A LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES. 1. Introduction

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES. 1. Introduction"

Transcription

1 A LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Abstract. In tis work we introduce a new land use equilibrium model wic is based on a goods and location excange process wit endogenous incomes. We define two possible market equilibrium conditions: one based on te auction teory and te oter on te utility maximization teory. We prove in te second part of tis paper tat bot approaces are equivalent under weak conditions. In te tird part we establis an existence result for te utility maximization equilibrium model. 1. Introduction In te istoric development of Land Use modelling, tere ave been two main approaces to understanding te economic agents decision making on location and te allocation of residential resources in an urban enronment. In te auction teory, described by Von Tünen (1966) and Alonso (1964), agents compete for land use wit teir willingness to pay. On te oter and, in te utility maximization approac, agents coose teir locations by maximizing teir utility given te set of location prices (McFadden, 1978; Anas, 1982). Bot approaces seek equilibrium prices tat allow all agents to locate following te corresponding process. In Martínez (1992) apparent differences between tese two approaces were acknowledged, and te equivalence between tem was discussed. Using linear utility functions, it was argued tat te two approaces produce te same distribution of ouseolds in space, and are complementary because tey prode complementary information on te land market clearing mecanism and indidual beaor. It was demonstrated tat troug te auction process, eac located agent is in fact maximizing is utility in equilibrium, owever, tere is no demonstration tat location based on maximum utility is consistent wit te auction process. As tere is no actual demonstration of tis equivalence, and as te one-sided demonstration was given only in te case of linear indirect utility functions, in tis work we formalize and generalize tis equivalency to te case of classical properties of direct utility functions. For tis purpose, it is necessary to compare bot equilibrium conditions defined in te same general economic context. In Section 2 a new economic framework for residential location models is introduced tat is flexible enoug to sustain te two approaces in land use modelling. We will define an Excange Economy wit Location. model wic describes an excange economy attaining general equilibrium on continuous goods and on te discrete 1

2 2 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ coice of residence location. Te equilibrium can be defined, following te two main frameworks in urban economics, as purely maximum utility equilibrium or as maximum bidding auction equilibrium ; an equivalence teorem merges tem into a consistent framework. Location attributes are defined eiter by te natural enronment or by te location pattern and te built enronment. Wile te former is exogenous to te urban market, te latter introduce a number of endogenous effects on te economy, generically called location externalities ; te best known are neigborood quality and agglomeration economies. Te interaction between agents is twofold: troug ouseold income tat depends on residences rents, defined by auction outputs, and troug location externalities tat define location attributes based on te result of te equilibrium location pattern. Te residential land use market offers an interesting setting to study an economy endowed wit an uncommon combination of features tat callenge state- of-te-art market equilibrium models. An additional feature differentiating tis model from oter land use models is tat in tis context we will seek equilibrium not only in te residential land use market, but also in consumption goods. Te set of goods includes te usual bundle of consumption goods and te residence; te former commonly considered as continuous, but location of residence introduces te case of discrete coices and te need for a discrete coice matematical framework. Additionally, ouseolds demand variable amounts of goods but only one residence. Te residential options are differentiated naturally by te difference in attributes defined by te spatial location, making eac residential option attribute unique. Tis feature calls for a trading process based on bid-auctions rules, as as been recognized in te urban economic literature since Alonso (1964). Te property of ouses is distributed among consumers, wit eac ouseold potentially playing te double role of consumer and owner simultaneously. Tis implies tat consumer income is naturally endogenous to te land use market equilibrium. Te urban economic model presented in tis paper takes into account all tese features assuming te ousing supply to be exogenous. Given te ig complexity added to modelling wit all te new features mentioned, only a static version of te model will be advanced ere suc tat te agent interaction a location externalities as been simplified, assuming tat tese externalities appen over time in a dynamic extension of te model. In tis case, agents only use te information about ow te urban enronment is at te moment tey make te location decision, but no inference about ow tis enronment may be in te future is considered. Neverteless, te teoretical economic framework proposed as te tools necessary to deal wit location externalities. In Section 3, wat is meant by using eac of te two approaces for our model is defined. To do tis, indirect utility and willingness to pay functions of ouseolds are introduced, wic lead to a formal definition of equilibrium regarding te two approaces. In Section 4 te conditions under wic equivalence properties of equilibrium points can effectively occur are stated, merging te two approaces into a consistent framework by an equivalence teorem for more general utility and willingness to pay functions. Finally, in Section 5, a result for te existence of equilibrium is demonstrated.

3 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 3 2. Te Model We begin by presenting our location model, in wic te property of all location options and available goods is distributed among te participating agents. Te model is based on an excange economy wit a finite number of goods, one of wic is location. Agents endogenous income consists of te value of teir endowment of goods and location possessions. Agents excange goods and decide were to locate. Consider a finite number of consumers denoted by { 1,..., }. Eac consumer is representative of a omogeneous cluster of agents, wic is a partition of total locating agents wit size N. In tis economy tere is a finite number of available location options partitioned into categories by building type v {1,..., v} and by zone i {1,..., ī} wit size f. Eac option is completely caracterized by a vector of attributes z IR a, were a is te number of attributes, including, among oters, te land lot size, a set of building caracteristics, index(es) of neigborood quality, accessibility and attractiveness advantages. Land use is described by a matrix H IR v ī + wose value for eac, H, indicates te number of agents of eac cluster located at. Some attributes describing dwelling caracteristics and te natural enronment are independent of te land use pattern, wile oters, like socioeconomic segregation, index of criminal records, access to local and city-wide serces, etc., are conditioned to te built enronment and so are dependent on te land use H. Terefore, te vector described above is actually: z = z (H) Tat is, te relevant information on location decisions, related to city structure, is considered in te attributes vector z. Houseolds decide teir consumption of goods and were to locate. Te total number of goods is l + 1. For an agent { 1,..., } te consumption quantities of te first l goods are given by a vector x IR l and for te location indexed by l + 1 te consumption quantity is equal to one. Tus, te consumption of an agent is a vector (x, x l+1 ) = (x 1,..., x j,..., x l, ) were te last term indicates agent s coice on te discrete set of location options, V := {1,..., v} {1,..., ī}. Te location of firms tat prode goods and serces is also affected by H, ence te space of feasible consumption for any locating agent in any zone i is also affected by H. Tis effect is modeled by te set-valued map X : IR + v ī IR +, l suc tat to eac tere is an associated set of feasible consumption X (H), assumed ereafter convex and closed, wic also includes tose goods tat are not affected by H and does not include location. Vector x can be described furter as te set of actities performed by te agent, including goods, serces and time. Te set-valued map X could include dependencies suc as time, spatial and/or tecnological constraints, among oters. Tis context would ten include te specifications described by Jara-Díaz and Martínez (1999) for te problem of te consumer tat faces tese kinds of decisions.

4 4 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ In contrast to te classical model, endowment is split into two components. One associated wit te property of dwelling, denoted w [0, 1], and te oter associated wit all oter goods, denoted e IR ++, l tat is independent of location. Te term w gives te fraction of te value of a location, type, tat an agent of type obtains. We suppose tat eac location is completely owned by a set of participating agents so we must ave: w = 1. =1 Tese components are included in te ouseold budget constraint. Agent s income, wic is given by te value of is endowment relative to a pair of price vectors (p, r), is ten p e + r w, wic can be spent in a vector of goods x and location, given tat x IR + l and tat te value p x + r does not exceed tat income. Agent s consumption must be in te set: C (p, r) := { (y, ) IR l + V : p y + r p e + r w }. Following Discrete Coice Teory - were agents are modelled as deciding in two steps: first, conditional on location, tey decide teir consumption of te first l goods; ten, tey decide location. Terefore, in te first step anoter consumption set were location is fixed must be defined: Definition 1. We define te conditional on location Budget Set, C (p, r) IR l +, as: (1) C (p, r) := { y IR l + : p y + r p e + r w } = { y IR l + : p y p e + r w r (1 w ) }, were r is te usual notation for te price vector on all locations except for and, analogously, w is te location endowment vector of agent on all locations except for is endowment on. Eac ouseold as a utility function U : IR + l IR a IR tat depends on a vector of consumption goods x IR +, l wic does not include location, and te above mentioned vector of attributes z IR a. It is assumed tat agent prefers (strictly) a pair (x, ) IR + l V to (y, v i ) IR + l V if and only if U (x, z ) (>) U (y, z v i ). Ten, tis utility function represents a rational preference relation over IR + l V. As we are interested in following a Discrete Coice approac, we will study preferences conditional on location. In tis context, ten, we suppose tat utility functions U (, z ) are upper semi-continuous, quasi-concave, locally non-satiated and non-decreasing on eac coordinate x j of x, for any pair V. Using tese elements, te main framework for our model can be defined. Definition 2. An Excange Economy wit Location wit IN clusters of agents, v IN types of location, in a city wit ī IN zones, is denoted: (U, e, w, X ) =1, (z ) V, were U : IR l + IR a IR, X : IR v ī + IR l +, z : IR v ī + IR a, e IR l ++, w [0, 1] v ī. Eac cluster () of agents (locations) as size N (f ).

5 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 5 3. Equilibria Given an Excange Economy wit Location and a city structure H 0, we can obtain indirect utility, willingness to pay functions, and consumption correspondences for eac agent conditional on every location. Tese tools will be used to get a new city structure were location can be determined by eiter of two rules: 1. Te price of dwellings is defined as agents bid over all available location alternatives and an auction determines te location structure by te best bidder rule. 2. Given te prices of goods and dwellings, agents decide were to locate by coosing teir utility maximizing consumption and location alternative. In equilibrium tere must be a market-clearing condition on goods and land use. Tat is, in equilibrium, every agent must be located and demand on consumption must be met Functions and Correspondences Indirect Utility Functions. Given p IR l + and r IR v ī +, agent cooses a point d IR l + tat maximizes is utility on eac location. Ten d must be in te conditional on location Budget Set C (p, r) defined on (1) and in X (H). We define ten te Utility Maximization Problem, conditional on location. Definition 3. We call te Utility Maximization Problem, conditional on location, denoted (P ), te following: { (P ) sup x IR l U (x, z (H)) : x C (p, r) X (H) } Te value of (P ) is a function tat, to eac term (, p, r), associates: (2) V (p, r, z (H)) := sup x IR l { U (x, z (H)) : x C (p, r) X (H) }, and we call it te Indirect Utility Function, conditional on location. Te Utility Maximizing Consumption Correspondence is te set: { (3) D (p, r, z (H)) := argmax U (x, z (H)) : x C (p, r) X (H) } x IR l Remark 1. Te Indirect Utility Function, conditional on location, for agent, is te greatest utility tat can reac on given prices (p, r) and te city structure H. It is important to note tat dependence on comes not only from (can we omit tis:evaluating) te direct utility function U in z, but also from te budget constraint tat defines te set C (p, r) (see equation (1)). 1 Usually equilibrium conditions include not only tat every agent locates, but also tat all dwellings be occupied. In tis work we assume tat te ousing supply is fixed, so tere is no point in asking for optimal beaor on building prosion. Instead, and to allow consistency, we assume tat total ousing is equal to total locating agents.

