Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Department of Economics Working Paper Series"

Transcription

1 Department of Economics Working Paper Series A Comparison of Two-Market Bertrand Duopoly and Two-Market Cournot Duopoly Vicki Knoblauch University of Connecticut Working Paper April Mansfield Road, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT Phone: (860) Fax: (860)

2 Abstract In a two-market Bertrand duopoly,each of two firms chooses one of two markets and a price in that market. All four choices are made simultaneously. In a two-market Cournot duopoly, the firms choose quantities rather than prices.it is well known that in the one-market case the threat of price undercutting means that Bertrand equilibrium prices and profits will be lower and quantities higher than Cournot equilibrium prices, profits and quantities.we find a quite different consequence of price undercutting in two-market duopoly. In the two-market case the threat of price undercutting means that Bertrand equilibria are in continuous mixed strategies, while every Cournot duopoly has an equilibrium in pure strategies, or in strategies that are pure in each market. Journal of Economic Literature Classification: C72, D43 Keywords: Cournot, Bertrand, Two-Market Duopoly

3 1. Introduction Two firms are licensed to sell a new product in Denver and Seattle. Each firm has sufficient resources to enter only one market. Each firm chooses a city and sets a price, and each firm must make both decisions without knowing the city chosen or the price set by the other firm. In other words, all four choices are made simultaneously. This game will be referred to as two-market Bertrand duopoly or two-market duopoly with price competition. In an alternative scenario, the two markets are distinguished by product rather than location. Two firms are capable of producing lawn mowers or golf carts. Each firm chooses a product and sets a price. Again, all four choices are made simultaneously. In this paper I investigate the equilibrium structure of two-market duopoly with price competition, as in the above scenarios, and with quantity competition. In each case, the equilibrium structure is shaped by the fact that a firm must set a price (or choose a quantity) without knowing whether it will be a monopolist or a duopolist in its chosen market. It is well known that in one-market duopoly with price competition, the threat of price undercutting drives profits to zero. In two-market duopoly with price competition, it seems likely that equilibrium profits should be nonzero. Therefore, we should search for equilibria among continuous mixed strategy profiles, since mixed strategy profiles with finite support (including pure strategies) are suseptible to price undercutting. We will in fact construct symmetric continuous mixed-strategy equilibria for all two-market duopolies with price competition. On the other hand we will show that every two-market duopoly with quantity competition has an equilibrium in pure strategies or in strategies that assign probability one to a union of two quantities, one in one market and one in the other. We will call such strategies semi-pure. We will also give an example of a two-market duopoly such that, for the proper selection of equilibria, Bertrand equilibrium profits exceed Cournot equilibrium profits. The literature on price and quantity competition has to a large extent focused on two-stage games that model markets in which capacity, product, or location decisions 2

4 must be made before prices or quantities are set. In the seminal paper by Kreps and Scheinkman(1983) firms first simultaneously choose capacities and then in the second stage choose prices simultaneously. Allen et al. (2000) consider a two-stage game in which the firms choose capacities sequentially and then compete in prices. In Elberfeld and Wolfstetter (1999) firms first decide whether to enter a market or not and then compete in prices in stage two. In papers by Gersbach and Schmutzler (1999) and Hamilton, Thisse and Weskamp (1989) firms choose location and then a pricing game ensues. There are also studies in which each firm s location or choice of product characteristic is determined exogenously (as in d Aspremont,Gabszewicz and Thisse (1979) and Salop (1979))and then a pricing or quantity game is played. In our two-market duopoly games, it is not assumed that product or location decisions must be made before prices or quantities are set. Consider the example alluded to briefly above in which each firm chooses to produce lawn mowers or golf carts. Because of the similarity of the two products, it would not be necessary to commit to one or the other far in advance of the date when lawn mowers or golf carts start rolling off the assembly line. On the other hand, if the choice were between lawn mowers and sports cars, it might be necessary to choose a product years in advance of setting prices or quantities and a two-stage game would be an appropriate model. In the other example alluded to above, firms locate in Denver or Seattle. If it is necessary for each firm to set up production facilities in the city it chooses (for example if the firms are opening sushi restaurants) it may need to commit to a city far in advance of setting prices or quantities and a two-stage game would be an appropriate model. On the other hand, if the firms plan to sell software produced in Arizona, there is no need to commit to a city far in advance of setting prices or quantities and our two-market duopoly games would be appropriate models. Janssen and Rasmusen (2002) study profits generated by price competition in a single market which each firm enters with an exogenously determined probability α. Their construction of a symmetric, continuous Nash equilibrium for Bertrand duopoly with uncertain entry into a single market proved useful to us *. It made possible considerable * I would like to thank Wieland Müller for suggesting that Janssen and Rasmusen (2002) might be of use in this paper 3

