OPTIMAL RISK TRANSFERS IN INSURANCE GROUPS. This version: 18 January 2012

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "OPTIMAL RISK TRANSFERS IN INSURANCE GROUPS. This version: 18 January 2012"

Transcription

1 OPTIMAL RISK TRANSFERS IN INSURANCE GROUPS Alexandru V. Asimit Alexandru M. Badescu 2 Andreas Tsanakas 3 This version: 8 January 202 Abstract. Optimal risk transfers are derived within an insurance group consisting of two separate legal entities, operating under potentially different regulatory capital requirements and capital costs. Consistently with regulatory practice, capital requirements for each entity are computed by either a Value-at-Risk or an Expected Shortfall risk measure. The optimality criterion consists of minimizing the risk-adjusted value of the total group liabilities, with valuation carried out using a cost-of-capital approach. The optimization problems are analytically solved and it is seen that optimal risk transfers often involve the transfer of tail risk unlimited reinsurance layers to the more weakly regulated entity. We show that, in the absence of a capital requirement for the credit risk arising from the risk transfer, optimal risk transfers achieve capital efficiency at the cost of increasing policyholder deficit. However, when credit risk is properly reflected in the capital requirement, incentives for tail-risk transfers vanish and policyholder welfare is restored. Keywords and phrases: Cost of Capital, Expected Shortfall, Insurance Groups, Optimal Reinsurance, Value-at-Risk. Corresponding author. Cass Business School, City University London, London ECY 8TZ, United Kingdom. asimit@city.ac.uk. Tel: Fax: Department of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Calgary, Calgary, Alberta T2N N4, Canada. abadescu@math.ucalgary.ca 3 Cass Business School, City University London, London ECY 8TZ, United Kingdom. E- mail: a.tsanakas.@city.ac.uk

2 2. Introduction Insurance groups often comprise a number of distinct legal entities, operating in different territories. Diversification across an insurance group is no trivial matter and the way it operates depends on the group s legal structure. On the one hand, the risk exposures of different entities will in general not be perfectly correlated, and thus some group level diversification Keller, 2007 is observed e.g. by a parent company. On the other hand, risks and assets in the group portfolio are not pooled across entities, hence there are limits to the cross-subsidy, as well as the capital fungibility, within the group. Nonetheless, the risk and capital requirements of individual entities can be reduced, through a web of capital and risk transfer arrangements across entities. The capital efficiency thus produced can be seen as a result of down-streaming of diversification Keller, The complexity of group legal structures and intra-group risk transfers, with entities being potentially subject to different regulatory regimes, poses a major challenge for regulators; it is not surprising that a substantial part of the European Solvency II Directive European Commission, 2009 is dedicated to group supervision. Studying such complexity has motivated a lively academic literature. Filipović and Kupper 2008 discuss optimal risk transfers, in a framework where a finite set of risk transfer instruments is available and the capital requirements of individual entities are calculated using convex risk measures. Gatzert and Schmeiser 20 study the impact of group diversification on shareholder value, considering a variety of group structures and capital and risk transfer instruments, while also offering a thorough literature review of diversification in financial conglomerates. Schlütter and Gründl 20 assess the impact of group building on policyholder welfare. In their analysis, it is assumed that a particular type of rational risk transfer arrangement is enforced, while the group sets premium and equity targets in order to maximize shareholder value, allowing for the impact of entities default risk on insurance demand. The above literature generally analyzes the impact of risk transfers of pre-specified type. In contrast, the focus here is on deriving optimal functional forms of risk transfers. For this purpose, we use a formal setting with two legal entities, subject to potentially discrepant regulatory requirements. Hence our work is also related to the literature on optimal insurance contract design see for example, Arrow, 963, Borch, 960, Kaluszka and Okolewski, 2008, Chi and Tan, 20. Optimal risk transfers are chosen such

3 that the risk adjusted value of the group liabilities is minimized, when valuation takes place under a cost-of-capital methodology, similar in principle to the ones discussed in Wüthrich et al 200 and lying at the heart of regulatory valuation approaches e.g. under the Swiss Solvency Test and Solvency II Federal Office of Private Insurance, 2006; European Commission, Analytical solutions are provided for the corresponding optimization problems, when the capital requirement for each entity is given either by Value-at-Risk VaR the risk measure used under Solvency II or Expected Shortfall ES used in the Swiss Solvency Test and each entity is subject to a different cost of capital, due to potential differences in taxation or other operating costs. The results bear out the properties of the risk measures used, specifically the Value-at-Risk measure s insensitivity to tail risk beyond the given confidence level. In particular, when one entity is subject to a lighter VaR-based regulatory requirement than the other, it ends up being allocated most of the group s extreme risk exposure, in the form of high usually infinite reinsurance layers. Such incentives ought to trouble regulators, since, beyond direct implications for policyholder welfare, transferring tail risk is arguably also associated to the transfer of operational and model risks. To further investigate these incentives, we focus on the case where the first entity is subject to an ES-based capital requirement, while the second entity, acting as subsidiary solely set up to reinsure the first, holds capital according to VaR. We then show that, in the absence of an allowance for credit risk in capital requirements, the transfer of tail risk to the VaR-regulated entity is detrimental to policyholder welfare as it increases the expected policyholder deficit. This is equivalent to saying the the value of the insurer s default option calculated under a physical measure increases Phillips et al. 998, Myers and Read, 200. Motivated by these findings, we then consider a situation where the counter-party credit risk arising from the risk transfer is reflected in the ES-based capital requirement of the first entity. A corresponding optimization problem is formulated and its solution shows that incentives for transferring tail risk to the second entity vanish. Moreover, policyholder welfare is restored to pre-transfer levels. We conclude from our analysis that discrepant regulatory regimes can produce risk transfers that trade off group capital efficiency against policyholder welfare. However, the group incentives for such action vanish as long as credit risk is fully allowed for, 3

4 4 both in terms of quantifying the dependence between entities exposures and assuming a low recovery given default. While our results are produced in a rather formal and simplified setting, we believe that they are informative in relation to the potentially damaging direction of incentives, which inconsistent capital requirements can produce. In Section 2, some background on the risk measures used is offered. Then the optimization problem studied is formally introduced and solutions are given for different combinations of risk measures. Section 3 deals with the impact of credit risk on policyholder deficit. Revised optimal risk transfers are obtained when the credit risk is reflected in the capital requirement, and the impact of the change is demonstrated by a numerical example. Finally, in the light of the results obtained, some of the key assumptions of our setting are discussed. Brief conclusions are stated in Section 4. Proofs are rather technical and lengthy; they are thus collected in the Appendix. 2. Optimal risk transfers 2.. Value-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall. We start this section by briefly discussing the risk measures that will be extensively used throughout the paper. Motivated by standard regulatory requirements developed in the insurance industry, the risk measures considered are Value-at-risk VaR and Expected Shortfall ES. The V ar of a generic loss variable Z at confidence level α, V ar α Z, represents the minimum amount of capital that will not be exceeded by the loss Z with probability α. Mathematically, V ar α Z := inf{z R : PrZ z α}. Value-at-Risk has been criticized for its incomplete allowance for the risk of extreme events beyond the confidence level α Dowd and Blake, 2006, which also leads to a violation of the commonly required subadditivity property Artzner et al, 999. To correct such shortcomings, Expected Shortfall has been proposed Artzner et al, 999 as an alternative risk measure. While V ar focuses on a particular point of the loss distribution, the ES at confidence level α, ES α Z, evaluates the expected loss amount incurred under the worst 00 α% loss scenarios of Z. The ES α has multiple formulations in the literature Acerbi and Tasche, 2002; Hürlimann, present paper, we only refer to the following two representations: ES α Z := α where the notation z + = max{z, 0} is used. α In the V ar s Z ds = V ar α Z + α E Z V ar α Z +, 2.