6 6 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Willingness to Pay Functions. Willingness to Pay Functions describe ow muc an agent is willing to pay for a certain location to obtain a specific utility level u given a vector of goods and location (but ) prices. In our context, in contrast to te Bid-Coice model (Martínez, 1992) in wic income is fixed and consumption goods are not considered, an optimal consumption correspondence will be obtained as a function of tese variables and conditional on location. Te following definition is closely related to te dual problem of Minimum Expenditure in te classical consumer teory. Following Jara (2003) Willingness to Pay is calculated as te most tat an agent can pay for location given te utility level and prices. Definition 4. Te Willingness to Pay Function for agent on location, denoted B (u, p, r, z (H)), is defined as: (4) B (u, p, r, z (H)) := sup b IR + : (b,x) D (u, p, z (H)) := argmin x p x + b(1 w ) p e + r w U (x, z (H)) u x X (H) We define te Expenditure Minimizing Consumption Correspondence, as: { } p x :. U (x, z (H)) u x X (H) Remark 2. In tis definition, agent cooses te ceapest consumption bundle tat delivers te utility level u. Condition b IR + ensures consistency in te sense tat: an agent will not be able to locate were e can not afford to (if te lowest bound for b is negative ten B = ) and it also assures feasibility of consumption on te budget constraint. Agents express a conditional demand as if tey were paying teir willingness to pay on eac location, wic is completely rational. If w = 1 ten te value of B depends only on te feasibility of x. If te problem is feasible ten B = +, and if it is unfeasible ten B =. Tus B is always a real extended valued function. Tis approac as an advantage wit respect to Sollow s (1973) and Rosen s (1974) approac were willingness to pay is te inverse in prices of te indirect utility function conditional on location because we avoid indetermination of bids wen w = 1. Remark 3. If te result of (4) is not B =, and w 1, ten te function B (u, p, r, z (H)) can be calculated as: B (u, p, r, z (H)) = p e + r w e (u, p, z (H)) (1 w ) were e (u, p, z (H)) is te minimum expenditure function defined by: { } (5) p x :. e (u, p, z (H)) := min x U (x, z (H)) u x X (H) Tat is, willingness to pay is income minus te value of te minimum expenditure 1 bundles, multiplied by te property correction factor. 1 w.

7 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES Equilibrium Definition. We consider four types of correspondences for eac ouseold cluster { 1,..., } and eac location option V: Te Conditional Indirect Utility Function, V (p, r, z (H)), is te maximum utility tat agent can obtain in location given te price vector (p, r) and te city structure H. Tat is, if agent were to locate in and beave in an optimal way, tis would be is utility level. Te Utility Maximizing Consumption Correspondence, D (p, r, z (H)), is te utility-optimal consumption set for agent in location, given te price vector (p, r) and te city structure H. If agent were to locate in is consumption bundle would be an element of tis set. Te Willingness to Pay Function, B (u, p, r, z (H)), is te maximum tat agent is willing to pay to locate in to reac a utility level u, given te price vectors p of consumption goods and r of all oter location options and city structure H. Tat is, if agent were to locate in seeking a utility level u, tis is te quantity tat e would be willing to pay for it. Te Expenditure Minimizing Consumption Correspondence, D (u, p, r, z (H)), is te expenditure-optimal consumption set for agent in location. Again, if agent were to locate in seeking a utility level u, given te price vectors p of consumption goods and r of all oter location options, and city structure H, is consumption bundle would be an element of tis set. Agents in te economy must locate and, given teir location, te aggregate demand for goods must be met. For consistency, and due to location options being fixed, we assume tat: (6) f = N. Land use will be described by te matrix H. In equilibrium all agents must be located and all available dwellings must be occupied. So te first equilibrium condition is: (7) (8) H =N H =f Aggregate consumption of cluster is te sum of elements of te Consumption Correspondences multiplied by te number of located agents. Elements of tis demand correspondence are denoted d and we calculate tem as: (9) d := H d were d is an element of te Consumption Correspondence conditional on.

8 8 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Total supply of consumption goods is e = e N so te excess supply correspondence is obtained as all te points s IR l tat can be calculated as: s := e N d. for any vector d obtained as above. Te second equilibrium condition is ten written as te existence of a point s in te excess supply correspondence suc tat: s IR l + Equilibrium is determined by matrix H, prices (p, r) and utility levels u. Depending on te cosen approac, we ave different rules to obtain H and an excess of supply points s Location Auction Equilibrium. Following Alonso (1964), dwelling prices are determined by auctions in wic bids are ouseolds Willingness to Pay Functions. To allocate location we use te best bidder rule. Tat is, in te f available locations of type, only ouseolds belonging to cluster(s) tat present te igest willingness to pay will be allocated. Te equilibrium allocation and prices must satisfy a Walrasian Equilibrium condition on consumption goods. In tis approac suppliers of dwellings coose teir inabitant troug te auction process and ouseolds compete to locate using teir Willingness to Pay Functions. To describe dwelling allocation we use a matrix µ M v ī {[0, 1]} wose coefficients µ indicate te proportion of ouseolds belonging to cluster cosen by dwellings of type by te best bidder rule. Eac column of matrix µ, µ, can be interpreted as a probabilistic distribution over te set { 1,..., }. Tat is, µ could be understood as te probability tat agent is te best bidder at location. For eac location, we would ten ave a distribution over te set of ouseolds. Ten, eac column µ of µ satisfies µ were: { } := µ IR + : µ = 1 So te allocation condition is: (10) µ > 0 = B = max g {1,..., } B g and can be written as a complementarity condition: µ (B max g {1,..., } B g) = 0. Te number of agents allocated to type dwellings is: H := µ f ; and te price of type dwellings is te value of te auction: r = max g {1,..., } B g.

9 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 9 Note tat as µ, condition (8) is already satisfied. Hence using tis rule, it is enoug to ask for condition (7). In tis approac, suc tat H > 0, te demand vectors d, tat appear in (9), must belong to te consumption correspondence set D (u, p, r, z (H 0 )). Definition 5. A vector (ū, p, r, µ, d) IR IR l + IR v ī + IR l v ī + is a Location Auction Equilibrium if it satisfies: (i) 0 = µ (B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) r ) (ii) µf N (iii) 0 e N µ f d (iv) r = max B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) (v) µ > 0 = d D (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) Condition (i) stands for condition (10). Condition (ii) ensures tat all agents locate 2. (iii) is a market-clearing condition on consumption goods and (iv) states tat dwelling prices are obtained by auctions. Remark 4. It is important to note tat in te determination of aggregate demand of cluster in condition (iii), only locations for wic H > 0, are considered Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. In te line of Discrete Coice Teory, agents decide te consumption of one unit of a good available on a finite set of options caracterized by its attributes, maximizing teir utility in two steps. In tis context, eac agent solves is conditional on location utility maximization problem for eac location option and ten cooses te alternative tat yields a maximum utility, given a price vector. Equilibrium prices and allocations must again satisfy tat demand in all markets. As above, te description of ousing allocation is given by a matrix µ M v ī {[0, 1]} in wic te columns of µ satisfy µ v ī, wit: { } v ī := Te allocation condition is: µ IR v ī + : V µ = 1 µ (V max V () ) = 0. () Wit tis, te number of agents tat coose type dwellings is calculated: H := µ N. Now condition (7) is automatically satisfied, tus it is necessary to meet only condition(8). In (9), d D (p, r, z (H 0 )) for all suc tat H > 0. Equilibrium in tis case is defined as follows.. 2 Condition (6) ensures tat, in equilibrium, condition (ii) is satisfied wit equality and all agents will be located.

10 10 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Definition 6. A vector (ū, p, r, µ, d) IR IR l + IR v ī + v ī IR l v ī + is a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium, if it satisfies: (i) 0 = µ (V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) ū ) (ii) µ T N f (iii) 0 e N µ N d (iv) ū = max V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) (v) µ > 0 = d D ( p, r, z (H 0 )) 4. Auction v/s Utility Maximization In Rosen (1974) and Martínez (1992) utility maximization relative to attributes of consumption goods is discussed. In te case of te Bid-Coice Model (Martínez, 1992), consumer surplus maximization is used to state an equivalence between te auction (or Bid ) and utility maximization (or Coice ) approaces on Land Use Models. However, tis treatment is limited to Indirect Utility Functions tat are linear or affine on utility level, wic does not fit te classical properties of tese functions nor te properties of Willingness to Pay Functions, as seen in Jara (2003). Furtermore te demonstration is one-sided in te sense tat utility maximization equilibria do not necessarily assure tat agents are best bidders in te implicit auctions eld in teir allocated dwellings. Tis section focuses on finding conditions to obtain equivalence between te two approaces in te context of our model, comparing te equilibrium conditions described in Definitions 5 and 6. Te next Proposition states tat in a Location Auction Equilibrium, te utility level reaced by ouseolds on teir allocated dwellings is greater tan te utility level tey would obtain if tey were to locate in any of te oter location options at equilibrium prices. Proposition 5. Let (ū, p, r, µ, d) be a Location Auction Equilibrium. Ten: µ > 0 = V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) max () µ () =0 V () ( p, r, z (H 0 )) Proof. Take ouseold and location option. Ten: B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) r. Now let us look at indirect utility as a function of te price in : V ( p, b, r, z (H 0 )) := (11) sup x IR l { U (x, z (H 0 )) : px + b(1 w ) pe + r w x X (H 0 ) Te utility tat would reac if e were located at at equilibrium prices, is calculated as V ( p, r, z (H 0 )); tat is, b = r. If B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) < r, ten, from (4), px + r (1 w ) pe + r w x X (H 0 ) suc tat, U (x, z (H 0 )) ū }

