TERM STRUCTURE MODELS DRIVEN BY WIENER PROCESSES AND POISSON MEASURES: EXISTENCE AND POSITIVITY

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "TERM STRUCTURE MODELS DRIVEN BY WIENER PROCESSES AND POISSON MEASURES: EXISTENCE AND POSITIVITY"

Transcription

1 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY WIN POCSSS AND POISSON MASUS: XISTNC AND POSITIVITY DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN Abstract. In the spirit of [3], we investigate term structure models driven by Wiener processes and Poisson measures with forward curve dependent volatilities. This includes a full existence and uniqueness proof for the corresponding Heath-Jarrow-Morton type term structure equation. Furthermore, we characterize positivity preserving models by means of the characteristic coefficients, which was open for ump-diffusions. A key role in our investigation is played by the method of the moving frame, which allows to transform term structure equations to time-dependent SDs. Key Words: term structure models driven by Wiener processes and Poisson measures, Heath-Jarrow-Morton-Musiela equation, positivity preserving models. 91B8, 6H15 1. Introduction Interest rate theory is dealing with zero-coupon bonds, which are subect to a stochastic evolution due to daily trading of related products like coupon bearing bonds, swaps, caps, floors, swaptions, etc. Zero-coupon bonds, which are financial assets paying the holder one unit of cash at maturity time T, are conceptually important products, since one can easily write all other products as derivatives on them. We always assume default-free bonds, i.e. there are no counterparty risks in the considered markets. The Heath-Jarrow-Morton methodology takes the bond market as a whole as today s aggregation of information on interest rates and one tries to model future flows of information by a stochastic evolution equation on the set of possible scenarios of bond prices. For the set of possible scenarios of bond prices the forward rate proved to be a flexible and useful parametrization, since it maps possible states of the bond market to open subsets of (Hilbert spaces of forward rate curves. Under some regularity assumptions the price of a zero coupon bond at t T can be written as ( T P (t, T = exp f(t, udu, t where f(t, T is the forward rate for date T. We usually assume the forward rate to be continuous in maturity time T. The classical continuous framework for the evolution of the forward rates goes back to Heath, Jarrow and Morton (HJM [3]. They assume that, for every date T, the forward rates f(t, T follow an Itô process Filipović gratefully acknowledges the support from WWTF (Vienna Science and Technology Fund and Swissquote. Tappe gratefully acknowledges the support from WWTF. Teichmann gratefully acknowledges the support from the FWF-grant Y 38 (STAT prize from the Austrian Science Fund. The authors thank two anonymous referees for their helpful remarks and suggestions.

2 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN of the form (1.1 d df(t, T = α(t, T dt + σ (t, T dw t, t [, T ] =1 where W = (W 1,..., W d is a standard Brownian motion in d. There are several reasons for generalizing the HJM framework (1.1 by introducing umps. Namely, this allows us to model the impact of unexpected news about the economy, such as interventions by central banks, credit events, or (natural disasters. Indeed, there is strong statistical evidence in the finance literature that empirical features of the data cannot be captured by continuous models. We also mention that for the particular case of deterministic integrands α and σ in (1.1, as it is for the Vasiček model, the log returns for discounted zero coupon bonds are normally distributed, which, however, is not true for empirically observed log returns, see the discussion in [37, Chap. 5]. Börk et al. [3, 4], berlein et al. [1, 11, 1, 13, 14, 15] and others ([38, 6, 4] thus proposed to replace the classical Brownian motion W in (1.1 by a more general driving noise, also taking into account the occurrence of umps. Carmona and Tehranchi [6] proposed models based on infinite dimensional Wiener processes, see also [16]. In the spirit of Börk et al. [3] and Carmona and Tehranchi [6], we focus on term structure models of the type (1. df(t, T = α(t, T dt + σ(t, T dw t + γ(t, x, T (µ(dt, dx F (dxdt, where W denotes a (possibly infinite dimensional Wiener process and, in addition, µ is a homogeneous Poisson random measure on with compensator dt F (dx, where denotes the mark space. For what follows, it will be convenient to switch to the alternative parametrization r t (ξ := f(t, t + ξ, ξ which is due to Musiela [3]. Then, we may regard (r t t as one stochastic process with values in H, that is r : Ω H, where H denotes a Hilbert space of forward curves h : to be specified later. ecall that we always assume that forward rate curves are continuous. Denoting by (S t t the shift semigroup on H, that is S t h = h(t +, equation (1. becomes in integrated form (1.3 r t (ξ = S t h (ξ + + t t S t s α(s, s + ξds + t S t s σ(s, s + ξdw s S t s γ(s, x, s + ξ(µ(ds, dx F (dxds, t where h H denotes the initial forward curve and S t s operates on the functions ξ α(s, s + ξ, ξ σ(s, s + ξ and ξ γ(s, x, s + ξ. From a financial modeling point of view, one would rather consider drift and volatilities to be functions of the prevailing forward curve, that is α : H H, σ : H H, γ : H H. for all

3 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 3 For example, the volatilities could be of the form σ (h = φ (l 1 (h,..., l p (h for some p N with φ : p H and l i : H. We may think of l i (h = 1 ξi ξ i h(ηdη (benchmark yields or l i(h = h(ξ i (benchmark forward rates. (1.4 The implied bond market P (t, T = exp ( T t r t (ξdξ is free of arbitrage if we can find an equivalent (local martingale measure Q P such that the discounted bond prices ( t (1.5 exp r s (ds P (t, T, t [, T ] are local Q-martingales for all maturities T. In the sequel, we will directly specify the HJM equation under a martingale measure. More precisely, we will assume that the drift α = α HJM : H H is given by α HJM (h := ( (1.6 σ (hσ (h γ(h, x e Γ(h,x 1 F (dx for all h H, where we have set (1.7 (1.8 Σ (h(ξ := ξ Γ(h, x(ξ := ξ σ (h(ηdη, γ(h, x(ηdη. for all According to [3] (if the Brownian motion is infinite dimensional, see also [16], condition (1.6 guarantees that the discounted zero coupon bond prices (1.5 are local martingales for all maturities T, whence the bond market (1.4 is free of arbitrage. In the classical situation, where the model is driven by a finite dimensional standard Brownian motion, (1.6 is the well-known HJM drift condition derived in [3]. Our requirements lead to the forward rates (r t t in (1.3 being a solution of the stochastic equation (1.9 r t = S t h + + t t S t s α HJM (r s ds + t S t s σ(r s dw s S t s γ(r s, x(µ(ds, dx F (dxds, t and it arises the question whether this equation possesses a solution. To our knowledge, there has not yet been an explicit proof for the existence of a solution to the Poisson measure driven equation (1.9. We thus provide such a proof in our paper, see Theorem 3.4. For term structure models driven by a Brownian motion, the existence proof has been provided in [16] and for the Lévy case in [19]. We also refer to the related papers [36] and [8]. In the spirit of [8] and [35], an H-valued stochastic process (r t t satisfying (1.9 is a so-called mild solution for the (semi-linear stochastic partial differential equation (1.1 { drt = ( d dξ r t + α HJM (r t dt + σ(r t dw t + γ(r t, x(µ(dt, dx F (dxdt r = h, where d dξ becomes the infinitesimal generator of the strongly continuous semigroup of shifts (S t t.

4 4 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN As in [], we understand stochastic partial differential equations as time-dependent transformations of time-dependent stochastic differential equations with infinite dimensional state space. More precisely, on an enlarged space H of forward curves h :, which are indexed by the whole real line, equipped with the strongly continuous group (U t t of shifts, we solve the stochastic differential equation (1.11 df t = U t lα HJM (πu t f t dt + U t lσ(πu t f t dw t + U tlγ(πu t f t, x(µ(dt, dx F (dxdt f = lh, where l : H H is an isometric embedding and π : H H is the orthogonal proection on H, and afterwards, we transform the solution process (f t t by r t := πu t f t in order to obtain a mild solution for (1.1. Notice that (1.11 ust corresponds to the original HJM dynamics in (1., where, of course, the forward rate f t (T has no economic interpretation for T < t. Thus, we will henceforth refer to (1.11 as the HJM (Heath-Jarrow-Morton equation. We emphasize that knowledge about the HJM equation (1.11 is not necessary in order to deduce existence and uniqueness for the forward curve evolution (1.1. The only thing we require in order to apply the existence result from [] is that we can embed the space H of forward curves into a larger Hilbert space H, on which the shift semigroup extends to a group. The point of the method of the moving frame from [] is to transform an SPD into a time-dependent SD on H, but we do not need the particular structure of this extension. Our existence result of this paper generalizes that for pure diffusion models from [16] and for term structure models driven by Lévy processes from [19] (we also mention the papers [36] and [8] concerning Lévy term structure models, see Corollary 3.6. As described above, in order to establish the proof we apply a result from [], which contains existence and uniqueness results for general SPDs on Hilbert spaces. Other references for SPDs on Hilbert spaces are [1] and [9]. Since the HJM drift term α HJM is of the particular form (1.6, we have to work out sufficient conditions which permit an application of this existence result. In practice, we are interested in term structure models producing positive forward curves, since negative forward rates are very rarely observed. After establishing the existence issue, we shall therefore focus on positivity preserving term structure models, and give a characterization of such models. The HJM equation (1.11 on the enlarged function space will be the key for analyzing positivity of forward curves. Indeed, the method of the moving frame, see [], allows us to use standard stochastic analysis (see [5] for our investigations. It will turn out that the conditions σ (h(ξ =, for all ξ (,, h P ξ and all h + γ(h, x P, for all h P and F -almost all x γ(h, x(ξ =, for all ξ (,, h P ξ and F -almost all x where P denotes the convex cone of all nonnegative forward curves, and P ξ is the edge consisting of all nonnegative forward curves h with h(ξ =, are necessary and sufficient for the positivity preserving property, see Theorem 4.4. For this purpose, we provide a general positivity preserving result, see Theorem 4., which is of independent interest and can also be applied on other function spaces. Positivity results for the diffusion case have been worked out in [7] and [3]. In particular, we would like to mention the important and beautiful work [34], where, through an application of a general support theorem, positivity is proved. We shall also apply this general argument for our reasonings.