5 abridgement of an earlier version of our construction of a symmetric, continuous Nash equilibrium in two-market Bertrand duopoly (see Proposition 2 below). Their construction was adaptable to the two-market case because in a symmetric Nash equilibrium for two-market Bertrand duopoly each firm enters market 1 with some positive (though not exogenously determined) probability α, and each firm enters market 2 with positive probability 1 α. The results of Janssen and Rasmusen are potentially useful not only when entry is uncertain for each firm, but, as they point out, in other scenarios, for example when consumers are imperfectly informed about entry or about prices. The classical mixed strategy equilibrium existence results of Glicksberg (1952), Dasgupta and Maskin (1986) and Simon (1987) do not apply directly to our two-market duopoly games which have strategy sets that are neither compact nor connected. Of course, even if it proved possible to adapt classical equilibrium existence theorems to two-market duopoly games, these theorems would not provide specific equilibria, as in the proof of Proposition 2 below, nor would they guarantee semi-pure-strategy equilibria as in the proofs of Propositions 4 and 5. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces a notation for mixed strategies in two-market duopoly games. In Section 3 a symmetric, continuous mixed-strategy equilibrium is constructed for an arbitrary two-market Bertrand duopoly game. Section 4 contains pure-strategy and semi-pure-strategy equilibrium existence theorems for twomarket Cournot duopoly games. An example illustrates the theorems. Section 5 compares Bertrand and Cournot equilibrium profits. 2. Definitions A two-market duopoly game is a two-player, one-period game of complete information. Regardless of whether the players compete in prices or quantities, the strategy set for each player is the disjoint union of two copies of [0, + ), the non-negative reals. One copy of [0, + ) represents possible prices (or quantities) in one market, and the other copy of [0, + ) represents possible prices (or quantities) in the other. Lower case letters will be used for prices and quantities in market 1, upper case letters for prices and quantities in market 2. 4

6 In the quantity competition version of two-market duopoly with inverse demand functions p(q) inmarket1andp (Q) in market 2, we will, for example, write π 1 (q 1,q 2 )= q 1 p(q 1 + q 2 ) as the payoff to firm 1 if firm one chooses market 1 and quantity q 1 and firm 2 chooses market 1 and quantity q 2. (Notice that in order to simplify the analysis we are assuming zero costs.) Similarly, π 1 (q, Q) =qp(q) denotes the payoff to firm 1 if firm 1 chooses market 1 and quantity q and firm 2 chooses market 2 and quantity Q. In the price competition version of two-market duopoly with demand functions q(p) in market 1 and Q(P )inmarket2, 0 if P 2 <P 1 ; Π 1 (P 1,P 2 )= P 1 Q(P 1 ) if P 1 <P 2 ; P 1 Q(P 1 )/2 if P 1 = P 2. denotes the payoff to firm 1 if firm 1 chooses market 2 and sets price P 1, and firm 2 chooses market 2 and sets price P 2. These three examples should be enough to explain the notation. Of course with this notation π 1 (4, 5) is meaningless since it could indicate π 1 (q 1,q 2 )withq 1 =4,q 2 =5,or π 1 (q, Q) withq =4,Q =5,etc. A mixed strategy for two-market duopoly with price competition is a real valued function F on the strategy space such that F is nondecreasing on both copies of [0, + ) (1) F is continuous from the right on both copies of [0, + ) (2) 0 F (p) F (P ) for every market 1 price p and market 2 price P (3) lim F (P )=1 (4) P + Then F determines a firm i mixed strategy as follows. Set Probability (i chooses market 1 and sets p i p) =F (p) Probability (i chooses market 2 and sets P i P )=F (P ) lim F (p) p + Similarly, a function F that satisfies (1)-(4) with quantities in place of price defines a firm i mixed strategy for two-market duopoly with quantity competition. 5

