On the Haezendonck-Goovaerts Risk Measure for Extreme Risks

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "On the Haezendonck-Goovaerts Risk Measure for Extreme Risks"

Transcription

1 On the Haezendonc-Goovaerts Ris Measure for Extreme Riss Qihe Tang [a],[b] and Fan Yang [b] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Iowa 241 Schaeffer Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA [b] Applied Mathematical and Computational Sciences Program University of Iowa 14 MacLean Hall, Iowa City, IA 52242, USA September 21, 211 Abstract In this paper we are concerned with the calculation of the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure, which is defined via a convex Young function and a parameter q, 1) representing the confidence level. We mainly focus on the case in which the ris variable follows a distribution function from a max-domain of attraction. For this case, we restrict the Young function to be a power function and we derive exact asymptotics for the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure as q 1. As a subsidiary, we also consider the case with an exponentially distributed ris variable and a general Young function, and we obtain an analytical expression for the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure. Keywords: Asymptotics; Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure; Max-domain of attraction; Regular/rapid variation; Young function Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 62P5; Secondary 6G7, 91B82, 62E2 1 Introduction Throughout the paper, let X be a real-valued random variable, representing a ris variable in loss-profit style, with a distribution function F = 1 F on R =, ). Let ϕ ) be a non-negative and convex function on [, ) with ϕ) =, ϕ1) = 1 and ϕ ) =. This function is called a normalized Young function, which, due to the convexity of ϕ ), is continuous and strictly increasing. Recall that the Orlicz space associated with the Young function ϕ ) is defined as L ϕ = {X : E [ϕcx)] < for some c > } Corresponding author: Fan Yang; fan-yang-2@uiowa.edu; Cell: ; Fax:

2 and the Orlicz heart as L ϕ = {X : E [ϕcx)] < for all c > }. It is easy to see that L ϕ and L ϕ coincide with each other if lim sup x ϕ2x)/ϕx) < ; see also page 77 of Rao and Ren 1991). For a Young function ϕ ) and a ris variable X L ϕ, let H q [X, x] be the unique solution h to the equation [ )] X x) E ϕ =, q, 1), 1.1) h if F x) > and let H q [X, x] = otherwise, where and throughout the paper, denote by Y = Y 1 Y ) = Y the positive part of a random variable Y and by 1 A the indicator of an event A. The existence and uniqueness of the solution h to equation 1.1) for the case F x) > can be seen from the fact that the left-hand side of 1.1) is a continuous and strictly decreasing function of h > with limits as h and as h. For q, 1), the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure for X is defined as H q [X] = inf x R x H q[x, x]). 1.2) This ris measure was first introduced by Haezendonc and Goovaerts 1982) and was named as the Haezendonc ris measure by Goovaerts et al. 24). Based on a recent conversation with Bellini and Rosazza Gianin during the 15th International Congress on Insurance: Mathematics and Economics in Trieste, we thin that it is more proper to call it the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure in order to acnowledge the contribution of both authors in their seminal paper Haezendonc and Goovaerts 1982). This ris measure has recently been studied by Bellini and Rosazza Gianin 28a, 28b, 211), Nam et al. 211), Krätschmer and Zähle 211), Goovaerts et al. 211) and Ahn and Shyamalumar 211). We have followed the style of Bellini and Rosazza Gianin 28a, 28b) to define this ris measure. As pointed out by Bellini and Rosazza Gianin 28a, 211), the Haezendonc- Goovaerts ris measure H q [X] is a law invariant and coherent ris measure. We remar that, due to its very definition, an analytic expression for H q [X] is not possible in general. The simplest, yet interesting, special case is when ϕt) = t for t. In this case, H q [X] = inf x E [ ]) X x) = F q) E[X F q)) ], 1.3) x R where, and throughout the paper, F q) = inf{x R : F x) q} denotes the inverse function of F, also called the quantile of F or the Value at Ris of X. Thus, the Haezendonc- Goovaerts ris measure is reduced to CTE q [X], the well-nown Conditional Tail Expectation of X. 2

3 The parameter q in the definition of the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure vaguely represents a confidence level. This is demonstrated by the special case above corresponding to ϕt) = t for t. In the post financial crisis era, ris managers become more and more concerned with the tail area of riss due to the excessive prudence of nowadays regulatory framewor. The majority of this paper focuses on the asymptotic behavior of H q [X] as q 1. For a ris variable X with a distribution function F on R, denote by ˆx = F 1) its upper endpoint and by ˆp = PrX = ˆx) the probability assigned to the upper endpoint. Note that ˆp = holds automatically if ˆx = or if F is continuous at ˆx. Theorem 3.1 of Goovaerts et al. 24) shows that F q) H q [X] ˆx. Thus, if < ˆp 1, then H q [X] = ˆx for all 1 ˆp < q < 1, while if ˆp =, then lim H q [X] = ˆx. q 1 We only need to consider the latter case with ˆp =. When ˆx = we shall establish exact asymptotics for H q [X] diverging to as q 1, while when ˆx < we shall establish exact asymptotics for ˆx H q [X] decaying to as q 1. Hence, the notion of extreme value theory becomes relevant. We shall assume that the ris variable X follows a distribution function F from the maxdomain of attraction of an extreme value distribution function. Due to the complexity of the problem, we shall only consider a power Young function, ϕt) = t for 1. We prove the following: If F is from the Fréchet max-domain of attraction, then H q [X] c 1 F q); If F is from the Gumbel max-domain of attraction, then H q [X] F 1 c 2 q) provided ˆx = or ˆx H q [X] ˆx F 1 c 2 q)) provided ˆx < ; If F is from the Weibull max-domain of attraction, then ˆx H q [X] c 3 ˆx F q)). In these assertions, the notation means that the quotient of both sides tends to 1 as q 1 and the coeffi cients c 1, c 2 and c 3 are explicitly given. As a subsidiary, we also consider the case with an exponentially distributed ris variable X and a general Young function ϕ ). For this case, we obtain an analytical expression for the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure H q [X]. However, at this stage we cannot extend the study to the case of both a generally distributed ris variable X and a general Young function ϕ ). The rest of this paper consists of six sections. In Section 2 we establish a general result for the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure with a power Young function. This result forms the 3

4 theoretical basis of our asymptotic analysis. Then after preparing some preliminaries on maxdomains of attraction and regular/rapid variation in Section 3, we derive exact asymptotic formulas for the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure with a power Young function for the Fréchet, Gumbel and Weibull cases in Sections 4, 5 and 6, respectively. For each case, numerical studies are also carried out to examine the accuracies of the asymptotic formulas. In Section 7 we consider the case of an exponentially distributed ris variable and a general Young function. 2 General discussions with a power Young function Let X be a ris variable distributed by F with an upper endpoint ˆx. Assume a power Young function, ϕt) = t for some 1. For this case, the Orlicz space and Orlicz heart coincide with each other, both equal to { X : E[X] < }. As we mentioned before, if = 1, then the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure for X is equal to CTE q [X] given by 1.3). Thus, we only consider > 1 in the following theorem in which we analyze the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure for a general ris variable X: Theorem 2.1 Let the Young function be ϕt) = t for some > 1 and let X be a ris variable with E[X] <, ˆx and PrX = ˆx) =. Then the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure for X is equal to [ ]) 1/ H q [X] = x, q, 1), 2.1) where x = xq), ˆx) is the unique solution to the equation [ ]) 1 [ ]) 1 =. 2.2) The proof of Theorem 2.1 relies on the following elementary result: Lemma 2.1 Consider the function gx) = E [ X x) ] for x R, where 1 is a constant and X is a random variable with E[X ] <. a) If > 1, then gx) is continuously differentiable with d dx gx) = E [ ] X x) 1, x R; 2.3) b) If = 1, then d dx g x) = F x) and d dx g x) = F x ) for each x R. 4

5 Proof. Our derivation for d g dx x) below is good for both > 1 and = 1. Observe that [ ] d E X x x)) dx g E [ ] X x) x) = lim x x = lim x E [ X x) x ] 1 x<x x x) X x x)) X x) 1 X>x x) x = lim x E [I 1 x) I 2 x)]. 2.4) Clearly, I 1 x) x) 1 1 x<x x x). Moreover, there is some ξ between X x x) and X x such that I 2 x) = ξ 1 1 X>x x). These estimates for I 1 x) and I 2 x) enable us to apply the dominated convergence theorem to interchange the order of the limit and expectation in 2.4). Hence, [ ] d dx g x) = E lim I 1 x) lim I 2 x) = E [ ] X x) 1. x x When = 1, this gives d dx g x) = F x). For d dx g x), we need to distinguish the cases > 1 and = 1. For > 1, going along the same lines as above we obtain d dx g x) = E [ ] X x) 1. For = 1, we have [ ] d dx g E X x x)) E [X x) ] x) = lim x x = lim x E [ X x x) x 1 x x<x<x) 1 X x) ]. Clearly, the first term after the expectation, denoted by I 3 x), satisfies I 3 x) 1 x x<x<x). Hence, by the dominated convergence theorem, [ ] d dx g x) = E lim I 3 x) 1 X x) x = F x ). Finally, for > 1, the expression for d gx) given by 2.3) is obviously continuous in dx x R. This ends the proof of Lemma