5 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 5 The remainder of this text is organized as follows. In Section we introduce the space H β of forward curves. Using this space, we prove in Section 3, under appropriate regularity assumptions, the existence of a unique solution for the HJMM equation (1.1. The positivity issue of term structure models is treated in Section 4. There, we show first the necessary conditions with a general semimartingale argument. The sufficient conditions are proved to hold true by switching on the umps slowly. This allows for a reduction to results from [34]. For the sake of lucidity, we postpone the proofs of some auxiliary results to Appendix A.. The space of forward curves In this section, we introduce the space of forward curves, on which we will solve the HJMM equation (1.1 in Section 3. We fix an arbitrary constant β >. Let H β be the space of all absolutely continuous functions h : such that ( 1/ h β := h( + h (ξ e βξ dξ <. Let (S t t be the shift semigroup on H β defined by S t h := h(t + for t. Since forward curves should flatten for large time to maturity ξ, the choice of H β is reasonable from an economic point of view. Moreover, let H β be the space of all absolutely continuous functions h : such that ( 1/ h β := h( + h (ξ e dξ β ξ <. Let (U t t be the shift group on H β defined by U t h := h(t + for t. The linear operator l : H β H β defined by { h(, ξ < l(h(ξ := h H β h(ξ, ξ, is an isometric embedding with adoint operator π := l : H β H β given by π(h = h +, h H β..1. Theorem. Let β > be arbitrary. (.1 (. (.3 (.4 (1 The space (H β, β is a separable Hilbert space. ( For each ξ, the point evaluation h h(ξ : H β is a continuous linear functional. (3 (S t t is a C -semigroup on H β with infinitesimal generator d dξ : D( d dξ H β H β, d dξ h = h, and domain D( d dξ = {h H β h H β }. (4 ach h H β is continuous, bounded and the limit h( := lim ξ h(ξ exists. (5 H β := {h H β h( = } is a closed subspace of H β. (6 There are universal constants C 1, C, C 3, C 4 >, only depending on β, such that for all h H β we have the estimates h L 1 ( C 1 h β, h L ( C h β, h h( L1 ( C 3 h β, (h h( 4 e β L 1 ( C 4 h 4 β.

6 6 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN (.5 (7 For each β > β, we have H β H β, the relation h β h β, h H β and there is a universal constant C 5 >, only depending on β and β, such that for all h H β we have the estimate (.6 (h h( e β L1 ( C 5 h β. (8 The space (H β, β is a separable Hilbert space, (U t t is a C -group on H β and, for each ξ, the point evaluation h h(ξ, H β is a continuous linear functional. (9 The diagram H β l U t Hβ π (.7 S H t β Hβ commutes for every t, that is Proof. See Appendix A. πu t l = S t for all t. 3. xistence of term structure models driven by Wiener processes and Poisson measures In this section, we establish existence and uniqueness of the HJMM equation (1.1 with diffusive and ump components on the Hilbert spaces introduced in the last section. Let < β < β be arbitrary real numbers. We denote by H β and H β the Hilbert spaces of the previous section, equipped with the strongly continuous semigroup (S t t of shifts, which has the infinitesimal generator d dξ. In the sequel, (Ω, F, (F t t, P denotes a filtered probability space satisfying the usual conditions. Let U be another separable Hilbert space and let Q L(U be a compact, selfadoint, strictly positive linear operator. Then there exist an orthonormal basis {e } of U and a bounded sequence λ of strictly positive real numbers such that Qu = λ u, e e, u U namely, the λ are the eigenvalues of Q, and each e is an eigenvector corresponding to λ, see, e.g., [41, Thm. VI.3.]. The space U := Q 1/ (U, equipped with the inner product u, v U := Q 1/ u, Q 1/ v U, is another separable Hilbert space and { λ e } is an orthonormal basis. Let W be a Q-Wiener process [8, p. 86,87]. We assume that tr(q = λ <. Otherwise, which is the case if W is a cylindrical Wiener process, there always exists a separable Hilbert space U 1 U on which W has a realization as a finite trace class Wiener process, see [8, Chap. 4.3]. We denote by L (H β := L (U, H β the space of Hilbert-Schmidt operators from U into H β, which, endowed with the Hilbert-Schmidt norm Φ L (H β := λ Φe, Φ L (H β itself is a separable Hilbert space.

7 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 7 According to [8, Prop. 4.1], the sequence of stochastic processes {β } defined as β := 1 λ W, e is a sequence of real-valued independent (F t -Brownian motions and we have the expansion (3.1 W = λ β e, where the series is convergent in the space M (U of U-valued square-integrable martingales. Let Φ : Ω L (H β be an integrable process, i.e. Φ is predictable and satisfies ( T P Φ t L (H β dt < = 1 for all T. Setting Φ := λ Φe for each, we have (3. t Φ s dw s = t Φ sdβ s, t where the convergence is uniform on compact time intervals in probability, see [8, Thm. 4.3]. Let (, be a measurable space which we assume to be a Blackwell space (see [9, ]. We remark that every Polish space with its Borel σ-field is a Blackwell space. Furthermore, let µ be a homogeneous Poisson random measure on, see [5, Def. II.1.]. Then its compensator is of the form dt F (dx, where F is a σ-finite measure on (,. Let measurable vector fields σ : H β L (Hβ and γ : H β Hβ be given, where the subspace Hβ was defined in Theorem.1. For each we define σ : H β Hβ as σ (h := λ σ(he. We shall now focus on the HJMM equation ( Assumption. We assume there exists a measurable function Φ : satisfying (3.3 a constant L > such that (3.4 (3.5 ( Γ(h, x(ξ Φ(x, h H β, x and ξ σ(h 1 σ(h L (H β L h 1 h β e Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x β F (dx 1/ L h 1 h β for all h 1, h H β, and a constant M > such that (3.6 (3.7 σ(h L (H β M e Φ(x ( γ(h, x β γ(h, x 4 β F (dx M for all h H β. Furthermore, we assume that for each h H β the map ( (3.8 α (h := γ(h, x e Γ(h,x 1 F (dx is absolutely continuous with weak derivative d (3.9 dξ α (h = γ(h, x e Γ(h,x F (dx d ( dξ γ(h, x e Γ(h,x 1 F (dx. 3.. emark. The proof of Proposition 3.3 below gives rise to the following remarks concerning conditions (3.8, (3.9 from Assumption 3.1.

8 8 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN For each h H β the map α (h is well-defined (that is, for every ξ the integral in (3.8 exists and continuous (but not necessarily absolutely continuous with α (h( = and lim ξ α (h(ξ =. If α (h is absolutely continuous for some h H β, then we have α (h Hβ. For Lévy driven term structure models we can verify conditions (3.8 and (3.9 directly, see Corollary 3.6 below. Let h H β be such that γ(h, x C 1 ( for all x. Suppose for each ξ there exist δ = δ(h, ξ > and C = C(h, ξ > such that d γ(h, x(η dη C γ(h, x β for all x and η (ξ δ, ξ + δ. Then, we even have α (h C 1 ( with derivative ( Proposition. Suppose Assumption 3.1 is fulfilled. Then we have α HJM (H β Hβ and there is a constant K > such that (3.1 α HJM (h 1 α HJM (h β K h 1 h β for all h 1, h H β. Proof. Note that α HJM = α 1 + α, where α 1 (h := σ (hσ (h, h H β and α is given by (3.8. By [16, Cor. 5.1.] we have σ (hσ (h Hβ, h H β for all. For an arbitrary h H β we obtain, by using [16, Cor. 5.1.] again, σ (hσ (h β 3(C3 + C 4 σ (h β = 3(C3 + C 4 σ(h L (H β, and hence, we deduce α 1 (H β H β. Let h H β be arbitrary. For all x and ξ we have by (. and (.5 (3.11 γ(h, x(ξ C γ(h, x β C γ(h, x β, and for all x and ξ we have by (3.3, (.3 and (.5 (3.1 e Γ(h,x(ξ 1 e Φ(x Γ(h, x(ξ e Φ(x γ(h, x L1 ( C 3 e Φ(x γ(h, x β. stimates (3.11, (3.1 and (3.7 show that lim ξ α (h(ξ =. From (3.3, (3.11, (3.7 and (.6 it follows that ( CM CM γ(h, x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ C MC 5 ( γ(h, x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ e Φ(x γ(h, x(ξ e βξ dξf (dx e Φ(x γ(h, x β F (dx C M C 5.

9 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 9 We obtain by (3.1, Hölder s inequality, (3.7 and (.5 ( d ( dξ γ(h, x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ 1 F (dx e βξ dξ ( C3 d γ(h, x(ξ dξ e 1 Φ(x e 1 Φ(x γ(h, x β F (dx e βξ dξ C3M e Φ(x d γ(h, x(ξ dξ e βξ dξf (dx C3M e Φ(x γ(h, x β F (dx C 3M. In view of (3.9, we conclude that α (H β H β, and hence α HJM(H β H β. Let h 1, h H β be arbitrary. By [16, Cor. 5.1.], Hölder s inequality, (3.4 and (3.6 we have α 1 (h 1 α 1 (h β 3(C3 + C 4 ( σ (h 1 β + σ (h β σ (h 1 σ (h β 3(C3 + C 4 ( σ (h 1 β + σ (h β σ (h 1 σ (h β 6(C3 + C 4( σ(h 1 L (H β + σ(h L (H β σ(h 1 σ(h L (H β ML 6(C3 + C 4 h 1 h β. Furthermore, by (3.9, α (h 1 α (h β 4(I 1 + I + I 3 + I 4, where we have put I 1 := I := I 3 := I 4 := ( ( ( ( γ(h 1, x(ξ ( e Γ(h1,x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ, e Γ(h,x(ξ (γ(h 1, x(ξ γ(h, x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ, d ( dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ e Γ(h1,x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ, ( ( e Γ(h,x(ξ d 1 dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ d dξ γ(h, x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ. We get for all x and ξ by (3.3, (.3 and (.5 (3.13 e Γ(h1,x(ξ e Γ(h,x(ξ e Φ(x Γ(h 1, x(ξ Γ(h, x(ξ e Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x L 1 ( C 3 e Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x β.

