticipates that Örm 2 will report its innovation cost truthfully is: B 1 (k 0 1 j k 1 ) $? 1 (k 0 1)[H(k 0 1) # k 1 ],where H(k 0 1) $ Z k2 0 f? 2 (k 0 1;k 2 )[1 z 1(k 0 1;k 2 )+T (k 0 1;k 2 )] + [1#? 2 (k 0 1;k 2 )]1 Mz 1 (k 0 1;k 2 ) g dg(k 2 ). (20) Following report k1 0 by Örm 1, Örm 2ís expected payo when its innovation cost is k 2 and it reports this cost to be k2 0 is: B 2 (k2 0 j k 2 ; k1) 0 $? 2 (k1;k 0 2)[1 0 z 2(k1;k 0 2) 0 # T (k1;k 0 2) 0 # k 2 ]. (21) The welfare-maximizing damage policy in this setting is the solution to the following problem, denoted [P-Z]: Maximize Z(k 1 ;k 2 ) W Z ; subject to, for all k i ; k 0 i 2 [0; ' k i ](i 2f1; 2g): B 1 (k 1 j k 1 ) " maximum f 0, B 1 (k 0 1 j k 1 ) g, and (22) B 2 (k 2 j k 2 ; k 1 ) " maximum f 0, B 2 (k 0 2 j k 2 ; k 1 ) g. (23) Inequality (22) ensures that Örm 1 truthfully reports its realized innovation cost and secures a nonnegative expected payo by doing so. Inequality (23) ensures the corresponding outcomes for Örm 2, for any cost report by Örm 1. To characterize the solution to [P-Z], it is helpful to consider problem [P-Z] 0,whichis [P-Z] except that constraints (22) and (23) are replaced by: B 1 (k 1 j k 1 ) " 0 and B 2 (k 2 j k 2 ; k 1 ) " 0. (24) Observe that if constraints (22) and (23) are satisöed at a solution to [P-Z] 0, then the identiöed solution to [P-Z] 0 is a solution to [P-Z]. Lemma 4. p M 1 (k 1 ;k 2 ) = p M 1 = v # 1 for all k 1 2 [0; k 1 ] and k 2 2 [0; k 2 ] for which? 1 (k 1 ) > 0 and? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )=0at a solution to [P-Z] 0.Moreover,q z i (k 1 ;k 2 )=q i (p 1 (k 1 ;k 2 ); 18

20 p 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )) as speciöed in equation (2) for i =1; 2, forallk 1 2 [0; k 1 ] and k 2 2 [0; k 2 ] for which? 1 (k 1 ) > 0 and? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 ) > 0 at a solution to [P-Z] 0. Lemma 4, which reáects Assumption 1, indicates that full market coverage is induced in both the monopoly and duopoly settings at the solution to [P-Z] 0. Lemma 5. At a solution to [P-Z] 0,thereexist ~ k 1 2 [0; k 1 ] and ~ k 2 2 [0; k 2 ] such that: (i)? 1 (k 1 ) = 1 for all k 1 2 [0; ~ k 1 ] and? 1 (k 1 ) = 0 for all k 1 2 ( ~ k 1 ; k 1 ]; (ii) for each k 1 2 [0; ~ k 1 ]:? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )=1 for all k 2 2 [0; ~ k 2 ] and? 2 (k 1 ;k 2 )=0for all k 2 2 ( ~ k 2 ; k 2 ]; and (iii) p i (k 0 1;k 0 2)=p i (k 00 1;k 00 2) and T (k 0 1;k 0 2)=T (k 0 1;k 00 2) for all k 0 2;k [0; ~ k 2 ] for each k [0; ~ k 1 ]. Lemma 5 indicates that if innovation is induced, it is induced for the smaller realizations of the Örmsí innovation costs. Furthermore, stochastic innovation (? i (,) 2 (0; 1)) serves no useful purpose in the present setting. 30 In addition, because the Örmsí production costs do not vary with their innovation costs, there is no gain from inducing duopoly prices and output levels (and thus transfer payments, T (,)) thatvarywithreported innovation costs. Lemmas 4 and 5 imply that each Örm e ectively faces the simple choice of innovating or not innovating at the identiöed solution to [P-Z] 0. The choices are structured so that innovation is proötable for a Örm if and only if its realized innovation cost is su ciently small, i.e., if k i ) k ~ i. Therefore, the Örms have no incentive to misrepresent their realized innovation costs, so constraints (22) and (23) are satisöed at the identiöed solution to [P-Z] 0. Consequently, a solution to [P-Z] 0 that satisöes the properties identiöed in Lemmas 4 and 5 is a solution to [P-Z]. It follows that expected welfare in the present setting can be written as: fw Z = F ( ~ k 1 ) G( ~ k 2 ) f W 12 + F ( ~ k 1 )[1# G( ~ k 2 )] f W 1 30 Hart and Reny (2015) analyze a setting in which randomization in product assignment can enhance a sellerís expected revenue when he sells multiple products, but not when he sells a single product. 19

