Influences in Product Spaces: KKL and BKKKL Revisited

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Influences in Product Spaces: KKL and BKKKL Revisited"

Transcription

1 Influences in Product Spaces: KKL and BKKKL Revisited Ehud Friedgut Abstract The notion of the influence of a variable on a Boolean function on a product space has drawn much attention in combinatorics, computer science and other fields. Two of the basic papers dealing with this notion are [KKL] and [BKKKL]. In this paper we survey the results in those papers and offer some simpler proofs, corrections, and extensions of the theorems presented there. We present several related open problems. 1 Introduction 1.1 Background The fundamental notion of the influence of a variable on a Boolean function on a product space arises naturally in game theory, economics, computer science, statistical physics, combinatorics and harmonic analysis. See [9],[3],[8],[2],[10], [11], for a (semi-random) collection of characteristic examples. In this paper we revisit two papers [KKL] and [BKKKL] that supplied basic insights about this important notion. We will expand and provide simpler proofs to some of the theorems proved in these two papers. We will present a conjecture as to what may replace a false statement presented in [BKKKL], and prove a related theorem that may be a step in this direction. Also we will present several conjectures and related open problems. Institute of Mathematics, Hebrew University, Givat Ram, Jerusalem, Israel. ehudf@math.huji.ac.il 1

2 We begin with some definitions: Let X be a probability space. Let X n be the product space endowed with the product measure. For any x = (x 1,...,x n ) X n let s j (x) be the fiber containing x in the j th direction: s j (x) = {y : y i = x i for i j}. Let f : X n {0, 1}. The influence of the j th variable on f, denoted by I f (j) is the probability that, choosing x X n at random according to the probability measure, f is not fixed on s j (x): I f (j) = Pr({x : f is not constant on s j (x)}). One may think of f as some voting procedure, where n players each make some choice, and f decides between 0 and 1 according to the vector of their choices. In that case I f (j) is the probability that the j th player can decide the outcome of the vote if all other players make their choices randomly. It is quite natural to consider not only the influence of one player(coordinate) but also that of a coalition (a set of coordinates.) For any set J {1,...,n} and for any x X n let s J (x) = {y : y i = x i for i J}. Given a function f : X n {0, 1} as above the influence of a set of coordinates J, denoted by I f (J) is I f (J) = Pr({x : f is not constant on s J (x)}). We will consider only two different cases of the measure space X: the most basic case where X = {0, 1} with the uniform measure (This is the case covered in [KKL]) and the most general case X = [0, 1] with the uniform measure (covered in [BKKKL]). In this paper we will restrict ourselves to monotone functions, however, for our purposes, as observed in [KKL], this causes no loss of generality since every function f as above can be shifted into a function having the same expected value and for which all influences, both of individuals and of coalitions, are no greater than the corresponding influences for f. [KKL] was a breakthrough in the study of influences, due to the fact that it introduced the hammer of powerful techniques of discrete Fourier analysis, together with an appropriate chisel: a hypercontractive estimate due to Bonami ([4]) and, independently, Beckner ([1]). There are no known proofs of the results in this paper that do not use these two ingredients. 2

3 1.2 The Main Results in KKL and BKKKL The main theorem of [KKL] states that there always exists a variable whose influence is of order at least log(n)/n: Theorem 1.1 (KKL1) There exists a constant c > 0 such that the following holds: Consider {0, 1} n as a measure space with the uniform (product) measure. Let f : {0, 1} n {0, 1}. Let Pr({x : f(x) = 1}) = p. Then there exists a variable k such that I f (k) cp(1 p) log n n. The tribes example presented in [3] shows that, up to the value of c this theorem is tight (indeed, [3] was the paper in which Theorem 1.1 was first conjectured.) Since this example and related ones will inspire some of our conjectures let us recall it: Given n variables partition them into blocks (tribes) of size log(n) log log(n)+ c. Let the tribes be denoted by J 1,...,J k, with k n/ log(n). The tribes function takes on the value 1 if there exists a tribe that voted 1 unanimously: f(x) = 1 i x j = 1 j J i. A related function is the dual function g(x) = 1 f(x): g(x) = 1 i j J i such that x j = 1. As noted in [7] the original proof of Theorem 1.1 can be modified, and by using a convexity argument one can show the following: Theorem 1.2 There exists a constant c > 0 such that the following holds: Consider {0, 1} n as a measure space with the uniform measure. Let f : {0, 1} n {0, 1}. Let Pr({x : f(x) = 1}) = p. If for all k I f (k) δ then I f (k) > c log(1/δ)p(1 p). k Perhaps this is the place to mention a later result of Talagrand which is slightly stronger than Theorem 1.2. To start with, it is more general because it deals with a general product measure on {0, 1} n. It also gives a stronger result about the vector of influences. Let µ q be the measure on the 2-point space {0, 1} such that µ q (1) = q and let µ n q denote the n th-power product of this measure on the product space {0, 1} n. 3

4 Theorem 1.3 (Talagrand, [12]) Consider {0, 1} n as a measure space with the product measure µ q. There exists a constant c such that the following holds: Let f : {0, 1} n {0, 1}. Let Pr({x : f(x) = 1}) = p. Then If (k)/ log(1/i f (k)) cp(1 p)q(1 q). Moving to consider the influence of coalitions, by repeated applications of Theorem 1.1 one can deduce the corollary stated in [KKL]. It states that there always exists a relatively small coalition that has influence close to 1: Theorem 1.4 (KKL2) Let {0, 1} n be a measure space with the uniform measure. For any ε > 0 and for any balanced f : {0, 1} n {0, 1} (i.e. Pr({x : f(x) = 1}) = 1/2) there exists a set J with J = O(log(1/ε)n/ log(n)) such that I f (J) 1 ε. The theorem can be adjusted to the case where f is not balanced, but for simplicity we will stick to the balanced case. We will spell out the exact process of deriving this theorem later in this paper. Now let us consider the case where our base space is [0, 1]. The first theorem in [BKKKL] is the exact analogue of Theorem 1.1: Theorem 1.5 (BKKKL) There exists a constant c such that the following holds: Consider [0, 1] n as a measure space with the uniform measure. Let f : [0, 1] n {0, 1}. Let Pr({x : f(x) = 1}) = p. Then there exists a variable k such that I f (k) cp(1 p) log n n. As before, it is perhaps natural to assume that by repeated application of the above one may deduce a theorem about the influence of a coalition exactly as in the discrete case. Indeed such a theorem is stated in [BKKKL], but, as noted already in [7], this is false. A simple counterexample actually appears in [BKKKL] itself. 1.3 Outline Here is a brief outline of what follows in this paper: First, using Theorem 1.2 we will show how the reasoning presented in [BKKKL] actually can be used to get an extremely simple proof of Theorem 1.5, much simpler than the original one. We then will move on to study influences of coalitions. We will see why the 4