10 1 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN elations (3.13, Hölder s inequality, (3.5, (.4, (.5 and (3.7 give us ( I 1 C3 γ(h 1, x(ξ e 1 Φ(x e 1 Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x β F (dx e βξ dξ C3L h 1 h β e Φ(x γ(h 1, x(ξ 4 e βξ dξf (dx + C3L C 4 h 1 h β e Φ(x γ(h 1, x 4 β F (dx C 3L C 4 M h 1 h β. For every ξ we obtain by (3.11 and (3.7 (3.14 e Φ(x (γ(h 1, x(ξ + γ(h, x(ξ F (dx e Φ(x (γ(h 1, x(ξ + γ(h, x(ξ F (dx ( C e Φ(x γ(h 1, x β F (dx + e Φ(x γ(h, x β F (dx 4CM. Using (3.3, Hölder s inequality, (3.14, (.6 and (3.5 we get ( I (γ(h 1, x(ξ + γ(h, x(ξe 1 Φ(x e 1 Φ(x (γ(h 1, x(ξ γ(h, x(ξf (dx e βξ dξ 4CM e Φ(x (γ(h 1, x(ξ γ(h, x(ξ e βξ dξf (dx + 4C MC 5 4C MC 5 L h 1 h β. e Φ(x γ(h 1, x(ξ γ(h, x(ξ β F (dx Using (3.13, Hölder s inequality, (3.5, (.5 and (3.7 gives us ( I 3 C3 d dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ e 1 Φ(x e 1 Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x β F (dx e βξ dξ C3L h 1 h β C3L h 1 h β e Φ(x d dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ e βξ dξf (dx e Φ(x γ(h 1, x β F (dx C 3L M h 1 h β. We obtain by (3.1, Hölder s inequality, (3.7, (.5 and (3.5 ( I 4 C3 γ(h, x β e 1 Φ(x e 1 Φ(x d dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ d dξ γ(h, x(ξ F (dx e βξ dξ C3M e Φ(x C3M d dξ γ(h 1, x(ξ d dξ γ(h, x(ξ e βξ dξf (dx e Φ(x γ(h 1, x γ(h, x β F (dx C 3ML h 1 h β. Summing up, we deduce that there is a constant K > such that (3.1 is satisfied for all h 1, h H β.

11 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS Theorem. Suppose Assumption 3.1 is fulfilled. Then, for each initial curve h L (Ω, F, P; H β there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, mean-square continuous H β -valued solution (f t t for the HJM equation (1.11 with f = lh satisfying [ ] (3.15 sup t [,T ] f t β < for all T, and there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, mean-square continuous mild and weak H β -valued solution (r t t for the HJMM equation (1.1 with r = h satisfying [ ] (3.16 sup t [,T ] r t β < for all T, which is given by r t := πu t f t, t. Moreover, the implied bond market (1.4 is free of arbitrage. Proof. By virtue of Theorem.1, Proposition 3.3 and (3.4, (3.5, (3.7, (.5, all assumptions from [, Cor. 1.9] are fulfilled, which therefore applies and establishes the claimed existence and uniqueness result. For all h H β, x and ξ we have by (3.3, (.3 and (.5 e Γ(h,x(ξ 1 Γ(h, x(ξ 1 eφ(x Γ(h, x(ξ ( eφ(x γ(h, x L 1 ( C 3 + eφ(x γ(h, x β. Integrating (1.6 we obtain, by using [16, Lemma 4.3.] and (3.17, (3.7 α HJM (h(ηdη = 1 ( Σ (h + e Γ(h,x 1 Γ(h, x F (dx for all h H β. Combining [3, Prop. 5.3] and [16, Lemma 4.3.3] (the latter result is only required if W is infinite dimensional, the probability measure P is a local martingale measure, and hence the bond market (1.4 is free of arbitrage. The case of Lévy-driven HJMM models is now a special case. We assume that the mark space is = e for some positive integer e N, equipped with its Borel σ-algebra = B( e. The measure F is given by e (3.18 F (B := 1 B (xe k F k (dx, B B( e k=1 where F 1,..., F e are Lévy measures on (, B( satisfying (3.19 (3. F k ({} =, k = 1,..., e ( x 1F k (dx <, k = 1,..., e and where the (e k k=1,...,e denote the unit vectors in e. Note that Definition (3.18 implies e (3.1 g(xf (dx = g(xe k F k (dx e k=1 for any nonnegative measurable function g : e. In particular, the support of F is contained in e k=1 span{e k}, the union of the coordinate axes in e. For each k = 1,..., e let δ k : H β Hβ be a vector field. We define γ : H β e Hβ as e (3. γ(h, x := δ k (hx k. k=1

12 1 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN Then, equation (1.1 corresponds to the situation where the term structure model is driven by several real-valued, independent Lévy processes with Lévy measures F k. For all h H β and ξ we set k (h(ξ := ξ δ k (h(ηdη, k = 1,..., e Assumption. We assume there exist constants N, ɛ > such that for all k = 1,..., e we have (3.3 e zx F k (dx <, z [ (1 + ɛn, (1 + ɛn] (3.4 { x >1} k (h(ξ N, h H β, ξ a constant L > such that (3.4 and (3.5 δ k (h 1 δ k (h β L h 1 h β, k = 1,..., e are satisfied for all h 1, h H β, and a constant M > such that (3.6 and (3.6 are satisfied for all h H β. δ k (h β M, k = 1,..., e Now, we obtain the statement of [19, Thm. 4.6] as a corollary Corollary. Suppose Assumption 3.5 is fulfilled. Then, for each initial curve h L (Ω, F, P; H β there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, mean-square continuous H β -valued solution (f t t for the HJM equation (1.11 with f = lh satisfying (3.15, and there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, mean-square continuous mild and weak H β -valued solution (r t t for the HJMM equation (1.1 with r = h satisfying (3.16, which is given by r t := πu t f t, t. Moreover, the implied bond market (1.4 is free of arbitrage. Proof. Using (3.4, the measurable function Φ : e defined as e Φ(x := N x k, x e satisfies (3.3. For each k = 1,..., e and every m N with m we have (3.7 x m e zx F k (dx <, z ( (1 + ɛn, (1 + ɛn. k=1 Indeed, let z ( (1 + ɛn, (1 + ɛn be arbitrary. There exists η (, ɛ such that z (1 + ηn. By (3., (3.3 and the basic inequality x m m!e x for x we obtain x m e zx F k (dx x m e (1+ηN x F k (dx { x ln (1+ηN } x m F k (dx + m! ((ɛ ηn m { x > ln (1+ηN } e (1+ɛN x F k (dx <, proving (3.7. Taking into account (3.1, (3.7, relations (3.5, (3.6 imply (3.5, (3.7. Furthermore, (3.7, the elementary inequalities e x 1 x 1 x e x, x e x 1 x e x, x and Lebesgue s theorem show that the cumulant generating functions Ψ k (z = (e zx 1 zxf k (dx, k = 1,..., e

13 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 13 belong to class C on the open interval ( (1 + ɛn, (1 + ɛn with derivatives Ψ k(z = x(e zx 1F k (dx, Ψ (m k (z = x m e zx F k (dx, m. Therefore, and because of (3.1, we can, for an arbitrary h H β, write α (h, which is defined in (3.8, as e ( α (h = δ k (hψ k δ k (ηdη. k=1 Hence, α (h is absolutely continuous with weak derivative (3.9. Consequently, Assumption 3.1 is fulfilled and Theorem 3.4 applies. Note that the boundedness assumptions (3.6, (3.7 of Theorem 3.4 resp. (3.6, (3.6 of Corollary 3.6 cannot be weakened substantially. For example, for arbitrage free term structure models driven by a single Brownian motion, it was shown in [31, Sec. 4.7] that for the simple case of proportional volatility, that is σ(h = σ h for some constant σ >, solutions necessarily explode. We mention, however, that [36, Sec. 6] contains some existence results for Lévy term structure models with linear volatility. 4. Positivity preserving term structure models driven by Wiener processes and Poisson measures In applications, we are often interested in term structure models producing positive forward curves. In this section, we characterize HJMM forward curve evolutions of the type (1.1, which preserve positivity, by means of the characteristics of the SPD. In the case of short rate models this can be characterized by the positivity of the short rate, a one-dimensional Markov process. In case of an infinite-factor evolution, as described by a generic HJMM equation (see for instance [], this problem is much more delicate. Indeed, one has to find conditions such that a Markov process defined by the HJMM equation (on a Hilbert space of forward rate curves stays in a small set of curves, namely the convex cone of positive curves bounded by a non-smooth set. Our strategy to solve this problem is the following: First we show by general semimartingale methods necessary conditions for positivity. These necessary conditions are basically described by the facts that the Itô drift is inward pointing and that the volatilities are parallel at the boundary of the set of non-negative functions. Taking those conditions we can also prove that the Stratonovich drift is inward pointing, since parallel volatilities produce parallel Stratonovich corrections (a fact which is not true for general closed convex sets, but holds true for the set of non-negative functions P. Then we reduce the sufficiency proof to two steps: First we essentially apply results from [34] in order to solve the pure diffusion case and then we slowly switch on the umps to see the general result. Let H β be the space of forward curves introduced in Section for some fixed β >. We introduce the half spaces and define the closed, convex cone H + ξ := {h H β h(ξ }, ξ P := ξ H + ξ