21 Z k ~ 2 Z k ~ 1 # F ( k ~ 1 ) k 2 dg(k 2 ) # k 1 df (k 1 ). (25) Furthermore, when ~ k i ) k i for i =1; 2: 0 0 [ 1! 1 + T ] G( ~ k 2 )+1 M 1 [1# G( ~ k 2 )] = ~ k 1 and 1! 2 # T = ~ k 2, (26) where T is a constant and 1! i = p i q i (p 1 ;p 2 ) does not vary with k 1 or k 2,fori 2f1; 2g. Because the corresponding industry proöt is 1! = 1! 1 + T +(1! 2 # T )= 1! 1 + T + ~ k 2, expression (26) can be written as: [1! # ~ k 2 ] G( ~ k 2 )+1 M 1 [1# G( ~ k 2 )] = ~ k 1 and 1! 2 # T = ~ k 2. (27) Therefore, problem [P-Z] 0 can be written as problem [P-Z] 00 : Maximize p 1 ;p 2 ;T fw Z,where f W Z is speciöed in equation (25), the Örmsí outputs are speciöed in expression (2), and ~ k i is speciöed in expression (27) when ~ k i ) k i,fori =1; 2. Consequently, problem [P-Z] 00 is identical to Problem [P], which ensures the following conclusion holds. Proposition 4. The optimal linear rule achieves the highest welfare among all balanced damage policies. Proposition 4 reáects the fact that linear rules can link damage payments to the proöts of both Örms and can specify lump-sum transfer payments between the Örms. Consequently, linear rules provide widespread latitude to induce desired allocations of industry output while implementing desired conögurations of industry proöt and corresponding innovation incentives. We now illustrate the welfare gains that the optimal linear rule can secure relative to the LP rule and the UE rule. We do so in the following baseline setting, whereconsumers value the two Örmsí products symmetrically, the innovation costs for the two Örms have the same uniform distribution, and Örm 2ís innovation increases the size of the market by eighty percent. Baseline Setting. v 1 = v 2 =7:5, L =1:8,! =0:50, andf (k 1 ) and G(k 2 ) are uniform 20

22 distributions with k i =0 and k i =5,for i =1; 2. Table 1 identiöes the optimal linear rule for patent infringement (d! 1;d! 2;m! ) in the baseline setting and as product valuations change. 31 The table also reports the level of expected welfare that arises under the optimal linear rule (W! ), under the UE rule (W UE ), under the LP rule (W LP ), and in the Örst-best outcome (W FB ). v 1 v 2 d! 1 d! 2 m! W! W UE W LP W FB 5 5 0:72 0:72 0:21 3:03 2:49 2:58 3: :25 1:5 5:56 7:94 6:96 5:35 7:94 7:5 7:5 0:81 0:81 0 7:69 5:98 6:22 7: :5 0:25 #5:56 7:94 6:37 6:16 7: :81 0: :19 10:03 9:45 12:19 Table 1. The E ects of Changing Product Valuations. Four elements of Table 1 warrant emphasis. First, there are many settings where the optimal linear rule ensures the Örst-best outcome. Second, the optimal linear rule often secures a substantial increase in welfare above the levels generated by the LP and UE rules. This is the case both when the optimal linear rule achieves the Örst-best outcome and when it does not do so. To illustrate, W! exceeds max fw UE ;W LP g by more than 21% when v 1 = v 2 =10,andbymorethan17% when v 1 = v 2 =5. Also observe that W! exceeds W LP by more than 48% when v 1 =7and v 2 =8. Third, the lump-sum payment from Örm 2 to Örm 1 under the optimal linear rule (m! ) can be positive, negative, or zero. For the settings in Table 1 where v 1 + v 2 = 15, m! is positive (negative) when consumers value Örm 2ís (Örm 1ís) product relatively highly and is zero when v 1 = v As the product valuations, v 1 and v 2, change in Table 1, the values of all other parameters remain at their values in the baseline setting. 32 Observe that when v 1 + v 2 = 15, W! is higher in Table 1 when v 1 6= v 2 than when v 1 = v 2. Welfare is higher in the presence of asymmetric product valuations here because consumers purchase more of the product they value most highly and less of the product they value less highly. 21