5 While it is clearly the case that V ar α Z ES α Z, it is sometimes desirable to derive a calibration of ES such that the two risk measures are comparable. One possibility is to set β = 2 α. Then, loosely speaking, ES β Z is the conditional expected value of Z given Z > V ar β, while V ar α Z is the median of the corresponding conditional distribution. Examples of such risk measures considered broadly consistent, are the V ar used under Solvency II and the ES 0.99 used in the Swiss Solvency Test EIOPA, 20. The typically observed skewness of tails of loss distributions mean that for such confidence level choices it will usually be ES β Z > V ar α Z General form of the optimization problem. Here, the formal setting is given for the optimization problems solved throughout Section 2. We denote by X 0 the total insurance liabilities that an insurance group consisting of two separate legal entities is exposed to. The distribution function of X is given by F and the survival function is F = F. The right end-point x F distribution can be either finite or infinite. := inf{z R : F z = } of the loss The insurance group allocates the total risk X between its two entities, using appropriate risk transfer agreements. In particular, after risk transfers take place, the liabilities of the two entities are I [X] and I 2 [X] respectively, such that I [X] + I 2 [X] = X. Each of the two entities is assumed to be subject to potentially different regulatory requirements, in each case quantified by a risk measure. We denote the risk measure used to regulate the first entity by φ, where φ V ar α or φ ES α and the risk measure used by the second entity by φ 2, where φ 2 V ar α2 or φ 2 ES α2. The total capital requirements of the first and second entity are thus φ I [X] and φ 2 I2 [X] respectively. In addition, for each of the entities, one can define the risk adjusted value of its liabilities, by RAV I k [X]; φ k, λ k := E I k [X] + λ k φ k Ik [X] E I k [X], k {, 2}, where λ k 0, is the cost of capital as a percentage of the pure risk capital φ k Ik [X] E I k [X]. Such a valuation principle is used commonly in practice and is embedded in regulatory requirements under the Swiss Solvency Test and Solvency II. The idea behind it is that the taker of a liability in an arm s length transaction must be compensated by receiving a the expected value of future claims and b funds equal to the cost of raising the necessary regulatory capital to support the liability. A detailed analysis of the cost-of-capital approach to actuarial valuation is given in Wüthrich et al 200.

6 6 Our purpose is now to derive risk transfers that minimize the risk adjusted value of liabilities across the group, reflecting the potentially different risk measures and capital costs pertaining to each of the two entities. Hence we seek to minimize the quantity: RAV I [X]; φ, λ + RAV I 2 [X]; φ 2, λ = E X + λ φ I [X] E I [X] + λ 2 φ 2 I2 [X] E I 2 [X], among the feasible set of risk allocations F := {I [x]+i 2 [x] = x : I [x] and I 2 [x] are non-decreasing functions with I [0] = I 2 [0] = 0}. Since I [X] and I 2 [X] are co-monotone random variables for details, see Denuit et al., 2005, minimizing the risk adjusted value of 2.3 is equivalent to: where φ I [X] min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] + λ 2 φ 2 I2 [X] λ φ I2 [X], 2.4 I,I 2 F { V ar α I [X], ES α I [X] }, φ 2 I2 [X] { V ar α I2 [X], ES α I2 [X] }. The rest of Section 2 is devoted to solving the four optimization problems arising from differen risk measure combinations. For technical purposes it is useful to note that I, I 2 F implies that the functions I and I 2 are Lipschitz continuous functions with unit constants, i.e. I [y] I [x] y x and I 2 [y] I 2 [x] y x hold for all x, y 0. An essential property of V ar that is heavily used in derivations is that V ar αk Ik [X] = I k V arαk X, k {, 2}, since I k is a non-decreasing and continuous function see eg Denuit et al., 2005, p.9. Finally, it is noted that the rationale by which we arrive at optimization problem 2.4 rests on a number of key assumptions, including: a Insurance liabilities are the only risk that the group is exposed to; in particular, the regulatory capital held is invested with no risk. b The optimization problem 2.4 remains meaningful even when capital held by the group is higher than the regulatory minimum. c The capital requirements do not explicitly allow for counter-party credit risk arising from the risk transfers considered. d The optimal risk allocations I [X], I 2 [X] must be co-monotone. e The risk transfers have no impact on the market value of insurance policies sold by the group and, hence, the group s profitability.

7 Assumption a is not particularly realistic, but is one that we are happy to make for reasons of formal clarity; in principle, some non-insurance risks could be absorbed into the random variable X. Assumption b can be justified as follows. While assets in excess of regulatory capital may be available to the group, regulatory minima retain their significance since they relate to assets that are not fungible across entities in different territories. Furthermore, if the risk adjusted value 2.2 represents the necessary payment to a third party for it to accept the risk, there is no reason why such a price should be dependent on the total assets of the bearer of the original risk. The other three assumptions are potentially contentious and deserve further explanations, which are best provided when the ideas of the present section are further developed. Section 3 deals at length with c, while assumptions d and e are discussed in Section VaR / VaR setting. In the scenario where both entities are subject to VaRbased capital requirements, ie φ V ar α, φ 2 V ar α2, the optimization problem at hand is: min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] + λ 2 V ar α2 I2 [X] λ V ar α I2 [X]. 2.5 I,I 2 F Theorem 2. states the optimal risk transfer arrangement under this setting. Theorem 2.. The optimal solution of 2.5 is: i If λ λ 2, I 2[X] = { min { X, V arα X }, λ > λ 2, X V arα2 X +, λ < λ 2. ii If λ = λ 2 and V ar α X < V ar α2 X, { I2[X] f2 X, X > V ar α2 X, = min { } f X, t, otherwise, iii If λ = λ 2 and V ar α X > V ar α2 X, { f4 X, X > V ar α X, I 2[X] = X V arα2 X + + min { f 3 X, t 2 }, otherwise,

8 8 f k, k {,..., 4}, are non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous functions with unit constants such that f 0 = f 3 0 = 0, f V arα X = f 2 V arα2 X = t, f 3 V arα2 X = t 2, f 4 V arα X = V ar α X V ar α2 X + t 2, t [0, V ar α X], t 2 [0, V ar α2 X]. To interpret this result, let us focus on the case that λ > λ 2, that is, it is more expensive for the first entity to hold capital. The optimal allocation of the risk X is then I[X] = X V ar α X, + I 2[X] = min{x, V ar α X}, implying that extreme risk is transferred to the second entity, while less extreme risk is retained by the first. The effectiveness of such action follows from V ar α I[X] = V ar α X V arα X + = 0 V ar α2 I2[X] = V ar α min{x, V arα X} = min{v ar α X, V ar α2 X}. Thus the blindness of the VaR measure to extreme risk nullifies the capital requirement of the first entity, while capital held by the second entity at a lower cost, is lower or equal to the capital arising from holding all risk X in either of the two entities. The way that the risk allocation affects individual risk profiles is depicted in Figure 2., where the percentiles VaRs of the random variables X, I[X], I2[X] are plotted against the confidence level β. It can be seen that the percentiles of I[X] remain at zero until β > α, while the percentiles of I2[X] increase with those of X up to confidence level α and remain constant thereafter. In the case λ < λ 2, the same argument holds in reverse. The case λ = λ 2 is somewhat different, as the equality of the cost-of-capital parameters makes solutions non-unique, making in turn the notation more complex. Focusing on the case V ar α X < V ar α2 X, the theorem essentially states that the function I2[x] should be constant for x [V ar α X, V ar α2 X] and non-decreasing outside this interval. This means that the first entity retains a layer of the total risk between V ar α X and V ar α2 X which is undetected by the V ar α measure used to calculate the first entity s capital while losses x < V ar α X or x > V ar α2 X are arbitrarily split between the entities VaR / ES setting. We now turn our attention to the optimal risk transfer for the insurance group, assuming that φ V ar α, φ 2 ES α2. This is perhaps the

9 9 VaR bx VaR bi*[x] VaR bi*[x] 2 VaR X a a b Figure 2.. VaR allocations of I [X] and I 2[X] for various confidence levels β. most interesting of the optimization problems we consider, as it addresses inconsistencies between not only confidence levels and capital costs, but also the risk measures themselves. In view of 2.4, the optimization problem becomes min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] + λ 2 ES α2 I2 [X] λ V ar α I2 [X], 2.6 I,I 2 F and its solution is stated in Theorem 2.2 below. Theorem 2.2. The optimal solution of 2.6 is: i If V ar α X V ar α2 X then { { min X, V I2[X] arα X }, λ > λ 2, = 0, λ < λ 2, ii If V ar α X > V ar α2 X then { } min X, V ar I2[X] α X, λ > λ 2, = { X } min V arα X, V ar 2 + α X V ar α X, λ 2 < λ 2, where α 2 = min { α, α 2} and α 2 = λ 2 α 2 λ α 2 +λ 2 α 2.