6 Proof of Theorem 2.1. For ϕt) = t, it follows straightforwardly from 1.1) that [ ] H q [X, x] = ) 1/. By virtue of Minowsi s inequality, one can easily verify that H q [X, ] is convex over R and is strictly convex over, ˆx); see also Proposition 3 of Bellini and Rosazza Gianin 211). Write g x) = x [ ]) 1/, x R, so that H q [X] = inf x R g x). The function g ) inherits the convexity of H q [X, ] and g x) diverges to as x ±. Hence, its overall infimum is attainable. To obtain this infimum, we naturally consider the equation d dx g x) =. By Lemma 2.1a), [ ]) d 1/) 1 [ ] dx g x) = ) ) 1/ Thus, the equation d dx g x) = is equivalent to 2.2). For every q, 1), the existence of a solution x, ˆx) to 2.2) can be verified as follows. The left-hand side of 2.2) is a continuous function of x R. As x, applying the dominated convergence theorem to both the numerator and denominator yields that [ [ ]) 1 X x) 1 ]) E x) [ ]) 1 = 1 [ ]) X x) 1 1; E x) while as x ˆx, applying Hölder s inequality to the numerator yields that [ ]) 1 [ ]) 1 1 X>x) [ ]) 1 = [ ]) 1 E [ X x) ]) 1 E [ 1X>x) ] E [ X x) ]) 1 = F x). 2.6) Moreover, the uniqueness of the solution to equation 2.2), or, equivalently, to the equation d dx g x) =, is ensured by the strict convexity of the function g ) on, ˆx). This ends the proof of Theorem 2.1. When proceeding our asymptotic analysis we shall need the following lemma too: Lemma 2.2 Consider equation 2.2) in which 1 is a constant, X is a random variable with E[X ] <, ˆx and PrX = ˆx) =, and q, 1), x, ˆx) are two deterministic variables. Then q 1 if and only if x ˆx. 6

7 Proof. For = 1, equation 2.2) is simplified to F x) =. Thus, the equivalence of q 1 and x ˆx is obvious. Now consider > 1 only. The derivation in 2.6) shows that the left-hand side of 2.2) is bounded by F x). Thus, F x), from which we easily infer that x ˆx implies q 1. Conversely, the proof of Theorem 2.1 shows that the function g ) is strictly convex over, ˆx). Thus, d dx g x) given by 2.5) is strictly increasing in x, ˆx), or, equivalently, the left-hand side of 2.2) is strictly decreasing in x, ˆx). Thus, q 1 must lead to x ˆx. 3 Max-domains of attraction and regular variation In this section we highlight some basic concepts in extreme value theory. Monographs on extreme value theory in the context of insurance and finance are Resnic 1987, 27), Embrechts et al. 1997), McNeil et al. 25) and Malevergne and Sornette 26), among others. In this paper we follow the main methodology of Hashorva et al. 21) and Asimit et al. 211), who studied some insurance problems using extreme value theory. A distribution function F on R is said to belong to the max-domain of attraction of an extreme value distribution function G, written as F MDAG), if lim sup F n c n x d n ) Gx) = n x R holds for some norming constants c n > and d n R, n N = {, 1,...}. By the classical Fisher-Tippett theorem see Fisher and Tippett 1928) and Gnedeno 1943)), only three choices for G are possible, namely the Fréchet, Gumbel and Weibull distributions, which we denote by Φ γ, Λ and Ψ γ, respectively, with γ > indexing members of the Fréchet and Weibull max-domains of attraction. The Fréchet distribution function is given by Φ γ x) = exp { x γ } for x >. A distribution function F belongs to MDAΦ γ ) if and only if its upper endpoint ˆx is infinite and the relation holds; see Theorem of Embrechts et al. 1997). F xy) lim x F x) = y γ, y >, 3.1) The standard Gumbel distribution function is given by Λx) = exp { e x } for x R. A distribution function F with an upper endpoint ˆx belongs to MDAΛ) if and only if the relation F x yax)) lim x ˆx F x) = e y, y R, 3.2) holds for some positive auxiliary function a ) on, ˆx). Recall that a ) is unique up to asymptotic equivalence and a commonly-used choice for ax) is the mean excess function, 7

8 ax) = E [X x X > x] for x < ˆx. Recall also that { ax) = ox), if ˆx =, ax) = oˆx x), if ˆx <. 3.3) See Resnic 1987) and Embrechts et al. 1997) for more details. The following representation theorem is useful; see Balema and de Haan 1972), Proposition 1.4 of Resnic 1987) or relation 3.35) of Embrechts et al. 1997). For F MDAΛ) with ˆx, there is some x < ˆx such that { x } 1 F x) = bx) exp x ay) dy, x < x < ˆx, 3.4) where a ) is an auxiliary function, chosen to be positive and absolutely continuous with lim x ˆx d ax) =, and b ) is a positive measurable function with lim dx x ˆx bx) = b >. The Weibull distribution function is given by Ψ γ x) = exp { x γ } for x. A distribution function F belongs to MDAΨ γ ) if and only if its upper endpoint ˆx is finite and see Theorem of Embrechts et al. 1997). F ˆx xy) lim x F ˆx x) = yγ, y > ; 3.5) The following elementary result might be nown somewhere but we cannot suitably address a reference: Lemma 3.1 Let F on R belong to the max-domain of attraction of a non-degenerate distribution function. Then a) F x ) F x) as x ˆx; b) F F q)) as q 1. Proof. a) The result for the Gumbel case is nown in Corollary 1.6 of Resnic 1987). The result for the Fréchet and Weibull cases easily follows from the equivalent conditions 3.1) and 3.5), respectively. b) This follows from the two-sided inequality F F q)) F F q) ) and the result in a). It is often convenient and useful to restate the equivalent conditions for the max-domains of attraction in terms of regular or rapid variation. A positive measurable function r ) is said to be regularly varying at x = ± or ± with a regularity index α, ), denoted by r ) R α x ), if rxy) lim x x rx) = yα, y >. 8

9 The class R x ) consists of functions slowly varying at x. Moreover, a positive measurable function r ) is said to be rapidly varying at x = ± or ±, denoted by r ) R x ) or 1/r ) R x ), if { rxy), for y > 1, lim x x rx) =, for < y < 1. Relation 3.1) shows that F MDAΦ γ ) if and only if F ) R γ ), while relation 3.5) shows that F MDAΨ γ ) if and only if F ˆx ) R γ ). Furthermore, for F MDAΛ), it easily follows from relations 3.2) and 3.3) that F ) R ) provided ˆx = or F ˆx ) R ) provided ˆx <. Recall Potter s bounds as summarized by Theorem of Bingham et al. 1987): Lemma 3.2 Let r ) be a function regularly varying at x = or with index α, ). It holds for arbitrary < ε < 1 and all x, y suffi ciently close to x that y αε y ) ) α ε 1 ε) x) ry) y αε y ) ) α ε 1 ε). x rx) x) x The following lemma is motivated by Proposition 1.1 of Davis and Resnic 1988): Lemma 3.3 Let F MDAΛ) with the representation given by 3.4). Then, for arbitrary < ε < 1, there is some x < ˆx such that, for all x < x < ˆx and all y, F x yax)) F x) 1 ε)1 εy) 1/ε. Proof. Since lim x ˆx d ax) =, there is some x dx < ˆx such that the inequality ax zax)) ax) εzax) holds for all x < x < ˆx and all z. It follows that Hence, for all x < x < ˆx and all y, F x yax)) F x) This proves Lemma 3.3. = = ax) ax zax)) 1 1 εz. bx yax)) bx) bx yax)) bx) 1 ε) exp exp { { { exp y = 1 ε)1 εy) 1/ε. 9 xyax) x y 1 1 εz dz } 1 az) dz } ax) ax zax)) dz }