23 Fourth, the optimal linear rule does not always resemble the UE rule more than the LP rule (in the sense that d! 2 >d! 1)whentheUErulegeneratesahigherlevelofwelfarethan the LP rule. 33 This is the case because d! 1 and d! 2 a ect multiple determinants of welfare ñ both output allocations and innovation decisions ñ in nonlinear fashion. Consequently, even though welfare might be higher when, say, d 2 =1and d 1 = m =0than when d 1 =1and d 2 = m =0,itdoesnotfollowthatd 2 will exceed d 1 under the optimal linear rule. Appendix B illustrates how the optimal linear rule and its performance vary as other model parameters (k 1 ; k 2 ;L,and!) change.thenumericalsolutionsreportedinappendix Bindicate,forexample,thattherelativeperformanceoftheoptimallinearrule(W! =W LP and W! =W UE )tendstoincreaseasl (the extent to which Örm 2ís innovation expands the market) increases. 6 Concluding Remarks We have introduced and characterized the optimal linear rule for patent infringement damages under sequential innovation. We have demonstrated that this rule often secures substantially higher welfare than common rules like the LP rule and the UE rule. We have also identiöed conditions under which a linear rule can induce both e cient incentives for sequential innovation and the e cient allocation of industry output. Moreover, we have shown that the linear rule is optimal among all balanced patent infringement damage rules. We have emphasized the welfare gains that the optimal linear rule can secure relative to the LP rule and the UE rule. However, the optimal linear rule can also secure substantially higher levels of welfare than other popular damage rules, including the reasonable royalty (RR) rule. Under the RR rule, when Örm 2 is found to have infringed Örm 1ís patent, Örm 2 is required to deliver to Örm 1 the royalty payments that Örm 1 would have collected if the two Örms had negotiated a licensing/royalty agreement, knowing that Örm 2ís product infringes Örm 1ís patent (e.g., Henry and Turner, 2010). 34 Absent contracting frictions, the Örms 33 See the fourth row of data in Table 1 where v 1 =8and v 2 =7. 34 As noted above, U.S. patent law stipulates that the damage penalty for patent infringement must be ìadequate to compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use 22

An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation

An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation An Optimal Rule for Patent Damages Under Sequential Innovation by Yongmin Chen* and David E. M. Sappington** Abstract: We analyze the optimal design of damages for patent infringement in settings where

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Licensing probabilistic Patents and Liability Rules: The Duopoly case

Licensing probabilistic Patents and Liability Rules: The Duopoly case MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Licensing probabilistic Patents and Liability Rules: The Duopoly case Martin Vargas Barrenechea 009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/687/ MPRA Paper No. 687,

More information

Research and Development

Research and Development Chapter 9. March 7, 2011 Firms spend substantial amounts on. For instance ( expenditure to output sales): aerospace (23%), o ce machines and computers (18%), electronics (10%) and drugs (9%). is classi

More information

All Entrepreneurial Productivity Increases are Not Created Equal

All Entrepreneurial Productivity Increases are Not Created Equal All Entrepreneurial Productivity Increases are Not Created Equal by Arup Bose,* Debashis Pal,** and David E. M. Sappington*** Abstract We examine the impact of productivity increases in a simple model

More information

Finding Lost Pro ts: An Equilibrium Analysis of Patent. Infringement Damages

Finding Lost Pro ts: An Equilibrium Analysis of Patent. Infringement Damages Finding Lost Pro ts: An Equilibrium Analysis of Patent Infringement Damages James J. Anton Duke University Dennis A. Yao Harvard University and University of Pennsylvania Abstract We examine the impact

More information

CESifo Area Conference on APPLIED MICROECONOMICS

CESifo Area Conference on APPLIED MICROECONOMICS CESifo Area Conference on APPLIED MICROECONOMICS 0 March 006 CESifo Conference Centre, Munich How Reasonable is the Reasonable Royalty Rate? Damage Rules and Probabilistic Intellectual Property Rights