5 continuous case is more complicated than the discrete one. We will present a conjecture as to what should replace the erroneous statement in [BKKKL], present a series of conjectures concerning the discrete cube that would imply the continuous conjecture and prove a new theorem that is a step in that direction. We will conclude with several other related conjectures. 2 From Discrete to Continuous We begin by showing that the main result in [BKKKL], Theorem 1.5 may be derived rather simply from the discrete case. Claim 2.1 Theorem 1.2 implies Theorem 1.5. Proof: Let f : [0, 1] n {0, 1} be a monotone function. We start, as is done in [BKKKL], by discretizing the continuous cube. Let k = 3 log n (one can improve the constants by choosing k more carefully.) Subdivide [0, 1] n into 2 kn equal subcubes by subdividing every one of the base intervals into 2 k equal parts. This partition is fine enough that we may assume for our purposes that f is constant on each of the small subcubes, else replace f by an appropriate approximation. Note that this is valid due to the fact that f is monotone: the number of mixed subcubes is no more than the number of subcubes that touch the boundary of [0, 1] n. Now f corresponds in a natural way to a function on the discrete cube g : {0, 1} kn {0, 1}, by replacing the interval [r2 k, (r + 1)2 k ] with the binary expansion of r. Every variable i {1,...,n} is now replaced by k variables i j : 1 j k. The following simple key observation was made in [BKKKL]: i j I g (i j ) 2I f (i). (1) This together with Theorem 1.2 immediately yields the required result: Assume that for all i I f (i) c 1, and hence by (1) log n n i,j I g (i j ) 2c 1 log n n. This implies by Theorem 1.2 that I g (i j ) c 2 log(n)p(1 p), i,j 5

6 and using (1) again i I f (i) c 2 2 log(n)p(1 p), and in particular there exists a variable i such that I f (i) c 2 2 log n p(1 p). n We now move on to the question of the influence of coalitions. Let us begin by sketching how repeated applications of Theorem 1.1 yield Theorem 1.4: Let f : {0, 1} n {0, 1} be a monotone function with E(f) = Pr(f = 1) = p 1. Let i 1 be a variable with large influence as guaranteed by Theorem 1.4, I f (i 1 ) = α > cp 1 (1 p 1 ) log(n)/n. From the definition of influence it follows that E(f(x) x i1 = 1) = p 1 + α/2 := p 2. Setting x i1 = 1 now gives a new function on n 1 variables with expected value p 2. Repeating the above argument we find a variable i 2 with large influence with respect to the new function, set it to be equal 1, etc. After O(log(1/ε)n/ log(n)) iterations we have a set J 1 of variables such that E(f(x) x j = 1 j J 1 ) > 1 ε/2. In the same manner we may find a set J 0 such that Putting these together shows that E(f(x) x j = 0 j J 0 ) < ε/2. I f (J 0 J 1 ) > 1 ε. Now why is this line of reasoning not valid in the continuous case? Why is it not true that for any function f : [0, 1] n : {0, 1} there exists a small coalition that dominates the function? The reason is that for a monotone function when one sets a variable x i to be equal to 1 the gain in the expectation of the function comes from the mixed fibers in the i th direction. In the discrete case every fiber consists of two points, hence if the measure of the union of the mixed fibers is α one gains α/2. Clearly this is not the case 6

7 in the continuous cube. The simplest counterexample is the following, The Subcube : f(x) = 1 1/n x i 1 i. (2) The expected value of f is (1 1/n) n 1/e. The influence of every variable is quite large - it is (1 1/n) n 1 1/e, however, since the mixed fibers have only a 1/n proportion where f = 0, setting one variable to be equal to 1 has almost no effect on the expectation of the function: E(f(x) x 1 = 1) = (1 1/n) n 1. Indeed if J is a coalition with J = o(n) then E(f(x) x j = 1 j J) = (1 1/n) n o(n) E(f). The astute reader must have noted that, on the other hand, setting even a single variable to be equal to 0 implies f = 0. (This may be compared to many real-life situations where the cooperation of a large coalition is needed to achieve a goal that can easily be foiled by one member defecting.) This suggests introducing the following notions and notations: for a variable j let E j=1 (f) = E(f(x) x j = 1) and define the influence of j towards 1 as Define similarly and I 1 f(j) = E j=1 (f) E(f). E j=0 (f) = E(f(x) x j = 0) I 0 f(j) = E(f) E j=0 (f). Note that I f (j) = If 1(j) + I0 f (j). As in the case of influence we make the analogous definitions for coalitions. If J {1,..., n} Define E J=1 (f) = E(f(x) x j = 1 j J) and similarly define If 1(J), E J=0(f) and If 0 (J). The previous example suggests that perhaps the following conjecture might be the correct continuous version of Theorem 1.4: 7

8 Conjecture 2.2 Let f : [0, 1] n {0, 1}. There exists a coalition J with J = o(n) such that either E J=1 (f) = 1 o(1) or E J=0 (f) = o(1). By following the approach of the proof relying on discretizing the continuous cube, the above conjecture would follow from the following one. Assume that, as in Israeli politics, one is given a set of parties and when building a coalition must either take a whole party or none of its members. Then perhaps it is still possible to build a small coalition, but perhaps with large influence only in one direction: Conjecture 2.3 Let m = nk. For i = 0,...,n 1, and let J i = {ik +1,ik + 2,...,ik + k}. Let f : {0, 1} m {0, 1}. Then there exists S {1,...,n} with S = o(n) such that for J = i S J i either E J=0 (f) = o(1) or E J=1 (f) = 1 o(1). The canonical tribes example (where the parties are the tribes) shows that one cannot strengthen this conjecture by replacing one-sided influence with the usual influence. In fact the tribes example is exactly the dual of what one gets when discretizing the subcube example (Although since we chose the tribes to be rather large by setting k = 3 log n we will get a function where only a minority in every tribe have the right to vote.) These examples are cases where one can build a small influential coalition but it uses representatives from all the parties (tribes). For our purposes it would suffice to prove a weaker conjecture that we state below - since we are interested in functions coming from monotone functions on the continuous cube one may assume that f in the above conjecture has a certain supermonotonicity: Let x,y {0, 1} m. We will say x dominates y if every one of the n blocks of k coordinates in x dominates the corresponding block of coordinates in y. We say that the block in x, dominates the block in y, if the first is the binary representation of an integer b x and the second of b y and b x b y. We will say f is supermonotone if whenever x dominates y, f(x) f(y). Conjecture 2.4 Conjecture 2.3 holds if we add the condition that f is supermonotone. 8

9 Actually an even weaker conjecture would suffice: in attempting to prove Conjecture 2.4 we can follow the derivation of theorem 1.4 as long as there exists, at each stage of the iteration a variable with large influence towards 1. hence we can add to the last conjecture the hypothesis that there does not exist such a variable. This corresponds to the following: Conjecture 2.5 Let k,n,m,j i be as in Conjecture 2.3. Let f : {0, 1} m {0, 1} be supermonotone and balanced, i.e. Pr[f = 1] = 1/2. Assume further that for every i {1,...,n} I 1 f(j i ) = O(log(m)/m) = O(1/n) Then there exists S {1,...,n} with S = o(n) such that for J = i S J i E J=0 (f) = o(1). To understand the above conjecture better, note that its hypothesis is fulfilled by the discretization of the subcube, the dual of the tribes function. Of course, the assumption that f is balanced can be weakened to the asumption that the expectation of f is bounded away from 0 and 1. There is another rationale hiding behind the above conjecture - the idea that the only extremal examples where all variables simultaneously have influence O(log(n)/n) are tribe-type functions. The question of understanding the extremal functions seems to be quite challenging, yet such an understanding would be quite rewarding in the sense that the conjecture below, for example, would imply all the previous ones. Conjecture 2.6 For every c > 0 and ε > 0 there exists b > 0 such that if f : {0, 1} n {0, 1} and for all i I f (i) c log(n)/n. Then there exists a small tribe - i.e. a set J of variables with J b log(n) such that E J=0 (f) ε or E J=1 (f) 1 ε. It seems that the only hope of attacking this is via Fourier analysis. As we see, the simple subcube example inspires many conjectures - and we are not done yet. We will now present a theorem inspired by it and follow it by yet another conjecture concerning subsets of [0, 1] n with small projections. 9