10 4 The Fréchet case with a power Young function Our asymptotic analysis in the next three sections is based on Theorem 2.1. In this section we consider the Fréchet case. As usual, denote by B, ) the beta function, namely, Ba, b) = 1 x a 1 1 x) b 1 dx, a, b >. Theorem 4.1 Let ϕt) = t for some 1 and let F MDAΦ γ ) for some γ >. Then, as q 1, H q [X] We first prepare an elementary result: γ γ )/γ) 1 1)/γ B γ, )) 1/γ F q). 4.1) Lemma 4.1 If F MDAΦ γ ) for some γ >, then it holds for all < < γ that E [ ] X x) lim = Bγ, ). 4.2) x x F x) Proof. Since F ) R γ ), by Lemma 3.2, for arbitrary < ε < γ, there is some x > such that, for all x > x and all y, ) γ ε x y 1 ε) x F x y) F x) ) γε x y 1 ε). x By the second inequality above, it holds for all x > x that E [ ] X x) F x y) = dy F x) F x) ) γε x y 1 ε) dy x = 1 ε)x z 1) γε dz. By the arbitrariness of ε, it follows that E [ ] X x) lim sup x x F x) z 1) γ dz. In the same way we can establish the corresponding inequality for the lower limit. In addition, using the change of variables u = z 1) 1 we have Thus, relation 4.2) holds. z 1) γ dz = 1 u γ 1 1 u) 1 du = Bγ, ). 1

11 Proof of Theorem 4.1. In the proof below we shall tacitly use this equivalence. Recall Lemma 2.2, which shows that q 1 if and only if x ˆx. We distinguish the cases = 1 and > 1. For = 1, applying Lemmas 4.1 and 3.1b) to relation 1.3) we have This proves relation 4.1) for = 1. H q [X] F q) F q) F F q)) γ 1 γ γ 1 F q). Now turn to the case > 1. Starting from Theorem 2.1 we need to approximate the optimal value of x that solves equation 2.2). By Lemma 4.1, = [ ]) 1 E [ X x) ]) 1 or, equivalently, 1)Bγ 1, 1)) F x) Bγ, )) 1 = γ ) Bγ, ) F x), 1 F x) 1 ). 4.3) γ ) Bγ, ) By Proposition.8V) of Resnic 1987), it is easy to verify that F ) R γ ) if and only if F 1 ) R 1/γ ). It follows from 4.3) that ) ) x = F 1 o1)) 1 γ ) 1/γ Bγ, ) 1 ) F q). 4.4) γ ) Bγ, ) 1 Now, substituting 4.2), 4.3) and 4.4) into 2.1) yields that H q [X] = x E [ X x) ] Bγ, ) x Bγ, ) x = γ γ x γ γ )/γ) 1 1)/γ This proves relation 4.1) for > 1. ) 1/ ) 1/ x F x) ) 1 1/ ) x γ ) Bγ, ) B γ, )) 1/γ F q). 11

12 Let us use R to numerically examine the accuracy of the asymptotic relation 4.1). Assume that F is a Pareto distribution given by ) α θ F x) = 1, x, α, θ >. x θ Thus, F MDAΦ γ ) with γ = α. We use uniroot to find the root x to 2.2) and then compute 2.1) to get the exact value of the Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measure H q [X]. Moreover, we compute the asymptotic formula given by 4.1). In both graphs below, we compare the asymptotic estimate to the exact value on the left and show their ratio on the right. For Graph 4.1, we set = 1.1 and 1.2, α = 1.6, and θ = 1. Apparently, the ratio converges to 1 as q 1. We also find that the accuracy improves as decreases. Graph 4.1 is inserted here. Similarly, for Graph 4.2, we set = 1.1, α = 1.5 and 1.6, and θ = 1. We find that the ratio converges to 1 as q 1 and that the accuracy improves gradually as α decreases. Graph 4.2 is inserted here. 5 The Gumbel case with a power Young function Now we consider the Gumbel case. Note that, for a random variable X distributed by F MDAΛ), the requirement E [ X ] < for all 1 holds automatically since either F R ) or ˆx <. As usual, denote by Γ ) the gamma function, namely, Γa) = x a 1 e x dx, a >. Theorem 5.1 Let ϕt) = t for some 1 and let F MDAΛ) with an upper endpoint < ˆx. Then, as q 1, i) when ˆx = we have ii) when ˆx < we have H q [X] F 1 ˆx H q [X] ˆx F 1 To prove Theorem 5.1, we first prepare an elementary result: ) ) ; 5.1) Γ 1) ) ). 5.2) Γ 1) 12

13 Lemma 5.1 If F MDAΛ) with an upper endpoint < ˆx, then it holds for all > that [ ] lim = Γ 1), 5.3) x ˆx a x)f x) where a ) is the auxiliary function appearing in the representation given by 3.4). Proof. When ˆx =, we have E [ ] X x) = F x y)dy = a x)f x) a x)f x) F x zax)) dz F x) e z dz, where in the last step we applied the dominated convergence theorem justified by Lemma 3.3. Similarly, when ˆx <, recalling 3.3) we have E [ ] ˆx x X x) = F x y)dy = a x)f x) a x)f x) Thus, for both cases, relation 5.3) holds. ˆx x)/ax) e z dz. F x zax)) dz F x) Proof of Theorem 5.1. In the proof below, we shall tacitly use the equivalence of q 1 and x ˆx, as shown by Lemma 2.2. The auxiliary function a ) appearing below corresponds to the one in the representation given by 3.4). i) We distinguish the cases = 1 and > 1. For = 1, applying Lemma 5.1 to relation 1.3) and then applying Lemma 3.1 and relation 3.3), we have This proves relation 5.1) for = 1. H q [X] F q) af q)) F F q)) For > 1, applying Lemma 5.1 to relation 2.2) leads to F q). = [ ]) 1 [ ]) 1 Γ)a 1 x)f x) ) Γ 1)a x)f x) ) 1 = Γ 1) F x). 5.4) Then, substituting 5.3) and 5.4) to 2.1) yields that [ ]) 1/ H q [X] x = ax), 5.5) 13

14 which implies that H q [X] x. By Proposition.8V) of Resnic 1987), F ) R ) implies F 1 ) R ). By this and 5.4) we have ) ) x = F 1 1 o1)) ) F 1 ). 5.6) Γ 1) Γ 1) This leads to relation 5.1) for > 1. ii) As before, we still distinguish the cases = 1 and > 1. For = 1, applying Lemma 5.1 to relation 1.3) and then applying Lemma 3.1 and relation 3.3), we have This proves relation 5.2) for = 1. ˆx H q [X] = ˆx F q)) E[X F q)) ] ˆx F q)) af q)) F F q)) ˆx F q). Next consider > 1. For this case the relations in 5.4) still hold. Then, substituting 5.3) and 5.4) to 2.1) yields that ˆx H q [X]) ˆx x) = [ ]) 1/ ax), 5.7) which implies that ˆx H q [X] ˆx x. By Proposition.8V) of Resnic 1987), F ˆx ) R ) implies ˆx F 1 ) R ). By this and 5.4) we have ) ) ˆx x = ˆx F 1 1 o1)) ) ˆx F 1 ). 5.8) Γ 1) Γ 1) This proves relation 5.2) for > 1. In the proof above, the asymptotics for x given by relation 5.6) can actually be changed to x F 1 c)) for any c > because F 1 ) R ). Similarly, the asymptotics for ˆx x given by relation 5.8) can be changed to ˆx x ˆx F 1 c)) for any c >. However, the most rational choice for c in both places should be c = /Γ 1). We would lie to point out that relations 5.5) and 5.7) give second-order asymptotics for H q [X]. They become more powerful than 5.1) and 5.2) provided that it is possible to get the exact value of x solving 2.2) or a good approximation for x. and Recall that a distribution function F belongs to the class Lλ) for some λ > if ˆx = F x y) lim x F x) = e λy, y R. 5.9) The class Lλ) contains many well-nown light-tailed distributions such as the exponential, gamma and inverse Gaussian distributions. Relation 5.9) directly shows that F MDAΛ) with a ) 1/λ. Thus, by 5.5) we arrive at the following: 14