10 0 iii If λ = λ 2 and V ar α X V ar α2 X then I 2[X] = min { f X, t }, while if λ = λ 2 and V ar α X > V ar α2 X it is { } min X, V ar I2[X] α X V ar α2 X + t 2, = f 2 X, X > V ar α2 X, otherwise, where f and f 2 are non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous functions with unit constants such that f 0 = f 2 0 = 0, f V arα X = t, f 2 V arα2 X = t 2, with parameters t [0, V ar α X] and t 2 [0, V ar α2 X]. Naturally, a mirror image of that result is obtained when we reverse the situation to φ ES α, φ 2 V ar α2. In view of 2.4 we now aim to solve min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] + λ 2 V ar α2 I2 [X] λ ES α I2 [X]. 2.7 I,I 2 F The solution to this problem is summarized in Corollary 2., for which a proof is not provided, as it is just a replication of that of Theorem 2.2. Corollary 2.. The optimal solution of 2.7 is: i If V ar α X V ar α2 X then { X, I2[X] λ > λ 2, = X V arα2 X, λ + < λ 2, ii If V ar α X < V ar α2 X then { X V I2[X] arα2 X + = + min { X, V ar α X}, λ > λ 2, X V arα2 X, λ + < λ 2, where α = min { α, α 2 } and α = λ α λ α +λ 2 α. iii If λ = λ 2 and V ar α X V ar α2 X then { X V I2[X] arα2 X + t, X > V ar α2 X, = min { } f X, t, otherwise, while for λ = λ 2 and V ar α X < V ar α2 X it is I 2[X] = X V ar α2 X + + min { f 2 X, t 2 }

11 where f and f 2 are non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous functions with unit constants such that f 0 = f 2 0 = 0, f V arα2 X = t, f 2 V arα X = t 2, with parameters t [0, V ar α2 X] and t 2 [0, V ar α X]. To interpret this result, let us focus on Corollary 2. and assume that V ar α X < V ar α X, α < α 2, as then the ES α may in a sense be comparable to V ar α2, as in the case of regulatory requirements under the Swiss Solvency Test ES 0.99 and Solvency II V ar EIOPA, 20. First consider the case that λ > λ 2, implying α < α, and also assume that α < α 2, such that I [X] = min { X V ar α X +, V ar α2 X V ar α X }, I 2[X] = X V ar α2 X + + min { X, V ar α X }. The risk sharing arrangement is then such that a thin layer of V ar α2 X V ar α X in excess of V ar α X is retained by the first entity, while the rest of the risk is transferred to the second. That most of the risk is optimally held by the second entity is justified by its lower cost of capital. The more different λ and λ 2 are, the further α and α are from eachother, hence the thinner the layer retained is. Moreover, the fact that the layer retained by the first entity is limited essentially takes the bite out of the tail-sensitive ES α risk measure used. At the same time, we note that P I2[X] > V ar α X = α 2, implying that V ar α2 I2[X] = V ar α X V ar α2 X. Thus, capital efficiency for the second entity arises again from the blindness of the V ar α2 measure to the tail component X V ar α2 X of + I 2[X], in the sense that V ar α2 X V arα2 X + = 0. This is further illustrated by Figure 2.2, where the percentiles VaRs of the random variables X, I[X] and I2[X] are plotted against the confidence level β. On the one hand, it is seen that the percentiles of I[X] are equal to zero until β > α, increase in line with V ar β X for β [α, α 2 ] and then remain constant for β > α 2. The fact that the high percentiles of I[X] are bounded by V ar α2 X V ar α X explains the lowering of ES α I[X], since Expected Shortfall, as seen in equation 2., is calculated by integrating over high percentiles. On the other hand, constancy of the

12 2 percentiles of I 2[X] for β [α, α 2 ] produces capital efficiency for the second entity, by forcing V ar α2 I 2[X] = V ar α X. VaR bx VaR bi*[x] VaR bi*[x] 2 VaR X - a 2 VaR X a 2 VaR X a* VaR X a* a* a 2 b Figure 2.2. VaR allocations of I [X] and I 2[X] for various confidence levels β. When λ = λ 2, the solution is similar, but no more unique. The same tail risk X V arα2 X + is transferred to the second entity and a layer between V ar α X and V ar α2 X is retained by the first. However the allocation of losses lower than V ar α X between the two entities is now arbitrary. The case where λ < λ 2 is simpler. More risk is retained by the first entity, which has a lower cost of capital, while the only risk transferred to the second entity is the extreme tail risk X V ar α2 X +, which, as argued before, the V ar α 2 to reflect. measure fails 2.5. ES / ES setting. The last setting of the section assumes that both entities operate in markets subject to Expected Shortfall based capital requirements. Thus, the mathematical formulation of our problem is: min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] + λ 2 ES α2 I2 [X] λ ES α I2 [X]. 2.8 I,I 2 F The solution to this problem is provided below.

13 3 Theorem 2.3. Let C be a constant given by: Then, the optimal solution 2.8 is: C = λ 2 α 2 α 2 λ α α. i If V ar α X = V ar α2 X then X, λ > λ 2, C < 0 I2[X] = min { X, V ar α X }, λ > λ 2, C > 0, X V arα X +, λ < λ 2, C < 0, 0, λ < λ 2, C > 0, X V arα X + + min { f X, t }, λ = λ 2, C < 0, min { f 2 X, t 2 }, λ = λ 2, C > 0, where f and f 2 are non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous functions with unit constants such that f 0 = f 2 0 = 0, f V arα X = t, f 2 V arα X = t 2, with parameters t, t 2 [0, V ar α X]. ii If V ar α X < V ar α2 X then X, λ > λ 2, C < 0, I2[X] min { X, V ar α = X }, λ > λ 2, C > 0, 0, λ < λ 2, min { } f 3 X, t 3, λ = λ 2, where α λ = α, and f λ α +λ 2 α 3 is a non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous function with unit constant such that f 3 0 = 0, f 3 V arα X = t 3 [0, V ar α X]. iii If V ar α X > V ar α2 X then X, λ > λ 2, I2[X] = X V arα 2 X, λ + < λ 2, C < 0, 0, λ < λ 2, C > 0, where α 2 = λ 2 α 2 λ α 2 +λ 2 α 2. In addition, the λ = λ 2 case is solved by I 2[X] = X V ar α2 X + + min { f 4 X, t 4 },

14 4 where f 4 is a non-decreasing Lipschitz continuous function with unit constant such that f 4 0 = 0, f 4 V arα2 X = t 4 [0, V ar α2 X]. We shall not discuss all the different cases of Theorem 2.3. Indicatively let us first consider the case that α = α 2 which implies but is not implied by V ar α X = V ar α2 X. In this case, C < 0 λ > λ 2, and the optimal risk share of the second entity is I2[X] = X; unsurprisingly, when the risk measures for the two entities are the same, all the risk is transferred to the one with the lowest cost of capital. A similar situation arises when V ar α X > V ar α2 X, λ > λ 2 ie capital for the first entity is both more costly and subject to a stronger requirement. More interesting risk transfers arise when V ar α X > V ar α2 X, but λ < λ 2, such that the weakest capital requirement attracts a higher capital cost. Part iii of Theorem 2.3 shows that the second entity ends up with either an unlimited layer in excess of V ar α 2 X or nothing, depending on the value of the constant C, which reflects the tradeoff between capital costs and conservativeness of the risk measure. 3. The impact of credit risk on policyholder welfare 3.. Expected policyholder deficit. The analysis of Section 2 does not consider the impact of potential default on policyholder welfare. Given that the optimal risk transfers proposed so far typically involve the transfer of some extreme tail risk from on entity to another, it is necessary to consider whether the resulting saving in cost of capital is achieved at the detriment of policyholder safety. This is of course related to the potential discrepancy of risk measures used to regulate different entities. In particular, when tail risk is transferred from an ES α -regulated entity to another regulated by V ar α2, capital savings occur due to V ar s blindness to the magnitude of extreme losses, even though it is exactly these sort of losses that policyholders are exposed to in the case of insurer default. In this section, we quantify the impact of risk transfer on policyholder welfare by studying the resulting expected policyholder deficit, and comparing it to the case where all risk is retained by the first entity. The policyholder deficit is equal to the difference between nominal liabilities to policyholders and liabilities that will actually be paid, thus reflecting the reduction in the payoff received due to potential default. The policyholder deficit can also be seen as an asset transferred from policyholders to shareholders,

15 reflecting the option of the latter to default on their obligations Phillips et al 998; Myers and Read, 200. Formally, define the expected policyholder deficit for liability Z a random variable and available assets c a fixed number in the current setting where asset risk is not considered by EP DZ; c = E [ ] xf Z c + = P Z > zdz. 3. For the purposes of the present section we focus on the case where capital requirements for the first entity are given by ES α c and for the second are given by V ar α2 with V ar α X < V ar α2 X. Moreover, let us also assume that all risk X is initially held by the first entity which thus acts as a primary insurer and the second entity is a subsidiary whose sole business is to reinsure the first by providing a contingent payment X 2. Consequently, X is the risk retained by the first entity and X = X + X 2. Before the risk transfer, the expected policyholder deficit is given by EP D X; ES α X = E [ X ES α X + ]. 3.2 There are several ways to examine the impact of risk transfer on policyholder deficit. First, one may consider the two entities as separately regulated, the deficit arising from each being the concern of a different regulator. In this case, the expected policyholder deficit is equal to the sum of those arising from the different entities: EP DX ; ES α X + EP DX 2 ; V ar α2 X 2 = E [ X ES α X + ] + E [ X2 V ar α2 X 2 + ]. 3.3 However, equation 3.3 does not properly reflect the impact of credit risk arising from the risk transfer, since it does not reflect the direction of the risk transfer. If we assume, as we do in this section, that all risk is transferred from the first entity to the second, a default of the second entity has no necessary direct impact on the policyholders, who have bought their policies from the first. The default of the second entity only matters to policyholders to the extent that it is related to the scenario of the first entity primary insurer defaulting. Following these considerations, the risk exposure of the first entity, allowing for the possible default of its subsidiary and assuming no recoveries given default, is given by: X = X + X 2 V ar α2 X There are now two possibilities. The first is that the capital requirement applied to the first entity does not actually reflect the credit risk arising from the risk transfer. In 5