11 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 11 ence, because of te upper semi-continuity of U we get: { V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) = U(x, z (H 0 )) : < ū max x IR l px + r (1 w ) pe + r w x X(H 0) } If B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) = r, ten, as r 0, tere exists an element y X(H 0 ) suc tat, px + b(1 w ( r, y) argmax (b,x) b IR ) pe + r w + : U (x, z (H 0 )) ū x X(H 0 ) because if not, B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) =. Ten V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) ū, because y is feasible in (11) for b = r, and U (y, z (H 0 )) ū. Ten if in equilibrium, is te best bidder in and not in () : V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) ū > V () ( p, r, z () (H 0 )) wic gives te stated result. Toug tis property states tat, at Auction Equilibrium prices, te utility an agent would get if e is located in a place were e is te best bidder, is iger tan te utility e would obtain in a place were e is not, we can not assure tat tis equilibrium utility level ū will be te actual utility tat type agents ave in equilibrium wen allocated. Tis is because in some of te places were an agent is te best bidder, e could actually get an even iger utility tan te equilibrium utility, and furtermore, te utility level need not be te same in all allocated places. To assure tat equilibrium utility is te actual utility, te following elements need to be defined: u min (p) := max x x min (p) U (x, z (H 0 )), is te igest utility an agent can obtain by consuming is ceapest feasible bundle. We state te following proposition. Proposition 6. If te functions U (, z (H 0 )) are continuous, let (ū, p, r, µ, d) be a Location Auction Equilibrium, suc tat { 1,..., }, (12) ū max { : µ >0} {umin ( p)} Ten, µ > 0 = V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) = max () V () ( p, r, z (H 0 )) Proof. Due to Proposition 5, it is enoug to prove: µ > 0 = V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) = ū.

12 12 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ As ū u min ( p) it must be tat d D (ū, p, z (H 0 )) U (d, z (H 0 )) = ū, if not, convexity of X (H 0 ) and te level sets of U and continuity of U allow us to move along a segment [d, x], wit x x min ( p), diminising te value of te consumption bundle and utility. Moreover, if µ > 0, ten we ave: r = B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) = pe + r w e (ū, p, z (H 0 )) 1 w = pe + r w p d 1 w Suppose tere exists x X (H 0 ) C ( p, r) suc tat U (x, z (H 0 )) > ū. Ten, Terefore, p e + r w p x + r e (ū, p, z (H 0 )) + r = p e + r w p x = e (ū, p, z (H 0 )) wic means tat x D (ū, p, z (H 0 )) and ten U (x, z (H 0 )) = ū, wic is a contradiction. So, for any x X (H 0 ) C ( p, r), it must be U (x, z (H 0 )) ū Wit te preous proposition we can identify Location Auction Equilibria in wic locating agents maximize teir utility. Next we study maximum utility allocation conditions to establis wen te Maximum Utility Equilibrium prices and allocation come from an auction process. Suppose tere is a price vector ( p, r) tat satisfies te Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium conditions. It may be necessary to know if dwelling prices are te result of an auction on eac location. To ascertain tis, we must ceck tat allocated ouseolds are best bidders. Willingness to Pay Functions must, terefore, be calculated for all ouseolds in all locations, and evaluated in equilibrium points. Tis produces te following result: Proposition 7. Let (ū, p, r, µ, d) be a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. Defining: ū := V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) ten: (i) ū = ū = B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) r (ii) ū < ū = B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) < r

13 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 13 Proof. (i) Take d D ( p, r, z (H 0 )), so tat ū = V ( p, r, z (H 0 )) = U (d, z (H 0 )). Ten d is feasible in te following problem: (13) B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) := sup b IR + : togeter wit b = r. Terefore, B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) r. px + b(1 w ) pe + r w U (x, z (H 0 )) ū x X(H 0 ) (ii) As ū < ū, x C ( p, r) X (H 0 ) suc tat U (x, z (H 0 )) ū. Hence r is not feasible in (13). If te supremum is finite, it is met, so: B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) < r. Te preous proposition states tat in places were ouseolds maximize teir utility, teir willingness to pay is equal to or iger tan te equilibrium price, wereas in locations were teir utility is not maximal, teir willingness to pay is strictly lower tan te equilibrium price. However, in a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium it is possible tat ouseolds maximize utility in a location option witout being allocated to it. We want to prode a condition tat allows us to conclude tat te price tey are willing to pay for suc places is at most equal to te equilibrium price. Tis would mean tat dwelling prices are a result of an auction. Proposition 8. Let (ū, p, r, µ, d) be a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. If it satisfies te following condition: (14) Ten: ū = ū = D ( p, r, z (H 0 )) intx (H 0 ) (i) ū = ū = B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) = r (ii) ū < ū = B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) < r Proof. We ten must prove only(i). Suppose tat B > r ten tere exist x X (H 0 ) and b > r 0, suc tat: U ( x, z (H 0 )) ū, p x pe + r w b(1 w ) < pe + r w r (1 w ). Tat is x C ( p, r) and U ( x, z (H 0 )) ū. Ten x D ( p, r, z (H 0 )) and because of condition (14), tere exists a neigborood V x of x suc tat V x X (H 0 ) C ( p, r). Locally non satiation of U gives te existence of an element y V x suc tat U (y, z (H 0 )) > U ( x, z (H 0 )) wic is a contradiction.

14 14 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Corollary 9. If X (H 0 ) IR l + and (ū, p, r, µ ) is a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium, wit p >> 0, ten prices r are te result of an auction. Given te results and comments tus far, we can state an equivalence result between te two approaces wit te following teorem: Teorem 10 (Equivalence). If te utility functions U (, z (H 0 )) are continuous, X (H 0 ) IR l +, and te following conditions are satisfied: (i) z IR a, inf x IR l + U (x, z) = U (0, z) = u min (ii) p >> 0. for some u min IR Ten, (ū, p, r, µ, d) is a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium if and only if (ū, p, r, µ, d) is a Location Auction Equilibrium wit ū u min, were ū := max V ( p, r, z (H 0 )); and te following relation olds: µ N = µ f A sufficient condition guaranteeing te equivalence of tese two approaces is for example te strict monotonicity on utility and on Willingness to Pay Functions. Indeed, te conditions of Teorem 10 allow us to invert Indirect Utility Functions to obtain Willingness to Pay Functions evaluated at equilibrium points wic leads to te conclusion tat suc a condition is enoug to demonstrate equivalence. Tis conclusion implies tat maximizing utility is consistent wit te auction process under te above condition, extending te results of te Bid-Coice Model (Martínez, 1992), were income is exogenous. 5. Existence In tis section we are interested in presenting an existence result for Equilibrium points. For tis purpose we will use te Utility-maximizing approac developed in te preous section. Suppose tat X (H 0 ) X wit X := { x IR l + : x e } were e is total endowment on consumption goods in te economy, ence X is a compact subset of IR l +. Clearly, e intx. Consider now positive and continuous utility functions U (x, z (H 0 )); in addition to te caracteristics mentioned in Section 2. Assume tat te utility function of eac agent satisfies: j suc tat x j = 0 U (x, z (H 0 )) = 0 x >> 0 U (x, z (H 0 )) > 0. Tis means, no matter te location option, an agent prefers a strictly positive bundle to any wit some null coordinate. In addition : u max = U (e, z (H 0 )) > U (x, z (H 0 )) x X In wat follows we make te following surval assumption:

15 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 15 (15) (p, r) suc tat I (p, r) > 0. wit I (p, r) defined as: I (p, r) := p e + r w r. Assumptions made over utility functions imply tat if income is strictly positive in some location, ten conditional indirect utility is strictly positive. If I (p, r) = 0 and p 0, agent can only consume in goods j suc tat p j = 0, ence p j > 0 implies d j = 0 and ten V (p, r, z (H 0 )) = 0. Teorem 11 (Existence). Under te surval assumption (15), if utility functions are strictly concave, ten tere exists a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. To demonstrate Teorem 11, we generate a correspondence tat associates a consumption set, for goods and location, wit eac pair (p, r). For tis purpose consider te conditional on location problem (P ): sup { U (x, z (H 0 )) : x C (p, r) X }. From tis problem we obtain te Utility Maximizing Consumption Correspondence D (p, r, z (H 0 )) and te Conditional Indirect Utility Function V (p, r, z (H 0 )). Wit all te Conditional Indirect Utility Functions, we state te second step maximization problem, in wic agents coose teir location: max {V (p, r, z (H 0 ))} As tis problem is not convex and can ave more tan one solution, we consider te following convexified problem over te simplex of IR v ī + : { } max µ V (p, r, z (H 0 )) µ v ī V From te second step convexified problem, we obtain its solution set Γ (p, r). Note tat, { } Γ (p, r) = µ v ī : V (p, r, z (H 0 )) < max V (p, r, z (H 0 )) µ = 0. Recall tat λ > 0, C (λ(p, r)) = C (p, r) = D (λ(p, r), z (H 0 )) = D (p, r, z (H 0 )) V (λ(p, r), z (H 0 )) = V (p, r, z (H 0 )) = Γ (λ(p, r)) = Γ (p, r). Terefore we can restrict te price set to: l := (p, r) IRl+ v ī + : p j + r = 1. j=1 V

16 16 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Given prices (p, r), eac agent will ave is consumption correspondences Γ (p, r) and, for eac, D (p, r, z (H 0 )). Ten, aggregate demand of cluster for location, will be any vector of te form: (H ) V = (µ N ) V were µ = (µ ) V Γ (p, r). Consumption goods demand is generated in an analogous way as described in (9); tat is, d = V N µ d wit µ Γ (p, r) and d D (p, r, z (H 0 )) for eac suc tat µ > 0. Ten te demand correspondence associates wit eac pair (p, r) te set: {( ) } d D(p, r) := IR l+ v ī (H ) + : µ Γ (p, r), d D (p, r, z (H 0 )) V wic is equal to N ϕ (p, r) were ϕ (p, r) is given by: ϕ (p, r) := Consider te set: (d, (µ ) ) IR l+ v ī + : d = V µ d, µ Γ (p, r), d D (p, r, z (H 0)) P := { (p, r) IR l+ v ī + : I (p, r) 0 }, For te demand of agent being non-empty and utility greater tan we seek prices in te set P = V P. In addition we need prices (p, r) to be in all te sets P, so te price set is P, given by: P := {1,..., } V P Tus, correspondence D(p, r) takes non-empty values in te set P. Te surval assumption (15) implies P, tus restricting te solution to prices in. Considering assumption (1) and te utility functions, we can assume tat (for any price vector) agents always maximize utility in a location tat gives strictly positive utility and in wic income is also strictly positive. Te following Lemmas are useful for te proof of te next Proposition. Lemma 12. If I (p, r) > 0, te Indirect Utility Function V is continuous in (p, r) and te Conditional Demand Correspondence D is u.s.c. in (p, r). Lemma 13. Let (p ν, r ν ) (p 0, r 0 ), wit p 0 0, suc tat I (p ν, r ν ) 0 wen ν. Ten lim sup V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) 0 ν Proposition 14. Under assumption (1), te correspondence ϕ : IR l+ v ī + is u.s.c..