15 Corollary 5.1 Let ϕt) = t for some > 1 and let F Lλ) for some λ >. Then lim H q [X] x) = q 1 λ, ) where x is determined by 2.2) and satisfies x F 1 ). Γ1) Finally, we use R to numerically examine the accuracy of the asymptotics given by 5.5). Assume that F is a lognormal distribution given by ) ln x µ F x) = Φ, x >, < µ <, σ >, σ where Φ ) denotes the standard normal distribution function. Note that ax) = Φσ 1 ln x µ))σx φσ 1 ln x µ)), where φ is the standard normal density function; see, e.g. page 15 of Embrechts et al. 1997). For Graph 5.1, we set = 1.5 and 2, µ = 2, and σ =.5. We compare the asymptotic estimate x ax) given by 5.5) to the exact value of H q [X] on the left and show their ratio on the right. Apparently, the ratio converges to 1 as q 1. We find that the accuracy is particularly good when σ is smaller than 1. Graph 5.1 is inserted here. 6 The Weibull case with a power Young function In the last section of asymptotic analysis we consider the Weibull case. For this case the requirement E [ X ] < for all 1 holds automatically since ˆx <. Theorem 6.1 Let ϕt) = t for some 1 and let F MDAΨ γ ) with γ > and < ˆx <. Then, as q 1, ) ˆx H q [X] γ 1/γ 1 ˆx F q)). 6.1) γ B γ 1, ) γ ) We first prepare an elementary result: Lemma 6.1 If F MDAΨ γ ) with γ > and < ˆx <, then it holds for all > that [ ] X x) lim = B γ 1, ). 6.2) ˆx x) F x) x ˆx E 15

16 Proof. Similarly as in the proof of Lemma 5.1, for x < ˆx, E [ ] ˆx x X x) = F x y)dy = F x) ˆx x F ˆx ˆx x y)) dy. 6.3) F ˆx ˆx x)) Since F ˆx ) R γ ), by Lemma 3.2, for arbitrary < ε < 1, there is some x < ˆx such that, for all x < x < ˆx and all < y < ˆx x, ) γε ) γ ε ˆx x y F ˆx ˆx x y)) ˆx x y 1 ε) 1 ε). ˆx x F ˆx ˆx x)) ˆx x Applying the second inequality above to 6.3), it holds for all x < x < ˆx that E [ ] ˆx x ) γ ε ˆx x y X x) 1 ε)f x) dy ˆx x 1 = 1 ε)f x) ˆx x) 1 z) γ ε dz. By the arbitrariness of ε, it follows that E [ ] X x) lim sup x ˆx ˆx x) F x) 1 1 z) γ dz. A corresponding lower bound can be obtained similarly. Thus, relation 6.2) holds. Proof of Theorem 6.1. In the proof below, we shall tacitly use the equivalence of q 1 and x ˆx, as shown by Lemma 2.2. We distinguish the cases = 1 and > 1. For = 1, starting from relation 1.3) and then applying Lemmas 6.1 and 3.1, we have ˆx H q [X] = ˆx F q)) E[X F q)) ] ˆx F q)) 1 γ 1 ˆx F q)) F F q)) γ γ 1 ˆx F q)). This proves relation 6.1) for = 1. Now consider > 1. Applying Lemma 6.1 to relation 2.2), we have = [ ]) 1 E [ X x) ]) 1 1)B γ 1, 1) ˆx x) 1 F x) ) 1 B γ 1, ) ˆx x) F x) ) = B γ 1, ) γ ) 1 F x). 6.4) 16

17 Substituting 6.2) and 6.4) into 2.1) yields that [ ]) 1/ H q [X] x = ˆx x). 6.5) γ By Proposition.8V) of Resnic 1987), F ˆx ) R γ ) implies ˆx F 1 ) R 1/γ ). Thus, after rewriting 6.4) as we see that F ˆx ˆx x)) ) 1 B γ 1, ) γ ), ) ˆx x = ˆx F 1 o1)) 1 1 ) B γ 1, ) γ ) ) 1/γ 1 ˆx F q)). 6.6) B γ 1, ) γ ) Finally, by 6.5) and 6.6), ˆx H q [X] = ˆx x) H q [X] x) γ ˆx x) γ ) γ 1/γ 1 ˆx F q)). γ B γ 1, ) γ ) This proves relation 6.1) for > 1. Similarly as before, we use R to numerically examine the accuracy of relation 6.1). Assume that F is a beta distribution with probability density function given by fx) = xa 1 1 x) b 1, < x < 1, a, b >. Ba, b) Thus, F MDAΨ γ ) with γ = b. We compare the asymptotic estimate for ˆx H q [X] given by relation 6.1) to its exact value on the left and show their ratio on the right. For Graph 6.1, we set = 3 and 6, a = 2, and b = 6. Apparently, the ratio converges to 1 as q 1. We also find that the varying value of does not affect much the convergence rate. Graph 6.1 is inserted here. For Graph 6.2, we set = 3, a = 2 and b = 6 or 1. The same as before, the ratio converges to 1 as q 1. We also find that the accuracy slightly improves as b increases. Graph 6.2 is inserted here. 17

18 7 The exponential case with a general Young function In this section we consider the case in which the ris variable X is exponentially distributed and the Young function is general. We see an analytical expression for the Haezendonc- Goovaerts ris measure. Theorem 7.1 Let ϕ ) be a general Young function such that e st dϕt) < for all s > and let X follow an exponential distribution function with rate λ >, namely, F x) = e λx for x. Then H q [X] = 1 λ ln e λht dϕt) h, q, 1), 7.1) where h, ) is the unique solution to the equation e λht dϕt) = te λht dϕt). 7.2) The condition on the Young function ϕ ) ensures that the exponential ris variable X belongs to the Orlicz heart of ϕ ). It is interesting to notice that the solution h to equation 7.2) is invariant with both q and x. In order to prove Theorem 7.1, we first prepare an elementary result below: Lemma 7.1 Let ϕ ) be a general Young function such that e st dϕt) < for all s >. Then te st dϕt) te st dϕt) lim = and lim s e st =. 7.3) dϕt) s e st dϕt) Proof. With arbitrary M > we derive te st dϕt) e st dϕt) M te st dϕt) M e st dϕt) M M e st dϕt) ϕm) M e st dϕt) M e st dϕt) M = M, as s, ϕm) 1 M e st dϕt) where the last step is due to the monotone convergence theorem and ϕ ) =. Hence, the first relation in 7.3) holds by the arbitrariness of M. Notice that, with arbitrary < ε < 1, Similarly, ε ε te st dϕt) te st dϕt) ε ε te st dϕt) ε/2 te st dϕt) lim s ε ε te st dϕt) ε ε 2 e sε ϕε) ϕ ε 2 e st dϕt) e st dϕt) =. 18 )), as s.

19 It follows that te st ε dϕt) lim sup = lim sup te st dϕt) s e st ε dϕt) s e st dϕt) ε. Hence, the second relation in 7.3) holds by the arbitrariness of ε. Proof of Theorem 7.1. Goovaerts ris measure in the following way. First of all, let us modify the definition of the Haezendonc- We thin of x in 1.1) as x = x q [X, h], a function of h and q, and introduce g h) = x h. Then we can rewrite 1.2) as H q [X] = inf <h< g h). 7.4) Our idea is to find the optimal value of h at which the infimum in 7.4) is attained. Relation 1.1) is rewritten as e λht dϕt) = ) e λx, which implies that x = 1 λ ln e λht dϕt). 7.5) Under the condition on ϕ ), it is easy to see that e λht dϕt) is infinitely differentiable with respect to h, ). By 7.5), dx dh = te λht dϕt) e λht dϕt). Furthermore, by Hölder s inequality, d 2 x dh = λ t 2 e λht dϕt) e λht dϕt) te λht dϕt) ) 2 2 e λht dϕt) ) 2 >, where the strict inequality is due to the non-degeneracy of the Young function ϕ ). This means that the function x = x q [X, h] and, hence, the function g h) = x h are strictly convex over h, ). Thus, the infimum in 7.4) is attained at h such that d te λht dϕt) dh g h) = e λht dϕt) 1 = 7.6) provided that this last equation admits a solution. Equations 7.6) and 7.2) are equivalent. The existence of a solution h, ) to equation 7.6) is justified by Lemma 7.1, while the uniqueness of the solution h to equation 7.6) results from the strict convexity of the function g ) over, ). Finally, substituting this optimal value h and the expression for x given by 7.1) into 7.4), we obtain the desired expression for H q [X] in 7.1). By Theorem 7.1, the calculation of H q [X] is reduced to solving equation 7.2). a general Young function ϕ ), it is not possible to solve this equation analytically. consider the following special cases: For We 19