16 6 that case the capital held by the first entity is still ES α X, and the corresponding expected policyholder deficit is: EP D X ; ES α X [ ] = E X ES α X Such an approach would however be not be consistent with the spirit of current regulatory requirements, where risk concentrations within groups need to be closely monitored EIOPA, A second and more appropriate approach is to include all credit risk in the capital requirement, which will thus become ES α X. The resulting expected policyholder deficit is EP D X ; ES α X [ = E X ES α X ] Policyholder deficit arising from optimal risk transfers. We now compare the expected policyholder deficit amounts, as calculated by equations 3.2, 3.3, 3.5, and 3.6. For those calculations it is assumed that the shares X, X 2 of the aggregate risk X are given respectively by the optimal solutions I [X], I 2[X] of Corollary 2.. We need to distinguish between the cases λ > λ 2 and λ < λ 2, as they lead to different risk transfers. The case λ > λ 2. In this case the optimal risk allocations are given by: X = min{x V ar α X +, V ar α2 X V ar α X}, X 2 = min{x, V ar α X} + X V ar α2 X +, 3.7 where α λ = α and λ λ α +λ 2 α, λ 2 are such that α < α 2. The expected policyholder deficits are given in the following lemma. Lemma 3.. For X, X 2 as in 3.7 it is: i EP DX ; ES α X + EP DX 2 ; V ar α2 X 2 = V ar α X+ES α X F xdx. ii iii EP D X ; ES α X = V ar α X+ES α X EP D X ; ES α X = V ar α X+ES α X F xdx. F xdx.

17 7 where ES α X = V arα2 X α V ar α X In particular, F xdx and ES α X = α V ar α X F xdx. EP D X ; ES α X EP DX; ES α X. Moreover, if V ar α2 X ES α X, it also holds that EP DX ; ES α X +EP DX 2 ; V ar α2 X 2 = EP D X ; ES α X EP DX; ES α X. To interpret the result, note first that for the confidence levels used in the regulatory practice of insurance eg α = 0.99, α 2 = 0.995, the condition V ar α2 X ES α X is typically satisfied. So, besides giving formulas for expected policyholder deficits, Lemma 3., tells us two things. First, the expected policyholder deficit increases with the risk transfer, if credit risk is not properly accounted for in capital setting cases i and ii. Second, allowing for credit risk in the capital requirement of the first entity, increases its capital sufficiently so that the expected policyholder deficit is actually reduced in relation to the situation before the risk transfer. Of course, the risk transfer is not anymore optimal in relation to this stronger regulatory requirement, which is an issue that will be picked up in the next section. The case λ < λ 2. In this case the optimal risk allocations are given by: X = min{x, V ar α2 X}, X 2 = X V ar α2 X The expected policyholder deficits are given in the following lemma. Lemma 3.2. For X, X 2 as in 3.8 it is: i EP DX ; ES α X + EP DX 2 ; V ar α2 X 2 = ES α X F xdx. ii iii EP D X ; ES α X = ES α X EP D X ; ES α X = ES α X F xdx. F xdx.

18 8 where ES α X = V ar α X + V arα2 X α V ar α X F xdx. In particular, EP D X ; ES α X = EP D X; ES α X. and EP DX ; ES α X +EP DX 2 ; V ar α2 X 2 = EP D X ; ES α X EP DX; ES α X. Once more, the expected policyholder deficit increases with the risk transfer, if credit risk is not properly accounted for in capital setting cases i and ii. On the contrary, when allowing for credit risk in the capital requirement of the first entity, the expected policyholder deficit remains unchanged in relation to the situation before the risk transfer Optimal risk transfer when credit risk is reflected in the capital requirement. In the previous section it was seen that reflecting credit risk in the capital requirement of the first entity, which acts as a primary insurer, leads to an expected policyholder deficit that is not higher than the one before the risk transfer. However, changing the capital setting criterion means that the risk transfers discussed above will no longer be optimal and so would not necessarily be chosen by the group. To address this issue, we derive optimal risk transfers, when the first entity incorporates the counter-party reinsurance default risk in its capital requirement. Slightly generalizing the arguments of the previous section, let us denote by γ the recovery rate, that this, the percentage of the exposure to the second entity that will be recovered in the case of default. Given that the only business of the second entity is to reinsure the first, and that in our setting the assets available to pay for reinsurance claims will mainly consist of regulatory requirements on the second entity, it is reasonable to assume that γ is close to. The mathematical formulation of the related problem is as follows. The risk to the first entity, including credit risk, now is g [X; γ] := I [X] + γ I 2 [X] I 2 V arα2 X +, and the corresponding optimisation problem can be written as min I,I 2 F E g [X; γ]+i 2 [X] +λ ESα g [X; γ] Eg [X; γ] +λ 2 V arα2 I 2 [X] EI 2 [X], 3.9

19 9 The solution to this problem is now given below. Theorem 3.. Denote γ = λ 2 + λ α / α + λ α / α, and let α be as in Corollary 2.. Furthermore, assume that V ar α X V ar α2 X. The optimal solutions of 3.9 are then given by: i If λ > λ 2, then I 2[X] = { X V arα2 X + + min { X, V ar α X}, 0 γ < γ, min { X, V ar α X }, γ < γ. ii If λ < λ 2, then X V ar I2[X] α2 X, 0 γ < γ, = + 0, γ < γ In each case it is I[X] = X I2[X]. It can be seen that the value of γ is crucial for the incentives produced. For a small value γ < γ, the optimal risk transfers are the same as in Corollary 2.. On the other hand, for γ > γ, reflecting a lower recovery given default, the optimal risk transfer changes substantially, in that tail risk is no more transferred from the first ES α - regulated to the second V ar α2 -regulated entity. We would argue that the case γ > γ is actually the more realistic one. For example, when λ = 0.0, λ 2 = 0.5, α = 0.99, it follows that γ = 0.922, while γ should be very close to. This disincentive for transferring tail risk also ensures that the optimal risk transfer will not lead to increases in policyholder deficit, as will be shown in the numerical example that follows. However, the importance of producing disincentives for tail risk transfer to an entity subject to a weaker eg V ar-based regulatory requirement go substantially beyond the consideration of formal welfare measures such as policyholder deficit. In particular, given the uncertainties and sensitivities involved in quantifying extreme risk, it may be argued that tail risk transfers are also associated with transfers of operational and model risks, which are now avoided Numerical example. We consider separately the cases λ > λ 2 and λ < λ 2. In each case we assume that α = 0.99, α 2 = 0.995, γ =, and that the total risk X follows a Log-Normal distribution with mean of 000 and standard deviation of 200. For each case, we consider 4 scenarios:

20 20 No Transfer: No risk is transferred, such that all risk is retained by the first entity. Transfer no CR: A risk transfer as in Corollary 2. takes place, and the capital requirements do not account for credit risk as in case ii of Lemmas 3. and 3.2. Transfer CR: A risk transfer as in Corollary 2. takes place, and the capital requirements do account for credit risk as in case iii of Lemmas 3. and 3.2. Transfer 2 CR: A risk transfer as in Theorem 3. takes place, such that capital requirements do account for credit risk. For each scenario, the following quantities are being calculated: Total Capital: The total capital held by the group. Value-EX: The risk adjusted value of the liabilities, in excess of EX. In scenarios No Transfer and Transfer no CR this is just the cost of capital; in scenarios Transfer CR and Transfer 2 CR one has to add the baddebt reserve Eg [X; ] I [X] to the cost of capital. EPD: The expected policyholder deficit. Case : 0.4 = λ > λ 2 = 0.. The results for this case are summarized in Table below. Table : Capital, risk adjusted value, and expected policyholder deficit for different risk transfer scenarios 0.4 = λ > λ 2 = 0.. Scenario Total Capital Value-EX EPD No Transfer Transfer no CR Transfer CR Transfer 2 CR The example shows that when moving optimally from the No Transfer to the Transfer no CR scenario, a substantial saving in capital and its cost is observed. However, the price of this is a big increase in expected policyholder deficit, arising from the transfer of the tail risk min{ X V ar a X, V ar + a 2 X V ar a X} to the more weakly regulated second entity. This anomaly is rectified once the capital requirement of the first entity is adjusted for credit risk scenario Transfer CR, with the expected policyholder deficit returning to a value below its original level. In relation to