More information

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries

Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries Pricing to Preclude Sabotage in Regulated Industries by Arup Bose*, Debashis Pal**, and David E. M. Sappington*** Abstract We characterize the optimal access price and retail price for a vertically-integrated

More information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information Alain Delacroix (UQAM) and Etienne Wasmer (Sciences-Po) September 4, 2009 Abstract Wage determination under asymmetric information generates ine ciencies

More information

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís** WP-AD 2008-12 Corresponding author: R. Fauli-Oller Universidad de Alicante,

More information

Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach

Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach Economics of Open Source: A Dynamic Approach Jeongmeen Suh y KIEP Murat Y lmaz z Bo¼gaziçi University March 29 Abstract This paper analyzes open innovation projects and their e ects on incentives for innovation.

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

Volume 35, Issue 2. Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions

Volume 35, Issue 2. Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions Volume 35, Issue 2 Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions Masahiko Hattori Faculty of Economics, oshisha University Yasuhito Tanaka Faculty

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key EconS 503 - Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key 1. WEAs with market power. Consider an exchange economy with two consumers, A and B, whose utility functions are u A (x A 1 ; x A 2 ) = x A

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Modeling Technological Change

Modeling Technological Change Modeling Technological Change Yin-Chi Wang The Chinese University of Hong Kong November, 202 References: Acemoglu (2009) ch2 Concepts of Innovation Innovation by type. Process innovation: reduce cost,

More information

Cross-Licensing and Competition

Cross-Licensing and Competition Cross-Licensing and Competition Doh-Shin Jeon and Yassine Lefouili y June 7, 2013 Very preliminary and incomplete - Please do not circulate Abstract We study bilateral cross-licensing agreements among

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Trade policy III: Export subsidies The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw June 25, 2015 Overview Overview 1 1 Under perfect competition lead to welfare loss 2 Effects depending on market structures 1 Subsidies to

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Katz and Shapiro (1985) Katz and Shapiro (1985) 1 The paper studies the compatibility choice of competing firms in industries with network externalities. Also investigated are the social vs. private incentives of compatibility

More information

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales Douglas Gale Piero Gottardi NYU April 23, 2013 Douglas Gale, Piero Gottardi (NYU) Capital Structure April 23, 2013 1 / 55 Introduction Corporate

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation Matteo Paradisi November 1, 2016 In this Section we develop a theoretical analysis of optimal minimum

More information

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems CSCI699: Topics in Learning and Game Theory Lecture 4 Lecturer: Shaddin Dughmi Scribes: Haifeng Xu,Reem Alfayez 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems Example 1: Single Item Auctions. There is a single

More information

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting Eric Avenel Université de Rennes I et CREM (UMR CNRS 6) March, 00 Abstract This article presents a model

More information

Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate

Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate Yair Tauman and Chang Zhao Stony Brook University and The Interdisciplinary Center, Herzliya Stony Brook University Abstract We analyze the economic

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline Joosung Lee Daniel Z. Li University of Edinburgh Durham University January, 2018 1 / 48 A Motivational Example A puzzling observation in mergers and acquisitions

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

Some Notes on Adverse Selection Some Notes on Adverse Selection John Morgan Haas School of Business and Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley Overview This set of lecture notes covers a general model of adverse selection

More information

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply Matthias Kräkel y Anja Schöttner z Abstract It is well-known that, in static models, minimum wages generate positive worker rents and, consequently, ine ciently

More information

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005 Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Jianwei Huang & Lin Gao Network Communications and Economics Lab (NCEL) Information Engineering Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong Huang

More information

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version) Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version) July 4, 2017 1. Person A lexicographically prefers good x to good y, i.e., when comparing two bundles of x and y, she strictly prefers

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation Daron Acemoglu y Kostas Bimpikis z Asuman Ozdaglar x October 2008. Abstract This paper studies a simple model of experimentation and innovation. Our analysis suggests

More information

OPTIMAL REMEDIES FOR PATENT INFRINGEMENT

OPTIMAL REMEDIES FOR PATENT INFRINGEMENT OPTIMAL REMEDIES FOR PATENT INFRINGEMENT Boston University School of Law Law & Economics Working Paper No. 15-53 December 3, 2015 Mengxi Zhang Boston University, Department of Economics Keith N. Hylton