7 3. Price Competition. Each of our two equilibrium existence results for two-market duopoly with price competition will require assumptions from the following list of assumptions involving the nonnegative demand functions q(p) andq(p ) defined for p 0andP 0. A1. q(p) and Q(P ) are continuous from the right. A2. q(p) and Q(P ) are continuous from the left. A3. There exist b, B > 0 such that pq(p) is nondecreasing on [0,b] and nonincreasing on [b, + ) PQ(P ) is nondecreasing on [0,B] and nonincreasing on [B,+ ) A4. q(b)q(b) 0. Recall that costs have been assumed to be zero so that pq(p) andpq(p )areprofit functions in market 1 and market 2, bq(b) is the monopoly profit in market 1 and BQ(B) is the monopoly profit in market 2. Proposition 1. Under assumptions A2, A3 and A4, duopoly with price competition has a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium if and only if market 1 monopoly profit equals market 2 monopoly profit. Proof. Suppose bq(b) =BQ(B). Then p 1 = b, P 2 = B is a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Suppose bq(b) BQ(B). Without loss of generality assume BQ(B) >bq(b). If firms 1 and 2 choose market 1 and set prices p 1 and p 2 respectively, then firm 1 can increase its payoff by changing its strategy to P 1 = B. Suppose the firms choose different markets. Without loss of generality assume firm 1 chooses market 1 and sets price p 1, and firm 2 chooses market 2 and sets price P 2. If P 2 Q(P 2 ) <BQ(B), then firm 2 can increase its payoff by changing its strategy from P 2 to B. IfP 2 Q(P 2 )=BQ(B) then firm 1 can increase its payoff by changing its strategy from 6

8 p 1 to P 1 = P 2 ɛ, whereɛ>0 is small enough so that P 1 Q(P 1 ) >bq(b). There is such an ɛ because BQ(B) >bq(b) and A2 holds. Finally, suppose firms 1 and 2 choose market 2 and set prices P 1 and P 2 respectively. Without loss of generality, assume P 1 P 2. If P 1 >P 2 or if P 1 = P 2 and P 2 Q(P 2 )=0, then π 1 (P 1,P 2 ) = 0 so that, by A4, firm 1 can increase its payoff by changing its strategy to p 1 = b. If P 1 = P 2 and P 2 Q(P 2 ) > 0, then π 1 (P 1,P 2 ) = P 2 Q(P 2 )/2 sothatfirm1can increase its payoff by changing its strategy to P 2 ɛ where ɛ>0 is small enough so that (P 2 ɛ)q(p 2 ɛ) >P 2 Q(P 2 )/2. Such an ɛ exists because P 2 Q(P 2 ) >P 2 Q(P 2 )/2 anda2 holds. Proposition 2. Under A1-A4 every two-market duopoly with price competition has a symmetric, continuous mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium. Our starting point in constructing an equilibrium is a result in Janssen and Rasmusen (2002, equation (22)). They consider a single market pricing game in which each of two firms knows that its opponent will enter the market with probability α, 0<α<1. They find an equilibrium in which each firm enters the market with probability α and chooses a price according to the cumulative distribution. { 0 if p a; F (p) = (1/α)(1 (1 α)p m q(p m )/pq(p)) if a<p b; 1 if p>b. Here b is as defined in A3 above and a will be defined below. Since in a continuous mixed strategy equilibrium of our two-market Bertrand duopoly each firm will enter market 1 with some positive probability and will enter market 2 with some positive probability, we find a symmetric equilibrium that in each market takes on the same general form as the cumulative distribution above. This saves us the trouble of setting up and solving differential equations to find a continuous equilibrium. Of course our mixed strategy must be defined over two markets. In addition, we do not have an exogenous probability α of entry. Instead the probability of entry into each market and therefore the explicit form of the equilibrium for two-market duopoly with price competition is 7

9 determined by the requirement that in playing against F,firmi is indifferent between points in the support of F and therefore indifferent between markets. After proving Proposition 2, we will determine the probability of entry into each market and each firm s profit in equilibrium. Proof. Let c = bq(b)bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) a = min{p: pq(p) =c} A = min{p : PQ(P )=c} 0 if 0 p a; F (p) = 1 c/pq(p) if a p b; 1 c/bq(b) if b p<+. { 1 c/bq(b) if 0 P A; F (P )= 1 c/bq(b)+1 c/p Q(P ) if A P B; 1 if B P<+. By A4, c is well defined and c>0. By A1 and A2, a and A are well defined and positive. By A1-A4, F is well defined and continuous. By A3, F is non-decreasing in both markets; that is (1) holds. By A1, (2) holds. Clearly (3) and (4) hold. Since (1)-(4) hold, F is a mixed strategy. To show that (F, F) is a Nash equilibrium, notice that for all p π 1 (p, F )=pq(p)(f (b) F (p)+1 F (b)) = pq(p)(1 F (p)) pq(p)(1 F (a)) if 0 p a; = pq(p)(1 F (p)) if a p b; pq(p)(1 F (b)) if b p<+. cpq(p)/aq(a) if 0 p a; = c if a p b; cpq(p)/bq(b) if b p<+. 8