21 the situation before the risk transfer, the total capital now somewhat increases from 666 to 67; however there is still a notable reduction in the risk adjusted value from 93.2 to 70.7 exploiting the lower cost of capital that the second entity is subject to. Finally, the scenario Transfer 2 CR, where risk is transferred optimally given that credit risk is included in the capital calculation, produces no further change apart from a very marginal reduction of risk adjusted value. 2 Case 2: 0. = λ < λ 2 = 0.4. The results for this case are summarized in Table 2 below. Table 2: Capital, risk adjusted value, and expected policyholder deficit for different risk transfer scenarios 0. = λ < λ 2 = 0.4. Scenario Total Capital Value-EX EPD No Transfer Transfer no CR Transfer CR Transfer 2 CR As before, the example shows that when moving from the No Transfer to the Transfer no CR scenario, a substantial saving in capital and its cost is observed. This is again at the expense of an increase in expected policyholder deficit, arising from the transfer of the tail risk X V ar a2 X to the more weakly regulated second + entity. This anomaly is rectified once the capital requirement of the first entity is adjusted for credit risk scenario Transfer CR, with the expected policyholder deficit and total capital returning to its original level 666 and only a marginal increase in the risk adjusted value from 66.6 to 67. Finally, under scenario Transfer 2 CR, we return exactly to the situation before the risk transfer. This arises from observing from Theorem 3. that I 2 [X] = Revisiting two assumptions. Two key assumptions in this paper, co-monotonicity of risk allocations and non-impact of risk transfer on insurance prices, are now discussed Co-monotone risk allocations. In the optimization problems solved in previous sections, it has always been assumed that the allocations of total risk to entities I [X] and I 2 [X] are co-monotonic, i.e. non-decreasing functions of the total risk X. In the framework of Section 3, where the second entity acts as a subsidiary with sole

22 22 business to reinsure the first, this assumption is fairly unproblematic, given the typical increasingness of reinsurance contracts. However, if it is assumed that each entity has a non-negative risk exposure before the risk transfer as may be the case in the results of Section 2, it is not obvious why the risk transfer should be structured such that the resulting risk allocations are co-monotone. Essentially, it is assumed that all risk is first pooled and then shared by the two entities. The reason behind making such a strong assumption is quite practical. In this paper we derive the forms of risk transfers that are optimal from the point of view of the group, rather than postulating a particular reasonable form for the contracts and then optimizing other quantities e.g. Schlütter and Gründl 20. As a consequence certain limitations on admissible risk transfers need to be placed in order to avoid situations where moral hazard / regulatory arbitrage appear in blatant form. This can be explained in the following example. Let the risk measures used be ES α, V ar α2. A particular form of admissible risk transfer arising for example in Corollary 2. when λ < λ 2 is one resulting into risk allocations X = min{x, V ar α2 X}, X 2 = X V ar α2 X +. In that case, the transfer of tail risk to the second V ar α2 - regulated entity ensures that V ar α2 X 2 = 0, which as long as credit risk is not allowed for generates capital efficiency at the expense of policyholder welfare see Lemma 3.2. Consider now an alternative risk transfer of the form: { X, if X V arα2 X ˆX = X {X V arα2 X} = 0, otherwise, { X, if X > V arα2 X ˆX 2 = X {X>V arα2 X} = 0, otherwise, where A is the indicator function of event A. The random variables ˆX, ˆX2 are not comonotone, as ˆX can decrease in X. Compared to the previous risk allocation, we can write ˆX = X V ar α2 X {X>V arα2 X} and ˆX 2 = X 2 + V ar α2 X {X>V arα2 X}, such that the liability V ar α2 X {X>V arα2 X} is shifted from the first entity to the second. As a result it will be ES α ˆX ES α X. However, note that it will still be V ar α2 ˆX 2 = V ar α2 X 2 = 0. Hence, in the absence of a capital requirement in respect to credit risk, the capital available is now substantially reduced, leading to a further increase in policyholder deficit.

23 The implications for risk management of allowing such risk transfers are more wideranging. The non-increasingness of the risk transfer ˆX, ˆX2 creates moral hazard problems in the sense that the management of the first entity may have an incentive to preside over a high group loss {X > V ar α2 X}, leading to payment of { ˆX = 0}, rather than a lower group loss {X V ar α2 X}, leading to payment of { ˆX = X} Impact of policyholder deficit on insurance prices. Throughout this paper, a key idea has been that the insurance group seeks to perform risk transfers in order to minimize the risk adjusted value of its liabilities. This is sensible, as long as we assume that such risk transfers have no negative impact on the group s profitability. This is a potentially contentious assumption and we would like to justify it at this stage. If a risk transfer takes place that damages policyholder welfare, then, economic arguments suggest that the market consistent value of the insurance policies sold will reduce by the market consistent value of the resulting increase in policyholder deficit. If this reduction in the value of the pay-off is reflected in market insurance premiums a strong assumption for some markets like personal lines insurance, the result is a reduction in profitability, which may outweigh the benefits of capital savings arising from the risk transfer. While this is a plausible scenario, we do not consider it of great relevance to our setting, particularly in view of the numerical example presented above. First, we note that changes in the expected policyholder deficit reflecting the reduction in policyholders expected pay-offs are an order of magnitude smaller than changes in the cost of capital. The changes in the value of the policyholder deficit would be increased if valued under a risk neutral measure as in Myers and Read 200 and Schlütter and Gründl 20 among others, however the upwards adjustment to the expected policyholder deficit would have to be very substantial in order for this to make any difference. Furthermore, it can be seen that optimal risk transfers, once credit risk is properly accounted for, do not actually lead to increases in policyholder deficit. Hence, there is no reason that a corresponding reduction in profit should be observed. In conclusion, and in the light of the incentives produced by Theorem 3., it seems that regulatory action, rather than market forces, is the most powerful mechanism to discourage risk transfers that damage policyholder welfare.

24 24 4. Conclusion This paper contributes to the literature on insurance groups, by discussing the implications of intra-group risk transfers for capital efficiency and policyholder welfare, and to the literature on insurance contract design, by deriving optimal risk transfers under preferences driven by risk measures. We find that optimal risk transfers under a cost-of-capital valuation criterion involve the transfer of extreme loss layers to the entity subject to a weaker regulatory regime. In particular, the discrepancy between the Value-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall measures may be exploited, with tail risk transferred to a VaR-regulated entity. Regulators should be wary of such incentives emerging. We show that, if the credit risk arising from risk transfers is not fully reflected in capital requirements, group capital efficiency is achieved at the cost of compromising policyholder security. If credit risk is fully reflected in the capital requirements, this problem does not emerge. Hence, it is crucial that regulators address the issue of intra-group credit risk when specifying quantitative requirements. Specifically, when an insurer transfers extreme risk to a subsidiary belonging to the same group, the high dependence between the insurer s gross loss and the subsidiary s default event, as well as the low recovery rate, need to be taken into account in the calculation of capital requirements. The following notations, Appendix A. Proofs A = { ξ, ξ 2 : 0 ξ V ar α X, 0 ξ 2 ξ V ar α2 X V ar α X } and A 2 = { ξ, ξ 2 : 0 ξ 2 V ar α2 X, 0 ξ ξ 2 V ar α X V ar α2 X } are useful for explaining all the proofs. In addition, PrZ z < α if and only if z < V ar α X represents a key property that is further used in our derivations. A.. proof of Theorem 2.. The details of the proof are heavily dependent on the order between benchmark risks, and therefore three cases are analyzed in the following order: V ar α X = V ar α2 X, V ar α X < V ar α2 X and V ar α X > V ar α2 X.