17 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 17 To obtain te existence result, we look for a zero value for te excess supply correspondence ϕ defined by: ( ) e ϕ(p, r) := D(p, r) f ( ) e (16) = N ϕ (p, r) f Proof of Teorem 11. If tere exists a price vector ( p, r) suc tat ϕ( p, r) IR + l+ v ī, take a point (x, y) ϕ( p, r) IR + l+ v ī. Suc point (x, y) is of te form : ( ) ( ) x e = ( N µ ) d (p, r, z (H 0 )) (17) y f µ As (x, y) IR l+ v ī + conditions (ii) and (iii) of Definition 6 old. As µ Γ ( p, r) we ten ave tat (i), (iv) and (v) old. Tat is, te vector ( p, r, µ, d), tat appears in te rigt side of equation (17), generates a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. So, we ave to prove te existence of suc a price vector ( p, r). To do tis we verify tat ϕ satisfies te ypotesis of te Debreu-Gale-Nikaïdo Teorem (see, Aubin, 1997). We already stated tat ϕ(p, r) as non-empty values in te simplex of IR l+ v ī +. Due to Proposition 14 and te fact tat every u.s.c. correspondence is upper emicontinuous we know ϕ(p, r) is upper emi-continuous. As utility functions are strictly concave, te sets D contain at most one element d (p, r, z (H 0 )). Terefore, for eac pair (p, r) te set ϕ (p, r) is convex. Indeed, take (d 1, µ 1 ),(d 2, µ 2 ) ϕ (p, r) and λ ]0, 1[. Ten λµ 1 + (1 λ)µ 2 =: µ λ Γ (p, r) since V (p, r, z) > V (p, r, z (H 0 )) implies µ 1 = µ2 = 0 wic in turn implies µ λ = 0. In addition, d 1 = d (p, r, z (H 0 ))µ 1 and d2 = d (p, r, z (H 0 ))µ 2 (recall tat in te case tat te conditional demand is empty for some µ = 0, so we can consider tis demand equal to zero), terefore, d λ :=λd 1 + (1 λ)d 2 =λ d (p, r, z (H 0 ))µ 1 + (1 λ) d (p, r, z (H 0 ))µ 2 = d (p, r, z (H 0 ))µ λ wit (d λ, µ λ ) ϕ (p, r).

18 18 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ As Γ (p, r) is compact, ten so is ϕ (p, r). Terefore, te set ϕ(p, r) is convex and compact. Tis implies tat ϕ(p, r) IR l+ v ī + is convex and closed. To complete te proof, we take (x, y) ϕ(p, r) and calculate (x, y) (p, r) = x p+y r. As (x, y) ϕ(p, r), we ave: ( ) ( ) x e = ( N µ ) d (p, r, z (H 0 )). y f µ Terefore, ( (x, y) (p, r) = e ) ( N µ d (p, r, z (H 0)) p + f ) N µ r = ( N e ) µ d (p, r, z (H 0)) p + f r N µ r. Note tat f r is te total value of location options, so we can calculate tis by adding values across all owners. Tat is, f r = wn r. Replacing, we get: (x, y) (p, r) = ( N e p µ d (p, r, z (H 0 )) p + N wr = ( N e p µ d (p, r, z (H 0 )) p µ r ) µ r + r w ) As µ Γ (p, r), µ = 1 so we get: (x, y) (p, r) = N ( µ e p + r w ) d (p, r, z (H 0 )) p r }{{} 0 0 Terefore σ(ϕ(p, r), (p, r)) 0. We ave sown tat ϕ(p, r) satisfies te ypotesis of te Debreu-Gale-Nikaido Teorem (see, Aubin, 1997), so we can conclude tat tere exists a price vector ( p, r) suc tat ϕ( p, r) IR l+ v ī +, wic completes te proof.

19 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES Conclusions In tis work we ave developed a new teoretical approac to model ow people make residential location decisions in an urban enronment. We ave defined wat we call an Excange Economy wit Location. As te property of all goods (consumption and location) is totally concentrated among te participating agents, teir income is endogenous to equilibrium and depends on te initial endowments and equilibrium prices. In addition to te usual budget constraints we incorporate several restrictions over consumption and actities, suc as time, capacity, spatial and tecnological constraints. Tese constraints are modelled by a set-valued map tat depends on te city structure and defines for eac agent is consumption possibilities associated wit is current location. Tis new feature does not affect te use of Willingness to Pay functions as we calculate tem, following Jara (2003), not as te inverse of te Conditional Indirect Utility Functions, but as te value of a minimum expenditure problem. Tis new metod extends all preous models in a coerent way allowing new constraints to te consumer s problem and terefore to te Conditional Indirect Utility Functions. Indeed, all te complexity added to te conditional on location consumer problem by te preously mentioned mapping, goes directly to te constraints of te minimum expenditure problem. In te case were te value of Willingness to Pay is finite, it is equal to te difference between income and te value of minimum expenditure on consumption goods. Two types of equilibrium conditions are defined. In te Location Auction Equilibrium, agents compete for location troug teir willingness to pay and location prices are determined by auctions. Te second type is te Location Utilitymaximizing Equilibrium. In tis case agents decide were to locate maximizing teir utility given goods and location prices. In bot equilibrium definitions marketclearing conditions are imposed on goods and locations determining all prices simultaneously. An important result in tis work gives conditions under wic te auction and utility approaces are equivalent, wic is defined as wen an equilibrium point satisfies conditions for bot Location Auction Equilibrium and Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium. Tis result answers an important question in Urban Economics. In te last part of te paper, we prode an existence result using te Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium approac. To obtain tis result we considered a version of te model wit budget constraints (only) in te consumer s problem and wit continuous, strictly concave utility functions. Tere are oter new features presented, altoug not fully explored in tis work. For example, we assume tat te interaction a location externalities appens in a dynamic version of te model. It remains for future researc to formulate suc an interaction and te notion of equilibrium, and to study issues suc as te equivalence of approaces and te existence of equilibrium in suc a dynamic setting. Anoter interesting extension of te model would be to study te location of firms and teir

20 20 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ agglomeration economies in a general location enronment, comparing results to te work of Lucas and Rossi-Hansberg(2002)in a monocentric enronment. References Alonso, W. (1964). Location and Land Use. Cambridge, Harvard University Press. Anas, A. (1982). Residential Location Markets and Urban Transportation. Academic Press, London. Aubin, J.P.(1997). Optima and Equilibria. Springer Verlag. Berge, C. (1997). Topological Spaces. Dover Publications Debreu, G. (1959). Teory of Value. Yale University Press Jara, P. (2003). Un Modelo de Equilibrio en Uso de Suelos con Ingreso Endógeno. Tesis de Magíster y Memoria de Ingeniero, Universidad de Cile. Jara-Díaz, S. and Martínez, F.J. (1999). On Te Specification of Indirect Utility and Willingness to Pay for Discrete Residential Location Models. Journal of Regional Science, 39, Lucas, R. E., Jr. y Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2002). On te Internal Structure of Cities. Econometrica Vol. 70, N o 4, Martínez, F.J. (1992) Te Bid-Coice Land Use Model: an Integrated Economic Framework. Enronment and Planning A. Vol. 24, McFadden, D.L.(1978). Modelling te coice of residential location, in Karlqst et. al. (eds), Spatial Interaction Teory and Planning Models. Nort-Holland, Amsterdam, Rosen, S. (1974), Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy Vol. 82 (1), Solow, R.M. (1973), On equilibrium models of urban location, in M. Parkin (ed.), Essays in modern economics, Barnes and Nobles, pp Von Tünen, J.H. (1863). See Von Tünen Isolated State, (ed) Peter Hall, Pergamon Press, London (1966). Appendix Proof of Teorem 10. We will ceck eac side of te statement separately. First implication (= )

21 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 21 Define µ as follows: so tat µ > 0 µ > 0. µ := µ N f Proposition 8 and Corollary 9 give: r = max B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) 0 = µ (B (ū, p, r ) r ) Besides: µ = µ N = 1 µ f f N = 1 f = 1 f and µ f = µ N = N. Let suc tat µ > 0. Because of Corollary 9 we get, B (ū, p, r, z (H 0 )) = r. Take d D ( p, r, z (H 0 )), wit wat Ten, d D (ū, p, z (H 0 )). p d + r = pe + rw. Terefore, (ū, p, r, µ, d) is a Location Auction Equilibrium. Second implication ( =) As p >> 0 and X (H 0 ) = IR l +, ū u min Due to Proposition 6, if we define, we get, and = u min ( p) for any pair µ := µ f N µ (ū V ( p, r, z (H 0 ))) = 0 µ = 1 µ N = f. Let s take now d D (ū, p, z (H 0 )) for suc tat µ > 0. Ten, again, r = pe + rw p d, wit d C ( p, r). From Proposition 6 we ave U ( d, z (H 0 )) = ū = V ( p, r, z (H 0 )), wit d D ( p, r, z (H 0 )). Tus, (ū, p, r, µ, d) is a Location Utility-maximizing Equilibrium.