14 14 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN consisting of all nonnegative forward curves from H β. In what follows, we shall use that, by the continuity of the functions from H β, we can write P as P = H + ξ. Furthermore, we define the edges ξ (, P ξ := {h P h(ξ = }, ξ (,. First, we consider the positivity problem for general forward curve evolutions, where the HJM drift condition (1.6 is not necessarily satisfied, and afterwards we apply our results to the arbitrage free situation. We emphasize that, in the sequel, we assume the existence of solutions. Sufficient conditions for existence and uniqueness are provided in [] (we also mention the related articles [1] and [9] for general stochastic partial differential equations and in the previous Section 3 for the HJMM term structure equation (1.1. As in the previous section, we work on the space H β of forward curves from Section for some β >. At first glance, it looks reasonable to treat the positivity problem by working with weak solutions on H β. However, this is unfeasible, because the point evaluations at ξ (,, i.e., a linear functional ζ H β such that h(ξ = ζ, h for all h H β, do never belong to the domain D(( d dξ of the adoint operator. Indeed, a well-known mollifying technique shows that for each ξ (, the linear functional h h (ξ : D( d dξ is unbounded. Therefore treating the positivity problem with weak solutions does not bring an immediate advantage, hence we shall work with mild solutions on H β. Let measurable vector fields α : H β H β, σ : H β L (H β and γ : H β H β be given. Currently, we do not assume that the drift term α is given by the HJM drift condition (1.6. For each we define σ : H β H β as σ (h := λ σ(he. We assume that for each h P the HJM equation (4.1 df t = U t lα(πu t f t dt + U t lσ(πu t f t dw t + U tlγ(πu t f t, x(µ(dt, dx F (dxdt f = lh, has at least one H β -valued solution (f t t. Then, because of (.7, the transformation r t := πu t f t, t is a mild H β -valued solution of the HJMM equation (4. { drt = ( d dξ r t + α(r t dt + σ(r t dw t + γ(r t, x(µ(dt, dx F (dxdt r = h Definition. The HJMM equation (4. is said to be positivity preserving if for all h L (Ω, F, P; H β with P(h P = 1 there exists a solution (f t t of (4.1 with f = lh such that P( t {r t P } = 1, where r t := πu t f t, t. 4.. emark. Note that the seemingly weaker condition P(r t P = 1 for all t is equivalent to the condition of the previous definition due to the càdlàg property of the traectories Definition. The HJMM equation (4. is said to be locally positivity preserving if for all h L (Ω, F, P; H β with P(h P = 1 there exists a solution (f t t of (4.1 with f = lh and a strictly positive stopping time τ such that P( t {r t τ P } = 1, where r t := πu t f t, t Lemma. Let h P be arbitrary and let (f t t be a solution for (4.1 with f = lh. Set r t := πu t f t, t. The following two statements are equivalent:

15 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 15 (1 We have P( t {r t P } = 1. ( We have P( t [,T ] {f t(t } = 1 for all T (,. Proof. The claim follows, because the processes (r t t and (f t (T t [,T ] for an arbitrary T (, are càdlàg, and because the functions from H β are continuous Assumption. We assume that the vector fields α : H β H β and σ : H β L (H β are continuous and that h B γ(h, xf (dx is continuous on H β for all B with F (B < emark. Notice that, by Hölder s inequality, Assumption 4.5 is implied by Assumptions 4.1, 4.11 below, and therefore in particular by Assumption Proposition. Suppose Assumption 4.5 is fulfilled. If equation (4. is positivity preserving, then we have (4.3 γ(h, x(ξf (dx <, for all ξ (,, h P ξ (4.4 α(h(ξ γ(h, x(ξf (dx, for all ξ (,, h P ξ (4.5 (4.6 σ (h(ξ =, for all ξ (,, h P ξ and all h + γ(h, x P, for all h P and F -almost all x emark. Observe that condition (4.6 implies (4.7 γ(h, x(ξ, for all ξ (,, h P ξ and F -almost all x. Therefore, condition (4.3 is equivalent to γ(h, x(ξ F (dx <, for all ξ (,, h P ξ. Consequently, conditions (4.3 and (4.4 can be unified to γ(h, x(ξ F (dx α(h(ξ for all ξ (, and h P ξ. Proof. Let h P be arbitrary and let (f t t be a solution for (4.1 with f = lh such that P( t {r t P } = 1, where r t := πu t f t, t. By Lemma 4.4, for each T (, and every stopping time τ T we have (4.8 P(f τ (T = 1. Let φ U be a linear functional such that φ := φe for only finitely many, and let ψ : be a measurable function of the form ψ = c1 B with c > 1 and B satisfying F (B <. Let Z be the Doléans-Dade xponential ( Z t = φ β + ψ(x(µ(ds, dx F (dxds, t. t By [5, Thm. I.4.61] the process Z is a solution of Z t = 1 + t t φ Z s dβs + Z s ψ(x(µ(ds, dx F (dxds, t and, since ψ > 1, the process Z is a strictly positive local martingale. There exists a strictly positive stopping time τ 1 such that Z τ1 is a martingale. Due to the method of the moving frame, see [], we can use standard stochastic analysis, to

16 16 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN proceed further. For an arbitrary T (,, integration by parts yields (see [5, Thm. I.4.5] (4.9 f t (T Z t = t f s (T dz s + Taking into account the dynamics (4.1 we have (4.11 (4.1 f t (T = lh (T + + t t + s t f s (T Z s, t. t f(t c, Z c t = f s (T Z s = s t U s lα(πu s f s (T ds + Z s df s (T + f(t c, Z c t t U s lσ (πu s f s (T dβ s U s lγ(πu s f s, x(t (µ(ds, dx F (dxds, t t t φ Z s U s lσ (πu s f s (T ds, t Z s ψ(xu s lγ(πu s f s, x(t µ(ds, dx, t. Incorporating (4.1, (4.11 and (4.1 into (4.9, we obtain t ( f t (T Z t = M t + Z s U s lα(πu s f s (T + φ U s lσ (πu s f s (T ( ψ(xu s lγ(πu s f s, x(t F (dx ds, t where M is a local martingale with M =. There exists a strictly positive stopping time τ such that M τ is a martingale. By Assumption 4.5 there exist a strictly positive stopping time τ 3 and a constant α > such that U (t τ3lα(πu t τ3 f (t τ3 (T α, t. Let B := {x : h + γ(h, x / P }. In order to prove (4.6, it suffices, since F is σ-finite, to show that F (B C = for all C with F (C <. Suppose, on the contrary, there exists C with F (C < such that F (B C >. By the continuity of the functions from H β, there exists T (, such that F (B T C >, where B T := {x : h (T + γ(h, x(t < }. We obtain γ(h, x(t F (dx (h (T + γ(h, x(t F (dx <. B T C B T C By Assumption 4.5 and the left-continuity of the process f., there exist η > and a strictly positive stopping time τ 4 T such that U (t τ4lγ(πu (t τ4f (t τ4, x(t F (dx η, t. B T C Let φ :=, ψ := α+1 η 1 B T C and τ := 4 i=1 τ i. Taking expectation in (4.13 we obtain [f τ (T Z τ ] <, implying P(f τ (T < >, which contradicts (4.8. This yields (4.6. From now on, we assume that h P T for an arbitrary T (,. Suppose that σ (h (T for some. By the continuity of σ (see Assumption 4.5 there exist η > and a strictly positive stopping time τ 4 T such that U (t τ4lσ (πu t τ4 f (t τ4 (T η, t.

17 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS 17 Let φ U be the linear functional with φ = sign(σ (h (T α+1 η and φ k = for k. Furthermore, let ψ := and τ := 4 i=1 τ i. Taking expectation in (4.13 yields [f τ (T Z τ ] <, implying P(f τ (T < >, which contradicts (4.8. This proves (4.5. Now suppose γ(h, x(t F (dx =. Using Assumption 4.5, relation (4.7 and the σ-finiteness of F, there exist B with F (B < and a strictly positive stopping time τ 4 T such that 1 U (t τ4lγ(πu t τ4 f (t τ4, x(t F (dx ( α + 1, t. B Let φ :=, ψ := 1 1 B and τ := 4 i=1 τ i. Taking expectation in (4.13 we obtain [f τ (T Z τ ] <, implying P(f τ (T < >, which contradicts (4.8. This yields (4.3. Since F is σ-finite, there exists a sequence (B n n N with B n and F (B n <, n N. Next, we show for all n N the relation (4.14 α(h (T + ψ n (xγ(h, x(t F (dx, where ψ n := (1 1 n 1 B n. Suppose, on the contrary, that (4.14 is not satisfied for some n N. Using Assumption 4.5, there exist η > and a strictly positive stopping time τ 4 T such that U (t τ4lα(πu t f (t τ4 (T + ψ n (xu (t τ4lγ(πu t τ4 f (t τ4, x(t F (dx η, t. Let φ := and τ := 4 i=1 τ i. Taking expectation in (4.13 we obtain [f τ (T Z τ ] <, implying P(f τ (T < >, which contradicts (4.8. This yields (4.14. By (4.14, (4.3 and Lebesgue s theorem, we conclude ( emark. The Cox-Ingersoll-oss (CI model [7] is celebrated for its feature to produce nonnegative interest rates. At this point, it is worth pointing out that the Hull-White extension of the CI model (HWCI is not positivity preserving. Indeed, in Musiela parametrization its term structure dynamics are given by { drt = ( d dξ r t + α HJM (r t dt + σ(r t dw t r = h, where W is a one-dimensional Wiener process and the vector fields α HJM, σ : H β Hβ are defined as α HJM (h := ρ h( λλ, σ(h := ρ h( λ, h H β h H β where ρ > is a constant, h h( : H β denotes the evaluation of the short rate, and where λ Hβ is a function with λ(x > for all x such that Λ = λ(ηdη satisfies a certain iccati equation, see [1, Sec. 6.] for more details. Note that Assumption 4.5 is satisfied, because the vector fields α HJM, σ : H β Hβ are continuous, but condition (4.5 from Proposition 4.7 does not hold, because σ only depends on the current state of the short rate. Hence, the HWCI model cannot be positivity preserving.