10 Recall that in our function f(x) = 1 1/n x i 1 i no variable has large influence towards 1, but all variables have very large influence - a constant which is approximately 1/e. (This tradeoff is reminiscent of the discrete case where, as stated in Theorem 1.2 if all influences are small their sum must be large.) This tradeoff is capture by the following theorem which states that when all influences towards 1 are small (e.g. much smaller than log(n)/n) then there exists a variable with large influence (much larger than log(n)/n.) Theorem 2.7 Let c = c where c is the constant from Theorem 1.2. Then 6 for any balanced monotone function f : [0, 1] n {0, 1} if for all i then there exists i such that I f (i) α n I 1 f(i) α n ( n ) c /α. 2α The case where all influences towards 1 are o(1/n) is not interesting because this implies that f is very close to the function which is identically 1 (and in particular is not balanced.) On the other extreme α can always be assumed to be at most c log(n), else the assertion of the theorem is that there exists a variable with influence Ω(log(n)/n), which is always true. Now note that up to the value of c the theorem is tight at both ends of the spectrum: for the subcube when all influences towards 1 are of order 1/n and in the tribes example where the influences are of order log(n)/n. Proof: Our basic approach will be, as in the proof of Claim 2.1, to discretize the cube. Assume as usual that f is monotone and as before divide every base interval into k = 3 log(n) equal parts inducing a partition of the cube into 2 kn subcubes and assume f is constant on each small subcube. As before this defines in a natural manner a function g : {0, 1} kn {0, 1}. For i {1,...,n} and x [0, 1] n. Recall the definition of s i (x) the fiber in the i th direction through x : s i (x) = {y : y j = x j for j i}. 10

11 let Z i (x) = 1 E(f(y) y s i (x)). If f is not constant on the fiber s i (x) then Z i (x) is the contribution of this fiber to I 1 f (i). We will make this precise shortly. Let i[0, 1] n be the union of the mixed fibers in the i th direction: Then i [0, 1] n = {x [0, 1] n : f is not constant on s i (x)}. If(i) 1 = Z i (x) i [0,1] n (3) where the integration is with respect to the uniform measure on [0, 1] n. We now want to connect Z i (x) to the contribution of s i (x) to the influences I g (i j ). This combines observations made in [BKKKL] and [7]. Claim 2.8 For all i and j I g (i j ) 2If(i) 1 = 2Z i (x) i [0,1] n (4) and for all i I g (i j ) 6Z i (x) log(1/z i (x)). (5) i [0,1] n j Proof of claim: The claim follows from the one dimensional case where i = 1 is the only variable and there is only one fiber in our space. In this case assume f is monotone so f(x) = 1 x z. Since changing the value of the j th variable in g corresponds to flipping the j th bit in the binary representation of x it is easy to see that for every j I g (1 j ) min(2z, 2 1 j ). This immediately implies (4). To get (5) we sum on j which gives I g (i j ) 2z log(1/z) + 4z 6z log(1/z). j 11

12 Returning to the proof of Theorem 2.7 we know that for all i i [0,1] n Z i (x) = I 1 f(i) α n (6) hence by (4) for all i and j I g (i j ) 2α n. Using Theorem 1.2 we deduce that I g (i j ) c log(n/2α), so there exists a variable i such that I g (i j ) c log(n/2α). n Using (5) we have i,j j 6Z i (x) log(1/z i (x)) c log(n/2α) i [0,1] n n, (7) but from (6) i [0,1] n Z i (x) α n so by concavity of the function z log(1/z) 6Z i (x) log(1/z i (x)) 6 α ( i [0,1] n log npr( i [0, 1] n ) α n Putting (7) and (8) together gives Pr( i [0, 1] n ) α n ( n ) c 6α 2α but Pr( i [0, 1] n ) is exactly the influence of i, so we are done. ). (8) Actually the same proof shows that under the assumptions of Theorem 2.7 the average influence is large: 12

13 Theorem 2.9 Let c = c where c is the constant from theorem 1.2. Let 6 f : [0, 1] n {0, 1} be such that for all i I 1 f(i) α n. Let g : {0, 1} kn {0, 1} be defined as in the proof of Theorem 2.7. Let p i = j Ig(i j) i j I g(i j ) (note that p i = 1.) Then for every i I f (i) α n ( n ) c np i α 2α and from the Arithmetic-Geometric Mean Inequality ( n ) c α If (i) α. 2α 2.1 Projections of Subsets of the Cube All theorems and conjectures in this paper can be interpreted as isoperimetric statements concerning subsets of either the discrete or the continuous cube, and their projections. Given A [0, 1] n let A 1 i be the projection of A onto the face of the cube that lies on the plane x i = 1. Let Vol(A) denote the volume of a set, taken in the appropriate dimension. Let Ḡ 1 i(a) = Vol(A 1 i) Vol(A) measure the growth of A when projected, and G 1 i(a) = Vol(A1 i) Vol(A) Vol(A)(1 Vol(A)) the normalized growth. Theorem 1.5 implies the following: Theorem 2.10 Let [0, 1] n be partitioned into two sets A and A c. Then there exists a direction i such that either G 1 i(a) or G 1 i(a c ) is of order Ω( log n n ). Once again, the example where A is the subcube gives rise to the idea that if G 1 i(a) is small for all i then A is close to being either a subcube or a union of subcubes. However, since the subcube occupies a large proportion 13

14 of every direction one cannot pack two such subcubes disjointly into [0, 1] n. So perhaps it is reasonable to expect that not only is G 1 i(a c ) large, but that this holds for any substantially large subset of A c. Here is a conjecture in this spirit, probably due to Nati Linial: Conjecture 2.11 Let [0, 1] n be partitioned into k subsets A 1,...,A k. Then there exists a direction i such that for all but at most one of the A j s ( ) log n G 1 i(a j ) = Ω. n 2.2 Continuous Juntas In [6] Boolean functions on {0, 1} n are studied in the case where the total sum of the influences is bounded. An example of such a function is the dictatorship: f(x) = x 1. For the dictatorship I f (1) = 1 and I f (j) = 0 for j 1. It turns out that whenever j I f(j) B then for every ε > 0 there exists a junta - a set J of size exp(cb/ε) and a function g that depends only on the coordinates in J such that f g 2 2 ε. In ongoing work of the author with Irit Dinur [5] the analogous case for functions f : {1, 2,...,r} n {0, 1} is studied. We have proven the analogous result in the case where f is monotone, however for junta-type theorems one cannot assume monotonicity, for, unlike influence, the control of the junta is not preserved under a shifting procedure that makes a function monotone. Since a few of the conjectures we have raised are very closely related to those in this paper we will end by quoting some results and conjectures. Consider {1,...,r} n endowed with the uniform measure. Theorem 2.12 There exists a constant c > 0 such that the following holds. Let ε > 0 and f : {1,...,r} n {0, 1} be a monotone function. Assume that I f (j) B. j Then there exists a set J {1,..., n} with J exp(cb/ε) and a function g : {1,...,r} n {0, 1} depending only on the coordinates in J such that f g 2 2 ε. Of course, as we have seen in this paper, this implies the same for monotone Boolean functions on the continuous cube. In the non-monotone case a 14