22 22 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ Proof of Lemma 12. U (x, z (H 0 )) is continuous and I (p, r) > 0 = min{p x : x X}. applying (1) in 4.8 Debreu, , we ave tat te mapping (p, r) C (p, r) X is continuous. Applying Berge s Teorem (Berge, 1997) we get te result. Proof of Lemma 13. Consider te correspondence tat to eac (p, r) associates te set C (p, r) X. If we take x ν C (p ν, r ν ) X suc tat x ν x, we ave tat: and terefore, p ν x ν I (p ν, r ν ) p 0 x I (p 0, r 0 ) Besides x X. So, x C (p 0, r 0 ) X. Tat is, C X is upper semi-continuous in (p 0, r 0 ). As U (x, z (H 0 )) is continuous, we can apply Teorem 2 in Berge (1997) Capter IV 3 and ten, V is upper semi-continuous in (p 0, r 0 ). But C (p 0, r 0 ) = {x IR l + : p 0 x 0} because I (p 0, r 0 ) = lim ν I (p ν, r ν ) = 0, and tis set is given by : {x IR l + : p 0 j > 0 x j = 0}, terefore, if p 0 0, U (x, z (H 0 )) = 0 x C (p 0, r 0 ) X, ten: lim sup V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) V (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = 0 ν Proof of Proposition 14. Since we are cecking te upper semi-continuity of ϕ for any { 1,..., } we will omit te subscript, for te vectors µ, in tis demonstration. Let (p 0, r 0 ), and consider a sequence in, (p ν, r ν ) (p 0, r 0 ), and (d ν, µ ν ) (d 0, µ 0 ) wit (d ν, µ ν ) ϕ (p ν, r ν ). We want (d 0, µ 0 ) ϕ (p 0, r 0 ), tat is: 3 Proposition 15. If X is compact, convex, and if (p 0, I 0 ) is a point suc tat: I 0 > min{p 0 x : x X}. Ten γ is continuous in (p 0, I 0 )

23 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 23 (i) V µ0 = 1 (ii) µ 0 > 0 = V (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = max () V V () (p 0, r 0, z () ) (iii) d 0 = V µ0 d0, were d0 D (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) for all V suc tat µ > 0 We ave (d ν, µ ν ) ϕ (p ν, r ν ), so for eac V tere is a sequence d ν D (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) suc tat d ν = µν dν 4. Every sequence is in X so troug a subsequence we can get d 0. Ten we must sow tat µ0 Γ (p 0, r 0 ), and d 0 D (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) for all V suc tat µ 0 > 0. We will call V (p, r, z) to te maximum of te indirect utilities: First note tat: (18) V (p, r, z) := max V V (p, r, z (H 0 )). V µ ν = 1 = V µ 0 = 1 To prove (ii) take µ 0 > 0. We must consider two cases: p0 0 and p 0 = 0. Case p 0 0. As p ν p 0 we can suppose p ν 0. Consider te sets: I (p, r) := { : V (p, r, z (H 0 )) = V (p, r, z)} J (p, r) := { : I (p, r) > 0} Clearly, if p 0, I (p, r) J (p, r). As I is continuous, for ν sufficiently large J (p 0, r 0 ) J (p ν, r ν ) because I (p 0, r 0 ) > 0 I (p ν, r ν ) > 0 and tere is a finite number of location types. Ten Terefore, tat is (19) I (p 0, r 0 ) J (p 0, r 0 ) J (p ν, r ν ) ν > ν. µ 0 > 0 = µν > 0 ν > ν = V (p ν, r ν, z) = V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) ν > ν, I (p ν, r ν ) ν > ν. If / J (p 0, r 0 ), as I (p ν, r ν ) > 0 ν > ν, ten we must ave I (p ν, r ν ) I (p 0, r 0 ) = 0. Because of Lemma 13, we ave: lim sup V (p ν, r ν ) 0 ν 4 If for some ν, D (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) = we can consider d ν = 0 since in tat case µν is equal to zero so tere is no arm doing tis.

24 24 PEDRO JARA, ALEJANDRO JOFRÉ, FRANCISCO MARTÍNEZ But we know tat V (p 0, r 0, z) > 0, wic means, () I (p 0, r 0 ), V () (p 0, r 0, z () ) = V (p 0, r 0, z) > 0. So, for ν sufficiently large V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) < V () (p ν, r ν, z () ) V (p ν, r ν, z), because V () is continuous in (p 0, r 0 ), wic contradicts (19). So, J (p 0, r 0 ). Terefore V is continuous in (p 0, r 0 ). If ten, for ν large, and tis also contradicts (19). We conclude tat: (20) V (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) < V (p 0, r 0, z), V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) < V () (p ν, r ν, z () ) µ 0 > 0 V (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = max () V () (p0, r 0, z () ) Case p 0 = 0 Problem (P ) for (0, r) is: { X if I (0, r) 0 C (0, r) = if I (0, r) < 0. Terefore V (0, r, z (H 0 )) = { U (e, z (H 0 )) if I (0, r) 0 if I (0, r) < 0 D (0, r, z (H 0 )) = { {e} if I (0, r) 0 if I (0, r) < 0 Γ (0, r) = {µ v ī : µ = 0 suc tat I (0, r) < 0} Now take µ 0 > 0. As before, tis implies tat µ ν > 0 ν > ν and ten V (p ν, r ν, z) = V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) ν > ν. Terefore I (p ν, r ν ) 0 ν > ν. In te limit, we get I (0, r 0 ) 0 and because of te preous results, V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = U (e, z (H 0 )) U (x, z (H 0 )), x X V. Terefore V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = V (0, r 0, z). So in tis case we also ave: (21) µ 0 > 0 V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = max () V () (0, r0, z () )

25 LAND USE EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS INCOMES 25 To see tat (µ 0, d 0 ) ϕ (p 0, r 0 ) we still need tat d 0 as te form stated above, d 0 = µ0 d0. For tis we prove, µ 0 > 0 = d 0 D (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )). Equation (20) tells us tat if p 0 0 te preous sum is only over elements of I (p 0, r 0 ) and lemma 12 gives te upper semi-continuity on (p 0, r 0 ) of te demand correspondences associated to tis set. Tus d 0 D (p 0, r 0, z (H 0 )) wic brings us to conclude tat (µ 0, d 0 ) ϕ (p 0, r 0 ). If p 0 = 0, ten, because of assumption 1, tere is at least one location for wic I (0, r 0 ) > 0. So, for tese locations we can still apply Lemma 12, to obtain upper semi-continuity of te conditional demand correspondences on (0, r 0 ) wit d 0 D (0, r 0, z (H 0 )). But, if I (0, r 0 ) = 0, we can not use Lemma 12 to assure te continuity. In tis case we ave to note tat, as µ ν > 0 ν > ν, we know tat we get a sequence d ν D (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )) tat converges (a a subsequence if necessary) to d 0. If d0 = e, ten tere is no problem, since D (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = {e}. If d 0 e, we ave te following: Since d ν D (0, r ν, z (H 0 )) and µ ν > 0, we get: U (d ν, z (H 0 )) = V (p ν, r ν, z (H 0 )), Due to te form of utility functions we get: U (d ν, z (H 0 )) < U (e, z (H 0 )). Wen we take te limit in te preous equations we get tat U (d 0, z (H 0 )) < U (e, z (H 0 )) = V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )). Te first inequality comes from te utility functions and te assumption tat d 0 e, wile te second is given above. As assumption 1 assures te continuity of V in (0, r 0 ) (due to te continuity of utility in te locations suc tat I (0, r 0 ) > 0), we get a contradiction since we would get V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) = U (d 0, z (H 0 )) < V (0, r 0, z (H 0 )). Tus, eiter we get d 0 = e or I (0, r 0 ) > 0. In eiter of tese two cases we recover te fact tat d 0 D (0, r 0, z (H 0 )) and terefore, we get (µ 0, d 0 ) ϕ (p 0, r 0 ). Equations (18), (20) and (21) give te result.

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households

Volume 29, Issue 3. Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies with multi-member households Volume 29, Issue 3 Existence of competitive equilibrium in economies wit multi-member ouseolds Noriisa Sato Graduate Scool of Economics, Waseda University Abstract Tis paper focuses on te existence of

More information

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY Essential Microeconomics -1-3. THE EXCHNGE ECONOMY Pareto efficient allocations 2 Edgewort box analysis 5 Market clearing prices 13 Walrasian Equilibrium 16 Equilibrium and Efficiency 22 First welfare

More information

Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an exchange economy

Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an exchange economy Microeconomic Teory -1- Equilibrium and efficiency Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an excange economy 1. Efficient economies 2 2. Gains from excange 6 3. Edgewort-ox analysis 15 4. Properties of a

More information

FUNDAMENTAL ECONOMICS Vol. I - Walrasian and Non-Walrasian Microeconomics - Anjan Mukherji WALRASIAN AND NON-WALRASIAN MICROECONOMICS

FUNDAMENTAL ECONOMICS Vol. I - Walrasian and Non-Walrasian Microeconomics - Anjan Mukherji WALRASIAN AND NON-WALRASIAN MICROECONOMICS FUNDAMENTAL ECONOMICS Vol. I - Walrasian and Non-Walrasian Microeconomics - Anjan Mukerji WALRASIAN AND NON-WALRASIAN MICROECONOMICS Anjan Mukerji Center for Economic Studies and Planning, Jawaarlal Neru

More information

Walrasian Equilibrium in an exchange economy

Walrasian Equilibrium in an exchange economy Microeconomic Teory -1- Walrasian equilibrium Walrasian Equilibrium in an ecange economy 1. Homotetic preferences 2 2. Walrasian equilibrium in an ecange economy 11 3. Te market value of attributes 18

More information

. If lim. x 2 x 1. f(x+h) f(x)

. If lim. x 2 x 1. f(x+h) f(x) Review of Differential Calculus Wen te value of one variable y is uniquely determined by te value of anoter variable x, ten te relationsip between x and y is described by a function f tat assigns a value

More information

3.2 THE FUNDAMENTAL WELFARE THEOREMS

3.2 THE FUNDAMENTAL WELFARE THEOREMS Essential Microeconomics -1-3.2 THE FUNDMENTL WELFRE THEOREMS Walrasian Equilibrium 2 First welfare teorem 3 Second welfare teorem (conve, differentiable economy) 12 Te omotetic preference 2 2 economy

More information

Optimal Mechanism with Budget Constraint Bidders

Optimal Mechanism with Budget Constraint Bidders Optimal Mecanism wit Budget Constraint Bidders Alexei Bulatov Sergei Severinov Tis draft: November 6 Abstract Te paper deals wit te optimal mecanism design for selling to buyers wo ave commonly known budget