18 18 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN Indeed, we can also verify this directly as follows. According to [1, Sec. 6.], for any initial curve h H β the short rate t = r t (, t has the dynamics { dt = (b(t c t dt + ρ t dw t (4.15 = h ( for some constant c and a time-dependent function b = b(h :. Due to [4], for each starting point h ( the stochastic differential equation (4.15 has a unique strong solution, and, according to [17], this solution is nonnegative if and only if h ( and b(t for all t. By [18, Prop. 5.], the forward rates are given by f(t, T = T which implies for the initial forward curve h (T = T t b(sλ(t sds + λ(t t t, b(sλ(t sds + λ(t h (, T. Having in mind that λ(t > for all t, we see that for certain nonnegative initial curves h P the function b can also reach negative values, which yields negative short rates. For example, take an initial curve h P with h ( > and h (T = for some T >. We shall now present sufficient conditions for positivity preserving term structure models. In the sequel, we will require the following linear growth and Lipschitz conditions Assumption. We assume γ(, x βf (dx < and that there is a constant K > such that ( 1/ γ(h 1, x γ(h, x βf (dx K h 1 h β for all h 1, h H β Assumption. We assume there is a constant L > such that for all h 1, h H β. α(h 1 α(h β L h 1 h β, σ(h 1 σ(h L (H β L h 1 h β This ensures existence and uniqueness of solutions by [, Cor. 1.9] Lemma. Suppose Assumptions 4.1, 4.11 are fulfilled, and for each h P we have P( t {r t P } = 1, where (r t t denotes the mild solution for (4. with r = h. Then, the HJMM equation (4. is positivity preserving. Proof. Let h L (Ω, F, P; H β with P(h P = 1 be arbitrary. There exists a sequence (h n n N L (Ω, F, P; H β such that h n h in L (Ω, F, P; H β and for each n N we have P(h n P = 1 and h n has only a finite number of values. By assumption we have P( t {rt n P } = 1 for all n N. Applying [, Prop. 9.1] yields [ ] sup t [,T ] r t rt n β showing that P( t {r t P } = 1. for all T, For the following Lemma 4.14 we prepare an auxiliary result, which is proven in Appendix A.

19 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS Lemma. Let τ be a bounded stopping time. We define the new filtration ( F t t by F t := F τ+t, the new U-valued process W by W t := W τ+t W τ and the new random measure µ on by µ(ω; B := µ(ω; B τ(ω, B B(, where B τ := {(t + τ, x : (t, x B}. Then W is a Q-Wiener process with respect to ( F t t and µ is a homogeneous Poisson random measure on with respect to ( F t t having the compensator dt F (dx. Moreover, we have the expansion W = (4.16 λ β e, where β defined as β t := β τ+t β τ is a sequence of real-valued independent ( F t - Brownian motions. Furthermore, if (r t t is a weak solution for (4., then the ( F t -adapted process ( r t t defined by r t := r τ+t is a weak solution for (4.17 { d rt = ( d dξ r t + α( r t dt + σ( r t d W t + γ( r t, x( µ(dt, dx F (dxdt r = r τ. Proof. See Appendix A Lemma. Suppose Assumptions 4.1, 4.11 are fulfilled. If equation (4. is locally positivity preserving and we have (4.6, then equation (4. is positivity preserving. Proof. Let h L (Ω, F, P; H β with P(h P = 1 be arbitrary. Moreover, let (r t t be the mild solution for (4. with r = h. We define the stopping time (4.18 τ := inf{t : r t / P }. By the closedness of P and (4.6 we have r τ P almost surely on {τ < }. We claim that P(τ = = 1. Assume, on the contrary, that (4.19 P(τ < N > for some N N. Let τ be the bounded stopping time τ := τ N. We define the new filtration ( F t t, the new Q-Wiener process W and the new Poisson random measure µ as in Lemma Note that r τ L (Ω, F, P; H β, because, by (3.16, we have [ [ r τ β] sup r t β t [,N] ] <. By Lemma 4.13, the ( F t -adapted process r t := r τ+t is the unique mild solution for (4.17. Since equation (4. is locally positivity preserving and P(r τ P = 1, there exists a strictly positive stopping time τ 1 such that P( t r t τ1 P = 1. Since {τ < N} {τ = τ}, we obtain r τ+t P almost surely on [, τ 1 ] {τ < N}, which is a contradiction because of (4.19 and the Definition (4.18 of τ. Consequently, we have P(τ = = 1, whence equation (4. is positivity preserving Assumption. We assume σ C (H β ; L (H β, and that the vector field (4. is globally Lipschitz on H β. h Dσ (hσ (h

20 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN emark. Note that Assumption 4.15 is satisfied if σ C b (H β; L (H β and the series (4. converges for every h H β Lemma. Suppose Assumption 4.15 and relation (4.5 are fulfilled. Then we have ( Dσ (hσ (h (ξ =, for all ξ (,, h P ξ. Proof. Let ξ (, be arbitrary. It suffices to show ( Dσ (hσ (h (ξ = for all h P ξ and all. Therefore let be fixed and denote σ = σ. By assumption for all h with h(ξ = we have that σ(h(ξ =. In other words the volatility vector field σ is parallel to the boundary at boundary elements of P. We denote the local flow of the Lipschitz vector field σ by Fl being defined on a small time interval ] ɛ, ɛ[ around time and a small neighborhood of each element h P. We state first that the flow Fl leaves the set P invariant, i.e., Fl t (h if h, by convexity and closedness of the cone of positive functions due to [39]. Indeed, P is a closed and convex cone, whose supporting hyperplanes l (a linear functional l is called supporting hyperplane of P at h if l(p and l(h = are given by appropriate positive measures µ on via l(h = h(ξµ(dξ, whence condition (4 from [39] is fulfilled due to (4.5. Next we show that even more holds: the solution Fl t (h evaluated at ξ vanishes if h(ξ =, which we show directly. Indeed, let us additionally fix h P ξ, i.e., h and h(ξ =. Looking now at the Picard-Lindelöf approximation scheme c (n+1 (t = h + t σ(c (n (sds with c (n ( = h and c ( (s = h for s, t ] ɛ, ɛ[ and n, we see by induction that under our assumptions c (n (t(ξ = for all n and t ] ɛ, ɛ[ for the given fixed element h. Consequently as n we obtain that Fl t (h(ξ =, which is the limit of c (n (t. Therefore (Dσ(hσ(h(ξ = d ds s=σ(fl s (h(ξ =, since Fl t (h by invariance and Fl t (h(ξ = by the previous consideration lead to σ(fl t (h(ξ = for t ] ɛ, ɛ[. Notice that we did not need the global Lipschitz property of the Stratonovich correction for the proof of this lemma. Before we show sufficiency for the HJMM equation (4. with umps, we consider the pure diffusion case. Notice that, due to Lemma 4.17, the condition (4.4 is in fact equivalent to the very same condition formulated with the Stratonovich drift σ, defined in (4.1 below, instead of α, since the Stratonovich correction vanishes at the boundary of P. In order to treat the pure diffusion case, we apply [34], which, by using the support theorem provided in [33], offers a general characterization of stochastic invariance of closed sets for SPDs. Other results for positivity preserving SPDs, where, in contrast to our framework, the state space is an L -space, can be found in [7] and [3]. The results from [3] have been used in [36] in order to derive some positivity results for Lévy term structure models on L -spaces.

21 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS Proposition. Suppose Assumptions 4.11, 4.15 are fulfilled and γ. If conditions (4.4, (4.5 are satisfied, then equation (4. is positivity preserving. Proof. In view of Lemma 4.1, it suffices to show that for all h P we have P( t {r t P } = 1, where (r t t denotes the mild solution for (4. with r = h. Moreover, we may assume that the vector fields α, σ and h σ (h := α(h 1 (4.1 Dσ (hσ (h are bounded in order to apply Nakayama s beautiful support theorem from [34]. Indeed, for n N we choose a bump function ψ n C (H β ; [, 1] such that ψ n 1 on B n ( and supp(ψ n B n+1 ( and define the vector fields α n (h := ψ n (hα(h, h H β σ n (h := ψ n (hσ(h, h H β. These vector fields and h σn(h := α n (h 1 Dσ n(hσn(h are bounded by the Lipschitz continuity of α, σ and σ, and Assumptions 4.11, 4.15 as well as conditions (4.4, (4.5 are again satisfied. Now, we show that the semigroup Nagumo s condition (3 from [33, Prop. 1.1] is fulfilled due to conditions (4.4 and (4.5. Introducing the distance d P (h from P as minimal distance of h H β from P, we can formulate Nagumo s condition as (4. lim inf t 1 t d P (S t h + tσ (h + tσ(hu = for all u U and h P. Fix now h P and u U and introduce the abbreviation σ = σ + σ( u, then we obviously have S t h + tσ (h + tσ(hu S Fl σ t t (h β = t Fl σ σ(h S t (h h t t, t > β which means that 1 lim t t S th + tσ (h + tσ(hu S Fl σ t t (h β =. Hence, Nagumo s condition (4. can equivalently be formulated as (4.3 lim inf t 1 t d P (S t Fl σ t (h =, for the particular choice of u U and h P, since the shortest distance proector onto P is a Lipschitz continuous map. Due to conditions (4.4, (4.5 and Lemma 4.17, the semiflow Fl σ leaves P invariant by [39], the semigroup (S t t certainly, too, and therefore we have d P (S t Fl σ t (h =, t whence Nagumo s condition (4.3 is more than satisfied. Finally, the next result states the sufficient conditions under which we can conclude that equation (4. is positivity preserving Proposition. Suppose Assumptions 4.1, 4.11, 4.15 and conditions (4.3 (4.6 are fulfilled. Then, equation (4. is positivity preserving. Proof. Since the measure F is σ-finite, there exists a sequence (B n n N with B n and F (B n < for all n N. Let h L (Ω, F, P; H β be arbitrary. elations (4.4, (4.7, (4.5, Proposition 4.18 and (4.6 together with the closedness