15 weaker result holds, where the size of the junta depends also on r: under the same assumptions, sans monotonicity, it can be shown that there exists a set J as above such that J exp(cb log r/ε). We actually conjecture that the monotonicity is not a necessary condition: Conjecture 2.13 Theorem 2.12 holds for any function f : {1,...,r} n {0, 1} regardless of monotonicity. This would follow from the following conjecture about functions on {0, 1} n which is reminiscent of Conjecture 2.3. We conjecture that in the case of the coordinates being partitioned into parties the junta can be composed from a bounded number of parties, regardless of their size: Conjecture 2.14 There exists a constant c such that the following holds. Let m = nk. For i = 0,...,n 1 Let J i = {ik + 1,ik + 2,...,ik + k}. Let f : {0, 1} m {0, 1} and assume I f (J i ) B. i Then for every ε > 0 there exists S {1,...,n} with S exp(cb/ε) and a function g : {0, 1} m {0, 1} depending only on the coordinates in i S J i such that f g 2 2 ε. 3 Acknowledgments It is a pleasure to thank the second K (Gil Kalai) and L (Nati Linial) for innumerable discussions of this topic throughout the years, from which all the ideas in this paper have stemmed. I would also like to thank Noga Alon, Irit Dinur, the first K (Jeff Kahn) and Avi Wigderson for useful conversations and remarks. Also, I wish to thank the anonymous referee for various remarks. References [1] W. Beckner, Inequalities in Fourier analysis. Annals of Mathematics, 102 (1975),

16 [2] I. Benjamini, G. Kalai, O. Schramm, Noise Sensitivity of Boolean Functions and Applications to Percolation, Inst. Hautes Etudes Sci. Publ. Math. No. 90, (1999), 5 43 (2001). [BKKKL] J. Bourgain, J. Kahn, G. Kalai, Y. Katznelson and N. Linial, The influence of variables in product spaces, Israel J. Math. 77(1992), [3] M. Ben-Or and N. Linial, Collective coin flipping, in Randomness and Computation (S. Micali, ed.), Academic Press, New York, 1990, pp Earlier version: Collective coin flipping, robust voting games, and minima of Banzhaf value, Proc. 26th IEEE Symp. on the Foundation of Computer Science, 1985, pp [4] Aline Bonami, Etude des coefficients Fourier des fonctiones de L p (G), Ann. Inst. Fourier (Grenoble) 20:2 (1970), [5] I. Dinur and E. Friedgut, Continuous Juntas, in Preparation. [6] E. Friedgut, Boolean functions with low average sensitivity depend on few coordinates, Combinatorica Vol 18 (1) 1998 pp [7] E. Friedgut, G. Kalai, Every monotone graph property has a sharp threshold, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 124 (1996), pp [KKL] J. Kahn, G. Kalai, and N. Linial, The influence of variables on Boolean functions, Proc. 29-th Ann. Symp. on Foundations of Comp. Sci., 68-80, Computer Society Press, [8] G. Kalai A Fourier-Theoretic Perspective for the Condorcet Paradox and Arrow s Theorem, to appear in Advances in Applied Mathematics. [9] Lehrer, E. An axiomatization of the Banzhaf value. Internat. J. Game Theory 17 (1988), no. 2, [10] M. Talagrand, How much are increasing sets correlated? Combinatorica 16, 1996, [11] M. Talagrand On boundaries and influences, Combinatorica 17, 1997, [12] M. Talagrand, On Russo s approximate 0-1 law, Annals of Probability, 1994 Vol 22, No

Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise

Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise Einstein Institute of Mathematics Hebrew University of Jerusalem Based on recent joint works with Jean Bourgain, Jeff Kahn, Guy Kindler, Nathan Keller,

More information

Threshold Intervals under Group Symmetries

Threshold Intervals under Group Symmetries Convex Geometric Analysis MSRI Publications Volume 34, 1998 Threshold Intervals under Group Symmetries JEAN BOURGAIN AND GIL KALAI Abstract. This article contains a brief description of new results on

More information

First Passage Percolation Has Sublinear Distance Variance

First Passage Percolation Has Sublinear Distance Variance arxiv:math/23262v5 [math.pr 25 May 27 First Passage Percolation Has Sublinear Distance Variance Itai Benjamini Gil Kalai Oded Schramm October 21, 22 Abstract Let < a < b

More information

FKN Theorem on the biased cube

FKN Theorem on the biased cube FKN Theorem on the biased cube Piotr Nayar Abstract In this note we consider Boolean functions defined on the discrete cube { γ, γ 1 } n equipped with a product probability measure µ n, where µ = βδ γ

More information

CSE 291: Fourier analysis Chapter 2: Social choice theory

CSE 291: Fourier analysis Chapter 2: Social choice theory CSE 91: Fourier analysis Chapter : Social choice theory 1 Basic definitions We can view a boolean function f : { 1, 1} n { 1, 1} as a means to aggregate votes in a -outcome election. Common examples are:

More information

Around two theorems and a lemma by Lucio Russo

Around two theorems and a lemma by Lucio Russo Around two theorems and a lemma by Lucio Russo Itai Benjamini and Gil Kalai 1 Introduction We did not meet Lucio Russo in person but his mathematical work greatly influenced our own and his wide horizons

More information

THRESHOLD. Abstract. In their seminal work which initiated random graph theory Erdos and

THRESHOLD. Abstract. In their seminal work which initiated random graph theory Erdos and EVERY MONOTONE GRAPH PROPERTY HAS A SHARP THRESHOLD EHUD FRIEDGUT AND GIL KALAI Abstract. In their seminal work which initiated random graph theory Erdos and Renyi discovered that many graph properties

More information

Harmonic Analysis of Boolean Functions

Harmonic Analysis of Boolean Functions Harmonic Analysis of Boolean Functions Lectures: MW 10:05-11:25 in MC 103 Office Hours: MC 328, by appointment (hatami@cs.mcgill.ca). Evaluation: Assignments: 60 % Presenting a paper at the end of the

More information

Thresholds and expectation thresholds

Thresholds and expectation thresholds Thresholds and expectation thresholds J. Kahn and G. Kalai Monotone properties and thresholds We use 2 X for the collection of subsets of a finite set X. Given X of size n and p [0,1], µ p is the product

More information

DAVID ELLIS AND BHARGAV NARAYANAN

DAVID ELLIS AND BHARGAV NARAYANAN ON SYMMETRIC 3-WISE INTERSECTING FAMILIES DAVID ELLIS AND BHARGAV NARAYANAN Abstract. A family of sets is said to be symmetric if its automorphism group is transitive, and 3-wise intersecting if any three