More information

Poisson Equation in Sobolev Spaces

Poisson Equation in Sobolev Spaces Poisson Equation in Sobolev Spaces OcMountain Dayligt Time. 6, 011 Today we discuss te Poisson equation in Sobolev spaces. It s existence, uniqueness, and regularity. Weak Solution. u = f in, u = g on

More information

Essential Microeconomics : EQUILIBRIUM AND EFFICIENCY WITH PRODUCTION Key ideas: Walrasian equilibrium, first and second welfare theorems

Essential Microeconomics : EQUILIBRIUM AND EFFICIENCY WITH PRODUCTION Key ideas: Walrasian equilibrium, first and second welfare theorems Essential Microeconomics -- 5.2: EQUILIBRIUM AND EFFICIENCY WITH PRODUCTION Key ideas: Walrasian equilibrium, irst and second welare teorems A general model 2 First welare Teorem 7 Second welare teorem

More information

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND

A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND CHAPTER A SHORT INTRODUCTION TO BANACH LATTICES AND POSITIVE OPERATORS In tis capter we give a brief introduction to Banac lattices and positive operators. Most results of tis capter can be found, e.g.,

More information

Differentiation in higher dimensions

Differentiation in higher dimensions Capter 2 Differentiation in iger dimensions 2.1 Te Total Derivative Recall tat if f : R R is a 1-variable function, and a R, we say tat f is differentiable at x = a if and only if te ratio f(a+) f(a) tends

More information

Subdifferentials of convex functions

Subdifferentials of convex functions Subdifferentials of convex functions Jordan Bell jordan.bell@gmail.com Department of Matematics, University of Toronto April 21, 2014 Wenever we speak about a vector space in tis note we mean a vector

More information

Polynomial Interpolation

Polynomial Interpolation Capter 4 Polynomial Interpolation In tis capter, we consider te important problem of approximatinga function fx, wose values at a set of distinct points x, x, x,, x n are known, by a polynomial P x suc

More information

1 The concept of limits (p.217 p.229, p.242 p.249, p.255 p.256) 1.1 Limits Consider the function determined by the formula 3. x since at this point

1 The concept of limits (p.217 p.229, p.242 p.249, p.255 p.256) 1.1 Limits Consider the function determined by the formula 3. x since at this point MA00 Capter 6 Calculus and Basic Linear Algebra I Limits, Continuity and Differentiability Te concept of its (p.7 p.9, p.4 p.49, p.55 p.56). Limits Consider te function determined by te formula f Note

More information

Matching with Contracts

Matching with Contracts Matcing wit Contracts Jon William atfield and Paul Milgrom * January 13, 2005 Abstract. We develop a model of matcing wit contracts wic incorporates, as special cases, te college admissions problem, te

More information

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions Chapter 1 Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions 1.1 Arrow-Debreu model of an economy via Walras equilibrium problem. Let us consider first the so-called Arrow-Debreu model. The presentation

More information

HOMEWORK HELP 2 FOR MATH 151

HOMEWORK HELP 2 FOR MATH 151 HOMEWORK HELP 2 FOR MATH 151 Here we go; te second round of omework elp. If tere are oters you would like to see, let me know! 2.4, 43 and 44 At wat points are te functions f(x) and g(x) = xf(x)continuous,

More information

Lecture 10: Carnot theorem

Lecture 10: Carnot theorem ecture 0: Carnot teorem Feb 7, 005 Equivalence of Kelvin and Clausius formulations ast time we learned tat te Second aw can be formulated in two ways. e Kelvin formulation: No process is possible wose

More information

Dedicated to the 70th birthday of Professor Lin Qun

Dedicated to the 70th birthday of Professor Lin Qun Journal of Computational Matematics, Vol.4, No.3, 6, 4 44. ACCELERATION METHODS OF NONLINEAR ITERATION FOR NONLINEAR PARABOLIC EQUATIONS Guang-wei Yuan Xu-deng Hang Laboratory of Computational Pysics,

More information

3.4 Worksheet: Proof of the Chain Rule NAME

3.4 Worksheet: Proof of the Chain Rule NAME Mat 1170 3.4 Workseet: Proof of te Cain Rule NAME Te Cain Rule So far we are able to differentiate all types of functions. For example: polynomials, rational, root, and trigonometric functions. We are

More information

Polynomial Interpolation

Polynomial Interpolation Capter 4 Polynomial Interpolation In tis capter, we consider te important problem of approximating a function f(x, wose values at a set of distinct points x, x, x 2,,x n are known, by a polynomial P (x

More information

The derivative function

The derivative function Roberto s Notes on Differential Calculus Capter : Definition of derivative Section Te derivative function Wat you need to know already: f is at a point on its grap and ow to compute it. Wat te derivative

More information

3.1 Extreme Values of a Function

3.1 Extreme Values of a Function .1 Etreme Values of a Function Section.1 Notes Page 1 One application of te derivative is finding minimum and maimum values off a grap. In precalculus we were only able to do tis wit quadratics by find

More information

Polynomials 3: Powers of x 0 + h

Polynomials 3: Powers of x 0 + h near small binomial Capter 17 Polynomials 3: Powers of + Wile it is easy to compute wit powers of a counting-numerator, it is a lot more difficult to compute wit powers of a decimal-numerator. EXAMPLE

More information

Numerical Differentiation

Numerical Differentiation Numerical Differentiation Finite Difference Formulas for te first derivative (Using Taylor Expansion tecnique) (section 8.3.) Suppose tat f() = g() is a function of te variable, and tat as 0 te function

More information

ch (for some fixed positive number c) reaching c

ch (for some fixed positive number c) reaching c GSTF Journal of Matematics Statistics and Operations Researc (JMSOR) Vol. No. September 05 DOI 0.60/s4086-05-000-z Nonlinear Piecewise-defined Difference Equations wit Reciprocal and Cubic Terms Ramadan

More information

Consider a function f we ll specify which assumptions we need to make about it in a minute. Let us reformulate the integral. 1 f(x) dx.

Consider a function f we ll specify which assumptions we need to make about it in a minute. Let us reformulate the integral. 1 f(x) dx. Capter 2 Integrals as sums and derivatives as differences We now switc to te simplest metods for integrating or differentiating a function from its function samples. A careful study of Taylor expansions

More information

OSCILLATION OF SOLUTIONS TO NON-LINEAR DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS WITH SEVERAL ADVANCED ARGUMENTS. Sandra Pinelas and Julio G. Dix

OSCILLATION OF SOLUTIONS TO NON-LINEAR DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS WITH SEVERAL ADVANCED ARGUMENTS. Sandra Pinelas and Julio G. Dix Opuscula Mat. 37, no. 6 (2017), 887 898 ttp://dx.doi.org/10.7494/opmat.2017.37.6.887 Opuscula Matematica OSCILLATION OF SOLUTIONS TO NON-LINEAR DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS WITH SEVERAL ADVANCED ARGUMENTS Sandra

More information

Combining functions: algebraic methods

Combining functions: algebraic methods Combining functions: algebraic metods Functions can be added, subtracted, multiplied, divided, and raised to a power, just like numbers or algebra expressions. If f(x) = x 2 and g(x) = x + 2, clearly f(x)

More information

Do Sunspots Matter under Complete Ignorance?

Do Sunspots Matter under Complete Ignorance? Do Sunspots Matter under Complete Ignorance? Guido Cozzi y Paolo E. Giordani z Abstract In a two-period, sunspot, pure-excange economy we analyze te case in wic agents do not assign subjective probabilistic

More information

How to Find the Derivative of a Function: Calculus 1

How to Find the Derivative of a Function: Calculus 1 Introduction How to Find te Derivative of a Function: Calculus 1 Calculus is not an easy matematics course Te fact tat you ave enrolled in suc a difficult subject indicates tat you are interested in te

More information

5 Ordinary Differential Equations: Finite Difference Methods for Boundary Problems

5 Ordinary Differential Equations: Finite Difference Methods for Boundary Problems 5 Ordinary Differential Equations: Finite Difference Metods for Boundary Problems Read sections 10.1, 10.2, 10.4 Review questions 10.1 10.4, 10.8 10.9, 10.13 5.1 Introduction In te previous capters we

More information

Cubic Functions: Local Analysis

Cubic Functions: Local Analysis Cubic function cubing coefficient Capter 13 Cubic Functions: Local Analysis Input-Output Pairs, 378 Normalized Input-Output Rule, 380 Local I-O Rule Near, 382 Local Grap Near, 384 Types of Local Graps

More information

Symmetry Labeling of Molecular Energies

Symmetry Labeling of Molecular Energies Capter 7. Symmetry Labeling of Molecular Energies Notes: Most of te material presented in tis capter is taken from Bunker and Jensen 1998, Cap. 6, and Bunker and Jensen 2005, Cap. 7. 7.1 Hamiltonian Symmetry

More information

Quantum Mechanics Chapter 1.5: An illustration using measurements of particle spin.

Quantum Mechanics Chapter 1.5: An illustration using measurements of particle spin. I Introduction. Quantum Mecanics Capter.5: An illustration using measurements of particle spin. Quantum mecanics is a teory of pysics tat as been very successful in explaining and predicting many pysical

More information

NUMERICAL DIFFERENTIATION. James T. Smith San Francisco State University. In calculus classes, you compute derivatives algebraically: for example,

NUMERICAL DIFFERENTIATION. James T. Smith San Francisco State University. In calculus classes, you compute derivatives algebraically: for example, NUMERICAL DIFFERENTIATION James T Smit San Francisco State University In calculus classes, you compute derivatives algebraically: for example, f( x) = x + x f ( x) = x x Tis tecnique requires your knowing

More information

Continuity and Differentiability Worksheet

Continuity and Differentiability Worksheet Continuity and Differentiability Workseet (Be sure tat you can also do te grapical eercises from te tet- Tese were not included below! Typical problems are like problems -3, p. 6; -3, p. 7; 33-34, p. 7;

More information

Material for Difference Quotient

Material for Difference Quotient Material for Difference Quotient Prepared by Stepanie Quintal, graduate student and Marvin Stick, professor Dept. of Matematical Sciences, UMass Lowell Summer 05 Preface Te following difference quotient

More information

DIGRAPHS FROM POWERS MODULO p

DIGRAPHS FROM POWERS MODULO p DIGRAPHS FROM POWERS MODULO p Caroline Luceta Box 111 GCC, 100 Campus Drive, Grove City PA 1617 USA Eli Miller PO Box 410, Sumneytown, PA 18084 USA Clifford Reiter Department of Matematics, Lafayette College,

More information

Online Appendix for Lerner Symmetry: A Modern Treatment

Online Appendix for Lerner Symmetry: A Modern Treatment Online Appendix or Lerner Symmetry: A Modern Treatment Arnaud Costinot MIT Iván Werning MIT May 2018 Abstract Tis Appendix provides te proos o Teorem 1, Teorem 2, and Proposition 1. 1 Perect Competition

More information

5.1 We will begin this section with the definition of a rational expression. We

5.1 We will begin this section with the definition of a rational expression. We Basic Properties and Reducing to Lowest Terms 5.1 We will begin tis section wit te definition of a rational epression. We will ten state te two basic properties associated wit rational epressions and go

More information

Recall from our discussion of continuity in lecture a function is continuous at a point x = a if and only if

Recall from our discussion of continuity in lecture a function is continuous at a point x = a if and only if Computational Aspects of its. Keeping te simple simple. Recall by elementary functions we mean :Polynomials (including linear and quadratic equations) Eponentials Logaritms Trig Functions Rational Functions

More information

A = h w (1) Error Analysis Physics 141

A = h w (1) Error Analysis Physics 141 Introduction In all brances of pysical science and engineering one deals constantly wit numbers wic results more or less directly from experimental observations. Experimental observations always ave inaccuracies.