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly

A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly A Model of Endogenous Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly Cheng-Zhong Qin, Shengping Zhang, and Dandan Zhu February 6, 2012 Abstract A network approach is proposed to analyze endogenous cross-holdings and their

More information

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems Alexis Anagnostopoulos (Stony Brook University) Eva Cárceles-Poveda (Stony Brook University) Yair Tauman (IDC and Stony Brook University) June 24th

More information

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Julan Du Chinese University of Hong Kong Yi Lu University of Hong Kong Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Abstract In acquiring the same intermediate inputs, a firm

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

1. Pareto E cient Allocation and Social Welfare Maximization

1. Pareto E cient Allocation and Social Welfare Maximization Spring 2013 1. Pareto E cient Allocation and Social Welfare Maximization! "R $ Consider a private ownership economy E priv = L + ; " i ;e i #i=1;:::;i ; fy jg j=1;:::;j ; f$ i;j g i;j where " i can be

More information

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract Spatial Cournot competition in a circular city with transport cost differentials Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract For an even number of firms with identical transport cost, spatial

More information

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum

The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum The Value of Sharing Intermittent Spectrum R. erry, M. Honig, T. Nguyen, V. Subramanian & R. V. Vohra Abstract We consider a model of Cournot competition with congestion motivated by recent initiatives

More information

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1 Ralph s Strategic Disclosure Ralph manages a firm that operates in a duopoly Both Ralph s (privatevalue) production cost and (common-value) inverse demand are uncertain Ralph s (constant marginal) production

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Module 18: VCG Mechanism

Module 18: VCG Mechanism Module 18: VCG Mechanism Information conomics c 515) George Georgiadis Society comprising of n agents. Set A of alternatives from which to choose. Agent i receives valuation v i x) if alternative x 2 A

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11 Externalities and PG MWG- Chapter 11 Simple Bilateral Externality When external e ects are present, CE are not PO. Assume: 1 Two consumers i = 1, 2 2 The actions of these consumers do not a ect prices

More information

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading Environmental R&D with Permits Trading Gamal Atallah Department of Economics, University of Ottawa Jianqiao Liu Environment Canada April 2012 Corresponding author: Gamal Atallah, Associate Professor, Department

More information

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Jianqing Chen Andrew Whinston Web Appendix A Heterogeneous Consumer Valuation In the baseline model, we assumed that consumers

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment Timothy Mathews and Soiliou Daw Namoro Abstract. A model of two tournaments, each with a field of

More information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology Daron Acemoglu MIT October 3, 2007 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Advanced Growth Lecture 8 October 3,

More information

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms Jonathan Levin 1 Economics 285 Market Design Winter 2009 1 These slides are based on Paul Milgrom s. onathan Levin VCG Mechanisms Winter 2009 1 / 23 Motivation We consider

More information

Non-governmental Copyright Protecti Title Market.

Non-governmental Copyright Protecti Title Market. Non-governmental Copyright Protecti Title Market Author(s) Arai, Yasuhiro Citation Issue 2005-2 Date Type Technical Report Text Version URL http://hdl.handle.net/0086/6965 Right Hitotsubashi University

More information

Cross-Licensing and Competition

Cross-Licensing and Competition Cross-Licensing and Competition Doh-Shin Jeon y and Yassine Lefouili z September 30, 2013 Abstract We study bilateral cross-licensing agreements among N(> 2) rms that engage in competition after the licensing

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design 1. Public Good Provision Imagine that you and your colleagues want to buy a co ee machine for your o ce. Suppose that some of you may

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Harsanyi [1967] What happens when players do not know one another s payoffs? Games of incomplete information versus games of imperfect

More information

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 Oligopoly Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 1 Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is an industry

More information

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key EconS 50 - Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam # - Answer Key 1. Revenue comparison in two auction formats. Consider a sealed-bid auction with bidders. Every bidder i privately observes his valuation

More information

National Treatment in International Agreements on. Intellectual Property

National Treatment in International Agreements on. Intellectual Property ational Treatment in International Agreements on Intellectual Property Yasukazu Ichino Faculty of Economics, Konan University June 27, 2010 Abstract ational treatment (T), a practice of governments granting

More information

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1) Answers to Exam Economics 201b First Half 1. (a) Observe, first, that no consumer ever wishes to consume more than 3/2 liters (i.e., 1.5 liters). To see this, observe that, even if the beverage were free,

More information

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network Effects Adriana Gama Mario Samano September 7, 218 Abstract We establish an important difference between Cournot oligopolies with and without positive