More information

Low degree almost Boolean functions are sparse juntas

Low degree almost Boolean functions are sparse juntas Low degree almost Boolean functions are sparse juntas Irit Dinur Yuval Filmus Prahladh Harsha November 19, 2017 Abstract Nisan and Szegedy showed that low degree Boolean functions are juntas. Kindler and

More information

Thresholds and expectation-thresholds of monotone properties with small minterms

Thresholds and expectation-thresholds of monotone properties with small minterms Thresholds and expectation-thresholds of monotone properties with small minterms Ehud Friedgut Jeff Kahn Clara Shikhelman April 11, 2014 Abstract Let N be a finite set, let p (0, 1), and let N p denote

More information

Sharp Thresholds. Zachary Hamaker. March 15, 2010

Sharp Thresholds. Zachary Hamaker. March 15, 2010 Sharp Threshols Zachary Hamaker March 15, 2010 Abstract The Kolmogorov Zero-One law states that for tail events on infinite-imensional probability spaces, the probability must be either zero or one. Behavior

More information

An Introduction to Analysis of Boolean functions

An Introduction to Analysis of Boolean functions An Introduction to Analysis of Boolean functions Mohammad Bavarian Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1 Introduction The focus of much of harmonic analysis is the study of functions, and operators on

More information

Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions (Extended abstract)

Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions (Extended abstract) Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions (Extended abstract) Abstract Noga Alon IBM Almaden Research Center, San Jose, CA 9510 and Sackler Faculty of Exact Sciences, Tel Aviv University,

More information

1 Boolean functions and Walsh-Fourier system

1 Boolean functions and Walsh-Fourier system 1 Boolean functions and Walsh-Fourier system In this chapter we would like to study boolean functions, namely functions f : { 1, 1} n { 1, 1}, using methods of harmonic analysis Recall that the discrete

More information

Entropy and Ergodic Theory Lecture 15: A first look at concentration

Entropy and Ergodic Theory Lecture 15: A first look at concentration Entropy and Ergodic Theory Lecture 15: A first look at concentration 1 Introduction to concentration Let X 1, X 2,... be i.i.d. R-valued RVs with common distribution µ, and suppose for simplicity that

More information

Theoretical Computer Science

Theoretical Computer Science Theoretical Computer Science 411 (2010) 3224 3234 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Theoretical Computer Science journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/tcs N-player partizan games Alessandro

More information

Constructive bounds for a Ramsey-type problem

Constructive bounds for a Ramsey-type problem Constructive bounds for a Ramsey-type problem Noga Alon Michael Krivelevich Abstract For every fixed integers r, s satisfying r < s there exists some ɛ = ɛ(r, s > 0 for which we construct explicitly an

More information

The Number of Independent Sets in a Regular Graph

The Number of Independent Sets in a Regular Graph Combinatorics, Probability and Computing (2010) 19, 315 320. c Cambridge University Press 2009 doi:10.1017/s0963548309990538 The Number of Independent Sets in a Regular Graph YUFEI ZHAO Department of Mathematics,

More information

Independent Sets in Graph Powers are Almost Contained in Juntas

Independent Sets in Graph Powers are Almost Contained in Juntas Independent Sets in Graph Powers are Almost Contained in Juntas Irit Dinur Ehud Friedgut Oded Regev January 7, 2008 Abstract Let G = (V, E) be a simple undirected graph. Define G n, the n-th power of G,

More information

Quantum boolean functions

Quantum boolean functions Quantum boolean functions Ashley Montanaro 1 and Tobias Osborne 2 1 Department of Computer Science 2 Department of Mathematics University of Bristol Royal Holloway, University of London Bristol, UK London,

More information

Fourier analysis of boolean functions in quantum computation

Fourier analysis of boolean functions in quantum computation Fourier analysis of boolean functions in quantum computation Ashley Montanaro Centre for Quantum Information and Foundations, Department of Applied Mathematics and Theoretical Physics, University of Cambridge

More information

NOISE SENSITIVITY and CHAOS in SOCIAL CHOICE THEORY

NOISE SENSITIVITY and CHAOS in SOCIAL CHOICE THEORY NOISE SENSITIVITY and CHAOS in SOCIAL CHOICE THEORY Gil Kalai Abstract In this paper we study the social preferences obtained from monotone neutral social welfare functions for random individual preferences.

More information

CONSECUTIVE INTEGERS IN HIGH-MULTIPLICITY SUMSETS

CONSECUTIVE INTEGERS IN HIGH-MULTIPLICITY SUMSETS CONSECUTIVE INTEGERS IN HIGH-MULTIPLICITY SUMSETS VSEVOLOD F. LEV Abstract. Sharpening (a particular case of) a result of Szemerédi and Vu [4] and extending earlier results of Sárközy [3] and ourselves

More information

Testing Equality in Communication Graphs

Testing Equality in Communication Graphs Electronic Colloquium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 86 (2016) Testing Equality in Communication Graphs Noga Alon Klim Efremenko Benny Sudakov Abstract Let G = (V, E) be a connected undirected

More information

Lecture 8: February 8

Lecture 8: February 8 CS71 Randomness & Computation Spring 018 Instructor: Alistair Sinclair Lecture 8: February 8 Disclaimer: These notes have not been subjected to the usual scrutiny accorded to formal publications. They

More information

On the mean connected induced subgraph order of cographs

On the mean connected induced subgraph order of cographs AUSTRALASIAN JOURNAL OF COMBINATORICS Volume 71(1) (018), Pages 161 183 On the mean connected induced subgraph order of cographs Matthew E Kroeker Lucas Mol Ortrud R Oellermann University of Winnipeg Winnipeg,

More information

Lecture 18: Inapproximability of MAX-3-SAT

Lecture 18: Inapproximability of MAX-3-SAT CS 880: Advanced Complexity Theory 3/7/2008 Lecture 18: Inapproximability of MAX-3-SAT Instructor: Dieter van Melkebeek Scribe: Jeff Kinne In this lecture we prove a tight inapproximability result for

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.co] 14 Apr 2011

arxiv: v2 [math.co] 14 Apr 2011 Complete Characterization of Functions Satisfying the Conditions of Arrow s Theorem Elchanan Mossel and Omer Tamuz arxiv:0910.2465v2 [math.co] 14 Apr 2011 April 15, 2011 Abstract Arrow s theorem implies

More information

Workshop on Discrete Harmonic Analysis Newton Institute, March 2011

Workshop on Discrete Harmonic Analysis Newton Institute, March 2011 High frequency criteria for Boolean functions (with an application to percolation) Christophe Garban ENS Lyon and CNRS Workshop on Discrete Harmonic Analysis Newton Institute, March 2011 C. Garban (ENS

More information

Communication is bounded by root of rank

Communication is bounded by root of rank Electronic Colloquium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 84 (2013) Communication is bounded by root of rank Shachar Lovett June 7, 2013 Abstract We prove that any total boolean function of rank r

More information

Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise

Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise Boolean Functions: Influence, threshold and noise Gil Kalai Abstract. This lecture studies the analysis of Boolean functions and present a few ideas, results, proofs, and problems. We start with the wider

More information

Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions

Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions Coin-flipping games immune against linear-sized coalitions Noga Alon Tel Aviv University Moni Naor IBM Almaden Research Center March 22, 993 Abstract Perfect information coin-flipping and leader-election