20 i) Let ϕt) = t for some 1. Then equation 7.2) has a unique positive solution h = /λ. Thus, H q [X] = 1 λ ln Γ 1) ) λ, which is consistent with Corollary 5.1. ii) Let ϕt) = n =1 a t for some n N and some real-valued coeffi cients a 1,..., a n fulfilling a certain condition such that ϕ ) is a normalized Young function. Then equation 7.2) becomes n 1 a 1 λh) n 1)a 1 a ) Γ 1)λh) n na n Γn 1) =. 7.7) =1 We can always numerically solve this polynomial equation 7.7) in R. For example, let ϕt) = 2t 5 3t 4 2t 3 3t 2 t)/7, q =.95 and λ = 1. Equation 7.7) becomes h 5 5h 4 24h 3 18h 2 48h 12 =. We use polyroot to find its unique positive solution h = Plugging it in 7.1) gives H q [X] = Acnowledgments. The wor was supported by the Centers of Actuarial Excellence CAE) Research Grant ) from the Society of Actuaries. References [1] Ahn, J. Y.; Shyamalumar, N. D. Asymptotic theory for the empirical Haezendonc ris measure. Woring Paper 211), University of Iowa. [2] Asimit, A. V.; Furman, E.; Tang, Q.; Vernic, R. Asymptotics for ris capital allocations based on conditional tail expectation. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 3, [3] Balema, A. A.; de Haan, L. On R. von Mises condition for the domain of attraction of exp e x ). Ann. Math. Statist ), [4] Bellini, F.; Rosazza Gianin, E. On Haezendonc ris measures. J. Ban Finance 32 28a), no. 6, [5] Bellini, F.; Rosazza Gianin, E. Optimal portfolios with Haezendonc ris measures. Statist. Decisions 26 28b), no. 2, [6] Bellini, F.; Rosazza Gianin, E. Haezendonc-Goovaerts ris measures and Orlicz quantiles. Insurance Math. Econom. 211), to appear. [7] Davis, R.; Resnic, S. Extremes of moving averages of random variables from the domain of attraction of the double exponential distribution. Stochastic Process. Appl ), no. 1,

21 [8] Embrechts, P.; Klüppelberg, C.; Miosch, T. Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, [9] Fisher, R. A.; Tippett, L. H. C. Limiting forms of the frequency distribution of the largest or smallest member of a sample. Math. Proc. Cambridge Philos. Soc ), no. 2, [1] Gnedeno, B. Sur la distribution limite du terme maximum d une série aléatoire. French) Ann. of Math ), no. 2, [11] Goovaerts, M. J.; Kaas, R.; Dhaene, J.; Tang, Q. Some new classes of consistent ris measures. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 3, [12] Goovaerts, M. J.; Linders, D.; Van Weert, K.; Tan, F. On the interplay between distortion -, mean value - and Haezendonc ris measures. Insurance Math. Econom. 211), to appear. [13] Haezendonc, J.; Goovaerts, M. A new premium calculation principle based on Orlicz norms. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 1, [14] Hashorva, E.; Paes, A. G.; Tang, Q. Asymptotics of random contractions. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 3, [15] Kortscha, D.; Albrecher, H. Asymptotic results for the sum of dependent nonidentically distributed random variables. Methodol. Comput. Appl. Probab ), no. 3, [16] Krätschmer, V.; Zähle, H. Sensitivity of ris measures with respect to the normal approximation of total claim distributions. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 3, [17] Malevergne, Y.; Sornette, D. Extreme Financial Riss. From Dependence to Ris Management. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 26. [18] McNeil, A. J.; Frey, R.; Embrechts, P. Quantitative Ris Management. Concepts, Techniques and Tools. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 25. [19] Nam, H. S.; Tang, Q.; Yang, F. Characterization of upper comonotonicity via tail convex order. Insurance Math. Econom ), no. 3, [2] Rao, M. M.; Ren, Z. D. Theory of Orlicz Spaces. Marcel Deer, Inc., New Yor, [21] Resnic, S. I. Extreme Values, Regular Variation, and Point Processes. Springer-Verlag, New Yor, [22] Resnic, S. I. Heavy-tail Phenomena. Probabilistic and Statistical Modeling. Springer, New Yor,

22 Haezendonc Goovaerts ris measure Asymptotic Exact =1.2 =1.1 Ratio of asymptotic estimate to exact value =1.1 = q q Graph 4.1 Young function with =1.1 and 1.2, and Pareto distribution with α=1.6 and θ=1

23 Haezendonc Goovaerts ris measure Asymptotic Exact α=1.5 α=1.6 Ratio of asymptotic estimate to exact value α=1.5 α= q q Graph 4.2 Young function with =1.1, and Pareto distribution with α=1.5 and 1.6 and θ=1

24 Haezendonc Goovaerts ris measure Asymptotic Exact =2 =1.5 Ratio of asymptotic estimate to exact value =1.5 = q q Graph 5.1 Young function with =1.5 and 2, and lognormal distribution with µ=2 and σ=.5

25 Haezendonc Goovaerts ris measure Asymptotic Exact =6 =3 Ratio of asymptotic estimate to exact value =3 = q q Graph 6.1 Young function with =3 and 6, and beta distribution with a=2 and b=6

26 Haezendonc Goovaerts ris measure Asymptotic Exact b=6 b=1 Ratio of asymptotic estimate to exact value b=6 b= q q Graph 6.2 Young function with =3, and beta distribution with a=2 and b=6 and 1

Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks

Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks University of Iowa Iowa Research Online Theses and Dissertations Summer 23 Asymptotics for Risk Measures of Extreme Risks Fan Yang University of Iowa Copyright 23 Fan Yang This dissertation is available

More information

The Subexponential Product Convolution of Two Weibull-type Distributions

The Subexponential Product Convolution of Two Weibull-type Distributions The Subexponential Product Convolution of Two Weibull-type Distributions Yan Liu School of Mathematics and Statistics Wuhan University Wuhan, Hubei 4372, P.R. China E-mail: yanliu@whu.edu.cn Qihe Tang

More information

Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order

Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order Characterization of Upper Comonotonicity via Tail Convex Order Hee Seok Nam a,, Qihe Tang a, Fan Yang b a Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Iowa, 241 Schaeffer Hall, Iowa City,

More information

Asymptotics for Risk Capital Allocations based on Conditional Tail Expectation

Asymptotics for Risk Capital Allocations based on Conditional Tail Expectation Asymptotics for Risk Capital Allocations based on Conditional Tail Expectation Alexandru V. Asimit Cass Business School, City University, London EC1Y 8TZ, United Kingdom. E-mail: asimit@city.ac.uk Edward

More information

Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables

Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables Jaap Geluk 1 and Qihe Tang 2 1 Department of Mathematics The Petroleum Institute P.O. Box 2533, Abu Dhabi, United Arab

More information

WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA

WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA Adv. Appl. Prob. 37, 510 522 2005 Printed in Northern Ireland Applied Probability Trust 2005 WEIGHTED SUMS OF SUBEXPONENTIAL RANDOM VARIABLES AND THEIR MAXIMA YIQING CHEN, Guangdong University of Technology

More information

EXTREMAL QUANTILES OF MAXIMUMS FOR STATIONARY SEQUENCES WITH PSEUDO-STATIONARY TREND WITH APPLICATIONS IN ELECTRICITY CONSUMPTION ALEXANDR V.

EXTREMAL QUANTILES OF MAXIMUMS FOR STATIONARY SEQUENCES WITH PSEUDO-STATIONARY TREND WITH APPLICATIONS IN ELECTRICITY CONSUMPTION ALEXANDR V. MONTENEGRIN STATIONARY JOURNAL TREND WITH OF ECONOMICS, APPLICATIONS Vol. IN 9, ELECTRICITY No. 4 (December CONSUMPTION 2013), 53-63 53 EXTREMAL QUANTILES OF MAXIMUMS FOR STATIONARY SEQUENCES WITH PSEUDO-STATIONARY

More information

A Note on Tail Behaviour of Distributions. the max domain of attraction of the Frechét / Weibull law under power normalization

A Note on Tail Behaviour of Distributions. the max domain of attraction of the Frechét / Weibull law under power normalization ProbStat Forum, Volume 03, January 2010, Pages 01-10 ISSN 0974-3235 A Note on Tail Behaviour of Distributions in the Max Domain of Attraction of the Frechét/ Weibull Law under Power Normalization S.Ravi

More information

Extreme Value Theory and Applications

Extreme Value Theory and Applications Extreme Value Theory and Deauville - 04/10/2013 Extreme Value Theory and Introduction Asymptotic behavior of the Sum Extreme (from Latin exter, exterus, being on the outside) : Exceeding the ordinary,

More information

Characterization through Hazard Rate of heavy tailed distributions and some Convolution Closure Properties

Characterization through Hazard Rate of heavy tailed distributions and some Convolution Closure Properties Characterization through Hazard Rate of heavy tailed distributions and some Convolution Closure Properties Department of Statistics and Actuarial - Financial Mathematics, University of the Aegean October

More information

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables

Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Explicit Bounds for the Distribution Function of the Sum of Dependent Normally Distributed Random Variables Walter Schneider July 26, 20 Abstract In this paper an analytic expression is given for the bounds

More information

Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule

Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule Faculty of Economics and Applied Economics Some results on Denault s capital allocation rule Steven Vanduffel and Jan Dhaene DEPARTMENT OF ACCOUNTANCY, FINANCE AND INSURANCE (AFI) AFI 0601 Some Results