10 Similarly, cp Q(P )/AQ(A) if 0 P A; π 1 (P, F) = c if A P B; cp Q(P )/BQ(B) if B P<+. Applying A3 one can see that π 1 (p, F ) attains a maximum value of c on [a, b] and π 1 (P, F) achievesamaximumofc on [A, B]. From the definition of F it is clear that if firm 1 plays F, the probability it chooses market 1 but prices outside of [a, b] is zero as is the probability that it chooses market 2 but prices outside of [A, B]. Therefore F is a best response to F.Inotherwords,(F, F) is a Nash equilibrium. If firm i employs strategy F, then the probability that firm i chooses market 1 is F (b) =1 c/bq(b) =bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) and the probability that firm i chooses market 2 is 1 F (b) =BQ(B)/(b(q(b)+BQ(B)). These probabilities depend only on the ratio of the monopoly profits in the two markets. Now suppose both firms employ strategy F and market 1 monopoly profits are much greater than those in market 2. Then F (b) =bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) 1andπ 1 (F, F) = c = bq(b)bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) BQ(B). In other words, both firms almost certainly enter market 1, but each firms profit is approximately equal to the monopoly profit in market 2. Next suppose both firms employ strategy F and market 1 monopoly profits are approximately equal to market 2 monopoly profits. Then F (b) =bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) 1/2and π 1 (F, F) =bq(b)bq(b)/(bq(b)+bq(b)) bq(b)/2. When monopoly profits are exactly equal, π 1 (F, F) =bq(b)/2 while for the pure-strategy equilibrium (b, B), π 1 (b, B) =bq(b). In the special case when there exists a pure-strategy equilibrium, the pure-strategy equilibrium outcome strictly Pareto dominates the mixed-strategy equilibrium outcome. In two-market duopoly with price competition, there is an incentive for a firm to price high in order to maximize profits if the firm s opponent chooses the other market. There 9

11 is also an incentive to price low in order to undercut and to avoid being undercut. The mixed-strategy equilibrium accommodates both incentives. On the other hand the special case pure-strategy equilibrium (b, B) eliminates the incentive to price low, but selection of a pure-strategy equilibrium requires choosing between two equilibria (b, B) and(b,b) which are indistinguishable in the sense that the two markets yield identical monopoly profits, so that the mixed-strategy equilibrium may be considered a focal point, since it is the unique mixed-strategy equilibrium. 4. Quantity Competition. Throughout this section, the following assumptions on the market 1 and market 2 inverse demand functions p(q) andp (Q) hold: there are market one quantities q D and q M and market 2 quantities Q D and Q M such that (q D,q D )and(q D,Q D ) are the unique pure strategy Nash equilibria for market 1 duopoly with quantity competition and market 2 duopoly with quantity competition, respectively; q M and Q M are the unique profit maximizing quantities for a market 1 monopolist and a market 2 monopolist, respectively; and duopoly equilibrium profits are positive in both markets (we are not assuming p(q) 0 for all q or P (Q) 0 for all Q). Proposition 3. Two -market duopoly with quantity competition possesses a purestrategy Nash equilibrium if and only if there is no q 0 such that π 1 (q D,q D ) <π(q M ) < π 1 (q 0,q M ) and no Q 0 such that π 1 (Q D,Q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (Q 0,Q M ). Proof. To prove necessity, suppose there is a q 0 such that π 1 (q D,q D ) < π(q M ) < π 1 (q 0,q M ). The only possible pure-strategy Nash equilibria are (q D,q D ), (Q D,Q D ), (q M,Q M )and(q M,q m ). First, π 1 (q D,q D ) <π(q M )=π 1 (Q M,q D ). Second, π 1 (Q D,Q D ) <π 1 (Q D,Q D )+π 2 (Q D,Q D ) π(q M ) <π 1 (q 0,q M ) <π(q M )= π 1 (q M,Q D ). Third, π 2 (q M,Q M )=π(q M ) <π 1 (q 0,q M )=π 2 (q M,q 0 ). 10