More information

BURGESS INEQUALITY IN F p 2. Mei-Chu Chang

BURGESS INEQUALITY IN F p 2. Mei-Chu Chang BURGESS INEQUALITY IN F p 2 Mei-Chu Chang Abstract. Let be a nontrivial multiplicative character of F p 2. We obtain the following results.. Given ε > 0, there is δ > 0 such that if ω F p 2\F p and I,

More information

Avoider-Enforcer games played on edge disjoint hypergraphs

Avoider-Enforcer games played on edge disjoint hypergraphs Avoider-Enforcer games played on edge disjoint hypergraphs Asaf Ferber Michael Krivelevich Alon Naor July 8, 2013 Abstract We analyze Avoider-Enforcer games played on edge disjoint hypergraphs, providing

More information

SANDWICH GAMES. July 9, 2014

SANDWICH GAMES. July 9, 2014 SANDWICH GAMES EHUD LEHRER AND ROEE TEPER July 9, 204 Abstract. The extension of set functions (or capacities) in a concave fashion, namely a concavification, is an important issue in decision theory and

More information

Inaccessible Entropy and its Applications. 1 Review: Psedorandom Generators from One-Way Functions

Inaccessible Entropy and its Applications. 1 Review: Psedorandom Generators from One-Way Functions Columbia University - Crypto Reading Group Apr 27, 2011 Inaccessible Entropy and its Applications Igor Carboni Oliveira We summarize the constructions of PRGs from OWFs discussed so far and introduce the

More information

FKN theorem for the multislice, with applications

FKN theorem for the multislice, with applications FKN theorem for the multislice, with applications Yuval Filmus * September 5, 2018 Abstract The Friedgut Kalai Naor (FKN) theorem states that if f is a Boolean function on the Boolean cube which is close

More information

ON SENSITIVITY OF k-uniform HYPERGRAPH PROPERTIES

ON SENSITIVITY OF k-uniform HYPERGRAPH PROPERTIES ON SENSITIVITY OF k-uniform HYPERGRAPH PROPERTIES JOSHUA BIDERMAN, KEVIN CUDDY, ANG LI, MIN JAE SONG Abstract. In this paper we present a graph property with sensitivity Θ( n), where n = ( v 2) is the

More information

Lecture 2: Basics of Harmonic Analysis. 1 Structural properties of Boolean functions (continued)

Lecture 2: Basics of Harmonic Analysis. 1 Structural properties of Boolean functions (continued) CS 880: Advanced Complexity Theory 1/25/2008 Lecture 2: Basics of Harmonic Analysis Instructor: Dieter van Melkebeek Scribe: Priyananda Shenoy In the last lecture, we mentioned one structural property

More information

Decoupling course outline Decoupling theory is a recent development in Fourier analysis with applications in partial differential equations and

Decoupling course outline Decoupling theory is a recent development in Fourier analysis with applications in partial differential equations and Decoupling course outline Decoupling theory is a recent development in Fourier analysis with applications in partial differential equations and analytic number theory. It studies the interference patterns

More information

The Minesweeper game: Percolation and Complexity

The Minesweeper game: Percolation and Complexity The Minesweeper game: Percolation and Complexity Elchanan Mossel Hebrew University of Jerusalem and Microsoft Research March 15, 2002 Abstract We study a model motivated by the minesweeper game In this

More information

Maximum union-free subfamilies

Maximum union-free subfamilies Maximum union-free subfamilies Jacob Fox Choongbum Lee Benny Sudakov Abstract An old problem of Moser asks: how large of a union-free subfamily does every family of m sets have? A family of sets is called

More information

SCALE INVARIANT FOURIER RESTRICTION TO A HYPERBOLIC SURFACE

SCALE INVARIANT FOURIER RESTRICTION TO A HYPERBOLIC SURFACE SCALE INVARIANT FOURIER RESTRICTION TO A HYPERBOLIC SURFACE BETSY STOVALL Abstract. This result sharpens the bilinear to linear deduction of Lee and Vargas for extension estimates on the hyperbolic paraboloid

More information

The Analysis of Partially Symmetric Functions

The Analysis of Partially Symmetric Functions The Analysis of Partially Symmetric Functions Eric Blais Based on joint work with Amit Weinstein Yuichi Yoshida Classes of simple functions Classes of simple functions Constant Classes of simple functions

More information

Reverse Hyper Contractive Inequalities: What? Why?? When??? How????

Reverse Hyper Contractive Inequalities: What? Why?? When??? How???? Reverse Hyper Contractive Inequalities: What? Why?? When??? How???? UC Berkeley Warsaw Cambridge May 21, 2012 Hyper-Contractive Inequalities The noise (Bonami-Beckner) semi-group on { 1, 1} n 1 2 Def 1:

More information

An upper bound on l q norms of noisy functions

An upper bound on l q norms of noisy functions Electronic Collouium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 68 08 An upper bound on l norms of noisy functions Alex Samorodnitsky Abstract Let T ɛ, 0 ɛ /, be the noise operator acting on functions on

More information

Chromatic number, clique subdivisions, and the conjectures of Hajós and Erdős-Fajtlowicz

Chromatic number, clique subdivisions, and the conjectures of Hajós and Erdős-Fajtlowicz Chromatic number, clique subdivisions, and the conjectures of Hajós and Erdős-Fajtlowicz Jacob Fox Choongbum Lee Benny Sudakov Abstract For a graph G, let χ(g) denote its chromatic number and σ(g) denote

More information

Optimal Inapproximability Results for MAX-CUT and Other 2-variable CSPs?

Optimal Inapproximability Results for MAX-CUT and Other 2-variable CSPs? Optimal Inapproximability Results for MAX-CUT and Other 2-variable CSPs? Subhash Khot School of Mathematics Institute for Advanced Study Princeton, NJ khot@ias.edu Guy Kindler DIMACS Rutgers University

More information

The one-way communication complexity of the Boolean Hidden Matching Problem

The one-way communication complexity of the Boolean Hidden Matching Problem The one-way communication complexity of the Boolean Hidden Matching Problem Iordanis Kerenidis CRS - LRI Université Paris-Sud jkeren@lri.fr Ran Raz Faculty of Mathematics Weizmann Institute ran.raz@weizmann.ac.il

More information

Random Lifts of Graphs

Random Lifts of Graphs 27th Brazilian Math Colloquium, July 09 Plan of this talk A brief introduction to the probabilistic method. A quick review of expander graphs and their spectrum. Lifts, random lifts and their properties.