22 DAMI FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN of P yield that, for each n N, the mild solution (r n t t of the stochastic partial differential equation (4.4 drt n = ( d dξ rn t + α(rt n B n γ(rt n, xf (dxdt + σ(rt n dw t + B n γ(rt, n xµ(dt, dx r n = h satisfies P( t r n t τ P = 1, where τ denotes the strictly positive stopping time τ := inf{t : µ([, t] B n = 1}. By virtue of Lemma 4.14, for each n N equation (4.4 is positivity preserving. According to [, Prop. 9.1] we have [ ] sup t [,T ] r t rt n β for all T, proving that equation (4. is positivity preserving. 4.. Theorem. Suppose Assumptions 4.1, 4.11, 4.15 are fulfilled. Then, for each initial curve h L (Ω, F, P; H β there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, meansquare continuous H β -valued solution (f t t for the HJM equation (4.1 with f = lh satisfying (3.15, and there exists a unique adapted, càdlàg, mean-square continuous mild and weak H β -valued solution (r t t for the HJMM equation (4. with r = h satisfying (3.16, which is given by r t := πu t f t, t. Moreover, equation (4. is positivity preserving if and only if we have (4.3 (4.6. Proof. The statement follows from [, Cor. 1.9], Proposition 4.7 (see also emark 4.6 and Proposition emark. Note that Theorem 4. is also valid on other state spaces. The only requirements are that the Hilbert space H consists of real-valued, continuous functions, on which the point evaluations are continuous linear functionals, and that the shift semigroup extends to a strongly continuous group on a larger Hilbert space H. 4.. emark. For the particular situation where equation (4. has no umps, Theorem 4. corresponds to the statement of [3, Thm. 3], where positivity on weighted L -spaces is investigated. Since point evaluations are discontinuous functionals on L -spaces, the conditions in [3] are formulated by taking other appropriate linear functionals. We shall now consider the arbitrage free situation. Let α = α HJM : H β H β in (4. be defined according to the HJM drift condition ( Proposition. Conditions (4.3 (4.6 are satisfied if and only if we have (4.5, (4.6 and (4.5 γ(h, x(ξ =, ξ (,, h P ξ and F -almost all x. Proof. Provided (4.5, (4.6 are fulfilled, conditions (4.3, (4.4 are satisfied if and only if we have (4.3 and (4.6 γ(h, x(ξe Γ(h,x(ξ F (dx, ξ (,, h P ξ because the drift α is given by (1.6. By (4.7, relations (4.3, (4.6 are fulfilled if and only if we have (4.5. Now let, as in Section 3, measurable vector fields σ : H β L (Hβ and γ : H β Hβ be given, where β > β is a real number.

23 TM STUCTU MODLS DIVN BY POISSON MASUS Theorem. Suppose Assumptions 3.1, 4.15 are fulfilled. Then, the statement of Theorem 3.4 is valid, and, in addition, the HJMM equation (1.1 is positivity preserving if and only if we have (4.5, (4.6, (4.5. Proof. The statement follows from Theorem 3.4, Theorem 4. and Proposition 4.3. Finally, let us consider the Lévy case, treated at the end of Section 3. In this framework, the following statement is valid Proposition. Conditions (4.5, (4.6 and (4.5 are satisfied if and only if we have (4.5 and (4.7 (4.8 h + δ k (hx P, h P, k = 1,..., e and F k -almost all x δ k (h(ξ =, ξ (,, h P ξ and all k = 1,..., e with F k ( >. Proof. The claim follows from the Definition (3.18 of F and the Definition (3. of γ Corollary. Suppose Assumption 3.5, 4.15 are fulfilled. Then, the statement of Corollary 3.6 is valid, and, in addition, the HJMM equation (1.1 is positivity preserving if and only if we have (4.5, (4.7, (4.8. Proof. The assertion follows from Theorem 4.4 and Proposition 4.5. Our above results on arbitrage free, positivity preserving term structure models apply in particular for local state dependent volatilities. The following two results are obvious Proposition. Suppose for each there exists σ :, and there are γ : and φ : (, such that σ (h(ξ = φ( h β σ (ξ, h(ξ, (h, ξ H β, for all γ(h, x(ξ = φ( h β γ(ξ, h(ξ, x, (h, x, ξ H β. Then, conditions (4.5, (4.6, (4.5 are fulfilled if and only if (4.9 (4.3 (4.31 σ (ξ, =, ξ (,, for all y + z γ(ξ, y, x, ξ (,, y, z φ( and F -almost all x γ(ξ,, x =, ξ (, and F -almost all x. Lévy term structure models with local state dependent volatilities have been studied in [36] and [8]. In the framework of Proposition 4.5 we obtain the following result Proposition. Suppose for each there is σ :, for all k = 1,..., e there is δ k : and there exists φ : (, such that σ (h(ξ = φ( h β σ (ξ, h(ξ, (h, ξ H β, for all δ k (h(ξ = φ( h β δ k (ξ, h(ξ, (h, ξ H β, k = 1,..., e. Then, conditions (4.5, (4.7, (4.8 are fulfilled if and only if we have (4.9 and (4.3 (4.33 y + zx δ k (ξ, y, ξ (,, y, z φ(, k = 1,..., e and F k -almost all x δ k (ξ, =, ξ (, and all k = 1,..., e with F k ( >.

INVARIANT MANIFOLDS WITH BOUNDARY FOR JUMP-DIFFUSIONS

INVARIANT MANIFOLDS WITH BOUNDARY FOR JUMP-DIFFUSIONS INVARIANT MANIFOLDS WITH BOUNDARY FOR JUMP-DIFFUSIONS DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN Abstract. We provide necessary and sufficient conditions for stochastic invariance of finite dimensional

More information

STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS AND SUBMANIFOLDS IN HILBERT SPACES

STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS AND SUBMANIFOLDS IN HILBERT SPACES STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFRNTIAL QUATIONS AND SUBMANIFOLDS IN HILBRT SPACS DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ, STFAN TAPP, AND JOSF TICHMANN Abstract. The goal of this appendix is to provide results about stochastic partial

More information

A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES

A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. In a work of van Gaans (25a) stochastic integrals are regarded as L 2 -curves. In Filipović and Tappe (28) we have shown the connection

More information

Affine realizations with affine state processes. the HJMM equation

Affine realizations with affine state processes. the HJMM equation for the HJMM equation Stefan Tappe Leibniz Universität Hannover 7th General AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference Session on Interest Rates September 7th, 2015 Introduction Consider a stochastic partial differential

More information

STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY PROCESSES WITH INDEPENDENT INCREMENTS

STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY PROCESSES WITH INDEPENDENT INCREMENTS STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY PROCESSES WITH INDEPENDENT INCREMENTS DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ AND STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. This article considers infinite dimensional stochastic differential equations

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

TIME-HOMOGENEOUS AFFINE STATE PROCESSES FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS

TIME-HOMOGENEOUS AFFINE STATE PROCESSES FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS TIME-HOMOGENEOUS AFFINE STATE PROCESSES FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. The goal of this paper is to clarify for which starting points the state processes of a stochastic

More information

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Title Author(s) Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4() P.493-P.54 Issue Date 3-6 Text

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 15. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

EXISTENCE OF AFFINE REALIZATIONS FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY LÉVY PROCESSES

EXISTENCE OF AFFINE REALIZATIONS FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY LÉVY PROCESSES EXISTENCE OF AFFINE REALIZATIONS FOR STOCHASTIC PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY LÉVY PROCESSES STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. The goal of this paper is to clarify when a semilinear stochastic partial

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t Lecture 12 1 Brownian motion: the Markov property Let C := C(0, ), R) be the space of continuous functions mapping from 0, ) to R, in which a Brownian motion (B t ) t 0 almost surely takes its value. Let

More information

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations with Levy Noise

Stochastic Partial Differential Equations with Levy Noise Stochastic Partial Differential Equations with Levy Noise An Evolution Equation Approach S..PESZAT and J. ZABCZYK Institute of Mathematics, Polish Academy of Sciences' CAMBRIDGE UNIVERSITY PRESS Contents

More information

Evaluation of the HJM equation by cubature methods for SPDE

Evaluation of the HJM equation by cubature methods for SPDE Evaluation of the HJM equation by cubature methods for SPDEs TU Wien, Institute for mathematical methods in Economics Kyoto, September 2008 Motivation Arbitrage-free simulation of non-gaussian bond markets

More information

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ Abstract. This paper discusses separable term structure diffusion models in an arbitrage-free environment. Using general consistency

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING 218. HOMEWORK PROBLEMS PROF. YURI BAKHTIN Instructions. You are allowed to work on solutions in groups, but you are required to write up solutions on your own. Please

More information

Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals

Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals Functional Limit theorems for the quadratic variation of a continuous time random walk and for certain stochastic integrals Noèlia Viles Cuadros BCAM- Basque Center of Applied Mathematics with Prof. Enrico

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem Koichiro TAKAOKA Dept of Applied Physics, Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract M Yor constructed a family

More information

THE GEOMETRY OF INTEREST RATE MODELS

THE GEOMETRY OF INTEREST RATE MODELS THE GEOMETRY OF INTEREST RATE MODELS Damir Filipović, University of Munich www.math.lmu.de/ filipo Dimitsana Summer School Stochastic Differential Geometry and Applications in Finance 1 17 July 25 1 Bond

More information

Poisson random measure: motivation

Poisson random measure: motivation : motivation The Lévy measure provides the expected number of jumps by time unit, i.e. in a time interval of the form: [t, t + 1], and of a certain size Example: ν([1, )) is the expected number of jumps

More information

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval Krzysztof Burdzy, Weining Kang and Kavita Ramanan University of Washington and Carnegie Mellon University Abstract: We consider the Skorokhod problem

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018 A short note on Anticipative portfolio optimization B. D Auria a,b,1,, J.-A. Salmerón a,1 a Dpto. Estadística, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Avda. de la Universidad 3, 8911, Leganés (Madrid Spain b