25 The derivations are based on geometric argumentations and we only focus on the first two cases, while the third case is briefly discussed. Note that E I 2 [X] = 0 V ar s I2 [X] ds = 0 I 2 V ars X ds. We first assume that V ar α X = V ar α2 X and the first step is to solve the following optimisation problem: min λ λ 2 E I2 [X] subject to I,I 2 F I 2 V arα X = ξ, 25 A. which reduces our problem to minimising and maximisation the function I 2 such that I 2 0 = 0 and I 2 V arα X = ξ provided that λ λ 2 > 0 and λ λ 2 < 0, respectively. Note that 0 ξ V ar α X is a constant. Let us assume first that λ > λ 2. Therefore, the second insurer loss share is 0 on [0, x ], where 0 x V ar α X, and then increases as fast as possible on [x, V ar α X]. The Lipschitz property does not allow the right and left derivatives at any point to be greater than. Consequently, the function I 2 increases linearly with slope on [x, V ar α X] and x = V ar α X ξ. Same reasoning can be used to justify that I 2 remains flat on [V ar α X, x F ]. Figure A.. All these facts are pictured in I*[X,x] 2 x VaR X -x a VaR X a X Figure A.. The construction of I 2[X; ξ] in Theorem 2..

26 26 Thus, the optimal arrangement in A. becomes { X I2[X; ξ] = min V arαx + ξ }, ξ. A.2 + The latter allows one to find the global solution of 2.5, which is obtained by minimising E I 2[X; ξ] ξ = = V arα X V ar α X ξ V arα X V ar α X ξ x V ar α X + ξ df x + ξ F V ar α X ξ F x dx ξ over all possible values of ξ [ 0, V ar α X ]. Note that the latter is a simple consequence of integration by parts. By differentiation of the above, it can be concluded that the function is non-increasing in ξ and therefore the minimum is attained at ξ = V ar α X, which concludes the λ > λ 2 case. Similarly, λ < λ 2 implies that I 2 should increase rapidly until reaches the value ξ and then remains constant until attains the point V ar α X, while increases as much as possible on [V ar α X, x F ]. Again, the Lipschitz property makes the optimal solution of A. to as given in Figure A.2. I*[X,x] 22 x x VaR X a X Figure A.2. The construction of I 22[X; ξ] in Theorem 2.. Thus, I 22[X; ξ] = min{x, ξ} + X V ar α X +.

27 27 Therefore, the global solution of 2.5 is reduced to maximizing on ξ [ 0, V ar α X ] of E I 22[X; ξ] ξ = = ξ 0 x df x + ξ F ξ F V ar α X + V ar α X ξ 0 F x dx + x V ar α X + ξ df x ξ V ar α X where the later is generated via integration by parts. F x dx ξ, The derivative of the above function is F ξ, which is always non-positive. Thus, the maximal value is attained at ξ = 0, which completes the first part of our proof. The second part is now investigated. Our optimisation problem defined by 2.5 is solved via a two-stage procedure. We first minimise min λ λ 2 E I 2 [X] subject to I,I 2 F I 2 V arα X = ξ, I 2 V arα2 X = ξ 2 A.3 where ξ, ξ 2 A are some constants. The I 2 function should be minimised at any point on the whole domain whenever λ > λ 2, but keeping in mind that we also need I 2 0 = 0, I 2 V arα X = ξ and I 2 V arα2 X = ξ 2. Thus, similar arguments as provided earlier, lead to an optimal risk transfer contract as given in Figure A.3. I*[X; ] 23 x,x 2 x 2 x VaR a X -x VaR X VaR X +x-x a VaR X a 2 2 a X 2 Figure A.3. The construction of I 23[X; ξ, ξ 2 ] in Theorem 2..

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Modern Risk Management of Insurance Firms Hannover, January 23, 2014 1 The

More information

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what?

Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Expected Shortfall is not elicitable so what? Dirk Tasche Bank of England Prudential Regulation Authority 1 dirk.tasche@gmx.net Finance & Stochastics seminar Imperial College, November 20, 2013 1 The opinions

More information

Multi Level Risk Aggregation

Multi Level Risk Aggregation Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 6 Multi Level Risk Aggregation Damir Filipović First version: February 2008 Current version: April 2009 Multi-Level Risk Aggregation Damir Filipović Vienna Institute

More information

Disclosures - IFFCO TOKIO General Insurance Co. Ltd. for the period 1st April, st December, 2018 S.No. Form No Description

Disclosures - IFFCO TOKIO General Insurance Co. Ltd. for the period 1st April, st December, 2018 S.No. Form No Description Disclosures - IFFCO TOKIO General Insurance Co. Ltd. for the period 1st April, 2018-31st December, 2018 S.No. Form No Description 1 NL-1-B-RA Revenue Account 2 NL-2-B-PL Profit & Loss Account 3 NL-3-B-BS

More information

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6 1 A Two-Period Example Suppose the economy lasts only two periods, t =0, 1. The uncertainty arises in the income (wage) of period 1. Not that

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.G.06 19 January 2015 Moral Hazard: Consider the contractual relationship between two agents (a principal and an agent) The principal

More information

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model Paul Pichler and Gerhard Sorger This Version: February 2006 Abstract We study the Ramsey (1928) model under the assumption that households act strategically.

More information

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Introduction Extreme Scenarios Asymptotic Behavior Challenges Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo, Canada Seminar at ETH Zurich

More information

A New Class of Non Existence Examples for the Moral Hazard Problem

A New Class of Non Existence Examples for the Moral Hazard Problem A New Class of Non Existence Examples for the Moral Hazard Problem Sofia Moroni and Jeroen Swinkels April, 23 Abstract We provide a class of counter-examples to existence in a simple moral hazard problem

More information

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market 1/51 Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market Ruodu Wang http://sas.uwaterloo.ca/ wang Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science University of Waterloo

More information

An Axiomatic Approach To Systemic Risk

An Axiomatic Approach To Systemic Risk An Axiomatic Approach To Systemic Risk Chen Chen Industrial Engineering and Operations Research Columbia University email: cc3136@columbia.edu Garud Iyengar Industrial Engineering and Operations Research

More information

MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS

MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS EDWARD FURMAN Department of Mathematics and Statistics York University Toronto, Ontario M3J 1P3, Canada EMail: efurman@mathstat.yorku.ca

More information

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015 ANSWER KEY University of California, Davis Date: June, 05 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomic Theory Reading Time: 0 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer four

More information

Weather Derivatives-Pricing and Design Issue in India

Weather Derivatives-Pricing and Design Issue in India Weather Derivatives-Pricing and Design Issue in India By Anshul Anand & Surendra Mahadik Introduction: In the last decades, agricultural policies of certain countries focused on adopting and strengthening

More information

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION Jan Werner European University Institute May 2010 1 I. Price Bubbles: An Example Example I.1 Time is infinite; so dates are t = 0,1,2,...,.

More information

Weak* Axiom of Independence and the Non-Expected Utility Theory

Weak* Axiom of Independence and the Non-Expected Utility Theory Review of Economic Analysis 4 (01) 67-75 1973-3909/01067 Weak* Axiom of Independence and the Non-Expected Utility Theory TAPAN BISWAS University of Hull 1 Introduction The axiomatic foundation of the expected

More information

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. On the impossibility of fair risk allocation. by Péter Csóka Miklós Pintér CEWP 12/2014

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. On the impossibility of fair risk allocation. by Péter Csóka Miklós Pintér CEWP 12/2014 CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS CEWP 12/2014 On the impossibility of fair risk allocation by Péter Csóka Miklós Pintér http://unipub.lib.uni-corvinus.hu/1658 On the impossibility of fair risk allocation

More information

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks University of Wisconsin Milwaukee UWM Digital Commons Theses and Dissertations May 2014 Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks Evelyn Susanne Gaus University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee Follow

More information

Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market. Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère

Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market. Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère Computing risk averse equilibrium in incomplete market Henri Gerard Andy Philpott, Vincent Leclère YEQT XI: Winterschool on Energy Systems Netherlands, December, 2017 CERMICS - EPOC 1/43 Uncertainty on

More information

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I Fundamentals in Optimal Investments Lecture I + 1 Portfolio choice Portfolio allocations and their ordering Performance indices Fundamentals in optimal portfolio choice Expected utility theory and its

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago January 2016 Consider a situation where one person, call him Sender,

More information

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure

A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure A Note on the Swiss Solvency Test Risk Measure Damir Filipović and Nicolas Vogelpoth Vienna Institute of Finance Nordbergstrasse 15 A-1090 Vienna, Austria first version: 16 August 2006, this version: 16

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago December 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) represent random

More information

How to Measure Interconnectedness between Banks, Insurers and Financial Conglomerates?

How to Measure Interconnectedness between Banks, Insurers and Financial Conglomerates? How to Measure Interconnectedness between Banks, Insurers and Financial Conglomerates? G. Hauton 1 JC. Héam 2 1 ACPR 2 ACPR, CREST 3 rd EBA Policy Research Workshop, November 2014, London. The views expressed

More information

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply. Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series. Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply. Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale Columbia University Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply Yeon-Koo Che Ian Gale Discussion Paper No.: 0506-15 Department of Economics Columbia University New

More information

MACRO-PRUDENTIAL RULES AND REGULATION (2015): DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS ANNEXURE I: FORMAT FOR ANNUAL DISCLOSURES DRUK PNB BANK LTD.