More information

Sample Spaces, Random Variables

Sample Spaces, Random Variables Sample Spaces, Random Variables Moulinath Banerjee University of Michigan August 3, 22 Probabilities In talking about probabilities, the fundamental object is Ω, the sample space. (elements) in Ω are denoted

More information

Independence numbers of locally sparse graphs and a Ramsey type problem

Independence numbers of locally sparse graphs and a Ramsey type problem Independence numbers of locally sparse graphs and a Ramsey type problem Noga Alon Abstract Let G = (V, E) be a graph on n vertices with average degree t 1 in which for every vertex v V the induced subgraph

More information

A Construction of Almost Steiner Systems

A Construction of Almost Steiner Systems A Construction of Almost Steiner Systems Asaf Ferber, 1 Rani Hod, 2 Michael Krivelevich, 1 and Benny Sudakov 3,4 1 School of Mathematical Sciences, Raymond and Beverly Sackler Faculty of Exact Sciences,

More information

On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors

On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors Nicole Immorlica Brendan Lucier Abstract We consider the problem of converting an arbitrary approximation algorithm for a singleparameter social

More information

Upper Bounds on Fourier Entropy

Upper Bounds on Fourier Entropy Upper Bounds on Fourier Entropy Sourav Chakraborty 1, Raghav Kulkarni 2, Satyanarayana V. Lokam 3, and Nitin Saurabh 4 1 Chennai Mathematical Institute, Chennai, India sourav@cmi.ac.in 2 Centre for Quantum

More information

An exponential separation between quantum and classical one-way communication complexity

An exponential separation between quantum and classical one-way communication complexity An exponential separation between quantum and classical one-way communication complexity Ashley Montanaro Centre for Quantum Information and Foundations, Department of Applied Mathematics and Theoretical

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information

The uniform uncertainty principle and compressed sensing Harmonic analysis and related topics, Seville December 5, 2008

The uniform uncertainty principle and compressed sensing Harmonic analysis and related topics, Seville December 5, 2008 The uniform uncertainty principle and compressed sensing Harmonic analysis and related topics, Seville December 5, 2008 Emmanuel Candés (Caltech), Terence Tao (UCLA) 1 Uncertainty principles A basic principle

More information

Probabilistic Proofs of Existence of Rare Events. Noga Alon

Probabilistic Proofs of Existence of Rare Events. Noga Alon Probabilistic Proofs of Existence of Rare Events Noga Alon Department of Mathematics Sackler Faculty of Exact Sciences Tel Aviv University Ramat-Aviv, Tel Aviv 69978 ISRAEL 1. The Local Lemma In a typical

More information

How Low Can Approximate Degree and Quantum Query Complexity be for Total Boolean Functions?

How Low Can Approximate Degree and Quantum Query Complexity be for Total Boolean Functions? How Low Can Approximate Degree and Quantum Query Complexity be for Total Boolean Functions? Andris Ambainis Ronald de Wolf Abstract It has long been known that any Boolean function that depends on n input

More information

A note on general sliding window processes

A note on general sliding window processes A note on general sliding window processes Noga Alon Ohad N. Feldheim September 19, 214 Abstract Let f : R k [r] = {1, 2,..., r} be a measurable function, and let {U i } i N be a sequence of i.i.d. random

More information

New lower bounds for hypergraph Ramsey numbers

New lower bounds for hypergraph Ramsey numbers New lower bounds for hypergraph Ramsey numbers Dhruv Mubayi Andrew Suk Abstract The Ramsey number r k (s, n) is the minimum N such that for every red-blue coloring of the k-tuples of {1,..., N}, there

More information

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results)

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) Ehrhard Behrends Abstract A metric space (M, d) is said to have the small ball property (sbp) if for every ε 0 > 0 there exists a sequence

More information

Junta Approximations for Submodular, XOS and Self-Bounding Functions

Junta Approximations for Submodular, XOS and Self-Bounding Functions Junta Approximations for Submodular, XOS and Self-Bounding Functions Vitaly Feldman Jan Vondrák IBM Almaden Research Center Simons Institute, Berkeley, October 2013 Feldman-Vondrák Approximations by Juntas

More information

Lectures 6: Degree Distributions and Concentration Inequalities

Lectures 6: Degree Distributions and Concentration Inequalities University of Washington Lecturer: Abraham Flaxman/Vahab S Mirrokni CSE599m: Algorithms and Economics of Networks April 13 th, 007 Scribe: Ben Birnbaum Lectures 6: Degree Distributions and Concentration

More information

Determining a Binary Matroid from its Small Circuits

Determining a Binary Matroid from its Small Circuits Determining a Binary Matroid from its Small Circuits James Oxley Department of Mathematics Louisiana State University Louisiana, USA oxley@math.lsu.edu Charles Semple School of Mathematics and Statistics

More information

Decomposition of Riesz frames and wavelets into a finite union of linearly independent sets

Decomposition of Riesz frames and wavelets into a finite union of linearly independent sets Decomposition of Riesz frames and wavelets into a finite union of linearly independent sets Ole Christensen, Alexander M. Lindner Abstract We characterize Riesz frames and prove that every Riesz frame

More information

Analyzing Boolean functions on the biased hypercube via higher-dimensional agreement tests

Analyzing Boolean functions on the biased hypercube via higher-dimensional agreement tests Analyzing Boolean functions on the biased hypercube via higher-dimensional agreement tests Irit Dinur Yuval Filmus ahladh Harsha August 12, 2018 Abstract We propose a new paradigm for studying the structure

More information

Lecture 10 + additional notes

Lecture 10 + additional notes CSE533: Information Theorn Computer Science November 1, 2010 Lecturer: Anup Rao Lecture 10 + additional notes Scribe: Mohammad Moharrami 1 Constraint satisfaction problems We start by defining bivariate

More information

Katarzyna Mieczkowska

Katarzyna Mieczkowska Katarzyna Mieczkowska Uniwersytet A. Mickiewicza w Poznaniu Erdős conjecture on matchings in hypergraphs Praca semestralna nr 1 (semestr letni 010/11 Opiekun pracy: Tomasz Łuczak ERDŐS CONJECTURE ON MATCHINGS

More information

1 Randomized Computation

1 Randomized Computation CS 6743 Lecture 17 1 Fall 2007 1 Randomized Computation Why is randomness useful? Imagine you have a stack of bank notes, with very few counterfeit ones. You want to choose a genuine bank note to pay at

More information

Nonamenable Products are not Treeable

Nonamenable Products are not Treeable Version of 30 July 1999 Nonamenable Products are not Treeable by Robin Pemantle and Yuval Peres Abstract. Let X and Y be infinite graphs, such that the automorphism group of X is nonamenable, and the automorphism

More information

Homework 1 Solutions

Homework 1 Solutions MATH 171 Spring 2016 Problem 1 Homework 1 Solutions (If you find any errors, please send an e-mail to farana at stanford dot edu) Presenting your arguments in steps, using only axioms of an ordered field,

More information

Separating Monotone VP and VNP

Separating Monotone VP and VNP Electronic Colloquium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 124 (2018) Separating Monotone VP and VNP Amir Yehudayoff Abstract This work is about the monotone versions of the algebraic complexity classes

More information

Two Comments on Targeted Canonical Derandomizers

Two Comments on Targeted Canonical Derandomizers Two Comments on Targeted Canonical Derandomizers Oded Goldreich Department of Computer Science Weizmann Institute of Science Rehovot, Israel. oded.goldreich@weizmann.ac.il April 8, 2011 Abstract We revisit

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.ag] 24 Jun 2015

arxiv: v2 [math.ag] 24 Jun 2015 TRIANGULATIONS OF MONOTONE FAMILIES I: TWO-DIMENSIONAL FAMILIES arxiv:1402.0460v2 [math.ag] 24 Jun 2015 SAUGATA BASU, ANDREI GABRIELOV, AND NICOLAI VOROBJOV Abstract. Let K R n be a compact definable set

More information

Testing Booleanity and the Uncertainty Principle

Testing Booleanity and the Uncertainty Principle Testing Booleanity and the Uncertainty Principle Tom Gur Weizmann Institute of Science tom.gur@weizmann.ac.il Omer Tamuz Weizmann Institute of Science omer.tamuz@weizmann.ac.il Abstract Let f : { 1, 1}