12 Finally, π 1 (Q M,q M )=π(q M ) <π 1 (q 0,q M ). Therefore there is no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. Symmetrically, there is no pure-strategy equilibrium if there is a Q 0 such that π 1 (Q D,Q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (Q 0,Q M ). To prove sufficiency, suppose there is no q 0 such that π 1 (q D,q D ) <π(q M ) < π 1 (q 0,q M ) and no Q 0 such that π 1 (Q D,Q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (Q 0,Q M ). Then π 1 (q D,q D ) π(q M ) or π 1 (Q D,Q D ) π(q M )orbothπ(q M ) π 1 (q, q M ) for all q and π(q M ) π 1 (Q, Q M ) for all Q. If π 1 (q D,q D ) π(q M ), then (q D,q D ) is a Nash equilibrium, since π 1 (q D,q D ) π(q M ) means neither player can gain by a unilateral move to market 2, and neither player can gain by a unilateral move within market 1 by the definition of q D. Similarly, if π(q D,Q D ) π(q M ), then (Q D,Q D ) is a Nash equilibrium. Finally, if π(q M ) π 1 (q, q M ) for all q and π(q M ) π(q, Q M ) for all Q, then (q M,Q M ) is a Nash equilibrium, since π 1 (q M,Q M )=π(q M ) π 1 (Q, Q M ) for all Q π 1 (q M,Q M )=π(q M ) π(q) =π 1 (q, Q M ) for all q π 2 (q M,Q M )=π(q M ) π 1 (q, q M )=π 2 (q M,q) for all q π 2 (q M,Q M )=π(q M ) π(q) =π 2 (q M,Q) for all Q. It is easy to construct examples that satisfy the hypotheses of Proposition 3 and therefore possess pure-strategy Nash equilibria. For example, if π(q M )=π(q M ), then π(q M )=π(q M ) π 1 (Q, Q M ) for all Q and π(q M )=π(q M ) π 1 (q, q M ) for all q. The following two-market duopoly game with quantity competition fails to satisfy the hypotheses of Proposition 3 and therefore has no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, but does satisfy the hypotheses of Proposition 4 below and therefore has a semi-pure mixed-strategy equilibrium. Example 1. Let p(q) =(q +1) 3 and P (Q) =(1 Q)/5. To maximize π(q) =QP (Q), set π (Q) =P (Q) +QP (Q) =0. ThenQ M = P (Q M )/P (Q M )=1 Q M. Solving, Q M =1/2. 11

13 To find an equilibrium (Q D,Q D )ofmarket2duopoly,set π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 1 = P (Q 1 + Q 2 )+Q 1 P (Q 1 + Q 2 )=0 π 2 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 2 = P (Q 1 + Q 2 )+Q 2 P (Q 1 + Q 2 )=0 Then Q D1 = Q D2 = P (Q D1 + Q D2 )/P (Q D1 + Q D2 )orq D = 1 2Q D. Solving, Q D =1/3. Notice that π(q M ) > 0andπ 1 (Q D,Q D ) > 0 as required for Proposition 3. In market 1, q M = p(q M )/p (q M )=(q M +1) 3 /3(q M +1) 4 =(q M +1)/3. Solving, q M =1/2 For market 1 duopoly, q D = p(2q D )/p (2q D )=(2q D +1)/3. Solving, q D =1. Then π 1 (q D,q D )=q D (2q D +1) 3 =3 3 =1/27 π(q M )=(1/2)(1/2)/5 =1/20 π 1 (q M,q M )=(1/2)2 3 =1/16 so that π 1 (q D,q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (q M,q M ) and by Proposition 3 Example 1 has no purestrategy Nash equilibrium. Example 1 will also be used to illustrate Proposition 4, a mixed-strategy equilibrium existence result. The hypotheses of Proposition 4 will include A5, a continuity assumption and A6, which generalizes the assumption of existence and uniqueness of q D, q M, Q D and Q M made at the beginning of this section. A5. p(q) and P (Q) are continuous on [0, + ). If a [0, 1], q is a market 1 quantity and Q is a market 2 quantity, let m(a, q, Q)denote the semi-pure strategy that plays q with probability a and Q with probability 1 a. A6. There exist bounded functions q, Q :[0, 1] [0, + ) such that for a [0, 1], q (a) and Q (a) are the unique market 1 and market 2 quantities such that π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a)) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))) q π 1 (Q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a)) = max π 1(Q, m(a, q (a),q (a))) Q 12