More information

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information preliminary

Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information preliminary Platform Competition under Asymmetric Information preliminary Hanna Ha laburda Harvard University Yaron Yehezkel Tel Aviv University January 31, 2011 Abstract In the context of platform competition in

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change Chapter 7 Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change 225 Economic Growth: Lecture Notes 7.1 Expanding Product Variety: The Romer Model There are three sectors: one for the final good sector, one

More information

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Limit pricing models and PBE 1 EconS 503 - Advanced Microeconomics II Limit pricing models and PBE 1 1 Model Consider an entry game with an incumbent monopolist (Firm 1) and an entrant (Firm ) who analyzes whether or not to join the

More information

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #10 - Externalities

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #10 - Externalities EconS 50 - Micro Theory I Recitation #0 - Externalities Exercise [ Pareto irrelevant externalities] If the two consumers in the economy have preferences U = [x x 2] [x 2 x 2 2] and U 2 = [x 2 x 2 2] [x

More information

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value February, 203 A Simultaneous Quality Decisions In the non-integrated case without royalty fees, the analysis closely

More information

The Design of a University System

The Design of a University System The Design of a University System Gianni De Fraja University of Leicester, Università di Roma Tor Vergata and CEPR Paola Valbonesi Università di Padova Public Economics UK 27 May 2011 Abstract This paper

More information

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear Katharina Huesmann February 13, 2017 Abstract This paper considers the problem of assigning an indivisible good of limited availability

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Expectations and Two-Sided Platform Profits

Expectations and Two-Sided Platform Profits Expectations and Two-Sided Platform Profits Andrei Hagiu Hanna Hałaburda Working Paper 12-045 March 19, 2013 Copyright 2011, 2013 by Andrei Hagiu and Hanna Hałaburda Working papers are in draft form. This

More information

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry! Econ 0A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sry! This Problem set tests the knowledge that you accumulated mainly in lectures 2 to 26. The problem set is focused

More information

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Geethanjali Selvaretnam Abstract This model takes into consideration the fact that depositors

More information

DISCUSSION PAPER 2010/77. Bargaining and delay in patent licensing. Ana Mauleon, Vincent Vannetelbosch and Cecilia Vergari

DISCUSSION PAPER 2010/77. Bargaining and delay in patent licensing. Ana Mauleon, Vincent Vannetelbosch and Cecilia Vergari 010/77 Bargaining and delay in patent licensing Ana Mauleon, Vincent Vannetelbosch and Cecilia Vergari DISCUSSION PAPER Center for Operations Research and Econometrics Voie du Roman Pays, 34 B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve

More information

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro Stagnation Traps Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro May 2015 Research question and motivation Can insu cient aggregate demand lead to economic stagnation? This question goes back, at least, to the Great

More information

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments Tymofiy Mylovanov Thomas Tröger University of Bonn June 21, 2008 1/28 Motivation 2/28 Motivation In most applications of mechanism design, the proposer

More information

Bayesian Nash equilibrium

Bayesian Nash equilibrium Bayesian Nash equilibrium Felix Munoz-Garcia Strategy and Game Theory - Washington State University So far we assumed that all players knew all the relevant details in a game. Hence, we analyzed complete-information

More information

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Ilan Guttman, Ilan Kremer and Andrzej Skrzypacz Stanford Graduate School of Business November 2011 1 Introduction

More information

Exclusive contracts and market dominance

Exclusive contracts and market dominance Exclusive contracts and market dominance Giacomo Calzolari and Vincenzo Denicolò Online Appendix. Proofs for the baseline model This Section provides the proofs of Propositions and 2. Proof of Proposition.

More information

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Microeconomic Theory (50b) Problem Set 0. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann 4/5/4 This problem set is due on Tuesday, 4//4..

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 750 Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Di erentiated

More information

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation Ismail Saglam Ipek University 4 May 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/71090/

More information

Asymmetric Information and Bank Runs

Asymmetric Information and Bank Runs Asymmetric Information and Bank uns Chao Gu Cornell University Draft, March, 2006 Abstract This paper extends Peck and Shell s (2003) bank run model to the environment in which the sunspot coordination

More information

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework. Economy: I consumers, i = 1,...I. J firms, j = 1,...J. L goods, l = 1,...L Initial Endowment of good l in the economy: ω l 0, l = 1,...L. Consumer i : preferences

More information