More information

Introduction to Derivatives

Introduction to Derivatives Introduction to Derivatives 5-Minute Review: Instantaneous Rates and Tangent Slope Recall te analogy tat we developed earlier First we saw tat te secant slope of te line troug te two points (a, f (a))

More information

Teaching Differentiation: A Rare Case for the Problem of the Slope of the Tangent Line

Teaching Differentiation: A Rare Case for the Problem of the Slope of the Tangent Line Teacing Differentiation: A Rare Case for te Problem of te Slope of te Tangent Line arxiv:1805.00343v1 [mat.ho] 29 Apr 2018 Roman Kvasov Department of Matematics University of Puerto Rico at Aguadilla Aguadilla,

More information

Copyright c 2008 Kevin Long

Copyright c 2008 Kevin Long Lecture 4 Numerical solution of initial value problems Te metods you ve learned so far ave obtained closed-form solutions to initial value problems. A closedform solution is an explicit algebriac formula

More information

SECTION 3.2: DERIVATIVE FUNCTIONS and DIFFERENTIABILITY

SECTION 3.2: DERIVATIVE FUNCTIONS and DIFFERENTIABILITY (Section 3.2: Derivative Functions and Differentiability) 3.2.1 SECTION 3.2: DERIVATIVE FUNCTIONS and DIFFERENTIABILITY LEARNING OBJECTIVES Know, understand, and apply te Limit Definition of te Derivative

More information

REVIEW LAB ANSWER KEY

REVIEW LAB ANSWER KEY REVIEW LAB ANSWER KEY. Witout using SN, find te derivative of eac of te following (you do not need to simplify your answers): a. f x 3x 3 5x x 6 f x 3 3x 5 x 0 b. g x 4 x x x notice te trick ere! x x g

More information

Chapter 1D - Rational Expressions

Chapter 1D - Rational Expressions - Capter 1D Capter 1D - Rational Expressions Definition of a Rational Expression A rational expression is te quotient of two polynomials. (Recall: A function px is a polynomial in x of degree n, if tere

More information

Pre-Calculus Review Preemptive Strike

Pre-Calculus Review Preemptive Strike Pre-Calculus Review Preemptive Strike Attaced are some notes and one assignment wit tree parts. Tese are due on te day tat we start te pre-calculus review. I strongly suggest reading troug te notes torougly

More information

Technical Details of: US-Europe Differences in Technology-Driven Growth Quantifying the Role of Education

Technical Details of: US-Europe Differences in Technology-Driven Growth Quantifying the Role of Education Tecnical Details of: US-Europe Differences in Tecnology-Driven Growt Quantifying te Role of Education Dirk Krueger Krisna B. Kumar July 2003 Abstract In tis companion document to our paper, US-Europe Differences

More information

Preface. Here are a couple of warnings to my students who may be here to get a copy of what happened on a day that you missed.

Preface. Here are a couple of warnings to my students who may be here to get a copy of what happened on a day that you missed. Preface Here are my online notes for my course tat I teac ere at Lamar University. Despite te fact tat tese are my class notes, tey sould be accessible to anyone wanting to learn or needing a refreser

More information

Exercises for numerical differentiation. Øyvind Ryan

Exercises for numerical differentiation. Øyvind Ryan Exercises for numerical differentiation Øyvind Ryan February 25, 2013 1. Mark eac of te following statements as true or false. a. Wen we use te approximation f (a) (f (a +) f (a))/ on a computer, we can

More information

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption Chiaki Hara April 5, 2004 Abstract We give a theorem on the existence of an equilibrium price vector for an excess

More information

Continuity and Differentiability of the Trigonometric Functions

Continuity and Differentiability of the Trigonometric Functions [Te basis for te following work will be te definition of te trigonometric functions as ratios of te sides of a triangle inscribed in a circle; in particular, te sine of an angle will be defined to be te

More information

Quantum Numbers and Rules

Quantum Numbers and Rules OpenStax-CNX module: m42614 1 Quantum Numbers and Rules OpenStax College Tis work is produced by OpenStax-CNX and licensed under te Creative Commons Attribution License 3.0 Abstract Dene quantum number.

More information

Efficient algorithms for for clone items detection

Efficient algorithms for for clone items detection Efficient algoritms for for clone items detection Raoul Medina, Caroline Noyer, and Olivier Raynaud Raoul Medina, Caroline Noyer and Olivier Raynaud LIMOS - Université Blaise Pascal, Campus universitaire

More information

1. Questions (a) through (e) refer to the graph of the function f given below. (A) 0 (B) 1 (C) 2 (D) 4 (E) does not exist

1. Questions (a) through (e) refer to the graph of the function f given below. (A) 0 (B) 1 (C) 2 (D) 4 (E) does not exist Mat 1120 Calculus Test 2. October 18, 2001 Your name Te multiple coice problems count 4 points eac. In te multiple coice section, circle te correct coice (or coices). You must sow your work on te oter

More information

MA455 Manifolds Solutions 1 May 2008

MA455 Manifolds Solutions 1 May 2008 MA455 Manifolds Solutions 1 May 2008 1. (i) Given real numbers a < b, find a diffeomorpism (a, b) R. Solution: For example first map (a, b) to (0, π/2) and ten map (0, π/2) diffeomorpically to R using

More information

Exam 1 Review Solutions

Exam 1 Review Solutions Exam Review Solutions Please also review te old quizzes, and be sure tat you understand te omework problems. General notes: () Always give an algebraic reason for your answer (graps are not sufficient),

More information

Weierstraß-Institut. im Forschungsverbund Berlin e.v. Preprint ISSN

Weierstraß-Institut. im Forschungsverbund Berlin e.v. Preprint ISSN Weierstraß-Institut für Angewandte Analysis und Stocastik im Forscungsverbund Berlin e.v. Preprint ISSN 0946 8633 Stability of infinite dimensional control problems wit pointwise state constraints Micael

More information

Regularized Regression

Regularized Regression Regularized Regression David M. Blei Columbia University December 5, 205 Modern regression problems are ig dimensional, wic means tat te number of covariates p is large. In practice statisticians regularize

More information

Quasiperiodic phenomena in the Van der Pol - Mathieu equation

Quasiperiodic phenomena in the Van der Pol - Mathieu equation Quasiperiodic penomena in te Van der Pol - Matieu equation F. Veerman and F. Verulst Department of Matematics, Utrect University P.O. Box 80.010, 3508 TA Utrect Te Neterlands April 8, 009 Abstract Te Van

More information

Mathematics 5 Worksheet 11 Geometry, Tangency, and the Derivative

Mathematics 5 Worksheet 11 Geometry, Tangency, and the Derivative Matematics 5 Workseet 11 Geometry, Tangency, and te Derivative Problem 1. Find te equation of a line wit slope m tat intersects te point (3, 9). Solution. Te equation for a line passing troug a point (x

More information

Multiplicity, Overtaking and Convergence in the Lucas Two-Sector Growth Model by José Ramón Ruiz-Tamarit* DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO

Multiplicity, Overtaking and Convergence in the Lucas Two-Sector Growth Model by José Ramón Ruiz-Tamarit* DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO Multiplicity, Overtaking and Convergence in te Lucas Two-Sector Growt Model by José Ramón Ruiz-Tamarit* DOCUMENTO DE TRABAJO 22-17 July 22 * Universitat de València Los Documentos de Trabajo se distribuyen

More information

MVT and Rolle s Theorem

MVT and Rolle s Theorem AP Calculus CHAPTER 4 WORKSHEET APPLICATIONS OF DIFFERENTIATION MVT and Rolle s Teorem Name Seat # Date UNLESS INDICATED, DO NOT USE YOUR CALCULATOR FOR ANY OF THESE QUESTIONS In problems 1 and, state

More information

arxiv: v3 [cs.ds] 4 Aug 2017

arxiv: v3 [cs.ds] 4 Aug 2017 Non-preemptive Sceduling in a Smart Grid Model and its Implications on Macine Minimization Fu-Hong Liu 1, Hsiang-Hsuan Liu 1,2, and Prudence W.H. Wong 2 1 Department of Computer Science, National Tsing

More information

lecture 26: Richardson extrapolation

lecture 26: Richardson extrapolation 43 lecture 26: Ricardson extrapolation 35 Ricardson extrapolation, Romberg integration Trougout numerical analysis, one encounters procedures tat apply some simple approximation (eg, linear interpolation)

More information

Math 2921, spring, 2004 Notes, Part 3. April 2 version, changes from March 31 version starting on page 27.. Maps and di erential equations

Math 2921, spring, 2004 Notes, Part 3. April 2 version, changes from March 31 version starting on page 27.. Maps and di erential equations Mat 9, spring, 4 Notes, Part 3. April version, canges from Marc 3 version starting on page 7.. Maps and di erential equations Horsesoe maps and di erential equations Tere are two main tecniques for detecting

More information

Topics in Generalized Differentiation

Topics in Generalized Differentiation Topics in Generalized Differentiation J. Marsall As Abstract Te course will be built around tree topics: ) Prove te almost everywere equivalence of te L p n-t symmetric quantum derivative and te L p Peano