More information

A An Overview of Complexity Theory for the Algorithm Designer

A An Overview of Complexity Theory for the Algorithm Designer A An Overview of Complexity Theory for the Algorithm Designer A.1 Certificates and the class NP A decision problem is one whose answer is either yes or no. Two examples are: SAT: Given a Boolean formula

More information

arxiv:math/ v3 [math.pr] 16 Jun 2005

arxiv:math/ v3 [math.pr] 16 Jun 2005 arxiv:math/0410359v3 [math.pr] 16 Jun 2005 A short proof of the Harris-Kesten Theorem Béla Bollobás Oliver Riordan February 1, 2008 Abstract We give a short proof of the fundamental result that the critical

More information

Economics 204 Fall 2011 Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions

Economics 204 Fall 2011 Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Economics 204 Fall 2011 Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions 1. Suppose k is a positive integer. Use induction to prove the following two statements. (a) For all n N 0, the inequality (k 2 + n)! k 2n holds.

More information

The Turán number of sparse spanning graphs

The Turán number of sparse spanning graphs The Turán number of sparse spanning graphs Noga Alon Raphael Yuster Abstract For a graph H, the extremal number ex(n, H) is the maximum number of edges in a graph of order n not containing a subgraph isomorphic

More information

Two Sides of the Coin Problem

Two Sides of the Coin Problem Electronic Colloquium on Computational Complexity, Report No. 23 (2014) Two Sides of the Coin Problem Gil Cohen Anat Ganor Ran Raz February 19, 2014 Abstract In the coin problem, one is given n independent

More information

14.1 Finding frequent elements in stream

14.1 Finding frequent elements in stream Chapter 14 Streaming Data Model 14.1 Finding frequent elements in stream A very useful statistics for many applications is to keep track of elements that occur more frequently. It can come in many flavours

More information

Nonnegative k-sums, fractional covers, and probability of small deviations

Nonnegative k-sums, fractional covers, and probability of small deviations Nonnegative k-sums, fractional covers, and probability of small deviations Noga Alon Hao Huang Benny Sudakov Abstract More than twenty years ago, Manickam, Miklós, and Singhi conjectured that for any integers

More information

Power in the US Legislature

Power in the US Legislature Power in the US Legislature Victoria Powers May 16, 2017 Abstract Using a standard model of the US legislative system as a monotonic simple game, we look at rankings of the four types of players the president,

More information

Lecture 7 Limits on inapproximability

Lecture 7 Limits on inapproximability Tel Aviv University, Fall 004 Lattices in Computer Science Lecture 7 Limits on inapproximability Lecturer: Oded Regev Scribe: Michael Khanevsky Let us recall the promise problem GapCVP γ. DEFINITION 1

More information

Arrow s Paradox. Prerna Nadathur. January 1, 2010

Arrow s Paradox. Prerna Nadathur. January 1, 2010 Arrow s Paradox Prerna Nadathur January 1, 2010 Abstract In this paper, we examine the problem of a ranked voting system and introduce Kenneth Arrow s impossibility theorem (1951). We provide a proof sketch

More information

Uniform-Distribution Attribute Noise Learnability

Uniform-Distribution Attribute Noise Learnability Uniform-Distribution Attribute Noise Learnability Nader H. Bshouty Technion Haifa 32000, Israel bshouty@cs.technion.ac.il Christino Tamon Clarkson University Potsdam, NY 13699-5815, U.S.A. tino@clarkson.edu

More information

THE NUMBER OF POINTS IN A COMBINATORIAL GEOMETRY WITH NO 8-POINT-LINE MINORS

THE NUMBER OF POINTS IN A COMBINATORIAL GEOMETRY WITH NO 8-POINT-LINE MINORS THE NUMBER OF POINTS IN A COMBINATORIAL GEOMETRY WITH NO 8-POINT-LINE MINORS JOSEPH E. BONIN AND JOSEPH P. S. KUNG ABSTRACT. We show that when n is greater than 3, the number of points in a combinatorial

More information

Neighborly families of boxes and bipartite coverings

Neighborly families of boxes and bipartite coverings Neighborly families of boxes and bipartite coverings Noga Alon Dedicated to Professor Paul Erdős on the occasion of his 80 th birthday Abstract A bipartite covering of order k of the complete graph K n

More information

Löwenheim-Skolem Theorems, Countable Approximations, and L ω. David W. Kueker (Lecture Notes, Fall 2007)

Löwenheim-Skolem Theorems, Countable Approximations, and L ω. David W. Kueker (Lecture Notes, Fall 2007) Löwenheim-Skolem Theorems, Countable Approximations, and L ω 0. Introduction David W. Kueker (Lecture Notes, Fall 2007) In its simplest form the Löwenheim-Skolem Theorem for L ω1 ω states that if σ L ω1

More information

A DECOMPOSITION THEOREM FOR FRAMES AND THE FEICHTINGER CONJECTURE

A DECOMPOSITION THEOREM FOR FRAMES AND THE FEICHTINGER CONJECTURE PROCEEDINGS OF THE AMERICAN MATHEMATICAL SOCIETY Volume 00, Number 0, Pages 000 000 S 0002-9939(XX)0000-0 A DECOMPOSITION THEOREM FOR FRAMES AND THE FEICHTINGER CONJECTURE PETER G. CASAZZA, GITTA KUTYNIOK,

More information

Analysis of Boolean Functions

Analysis of Boolean Functions Analysis of Boolean Functions Kavish Gandhi and Noah Golowich Mentor: Yufei Zhao 5th Annual MIT-PRIMES Conference Analysis of Boolean Functions, Ryan O Donnell May 16, 2015 1 Kavish Gandhi and Noah Golowich

More information

On the measure of intersecting families, uniqueness and stability.

On the measure of intersecting families, uniqueness and stability. On the measure of intersecting families, uniueness and stability. Ehud Friedgut Abstract Let t 1 be an integer and let A be a family of subsets of {1, 2,... n} every two of which intersect in at least

More information

c 2010 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics

c 2010 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics SIAM J. DISCRETE MATH. Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 1038 1045 c 2010 Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics SET SYSTEMS WITHOUT A STRONG SIMPLEX TAO JIANG, OLEG PIKHURKO, AND ZELEALEM YILMA Abstract. A

More information

1 The Low-Degree Testing Assumption

1 The Low-Degree Testing Assumption Advanced Complexity Theory Spring 2016 Lecture 17: PCP with Polylogarithmic Queries and Sum Check Prof. Dana Moshkovitz Scribes: Dana Moshkovitz & Michael Forbes Scribe Date: Fall 2010 In this lecture

More information

Deterministic Extractors - Lecture Notes

Deterministic Extractors - Lecture Notes Deterministic Extractors - Lecture Notes Speaker: Avi Wigderson Scribe: Zeev Dvir February 4, 2009 1 Motivation Randomness is used in many places in our daily lives. Some examples are gambling, statistics,

More information

Module 1. Probability

Module 1. Probability Module 1 Probability 1. Introduction In our daily life we come across many processes whose nature cannot be predicted in advance. Such processes are referred to as random processes. The only way to derive

More information