More information

Precise Asymptotics of Generalized Stochastic Order Statistics for Extreme Value Distributions

Precise Asymptotics of Generalized Stochastic Order Statistics for Extreme Value Distributions Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 5, 2011, no. 22, 1089-1102 Precise Asymptotics of Generalied Stochastic Order Statistics for Extreme Value Distributions Rea Hashemi and Molood Abdollahi Department

More information

Convex Functions and Optimization

Convex Functions and Optimization Chapter 5 Convex Functions and Optimization 5.1 Convex Functions Our next topic is that of convex functions. Again, we will concentrate on the context of a map f : R n R although the situation can be generalized

More information

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums

Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Comonotonicity and Maximal Stop-Loss Premiums Jan Dhaene Shaun Wang Virginia Young Marc J. Goovaerts November 8, 1999 Abstract In this paper, we investigate the relationship between comonotonicity and

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures F. Bellini 1, B. Klar 2, A. Müller 3, E. Rosazza Gianin 1 1 Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca 2 Institut für Stochastik,

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Bellini, Klar, Muller, Rosazza Gianin December 1, 2014 Vorisek Jan Introduction Quantiles q α of a random variable X can be defined as the minimizers of a piecewise

More information

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics

Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics Shape of the return probability density function and extreme value statistics 13/09/03 Int. Workshop on Risk and Regulation, Budapest Overview I aim to elucidate a relation between one field of research

More information

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures

Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Remarks on quantiles and distortion risk measures Jan Dhaene Alexander Kukush y Daniël Linders z Qihe Tang x Version: October 7, 202 Abstract Distorted expectations can be expressed as weighted averages

More information

AN ASYMPTOTICALLY UNBIASED MOMENT ESTIMATOR OF A NEGATIVE EXTREME VALUE INDEX. Departamento de Matemática. Abstract

AN ASYMPTOTICALLY UNBIASED MOMENT ESTIMATOR OF A NEGATIVE EXTREME VALUE INDEX. Departamento de Matemática. Abstract AN ASYMPTOTICALLY UNBIASED ENT ESTIMATOR OF A NEGATIVE EXTREME VALUE INDEX Frederico Caeiro Departamento de Matemática Faculdade de Ciências e Tecnologia Universidade Nova de Lisboa 2829 516 Caparica,

More information

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications Remigijus Leipus (with Yang Yang, Yuebao Wang, Jonas Šiaulys) CIRM, Luminy, April 26-30, 2010 1. Preliminaries

More information

THIELE CENTRE for applied mathematics in natural science

THIELE CENTRE for applied mathematics in natural science THIELE CENTRE for applied mathematics in natural science Tail Asymptotics for the Sum of two Heavy-tailed Dependent Risks Hansjörg Albrecher and Søren Asmussen Research Report No. 9 August 25 Tail Asymptotics

More information

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks

Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Losses Given Default in the Presence of Extreme Risks Qihe Tang [a] and Zhongyi Yuan [b] [a] Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Iowa [b] Smeal College of Business Pennsylvania

More information

Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation

Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation Randomly weighted sums under a wide type of dependence structure with application to conditional tail expectation Shijie Wang a, Yiyu Hu a, Lianqiang Yang a, Wensheng Wang b a School of Mathematical Sciences,

More information

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1 Damir Filipović Gregor Svindland 3 November 2008 Abstract In this paper we establish a one-to-one correspondence between lawinvariant

More information

Chapter 2 Asymptotics

Chapter 2 Asymptotics Chapter Asymptotics.1 Asymptotic Behavior of Student s Pdf Proposition.1 For each x R d,asν, f ν,,a x g a, x..1 Proof Let a = 0. Using the well-known formula that Ɣz = π z e z z z 1 + O 1, as z,. z we

More information

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Proceedings of the World Congress on Engineering 29 Vol II WCE 29, July 1-3, 29, London, U.K. Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims Tao Jiang Abstract

More information

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds

Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Tail Mutual Exclusivity and Tail- Var Lower Bounds Ka Chun Cheung, Michel Denuit, Jan Dhaene AFI_15100 TAIL MUTUAL EXCLUSIVITY AND TAIL-VAR LOWER BOUNDS KA CHUN CHEUNG Department of Statistics and Actuarial

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

A NOTE ON SECOND ORDER CONDITIONS IN EXTREME VALUE THEORY: LINKING GENERAL AND HEAVY TAIL CONDITIONS

A NOTE ON SECOND ORDER CONDITIONS IN EXTREME VALUE THEORY: LINKING GENERAL AND HEAVY TAIL CONDITIONS REVSTAT Statistical Journal Volume 5, Number 3, November 2007, 285 304 A NOTE ON SECOND ORDER CONDITIONS IN EXTREME VALUE THEORY: LINKING GENERAL AND HEAVY TAIL CONDITIONS Authors: M. Isabel Fraga Alves

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015 Convex KKM maps, monotone operators and Minty variational inequalities arxiv:1503.06363v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015 Marc Lassonde Université des Antilles, 97159 Pointe à Pitre, France E-mail: marc.lassonde@univ-ag.fr

More information

ASYMPTOTIC MULTIVARIATE EXPECTILES

ASYMPTOTIC MULTIVARIATE EXPECTILES ASYMPTOTIC MULTIVARIATE EXPECTILES Véronique Maume-Deschamps Didier Rullière Khalil Said To cite this version: Véronique Maume-Deschamps Didier Rullière Khalil Said ASYMPTOTIC MULTIVARIATE EX- PECTILES

More information

Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis

Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis Portland State University PDXScholar University Honors Theses University Honors College 2014 Helly's Theorem and its Equivalences via Convex Analysis Adam Robinson Portland State University Let us know

More information

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY Elementary properties of convex functions Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 181 KC Border Convex Analysis and Economic Theory AY 2018 2019 Topic 6: Convex functions I 6.1 Elementary properties of convex functions We may occasionally

More information

Exercises in Extreme value theory

Exercises in Extreme value theory Exercises in Extreme value theory 2016 spring semester 1. Show that L(t) = logt is a slowly varying function but t ǫ is not if ǫ 0. 2. If the random variable X has distribution F with finite variance,

More information

The Convergence Rate for the Normal Approximation of Extreme Sums

The Convergence Rate for the Normal Approximation of Extreme Sums The Convergence Rate for the Normal Approximation of Extreme Sums Yongcheng Qi University of Minnesota Duluth WCNA 2008, Orlando, July 2-9, 2008 This talk is based on a joint work with Professor Shihong

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

The Ruin Probability of a Discrete Time Risk Model under Constant Interest Rate with Heavy Tails

The Ruin Probability of a Discrete Time Risk Model under Constant Interest Rate with Heavy Tails Scand. Actuarial J. 2004; 3: 229/240 æoriginal ARTICLE The Ruin Probability of a Discrete Time Risk Model under Constant Interest Rate with Heavy Tails QIHE TANG Qihe Tang. The ruin probability of a discrete

More information

CHAPTER 1. Metric Spaces. 1. Definition and examples

CHAPTER 1. Metric Spaces. 1. Definition and examples CHAPTER Metric Spaces. Definition and examples Metric spaces generalize and clarify the notion of distance in the real line. The definitions will provide us with a useful tool for more general applications

More information

Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae

Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae Convexity of chance constraints with dependent random variables: the use of copulae René Henrion 1 and Cyrille Strugarek 2 1 Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics, 10117 Berlin, Germany.