MACRO-PRUDENTIAL RULES AND REGULATION (2015): DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS ANNEXURE I: FORMAT FOR ANNUAL DISCLOSURES DRUK PNB BANK LTD. MACRO-PRUDENTIAL RULES AND REGULATION (2015): DISCLOSURE REQUIREMENTS ANNEXURE I: FORMAT FOR ANNUAL DISCLOSURES DRUK PNB BANK LTD. For the Year ended December 31, 2016 Item 1: Tier I Capital and its Sub-components

More information

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics Hawkes Seminar May 23, 2018 1 / 46 Some Problems in Insurance and Reinsurance Mohamed Badaoui Department of Electrical Engineering National

More information

Circling the Square: Experiments in Regression

Circling the Square: Experiments in Regression Circling the Square: Experiments in Regression R. D. Coleman [unaffiliated] This document is excerpted from the research paper entitled Critique of Asset Pricing Circularity by Robert D. Coleman dated

More information

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Ris Christopher S. Tang S. Alex Yang Jing Wu Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. In a centralized chain, the system

More information

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers Lecture 3. Calculaus in Deterministic and Stochastic Environments Steve Yang Stevens Institute of Technology 01/31/2012 Outline 1 Modeling Random Behavior

More information

Acknowledgment of Aramco Asia. Supplier Code of Conduct

Acknowledgment of Aramco Asia. Supplier Code of Conduct Acknowledgment of Aramco Asia Supplier Code of Conduct (Applicable to Vendors, Manufacturers, and Contractors) Aramco Asia is committed to the highest ethical and legal standards in the conduct of its

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Contracts under Asymmetric Information Contracts under Asymmetric Information 1 I Aristotle, economy (oiko and nemo) and the idea of exchange values, subsequently adapted by Ricardo and Marx. Classical economists. An economy consists of a set

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Claims Reserving under Solvency II

Claims Reserving under Solvency II Claims Reserving under Solvency II Mario V. Wüthrich RiskLab, ETH Zurich Swiss Finance Institute Professor joint work with Michael Merz (University of Hamburg) April 21, 2016 European Congress of Actuaries,

More information

Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures

Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures Regulatory Arbitrage of Risk Measures Ruodu Wang November 29, 2015 Abstract We introduce regulatory arbitrage of risk measures as one of the key considerations in choosing a suitable risk measure to use

More information

COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY

COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY COHERENT APPROACHES TO RISK IN OPTIMIZATION UNDER UNCERTAINTY Terry Rockafellar University of Washington, Seattle University of Florida, Gainesville Goal: a coordinated view of recent ideas in risk modeling

More information

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015 & & MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation February 4, 2015 & Meucci s Program for Asset Allocation detect market invariance select the invariants estimate the market specify the distribution

More information

Filling in the Blanks: Network Structure and Systemic Risk

Filling in the Blanks: Network Structure and Systemic Risk Filling in the Blanks: Network Structure and Systemic Risk Kartik Anand, Bank of Canada Ben Craig, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland & Deutsche Bundesbank Goetz von Peter, Bank for International Settlements

More information

120 CHAPTER 1. RATES OF CHANGE AND THE DERIVATIVE. Figure 1.30: The graph of g(x) =x 2/3.

120 CHAPTER 1. RATES OF CHANGE AND THE DERIVATIVE. Figure 1.30: The graph of g(x) =x 2/3. 120 CHAPTER 1. RATES OF CHANGE AND THE DERIVATIVE Figure 1.30: The graph of g(x) =x 2/3. We shall return to local extrema and monotonic functions, and look at them in more depth in Section 3.2. 1.5.1 Exercises

More information

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}.

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}. So far in this course we have used several different mathematical expressions to quantify risk, without a deeper discussion of their properties. Coherent Risk Measures Lecture 11, Optimisation in Finance

More information

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation Ismail Saglam Ipek University 4 May 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/71090/

More information

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS THIRD EDITION STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS Eugene Silberberg University of Washington Wing Suen University of Hong Kong I Us Irwin McGraw-Hill Boston Burr Ridge, IL Dubuque, IA Madison,

More information

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3) Tsun-Feng Chiang* *School of Economics, Henan University, Kaifeng, China November 22, 2015 First Last (shortinst) Short title November 22, 2015 1

More information

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College 2015 Course Overview 1. Bargaining 2. Hidden information and self-selection Optimal contracting with hidden information

More information

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General Equilibrium and Welfare and Welfare Lectures 2 and 3, ECON 4240 Spring 2017 University of Oslo 24.01.2017 and 31.01.2017 1/37 Outline General equilibrium: look at many markets at the same time. Here all prices determined in the

More information

Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy

Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy Shahar Dobzinski Department of Computer Science Cornell Unversity shahar@cs.cornell.edu Robert Kleinberg Department of Computer Science Cornell Unversity

More information

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Risk Measures under Solvency II Dietmar Pfeifer (2004) Risk measures and premium principles a comparison VaR vs. Expected Shortfall Dependence and its implications for risk measures

More information

Annexes to the Technical Specification for Preparatory Phase. (Part I)

Annexes to the Technical Specification for Preparatory Phase. (Part I) Disclaimer Following the publication of the Commission s Delegated Act containing implementing rules for Solvency II and the publication of EIOPA s Guidelines on Pillar I, reference should be made to the

More information

Mechanism Design II. Terence Johnson. University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design II 1 / 30

Mechanism Design II. Terence Johnson. University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design II 1 / 30 Mechanism Design II Terence Johnson University of Notre Dame Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design II 1 / 30 Mechanism Design Recall: game theory takes the players/actions/payoffs as given, and makes predictions

More information

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective Alex Possajennikov University of Nottingham January 2012 Abstract Suppose that in aggregative games, in which a player s payoff

More information

A Merchant Mechanism for Electricity Transmission Expansion

A Merchant Mechanism for Electricity Transmission Expansion A Merchant Mechanism for Electricity Transmission Expansion Tarjei Kristiansen, Norwegian University of Science and Technology. Tarjei.Kristiansen@elkraft.ntnu.no Juan Rosellon, Harvard University/CIDE.

More information

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 18, 2015

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 18, 2015 MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation February 18, 2015 No introduction to portfolio optimization would be complete without acknowledging the significant contribution of the Markowitz mean-variance

More information

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Teoria das organizações e contratos Teoria das organizações e contratos Chapter 6: Adverse Selection with two types Mestrado Profissional em Economia 3 o trimestre 2015 EESP (FGV) Teoria das organizações e contratos 3 o trimestre 2015 1

More information

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS This exam is take-home, open-book, open-notes. You may consult any published source (cite

More information

X

X Correlation: Pitfalls and Alternatives Paul Embrechts, Alexander McNeil & Daniel Straumann Departement Mathematik, ETH Zentrum, CH-8092 Zürich Tel: +41 1 632 61 62, Fax: +41 1 632 15 23 embrechts/mcneil/strauman@math.ethz.ch

More information

University of California Berkeley

University of California Berkeley Working Paper #2018-02 Infinite Horizon CCAPM with Stochastic Taxation and Monetary Policy Revised from the Center for Risk Management Research Working Paper 2018-01 Konstantin Magin, University of California,

More information

DELAWARE COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU, INC. Internal Rate Of Return Model

DELAWARE COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU, INC. Internal Rate Of Return Model Exhibit 9 As Filed DELAWARE COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU, INC. Internal Rate Of Return Model The attached pages present exhibits and a description of the internal rate of return model used in deriving the

More information

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620 May 16, 2006 Philip Bond 1 Are cheap talk and hard evidence both needed in the courtroom? Abstract: In a recent paper, Bull and Watson (2004) present a formal model of verifiability in which cheap messages

More information

Sharing a Polluted River

Sharing a Polluted River Sharing a Polluted River Debing Ni School of Management University of Electronic Science and Technology of China Chengdu, Sichuan, P.R. China, 610054 Yuntong Wang Department of Economics University of

More information

Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport

Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport Daniel Hörcher 1, Woubit Seifu 2, Bruno De Borger 2, and Daniel J. Graham 1 1 Imperial College London. South Kensington Campus,

More information

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S. In the Name of God Sharif University of Technology Graduate School of Management and Economics Microeconomics 1 44715 (1396-97 1 st term) - Group 1 Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi Chapter 10: Competitive Markets