More information

Robotic manipulation project

Robotic manipulation project Robotic manipulation project Bin Nguyen December 5, 2006 Abstract Tis is te draft report for Robotic Manipulation s class project. Te cosen project aims to understand and implement Kevin Egan s non-convex

More information

LIMITS AND DERIVATIVES CONDITIONS FOR THE EXISTENCE OF A LIMIT

LIMITS AND DERIVATIVES CONDITIONS FOR THE EXISTENCE OF A LIMIT LIMITS AND DERIVATIVES Te limit of a function is defined as te value of y tat te curve approaces, as x approaces a particular value. Te limit of f (x) as x approaces a is written as f (x) approaces, as

More information

1 Calculus. 1.1 Gradients and the Derivative. Q f(x+h) f(x)

1 Calculus. 1.1 Gradients and the Derivative. Q f(x+h) f(x) Calculus. Gradients and te Derivative Q f(x+) δy P T δx R f(x) 0 x x+ Let P (x, f(x)) and Q(x+, f(x+)) denote two points on te curve of te function y = f(x) and let R denote te point of intersection of

More information

The Krewe of Caesar Problem. David Gurney. Southeastern Louisiana University. SLU 10541, 500 Western Avenue. Hammond, LA

The Krewe of Caesar Problem. David Gurney. Southeastern Louisiana University. SLU 10541, 500 Western Avenue. Hammond, LA Te Krewe of Caesar Problem David Gurney Souteastern Louisiana University SLU 10541, 500 Western Avenue Hammond, LA 7040 June 19, 00 Krewe of Caesar 1 ABSTRACT Tis paper provides an alternative to te usual

More information

Time (hours) Morphine sulfate (mg)

Time (hours) Morphine sulfate (mg) Mat Xa Fall 2002 Review Notes Limits and Definition of Derivative Important Information: 1 According to te most recent information from te Registrar, te Xa final exam will be eld from 9:15 am to 12:15

More information

Financial Econometrics Prof. Massimo Guidolin

Financial Econometrics Prof. Massimo Guidolin CLEFIN A.A. 2010/2011 Financial Econometrics Prof. Massimo Guidolin A Quick Review of Basic Estimation Metods 1. Were te OLS World Ends... Consider two time series 1: = { 1 2 } and 1: = { 1 2 }. At tis

More information

2.11 That s So Derivative

2.11 That s So Derivative 2.11 Tat s So Derivative Introduction to Differential Calculus Just as one defines instantaneous velocity in terms of average velocity, we now define te instantaneous rate of cange of a function at a point

More information

Approximation of the Viability Kernel

Approximation of the Viability Kernel Approximation of te Viability Kernel Patrick Saint-Pierre CEREMADE, Université Paris-Daupine Place du Marécal de Lattre de Tassigny 75775 Paris cedex 16 26 october 1990 Abstract We study recursive inclusions

More information

Lecture XVII. Abstract We introduce the concept of directional derivative of a scalar function and discuss its relation with the gradient operator.

Lecture XVII. Abstract We introduce the concept of directional derivative of a scalar function and discuss its relation with the gradient operator. Lecture XVII Abstract We introduce te concept of directional derivative of a scalar function and discuss its relation wit te gradient operator. Directional derivative and gradient Te directional derivative

More information

Math 161 (33) - Final exam

Math 161 (33) - Final exam Name: Id #: Mat 161 (33) - Final exam Fall Quarter 2015 Wednesday December 9, 2015-10:30am to 12:30am Instructions: Prob. Points Score possible 1 25 2 25 3 25 4 25 TOTAL 75 (BEST 3) Read eac problem carefully.

More information

2.8 The Derivative as a Function

2.8 The Derivative as a Function .8 Te Derivative as a Function Typically, we can find te derivative of a function f at many points of its domain: Definition. Suppose tat f is a function wic is differentiable at every point of an open

More information

MODELING TIME AND MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS. Preliminary, November 27, 2004

MODELING TIME AND MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS. Preliminary, November 27, 2004 MODELING TIME AND MACROECONOMIC DYNAMICS Alexis Anagnostopoulos Cryssi Giannitsarou Preliminary, November 27, 2004 Abstract. Wen analyzing dynamic macroeconomic models, a commonly eld view is tat assuming

More information

Derivatives. By: OpenStaxCollege

Derivatives. By: OpenStaxCollege By: OpenStaxCollege Te average teen in te United States opens a refrigerator door an estimated 25 times per day. Supposedly, tis average is up from 10 years ago wen te average teenager opened a refrigerator

More information

MAT 145. Type of Calculator Used TI-89 Titanium 100 points Score 100 possible points

MAT 145. Type of Calculator Used TI-89 Titanium 100 points Score 100 possible points MAT 15 Test #2 Name Solution Guide Type of Calculator Used TI-89 Titanium 100 points Score 100 possible points Use te grap of a function sown ere as you respond to questions 1 to 8. 1. lim f (x) 0 2. lim

More information

4.2 - Richardson Extrapolation

4.2 - Richardson Extrapolation . - Ricardson Extrapolation. Small-O Notation: Recall tat te big-o notation used to define te rate of convergence in Section.: Definition Let x n n converge to a number x. Suppose tat n n is a sequence

More information

IEOR 165 Lecture 10 Distribution Estimation

IEOR 165 Lecture 10 Distribution Estimation IEOR 165 Lecture 10 Distribution Estimation 1 Motivating Problem Consider a situation were we ave iid data x i from some unknown distribution. One problem of interest is estimating te distribution tat

More information

Numerical Experiments Using MATLAB: Superconvergence of Nonconforming Finite Element Approximation for Second-Order Elliptic Problems

Numerical Experiments Using MATLAB: Superconvergence of Nonconforming Finite Element Approximation for Second-Order Elliptic Problems Applied Matematics, 06, 7, 74-8 ttp://wwwscirporg/journal/am ISSN Online: 5-7393 ISSN Print: 5-7385 Numerical Experiments Using MATLAB: Superconvergence of Nonconforming Finite Element Approximation for

More information

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics Journal of Computational and Applied Matematics 94 (6) 75 96 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Computational and Applied Matematics journal omepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/cam Smootness-Increasing

More information

Simulation and verification of a plate heat exchanger with a built-in tap water accumulator

Simulation and verification of a plate heat exchanger with a built-in tap water accumulator Simulation and verification of a plate eat excanger wit a built-in tap water accumulator Anders Eriksson Abstract In order to test and verify a compact brazed eat excanger (CBE wit a built-in accumulation

More information

A Hybrid Mixed Discontinuous Galerkin Finite Element Method for Convection-Diffusion Problems

A Hybrid Mixed Discontinuous Galerkin Finite Element Method for Convection-Diffusion Problems A Hybrid Mixed Discontinuous Galerkin Finite Element Metod for Convection-Diffusion Problems Herbert Egger Joacim Scöberl We propose and analyse a new finite element metod for convection diffusion problems

More information

Chapter 2 Limits and Continuity

Chapter 2 Limits and Continuity 4 Section. Capter Limits and Continuity Section. Rates of Cange and Limits (pp. 6) Quick Review.. f () ( ) () 4 0. f () 4( ) 4. f () sin sin 0 4. f (). 4 4 4 6. c c c 7. 8. c d d c d d c d c 9. 8 ( )(

More information

232 Calculus and Structures

232 Calculus and Structures 3 Calculus and Structures CHAPTER 17 JUSTIFICATION OF THE AREA AND SLOPE METHODS FOR EVALUATING BEAMS Calculus and Structures 33 Copyrigt Capter 17 JUSTIFICATION OF THE AREA AND SLOPE METHODS 17.1 THE

More information

Solution. Solution. f (x) = (cos x)2 cos(2x) 2 sin(2x) 2 cos x ( sin x) (cos x) 4. f (π/4) = ( 2/2) ( 2/2) ( 2/2) ( 2/2) 4.

Solution. Solution. f (x) = (cos x)2 cos(2x) 2 sin(2x) 2 cos x ( sin x) (cos x) 4. f (π/4) = ( 2/2) ( 2/2) ( 2/2) ( 2/2) 4. December 09, 20 Calculus PracticeTest s Name: (4 points) Find te absolute extrema of f(x) = x 3 0 on te interval [0, 4] Te derivative of f(x) is f (x) = 3x 2, wic is zero only at x = 0 Tus we only need

More information

More on generalized inverses of partitioned matrices with Banachiewicz-Schur forms

More on generalized inverses of partitioned matrices with Banachiewicz-Schur forms More on generalized inverses of partitioned matrices wit anaciewicz-scur forms Yongge Tian a,, Yosio Takane b a Cina Economics and Management cademy, Central University of Finance and Economics, eijing,

More information

Chapters 19 & 20 Heat and the First Law of Thermodynamics

Chapters 19 & 20 Heat and the First Law of Thermodynamics Capters 19 & 20 Heat and te First Law of Termodynamics Te Zerot Law of Termodynamics Te First Law of Termodynamics Termal Processes Te Second Law of Termodynamics Heat Engines and te Carnot Cycle Refrigerators,

More information

University Mathematics 2

University Mathematics 2 University Matematics 2 1 Differentiability In tis section, we discuss te differentiability of functions. Definition 1.1 Differentiable function). Let f) be a function. We say tat f is differentiable at

More information

Differential Calculus (The basics) Prepared by Mr. C. Hull

Differential Calculus (The basics) Prepared by Mr. C. Hull Differential Calculus Te basics) A : Limits In tis work on limits, we will deal only wit functions i.e. tose relationsips in wic an input variable ) defines a unique output variable y). Wen we work wit

More information

Unilateral substitutability implies substitutable completability in many-to-one matching with contracts

Unilateral substitutability implies substitutable completability in many-to-one matching with contracts Unilateral substitutability implies substitutable completability in many-to-one matcing wit contracts Sangram Vilasrao Kadam April 6, 2015 Abstract We prove tat te unilateral substitutability property

More information

Solutions to the Multivariable Calculus and Linear Algebra problems on the Comprehensive Examination of January 31, 2014

Solutions to the Multivariable Calculus and Linear Algebra problems on the Comprehensive Examination of January 31, 2014 Solutions to te Multivariable Calculus and Linear Algebra problems on te Compreensive Examination of January 3, 24 Tere are 9 problems ( points eac, totaling 9 points) on tis portion of te examination.

More information