More information

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 10 Risk Management Haksun Li haksun.li@numericalmethod.com www.numericalmethod.com Outline Value at Risk (VaR) Extreme Value Theory (EVT) References

More information

Extreme Value Analysis and Spatial Extremes

Extreme Value Analysis and Spatial Extremes Extreme Value Analysis and Department of Statistics Purdue University 11/07/2013 Outline Motivation 1 Motivation 2 Extreme Value Theorem and 3 Bayesian Hierarchical Models Copula Models Max-stable Models

More information

Estimation of the extreme value index and high quantiles under random censoring

Estimation of the extreme value index and high quantiles under random censoring Estimation of the extreme value index and high quantiles under random censoring Jan Beirlant () & Emmanuel Delafosse (2) & Armelle Guillou (2) () Katholiee Universiteit Leuven, Department of Mathematics,

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.mg] 14 Apr 2014

arxiv: v2 [math.mg] 14 Apr 2014 An intermediate quasi-isometric invariant between subexponential asymptotic dimension growth and Yu s Property A arxiv:404.358v2 [math.mg] 4 Apr 204 Izhar Oppenheim Department of Mathematics The Ohio State

More information

Limit Distributions of Extreme Order Statistics under Power Normalization and Random Index

Limit Distributions of Extreme Order Statistics under Power Normalization and Random Index Limit Distributions of Extreme Order tatistics under Power Normalization and Random Index Zuoxiang Peng, Qin Jiang & aralees Nadarajah First version: 3 December 2 Research Report No. 2, 2, Probability

More information

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems

On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems Journal of Convex Analysis Volume 10 (2003), No. 2, 517 529 On a Class of Multidimensional Optimal Transportation Problems G. Carlier Université Bordeaux 1, MAB, UMR CNRS 5466, France and Université Bordeaux

More information

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions

Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Tail dependence in bivariate skew-normal and skew-t distributions Paola Bortot Department of Statistical Sciences - University of Bologna paola.bortot@unibo.it Abstract: Quantifying dependence between

More information

SOME INDICES FOR HEAVY-TAILED DISTRIBUTIONS

SOME INDICES FOR HEAVY-TAILED DISTRIBUTIONS SOME INDICES FOR HEAVY-TAILED DISTRIBUTIONS ROBERTO DARIS and LUCIO TORELLI Dipartimento di Matematica Applicata B. de Finetti Dipartimento di Scienze Matematiche Universitk degli Studi di Trieste P.le

More information

Math123 Lecture 1. Dr. Robert C. Busby. Lecturer: Office: Korman 266 Phone :

Math123 Lecture 1. Dr. Robert C. Busby. Lecturer: Office: Korman 266 Phone : Lecturer: Math1 Lecture 1 Dr. Robert C. Busby Office: Korman 66 Phone : 15-895-1957 Email: rbusby@mcs.drexel.edu Course Web Site: http://www.mcs.drexel.edu/classes/calculus/math1_spring0/ (Links are case

More information

A class of probability distributions for application to non-negative annual maxima

A class of probability distributions for application to non-negative annual maxima Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci. Discuss., doi:.94/hess-7-98, 7 A class of probability distributions for application to non-negative annual maxima Earl Bardsley School of Science, University of Waikato, Hamilton

More information

Overview of Extreme Value Theory. Dr. Sawsan Hilal space

Overview of Extreme Value Theory. Dr. Sawsan Hilal space Overview of Extreme Value Theory Dr. Sawsan Hilal space Maths Department - University of Bahrain space November 2010 Outline Part-1: Univariate Extremes Motivation Threshold Exceedances Part-2: Bivariate

More information

Probability and Measure

Probability and Measure Part II Year 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2018 84 Paper 4, Section II 26J Let (X, A) be a measurable space. Let T : X X be a measurable map, and µ a probability

More information

Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks

Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks 1 Calculation of Bayes Premium for Conditional Elliptical Risks Alfred Kume 1 and Enkelejd Hashorva University of Kent & University of Lausanne February 1, 13 Abstract: In this paper we discuss the calculation

More information

PENULTIMATE APPROXIMATIONS FOR WEATHER AND CLIMATE EXTREMES. Rick Katz

PENULTIMATE APPROXIMATIONS FOR WEATHER AND CLIMATE EXTREMES. Rick Katz PENULTIMATE APPROXIMATIONS FOR WEATHER AND CLIMATE EXTREMES Rick Katz Institute for Mathematics Applied to Geosciences National Center for Atmospheric Research Boulder, CO USA Email: rwk@ucar.edu Web site:

More information

Precise Large Deviations for Sums of Negatively Dependent Random Variables with Common Long-Tailed Distributions

Precise Large Deviations for Sums of Negatively Dependent Random Variables with Common Long-Tailed Distributions This article was downloaded by: [University of Aegean] On: 19 May 2013, At: 11:54 Publisher: Taylor & Francis Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer

More information

Math 576: Quantitative Risk Management

Math 576: Quantitative Risk Management Math 576: Quantitative Risk Management Haijun Li lih@math.wsu.edu Department of Mathematics Washington State University Week 11 Haijun Li Math 576: Quantitative Risk Management Week 11 1 / 21 Outline 1

More information

Refining the Central Limit Theorem Approximation via Extreme Value Theory

Refining the Central Limit Theorem Approximation via Extreme Value Theory Refining the Central Limit Theorem Approximation via Extreme Value Theory Ulrich K. Müller Economics Department Princeton University February 2018 Abstract We suggest approximating the distribution of

More information

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks

A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks A new approach for stochastic ordering of risks Liang Hong, PhD, FSA Department of Mathematics Robert Morris University Presented at 2014 Actuarial Research Conference UC Santa Barbara July 16, 2014 Liang

More information

Randomly Weighted Sums of Conditionnally Dependent Random Variables

Randomly Weighted Sums of Conditionnally Dependent Random Variables Gen. Math. Notes, Vol. 25, No. 1, November 2014, pp.43-49 ISSN 2219-7184; Copyright c ICSRS Publication, 2014 www.i-csrs.org Available free online at http://www.geman.in Randomly Weighted Sums of Conditionnally

More information

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity

Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity 3 214 5 ( ) Journal of East China Normal University (Natural Science) No. 3 May 214 Article ID: 1-5641(214)3-23-7 Representation theorem for AVaR under a submodular capacity TIAN De-jian, JIANG Long, JI

More information

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures Nonlife Actuarial Models Chapter 4 Risk Measures Learning Objectives 1. Risk measures based on premium principles 2. Risk measures based on capital requirements 3. Value-at-Risk and conditional tail expectation

More information

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 on bivariate Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015 Prof. Dr. Erich Walter Farkas Lecture 07: April 2, 2015 1 / 54 Outline on bivariate 1 2 bivariate 3 Distribution 4 5 6 7 8 Comments and conclusions

More information

MATH 205C: STATIONARY PHASE LEMMA

MATH 205C: STATIONARY PHASE LEMMA MATH 205C: STATIONARY PHASE LEMMA For ω, consider an integral of the form I(ω) = e iωf(x) u(x) dx, where u Cc (R n ) complex valued, with support in a compact set K, and f C (R n ) real valued. Thus, I(ω)

More information

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES JEREMY J. BECNEL Abstract. We examine the main topologies wea, strong, and inductive placed on the dual of a countably-normed space

More information

Asymptotic behavior for sums of non-identically distributed random variables

Asymptotic behavior for sums of non-identically distributed random variables Appl. Math. J. Chinese Univ. 2019, 34(1: 45-54 Asymptotic behavior for sums of non-identically distributed random variables YU Chang-jun 1 CHENG Dong-ya 2,3 Abstract. For any given positive integer m,

More information

A PRACTICAL WAY FOR ESTIMATING TAIL DEPENDENCE FUNCTIONS

A PRACTICAL WAY FOR ESTIMATING TAIL DEPENDENCE FUNCTIONS Statistica Sinica 20 2010, 365-378 A PRACTICAL WAY FOR ESTIMATING TAIL DEPENDENCE FUNCTIONS Liang Peng Georgia Institute of Technology Abstract: Estimating tail dependence functions is important for applications

More information

Scandinavian Actuarial Journal. Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks

Scandinavian Actuarial Journal. Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks Asymptotics for ruin probabilities in a discrete-time risk model with dependent financial and insurance risks For eer Review Only Journal: Manuscript ID: SACT-- Manuscript Type: Original Article Date Submitted

More information

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS

BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS BASICS OF CONVEX ANALYSIS MARKUS GRASMAIR 1. Main Definitions We start with providing the central definitions of convex functions and convex sets. Definition 1. A function f : R n R + } is called convex,

More information

arxiv:math/ v2 [math.pr] 9 Oct 2007

arxiv:math/ v2 [math.pr] 9 Oct 2007 Tails of random sums of a heavy-tailed number of light-tailed terms arxiv:math/0703022v2 [math.pr] 9 Oct 2007 Christian Y. Robert a, a ENSAE, Timbre J120, 3 Avenue Pierre Larousse, 92245 MALAKOFF Cedex,

More information

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk Stoyan V. Stoyanov Svetlozar T. Rachev September 3, 7 Abstract In this paper, we prove a result for the asymptotic distribution of the sample

More information

SOLUTIONS TO ADDITIONAL EXERCISES FOR II.1 AND II.2

SOLUTIONS TO ADDITIONAL EXERCISES FOR II.1 AND II.2 SOLUTIONS TO ADDITIONAL EXERCISES FOR II.1 AND II.2 Here are the solutions to the additional exercises in betsepexercises.pdf. B1. Let y and z be distinct points of L; we claim that x, y and z are not

More information

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures MATHEMATICS OF OPERATIONS RESEARCH Vol. 38, No. 1, February 213, pp. 142 152 ISSN 364-765X (print) ISSN 1526-5471 (online) http://dx.doi.org/1.1287/moor.112.563 213 INFORMS On Kusuoka Representation of

More information

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times.