More information

Completeness of bond market driven by Lévy process

Completeness of bond market driven by Lévy process Completeness of bond market driven by Lévy process arxiv:812.1796v1 [math.p] 9 Dec 28 Michał Baran Mathematics Department of Cardinal Stefan Wyszyński University in Warsaw, Poland Jerzy Zabczyk Institute

More information

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time Stefan Ankirchner Institute for Applied Mathematics University of Bonn Endenicher Allee 6 D-535 Bonn ankirchner@hcm.uni-bonn.de Philipp Strack Bonn Graduate School

More information

Interest Rate Models:

Interest Rate Models: 1/17 Interest Rate Models: from Parametric Statistics to Infinite Dimensional Stochastic Analysis René Carmona Bendheim Center for Finance ORFE & PACM, Princeton University email: rcarmna@princeton.edu

More information

Information and Credit Risk

Information and Credit Risk Information and Credit Risk M. L. Bedini Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest - Friedrich Schiller Universität, Jena Jena, March 2011 M. L. Bedini (Université de Bretagne Occidentale, Brest Information

More information

HEATH JARROW MORTON INTEREST RATE DYNAMICS AND APPROXIMATELY CONSISTENT FORWARD RATE CURVES

HEATH JARROW MORTON INTEREST RATE DYNAMICS AND APPROXIMATELY CONSISTENT FORWARD RATE CURVES HEATH JARROW MORTON INTEREST RATE DYNAMICS AND APPROXIMATELY CONSISTENT FORWARD RATE CURVES CLAUDIA LA CHIOMA AND BENEDETTO PICCOLI Abstract We study a finite dimensional approach to the Heath Jarrow Morton

More information

Exercises in stochastic analysis

Exercises in stochastic analysis Exercises in stochastic analysis Franco Flandoli, Mario Maurelli, Dario Trevisan The exercises with a P are those which have been done totally or partially) in the previous lectures; the exercises with

More information

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations 1. Stochastic Processes and 1. Stoch. pr., A stochastic process (X t ) t T is a collection of random variables on (Ω, F) with values in a measurable space (S, S), i.e., for all t, In our case X t : Ω S

More information

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes BMS Basic Course Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III Michael Scheutzow Lecture Notes Technische Universität Berlin Sommersemester 218 preliminary version October 12th 218 Contents

More information

A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1

A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1 Chapter 3 A Change of Variable Formula with Local Time-Space for Bounded Variation Lévy Processes with Application to Solving the American Put Option Problem 1 Abstract We establish a change of variable

More information

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Stochastic Processes Winter Term 2016-2017 Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Contents 1 Preliminaries 5 1.1 Uniform integrability.............................. 5 1.2

More information

Squared Bessel Process with Delay

Squared Bessel Process with Delay Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Articles and Preprints Department of Mathematics 216 Squared Bessel Process with Delay Harry Randolph Hughes Southern Illinois University Carbondale, hrhughes@siu.edu

More information

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij Stochastic integration P.J.C. Spreij this version: April 22, 29 Contents 1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1 General theory............................... 1 1.2 Stopping times...............................

More information

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition David pplebaum Probability and Statistics Department,

More information

Wiener Measure and Brownian Motion

Wiener Measure and Brownian Motion Chapter 16 Wiener Measure and Brownian Motion Diffusion of particles is a product of their apparently random motion. The density u(t, x) of diffusing particles satisfies the diffusion equation (16.1) u

More information

We denote the space of distributions on Ω by D ( Ω) 2.

We denote the space of distributions on Ω by D ( Ω) 2. Sep. 1 0, 008 Distributions Distributions are generalized functions. Some familiarity with the theory of distributions helps understanding of various function spaces which play important roles in the study

More information

Modelling energy forward prices Representation of ambit fields

Modelling energy forward prices Representation of ambit fields Modelling energy forward prices Representation of ambit fields Fred Espen Benth Department of Mathematics University of Oslo, Norway In collaboration with Heidar Eyjolfsson, Barbara Rüdiger and Andre Süss

More information

Stochastic Differential Equations.

Stochastic Differential Equations. Chapter 3 Stochastic Differential Equations. 3.1 Existence and Uniqueness. One of the ways of constructing a Diffusion process is to solve the stochastic differential equation dx(t) = σ(t, x(t)) dβ(t)

More information

Gaussian Processes. 1. Basic Notions

Gaussian Processes. 1. Basic Notions Gaussian Processes 1. Basic Notions Let T be a set, and X : {X } T a stochastic process, defined on a suitable probability space (Ω P), that is indexed by T. Definition 1.1. We say that X is a Gaussian

More information

Applications of Ito s Formula

Applications of Ito s Formula CHAPTER 4 Applications of Ito s Formula In this chapter, we discuss several basic theorems in stochastic analysis. Their proofs are good examples of applications of Itô s formula. 1. Lévy s martingale

More information

Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes

Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes Exponential martingales: uniform integrability results and applications to point processes Alexander Sokol Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Copenhagen 26 September, 2012 1 / 39 Agenda

More information

Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration

Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration Lecture 19: L 2 -Stochastic integration 1 of 12 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration The stochastic integral for processes

More information

Reflected Brownian Motion

Reflected Brownian Motion Chapter 6 Reflected Brownian Motion Often we encounter Diffusions in regions with boundary. If the process can reach the boundary from the interior in finite time with positive probability we need to decide

More information

Malliavin Calculus: Analysis on Gaussian spaces

Malliavin Calculus: Analysis on Gaussian spaces Malliavin Calculus: Analysis on Gaussian spaces Josef Teichmann ETH Zürich Oxford 2011 Isonormal Gaussian process A Gaussian space is a (complete) probability space together with a Hilbert space of centered

More information

ON THE GEOMETRY OF THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES

ON THE GEOMETRY OF THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES ON THE GEOMETRY OF THE TERM STRUCTURE OF INTEREST RATES DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ AND JOSEF TEICHMANN Abstract. We present recently developed geometric methods for the analysis of finite dimensional term structure

More information

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Brownian motion Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Mostly taken from Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus by I. Karatzas and S. Shreve Samy T. Brownian motion Probability Theory

More information

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 29,4 (22), pp. 387 398 Mariusz Michta (Zielona Góra) OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS Abstract. A martingale problem approach is used first to analyze

More information

4 Hilbert spaces. The proof of the Hilbert basis theorem is not mathematics, it is theology. Camille Jordan

4 Hilbert spaces. The proof of the Hilbert basis theorem is not mathematics, it is theology. Camille Jordan The proof of the Hilbert basis theorem is not mathematics, it is theology. Camille Jordan Wir müssen wissen, wir werden wissen. David Hilbert We now continue to study a special class of Banach spaces,

More information

Strong uniqueness for stochastic evolution equations with possibly unbounded measurable drift term

Strong uniqueness for stochastic evolution equations with possibly unbounded measurable drift term 1 Strong uniqueness for stochastic evolution equations with possibly unbounded measurable drift term Enrico Priola Torino (Italy) Joint work with G. Da Prato, F. Flandoli and M. Röckner Stochastic Processes

More information

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define Homework, Real Analysis I, Fall, 2010. (1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define ρ(f, g) = 1 0 f(x) g(x) dx. Show that

More information

Doléans measures. Appendix C. C.1 Introduction

Doléans measures. Appendix C. C.1 Introduction Appendix C Doléans measures C.1 Introduction Once again all random processes will live on a fixed probability space (Ω, F, P equipped with a filtration {F t : 0 t 1}. We should probably assume the filtration

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

Introduction to Random Diffusions

Introduction to Random Diffusions Introduction to Random Diffusions The main reason to study random diffusions is that this class of processes combines two key features of modern probability theory. On the one hand they are semi-martingales

More information

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES APPLICATIONES MATHEMATICAE 25,3 (1998), pp. 381 386 E. IGNACZAK (Szczecin) A. PASZKIEWICZ ( Lódź) EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES Abstract. We prove that under some topological assumptions

More information

Some Properties of NSFDEs

Some Properties of NSFDEs Chenggui Yuan (Swansea University) Some Properties of NSFDEs 1 / 41 Some Properties of NSFDEs Chenggui Yuan Swansea University Chenggui Yuan (Swansea University) Some Properties of NSFDEs 2 / 41 Outline

More information

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS Di Girolami, C. and Russo, F. Osaka J. Math. 51 (214), 729 783 GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS CRISTINA DI GIROLAMI and FRANCESCO RUSSO (Received

More information

An introduction to Birkhoff normal form

An introduction to Birkhoff normal form An introduction to Birkhoff normal form Dario Bambusi Dipartimento di Matematica, Universitá di Milano via Saldini 50, 0133 Milano (Italy) 19.11.14 1 Introduction The aim of this note is to present an

More information

Cores for generators of some Markov semigroups

Cores for generators of some Markov semigroups Cores for generators of some Markov semigroups Giuseppe Da Prato, Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Italy and Michael Röckner Faculty of Mathematics, University of Bielefeld, Germany and Department of

More information

Regularity of the density for the stochastic heat equation

Regularity of the density for the stochastic heat equation Regularity of the density for the stochastic heat equation Carl Mueller 1 Department of Mathematics University of Rochester Rochester, NY 15627 USA email: cmlr@math.rochester.edu David Nualart 2 Department

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet

Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet LATP June 5, 2011 A ratchet source : wikipedia Plan 1 Introduction : The model of Haigh 2 3 Hypothesis (Biological) : The population

More information

Linear Ordinary Differential Equations

Linear Ordinary Differential Equations MTH.B402; Sect. 1 20180703) 2 Linear Ordinary Differential Equations Preliminaries: Matrix Norms. Denote by M n R) the set of n n matrix with real components, which can be identified the vector space R

More information

13 The martingale problem

13 The martingale problem 19-3-2012 Notations Ω complete metric space of all continuous functions from [0, + ) to R d endowed with the distance d(ω 1, ω 2 ) = k=1 ω 1 ω 2 C([0,k];H) 2 k (1 + ω 1 ω 2 C([0,k];H) ), ω 1, ω 2 Ω. F