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

ARBITRAGE AND GROWTH RATE FOR RISKLESS INVESTMENTS IN A STATIONARY ECONOMY

ARBITRAGE AND GROWTH RATE FOR RISKLESS INVESTMENTS IN A STATIONARY ECONOMY Mathematical Finance, Vol. 7, No. 1 (January 1997), 73 81 ARBITRAGE AND GROWTH RATE FOR RISKLESS INVESTMENTS IN A STATIONARY ECONOMY ILAN ADLER IEOR Department, University of California, Berkeley, CA DAVID

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? APPENIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? Santanu Chatterjee epartment of Economics Terry College of Business University of eorgia Appendix A The appendix describes the optimization problem

More information

The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach

The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach Marcello Galeotti 1, Emanuele Vannucci 2 1 University of Florence, marcello.galeotti@dmd.unifi.it 2 University of Pisa,

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

Probabilities & Statistics Revision

Probabilities & Statistics Revision Probabilities & Statistics Revision Christopher Ting Christopher Ting http://www.mysmu.edu/faculty/christophert/ : christopherting@smu.edu.sg : 6828 0364 : LKCSB 5036 January 6, 2017 Christopher Ting QF

More information

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures Nonlife Actuarial Models Chapter 4 Risk Measures Learning Objectives 1. Risk measures based on premium principles 2. Risk measures based on capital requirements 3. Value-at-Risk and conditional tail expectation

More information

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion

A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion A Rothschild-Stiglitz approach to Bayesian persuasion Matthew Gentzkow and Emir Kamenica Stanford University and University of Chicago September 2015 Abstract Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) introduce a

More information

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk

Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Spectral Measures of Uncertain Risk Jin Peng, Shengguo Li Institute of Uncertain Systems, Huanggang Normal University, Hubei 438, China Email: pengjin1@tsinghua.org.cn lisg@hgnu.edu.cn Abstract: A key

More information

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is.

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is. Problem 1: Choice models and assortment optimization Consider a MNL choice model over five products with prices (p1,..., p5) = (7, 6, 4, 3, 2) and preference weights (i.e., MNL parameters) (v1,..., v5)

More information

EXPERIENCE-BASED LONGEVITY ASSESSMENT

EXPERIENCE-BASED LONGEVITY ASSESSMENT EXPERIENCE-BASED LONGEVITY ASSESSMENT ERMANNO PITACCO Università di Trieste ermanno.pitacco@econ.units.it p. 1/55 Agenda Introduction Stochastic modeling: the process risk Uncertainty in future mortality

More information

Matching with Contracts: The Critical Role of Irrelevance of Rejected Contracts

Matching with Contracts: The Critical Role of Irrelevance of Rejected Contracts Matching with Contracts: The Critical Role of Irrelevance of Rejected Contracts Orhan Aygün and Tayfun Sönmez May 2012 Abstract We show that an ambiguity in setting the primitives of the matching with

More information

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model

Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Calculating credit risk capital charges with the one-factor model Susanne Emmer Dirk Tasche September 15, 2003 Abstract Even in the simple Vasicek one-factor credit portfolio model, the exact contributions

More information

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures

An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures An axiomatic characterization of capital allocations of coherent risk measures Michael Kalkbrener Deutsche Bank AG Abstract An axiomatic definition of coherent capital allocations is given. It is shown

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency Sjur Didrik Flåm University of Bergen, Norway Background Customary Nash equilibrium has no coupling constraints. Here: coupling constraints

More information

Rebate Report. $15,990,000 Public Finance Authority Charter School Revenue Bonds (Voyager Foundation, Inc. Project) Series 2012A

Rebate Report. $15,990,000 Public Finance Authority Charter School Revenue Bonds (Voyager Foundation, Inc. Project) Series 2012A Rebate Report $15,990,000 Delivery Date: October 9, 2012 Installment Computation Period Ending Date: October 8, 2017 The Bank of New York Mellon Trust Company, N.A. Corporate Trust 5050 Poplar Avenue,

More information

Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance

Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance Distortion Risk Measures: Coherence and Stochastic Dominance Dr. Julia L. Wirch Dr. Mary R. Hardy Dept. of Actuarial Maths Dept. of Statistics and and Statistics Actuarial Science Heriot-Watt University

More information

An Introduction to Moral Hazard in Continuous Time

An Introduction to Moral Hazard in Continuous Time An Introduction to Moral Hazard in Continuous Time Columbia University, NY Chairs Days: Insurance, Actuarial Science, Data and Models, June 12th, 2018 Outline 1 2 Intuition and verification 2BSDEs 3 Control

More information

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost. Opportunity Cost (or "Wow, I coulda had a V8!") The underlying idea is derived

More information

PENNSYLVANIA COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU F CLASS FILING INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN MODEL

PENNSYLVANIA COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU F CLASS FILING INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN MODEL F Class Exhibit 4 Proposed 10/1/16 PENNSYLVANIA COMPENSATION RATING BUREAU F CLASS FILING INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN MODEL The attached pages present exhibits and a description of the internal rate of return

More information

Quantitative Modeling of Operational Risk: Between g-and-h and EVT

Quantitative Modeling of Operational Risk: Between g-and-h and EVT : Between g-and-h and EVT Paul Embrechts Matthias Degen Dominik Lambrigger ETH Zurich (www.math.ethz.ch/ embrechts) Outline Basel II LDA g-and-h Aggregation Conclusion and References What is Basel II?

More information

Worst-Case Optimal Redistribution of VCG Payments in Multi-Unit Auctions

Worst-Case Optimal Redistribution of VCG Payments in Multi-Unit Auctions Worst-Case Optimal Redistribution of VCG Payments in Multi-Unit Auctions Mingyu Guo Duke University Dept. of Computer Science Durham, NC, USA mingyu@cs.duke.edu Vincent Conitzer Duke University Dept. of

More information

FINANCIAL STATEMENTS OF THE COMPANY

FINANCIAL STATEMENTS OF THE COMPANY FINANCIAL STATEMENTS OF THE COMPANY getback Spółka Akcyjna for the period between 01.01.2014 and 31.12.2014 which include: 1. INTRODUCTION TO THE FINANCIAL STATEMENTS 2. BALANCE SHEET 3. PROFIT AND LOSS

More information

One way to deal with the unpredictable costs of winter weather. By Shane Belvin

One way to deal with the unpredictable costs of winter weather. By Shane Belvin One way to deal with the unpredictable costs of winter weather. By Shane Belvin 32 INTERNATIONAL PARKING INSTITUTE SEPTEMBER 2016 Believe it or not, snow and ice are right around the corner. The volatility

More information

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: The value of information and the value of awareness. Author: John Quiggin. Working Paper: R13_2

RSMG Working Paper Series. TITLE: The value of information and the value of awareness. Author: John Quiggin. Working Paper: R13_2 2013 TITLE: The value of information and the value of awareness 2011 RSMG Working Paper Series Risk and Uncertainty Program Author: John Quiggin Working Paper: R13_2 Schools of Economics and Political

More information

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness On-Line Appendix Jérôme Dugast Thierry Foucault August 30, 07 This note is the on-line appendix for Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. It contains

More information

The Standard Market Risk Model of the Swiss Solvency Test: an Analytical Solution

The Standard Market Risk Model of the Swiss Solvency Test: an Analytical Solution The Standard Market Risk Model of the Swiss Solvency Test: an Analytical Solution Working Paper Series 013-11 01) SolvencyAnalytics.com November 013 The Standard Market Risk Model of the Swiss Solvency

More information

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206) Theory Field Exam Summer 2011 Instructions You must complete two of the four areas (the areas being (I) contract theory, (II) game theory A, (III) game theory B, and (IV) psychology & economics). Be sure

More information

Evaluation Method on Geological Deposit Potential Value

Evaluation Method on Geological Deposit Potential Value Evaluation Method on Geological Deposit Potential Value Zhihong Zhang & Wei Huang School of Accounting, Shandong Economic University, Jinan 250014, Shandong, China Ning Xu Aluminum Corporation of China

More information

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem BGPE Intensive Course: Contracts and Asymmetric Information Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem Anke Kessler Anke Kessler p. 1/?? Introduction standard neoclassical economic theory

More information

Bayesian Optimization

Bayesian Optimization Practitioner Course: Portfolio October 15, 2008 No introduction to portfolio optimization would be complete without acknowledging the significant contribution of the Markowitz mean-variance efficient frontier

More information

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101 3 Tournaments 3.1 Motivation General idea Firms can use competition between agents for 1 incentive and 2 selection purposes We mainly focus on incentives 3 / 101 Main characteristics Agents fulll similar

More information

Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency

Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency Multivariate Stress Testing for Solvency Alexander J. McNeil 1 1 Heriot-Watt University Edinburgh Vienna April 2012 a.j.mcneil@hw.ac.uk AJM Stress Testing 1 / 50 Regulation General Definition of Stress

More information