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times. On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times. Angelos Dassios London School of Economics May 23 Abstract The distribution of the α-quantile of a Brownian motion on an interval [, t]

More information

Proof. We indicate by α, β (finite or not) the end-points of I and call

Proof. We indicate by α, β (finite or not) the end-points of I and call C.6 Continuous functions Pag. 111 Proof of Corollary 4.25 Corollary 4.25 Let f be continuous on the interval I and suppose it admits non-zero its (finite or infinite) that are different in sign for x tending

More information

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas

Laplace s Equation. Chapter Mean Value Formulas Chapter 1 Laplace s Equation Let be an open set in R n. A function u C 2 () is called harmonic in if it satisfies Laplace s equation n (1.1) u := D ii u = 0 in. i=1 A function u C 2 () is called subharmonic

More information

Part 2 Continuous functions and their properties

Part 2 Continuous functions and their properties Part 2 Continuous functions and their properties 2.1 Definition Definition A function f is continuous at a R if, and only if, that is lim f (x) = f (a), x a ε > 0, δ > 0, x, x a < δ f (x) f (a) < ε. Notice

More information

Iterative Convex Optimization Algorithms; Part One: Using the Baillon Haddad Theorem

Iterative Convex Optimization Algorithms; Part One: Using the Baillon Haddad Theorem Iterative Convex Optimization Algorithms; Part One: Using the Baillon Haddad Theorem Charles Byrne (Charles Byrne@uml.edu) http://faculty.uml.edu/cbyrne/cbyrne.html Department of Mathematical Sciences

More information

Trimmed sums of long-range dependent moving averages

Trimmed sums of long-range dependent moving averages Trimmed sums of long-range dependent moving averages Rafal l Kulik Mohamedou Ould Haye August 16, 2006 Abstract In this paper we establish asymptotic normality of trimmed sums for long range dependent

More information

Iowa State University. Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer Homework #1. Solutions

Iowa State University. Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer Homework #1. Solutions Math 501 Iowa State University Introduction to Real Analysis Department of Mathematics Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer 015 EXERCISES FROM CHAPTER 1 Homework #1 Solutions The following version of the

More information

Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences

Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences ISSN 1342-2804 Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences Long-tailed degree distribution of a random geometric graph constructed by the Boolean model with spherical grains Naoto Miyoshi,

More information

Weak max-sum equivalence for dependent heavy-tailed random variables

Weak max-sum equivalence for dependent heavy-tailed random variables DOI 10.1007/s10986-016-9303-6 Lithuanian Mathematical Journal, Vol. 56, No. 1, January, 2016, pp. 49 59 Wea max-sum equivalence for dependent heavy-tailed random variables Lina Dindienė a and Remigijus

More information

MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitiative Risk Management. John Dodson. October 14, 2015

MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitiative Risk Management. John Dodson. October 14, 2015 MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitiative Risk Management October 14, 2015 The n-block maxima 1 is a random variable defined as M n max (X 1,..., X n ) for i.i.d. random variables X i with distribution function

More information

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han

Set, functions and Euclidean space. Seungjin Han Set, functions and Euclidean space Seungjin Han September, 2018 1 Some Basics LOGIC A is necessary for B : If B holds, then A holds. B A A B is the contraposition of B A. A is sufficient for B: If A holds,

More information

LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS. S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov. September 25, 2011

LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS. S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov. September 25, 2011 LARGE DEVIATIONS OF TYPICAL LINEAR FUNCTIONALS ON A CONVEX BODY WITH UNCONDITIONAL BASIS S. G. Bobkov and F. L. Nazarov September 25, 20 Abstract We study large deviations of linear functionals on an isotropic

More information

Characterizations on Heavy-tailed Distributions by Means of Hazard Rate

Characterizations on Heavy-tailed Distributions by Means of Hazard Rate Acta Mathematicae Applicatae Sinica, English Series Vol. 19, No. 1 (23) 135 142 Characterizations on Heavy-tailed Distributions by Means of Hazard Rate Chun Su 1, Qi-he Tang 2 1 Department of Statistics

More information

and finally, any second order divergence form elliptic operator

and finally, any second order divergence form elliptic operator Supporting Information: Mathematical proofs Preliminaries Let be an arbitrary bounded open set in R n and let L be any elliptic differential operator associated to a symmetric positive bilinear form B

More information

Riemann integral and volume are generalized to unbounded functions and sets. is an admissible set, and its volume is a Riemann integral, 1l E,

Riemann integral and volume are generalized to unbounded functions and sets. is an admissible set, and its volume is a Riemann integral, 1l E, Tel Aviv University, 26 Analysis-III 9 9 Improper integral 9a Introduction....................... 9 9b Positive integrands................... 9c Special functions gamma and beta......... 4 9d Change of

More information

Power series solutions for 2nd order linear ODE s (not necessarily with constant coefficients) a n z n. n=0

Power series solutions for 2nd order linear ODE s (not necessarily with constant coefficients) a n z n. n=0 Lecture 22 Power series solutions for 2nd order linear ODE s (not necessarily with constant coefficients) Recall a few facts about power series: a n z n This series in z is centered at z 0. Here z can

More information

David Hilbert was old and partly deaf in the nineteen thirties. Yet being a diligent

David Hilbert was old and partly deaf in the nineteen thirties. Yet being a diligent Chapter 5 ddddd dddddd dddddddd ddddddd dddddddd ddddddd Hilbert Space The Euclidean norm is special among all norms defined in R n for being induced by the Euclidean inner product (the dot product). A

More information

Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting

Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting Quantile prediction of a random eld extending the gaussian setting 1 Joint work with : Véronique Maume-Deschamps 1 and Didier Rullière 2 1 Institut Camille Jordan Université Lyon 1 2 Laboratoire des Sciences

More information

GIOVANNI COMI AND MONICA TORRES

GIOVANNI COMI AND MONICA TORRES ONE-SIDED APPROXIMATION OF SETS OF FINITE PERIMETER GIOVANNI COMI AND MONICA TORRES Abstract. In this note we present a new proof of a one-sided approximation of sets of finite perimeter introduced in

More information

Week 3: Faces of convex sets

Week 3: Faces of convex sets Week 3: Faces of convex sets Conic Optimisation MATH515 Semester 018 Vera Roshchina School of Mathematics and Statistics, UNSW August 9, 018 Contents 1. Faces of convex sets 1. Minkowski theorem 3 3. Minimal

More information

Tools from Lebesgue integration

Tools from Lebesgue integration Tools from Lebesgue integration E.P. van den Ban Fall 2005 Introduction In these notes we describe some of the basic tools from the theory of Lebesgue integration. Definitions and results will be given

More information

Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences

Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences ISSN 134-84 Research Reports on Mathematical and Computing Sciences Subexponential interval graphs generated by immigration-death processes Naoto Miyoshi, Mario Ogura, Taeya Shigezumi and Ryuhei Uehara

More information

Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence

Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence Journal of Operational Risk 51 57) Volume 1/Number 2, Summer 2006 Extreme value theory and high quantile convergence Mikhail Makarov EVMTech AG, Baarerstrasse 2, 6300 Zug, Switzerland In this paper we

More information

Random Bernstein-Markov factors

Random Bernstein-Markov factors Random Bernstein-Markov factors Igor Pritsker and Koushik Ramachandran October 20, 208 Abstract For a polynomial P n of degree n, Bernstein s inequality states that P n n P n for all L p norms on the unit

More information

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures Generalized quantiles as risk measures Fabio Bellini a, Bernhard Klar b, Alfred Müller c,, Emanuela Rosazza Gianin a,1 a Dipartimento di Statistica e Metodi Quantitativi, Università di Milano Bicocca,

More information

On distribution functions of ξ(3/2) n mod 1

On distribution functions of ξ(3/2) n mod 1 ACTA ARITHMETICA LXXXI. (997) On distribution functions of ξ(3/2) n mod by Oto Strauch (Bratislava). Preliminary remarks. The question about distribution of (3/2) n mod is most difficult. We present a

More information

Frontier estimation based on extreme risk measures

Frontier estimation based on extreme risk measures Frontier estimation based on extreme risk measures by Jonathan EL METHNI in collaboration with Ste phane GIRARD & Laurent GARDES CMStatistics 2016 University of Seville December 2016 1 Risk measures 2

More information

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Supergradients. KC Border Fall 2001 v ::15.45 Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Supergradients KC Border Fall 2001 1 The supergradient of a concave function There is a useful way to characterize the concavity of differentiable functions.

More information