More information

Appendix B Convex analysis

Appendix B Convex analysis This version: 28/02/2014 Appendix B Convex analysis In this appendix we review a few basic notions of convexity and related notions that will be important for us at various times. B.1 The Hausdorff distance

More information

Consistency Problems for HJM Interest Rate Models

Consistency Problems for HJM Interest Rate Models Diss. ETH No. 1363 Consistency Problems for HJM Interest Rate Models A dissertation submitted to the SWISS FEDERAL INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY ZURICH for the degree of Dr. sc. math. presented by DAMIR FILIPOVIĆ

More information

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY 1. The Hopf-Rinow Theorem Recall that a Riemannian manifold (M, g) is called geodesically complete if the maximal defining interval of any geodesic is R. On the other

More information

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models Purpose: Study Risk Measures taking into account the model uncertainty in mathematical finance. Plan 1 Non-dominated Models Model Uncertainty Fundamental topological Properties 2 Risk Measures on L p (c)

More information

Fourier Transform & Sobolev Spaces

Fourier Transform & Sobolev Spaces Fourier Transform & Sobolev Spaces Michael Reiter, Arthur Schuster Summer Term 2008 Abstract We introduce the concept of weak derivative that allows us to define new interesting Hilbert spaces the Sobolev

More information

ON WEAKLY NONLINEAR BACKWARD PARABOLIC PROBLEM

ON WEAKLY NONLINEAR BACKWARD PARABOLIC PROBLEM ON WEAKLY NONLINEAR BACKWARD PARABOLIC PROBLEM OLEG ZUBELEVICH DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS THE BUDGET AND TREASURY ACADEMY OF THE MINISTRY OF FINANCE OF THE RUSSIAN FEDERATION 7, ZLATOUSTINSKY MALIY PER.,

More information

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( )

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( ) Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio (2014-2015) Etienne Tanré - Olivier Faugeras INRIA - Team Tosca November 26th, 2014 E. Tanré (INRIA - Team Tosca) Mathematical

More information

ON THE REGULARITY OF SAMPLE PATHS OF SUB-ELLIPTIC DIFFUSIONS ON MANIFOLDS

ON THE REGULARITY OF SAMPLE PATHS OF SUB-ELLIPTIC DIFFUSIONS ON MANIFOLDS Bendikov, A. and Saloff-Coste, L. Osaka J. Math. 4 (5), 677 7 ON THE REGULARITY OF SAMPLE PATHS OF SUB-ELLIPTIC DIFFUSIONS ON MANIFOLDS ALEXANDER BENDIKOV and LAURENT SALOFF-COSTE (Received March 4, 4)

More information

{σ x >t}p x. (σ x >t)=e at.

{σ x >t}p x. (σ x >t)=e at. 3.11. EXERCISES 121 3.11 Exercises Exercise 3.1 Consider the Ornstein Uhlenbeck process in example 3.1.7(B). Show that the defined process is a Markov process which converges in distribution to an N(0,σ

More information

5 Compact linear operators

5 Compact linear operators 5 Compact linear operators One of the most important results of Linear Algebra is that for every selfadjoint linear map A on a finite-dimensional space, there exists a basis consisting of eigenvectors.

More information

Brownian Motion on Manifold

Brownian Motion on Manifold Brownian Motion on Manifold QI FENG Purdue University feng71@purdue.edu August 31, 2014 QI FENG (Purdue University) Brownian Motion on Manifold August 31, 2014 1 / 26 Overview 1 Extrinsic construction

More information

ON THE UNIQUENESS PROPERTY FOR PRODUCTS OF SYMMETRIC INVARIANT PROBABILITY MEASURES

ON THE UNIQUENESS PROPERTY FOR PRODUCTS OF SYMMETRIC INVARIANT PROBABILITY MEASURES Georgian Mathematical Journal Volume 9 (2002), Number 1, 75 82 ON THE UNIQUENESS PROPERTY FOR PRODUCTS OF SYMMETRIC INVARIANT PROBABILITY MEASURES A. KHARAZISHVILI Abstract. Two symmetric invariant probability

More information

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem Lecture 22: Girsanov s Theorem of 8 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 25 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem An example Consider a finite Gaussian random walk X n = n

More information

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Probability Surveys Vol. 3 (26) 345 412 ISSN: 1549-5787 DOI: 1.1214/1549578614 An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Ashkan Nikeghbali ETHZ Departement Mathematik, Rämistrasse 11, HG G16

More information

A Limit Theorem for the Squared Norm of Empirical Distribution Functions

A Limit Theorem for the Squared Norm of Empirical Distribution Functions University of Wisconsin Milwaukee UWM Digital Commons Theses and Dissertations May 2014 A Limit Theorem for the Squared Norm of Empirical Distribution Functions Alexander Nerlich University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee

More information

Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces

Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces Samuel N. Cohen and Robert J. Elliott University of Adelaide and University of Calgary BFS 2010 S.N. Cohen, R.J. Elliott (Adelaide, Calgary) BSDEs

More information

1 Lyapunov theory of stability

1 Lyapunov theory of stability M.Kawski, APM 581 Diff Equns Intro to Lyapunov theory. November 15, 29 1 1 Lyapunov theory of stability Introduction. Lyapunov s second (or direct) method provides tools for studying (asymptotic) stability

More information

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra.

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra. DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall 2016 Linear Algebra These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra. 1 Vector spaces You are no doubt familiar with vectors in R 2 or R 3, i.e. [ ] 1.1

More information

MA8109 Stochastic Processes in Systems Theory Autumn 2013

MA8109 Stochastic Processes in Systems Theory Autumn 2013 Norwegian University of Science and Technology Department of Mathematical Sciences MA819 Stochastic Processes in Systems Theory Autumn 213 1 MA819 Exam 23, problem 3b This is a linear equation of the form

More information

Integral Jensen inequality

Integral Jensen inequality Integral Jensen inequality Let us consider a convex set R d, and a convex function f : (, + ]. For any x,..., x n and λ,..., λ n with n λ i =, we have () f( n λ ix i ) n λ if(x i ). For a R d, let δ a

More information

Contagious default: application of methods of Statistical Mechanics in Finance

Contagious default: application of methods of Statistical Mechanics in Finance Contagious default: application of methods of Statistical Mechanics in Finance Wolfgang J. Runggaldier University of Padova, Italy www.math.unipd.it/runggaldier based on joint work with : Paolo Dai Pra,

More information

Spring 2014 Advanced Probability Overview. Lecture Notes Set 1: Course Overview, σ-fields, and Measures

Spring 2014 Advanced Probability Overview. Lecture Notes Set 1: Course Overview, σ-fields, and Measures 36-752 Spring 2014 Advanced Probability Overview Lecture Notes Set 1: Course Overview, σ-fields, and Measures Instructor: Jing Lei Associated reading: Sec 1.1-1.4 of Ash and Doléans-Dade; Sec 1.1 and A.1

More information

The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion

The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion 1 The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion The celebrated Wiener Itô chaos expansion is fundamental in stochastic analysis. In particular, it plays a crucial role in the Malliavin calculus as it is presented in

More information

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS Libo Li and Marek Rutkowski School of Mathematics and Statistics University of Sydney NSW 26, Australia July 1, 211 Abstract We

More information

Jump-type Levy Processes

Jump-type Levy Processes Jump-type Levy Processes Ernst Eberlein Handbook of Financial Time Series Outline Table of contents Probabilistic Structure of Levy Processes Levy process Levy-Ito decomposition Jump part Probabilistic

More information

Topological vectorspaces

Topological vectorspaces (July 25, 2011) Topological vectorspaces Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ Natural non-fréchet spaces Topological vector spaces Quotients and linear maps More topological

More information

Scattered Data Interpolation with Polynomial Precision and Conditionally Positive Definite Functions

Scattered Data Interpolation with Polynomial Precision and Conditionally Positive Definite Functions Chapter 3 Scattered Data Interpolation with Polynomial Precision and Conditionally Positive Definite Functions 3.1 Scattered Data Interpolation with Polynomial Precision Sometimes the assumption on the

More information

Partial Differential Equations with Applications to Finance Seminar 1: Proving and applying Dynkin s formula

Partial Differential Equations with Applications to Finance Seminar 1: Proving and applying Dynkin s formula Partial Differential Equations with Applications to Finance Seminar 1: Proving and applying Dynkin s formula Group 4: Bertan Yilmaz, Richard Oti-Aboagye and Di Liu May, 15 Chapter 1 Proving Dynkin s formula

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces. 1. Boundedness, continuity, operator norms

08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces. 1. Boundedness, continuity, operator norms (February 24, 2017) 08a. Operators on Hilbert spaces Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/real/notes 2016-17/08a-ops

More information

Sobolev Spaces. Chapter Hölder spaces

Sobolev Spaces. Chapter Hölder spaces Chapter 2 Sobolev Spaces Sobolev spaces turn out often to be the proper setting in which to apply ideas of functional analysis to get information concerning partial differential equations. Here, we collect

More information

1 Brownian Local Time

1 Brownian Local Time 1 Brownian Local Time We first begin by defining the space and variables for Brownian local time. Let W t be a standard 1-D Wiener process. We know that for the set, {t : W t = } P (µ{t : W t = } = ) =

More information

Stochastic Differential Equations

Stochastic Differential Equations CHAPTER 1 Stochastic Differential Equations Consider a stochastic process X t satisfying dx t = bt, X t,w t dt + σt, X t,w t dw t. 1.1 Question. 1 Can we obtain the existence and uniqueness theorem for

More information

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions

2 Statement of the problem and assumptions Mathematical Notes, 25, vol. 78, no. 4, pp. 466 48. Existence Theorem for Optimal Control Problems on an Infinite Time Interval A.V. Dmitruk and N.V. Kuz kina We consider an optimal control problem on

More information