14 Notice that when a = 0, A6 asserts the existence and uniqueness, of q M and Q D,and when a = 1, A6 asserts the existence and uniqueness of q D and Q M. Assumption A6 may seem extravagant, which criticism would translate into a criticism of any proposition containing A6 in its hypothesis as weak. However, after stating and proving a result using assumption A6, we will show that A6 follows from a simple convexity assumption. Proposition 4. If a two-market duopoly game with quantity competition satisfies A5, A6, π(q M ) >π 1 (q D,q D ),andπ(q M ) >π 1 (Q D,Q D ), then it possesses a symmetric, semi-pure strategy equilibrium. Proof. Suppose q and Q are as in A6. If the existence of a [0, 1] such that π 1 (q (a ),m(a,q (a ),Q (a ))) = π 1 (Q (a ),m(a,q (a ),Q (a ))) can be established, then by this equation and the two equations in A6 with a = a, (m(a,q (a ),Q (a )),m(a,q (a ),Q (a ))) will be a Nash equilibrium. Since q (0) maximizes π 1 (q, m(0,q (0),Q (0))) = π(q), q (0) = q M.SinceQ (0) maximizes π 1 (Q, m(0,q (0),Q (0))) = π 1 (Q, Q (0)) = π 2 (Q (0),Q), Q (0) = Q D. Therefore π 1 (q (0),m(0,q (0),Q (0))) π 1 (Q (0),m(0,q (0),Q (0))) = π(q M ) π 1 (Q D,Q D ) > 0 (5) The inequality is from the hypotheses of Proposition 4. By a similar argument π 1 (q (1),m(1,q (1),Q (1))) π 1 (Q (1),m(1,q (1),Q (1))) = π 1 (q D,q D ) π(q m ) < 0 (6) To see that q (a) is a continuous function of a, suppose a 0 [0, 1] and (a n )isa sequence in [0, 1] such that a n a 0. Since by A6 (q (a n )) is a bounded sequence, it has a convergent subsequence (q (a nk )). Let q 0 = lim k + q (a nk ). Since q (a nk ) q 0, q (a nk ) maximizes π 1 (q, m(a nk,q (a nk ),Q (a nk ))), and π 1 (q, m(a, q, Q)) is continuous in q, a and q and constant in Q, itmustbethatq 0 maximizes π 1 (q, m(a 0,q 0,Q (a 0 ))). By 13

15 the uniqueness provision of A6, q 0 = q (a 0 ). In summary, every sequence (q (a n )) such that a n a 0 has a subsequence that converges to q (a 0 ). Therefore q (a) is a continuous function of a. Similarly Q (a) is a continuous function of a. Therefore π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) π 1 (Q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) is a continuous function of a. By (5), (6) and the Intermediate Value Theorem, there is an a such that π 1 (q (a ),m(a,q (a ),Q (a ))) = π 1 (Q (a ),m(a,q (a ),Q (a ))). We will see in the proof of Proposition 5 that A6 holds if the following simple convexity assumptions hold. A7. π 1 (q 1,q 2 ) and π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 ) are twice continously differentiable, 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q1 2 < 0, 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q 2 q 1 < 0, 2 π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 2 1 < 0 and 2 π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 2 Q 1 < 0. Proposition 5. If a two-market duopoly game with quantity competition satisfies A5, A7, π(q M ) >π 1 (q D,q D ) and π(q M ) >π 1 (Q D,Q D ), then it possesses a symmetric, semipure-strategy equilibrium. Proof. Fix a, q 2 and Q 2. Since π(q 1 )=π 1 (q 1,q)whenq =0,byA7d 2 π(q 1 )/dq1 2 < 0. Since q M exists (assumed at the beginning of this section) and d 2 π(q 1 )/dq1 2 < 0, there exists q 0 such that q 1 q 0 implies π(q 1 ) < 0. Since d 2 π(q 1 )/dq1 2 < 0, dπ(q 1 )/dq 1 < 0for q 1 >q M and therefore p(q 1 ) is decreasing for q 1 >q M. Therefore π 1 (q 1,q 2 ) π(q 1 )for q 1 >q M so that π 1 (q 1,q 2 ) < 0forq 1 q 0. Therefore, π 1 (q 1,m(a, q 2,Q 2 )) < 0forq 1 q 0. Since 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q1 2 < 0andd 2 π(q 1 )/dq1 2 < 0, 2 π 1 (q 1,m(a, q 2,Q 2 ))/ q1 2 < 0. Since 2 π 1 (q 1,m(a, q 2,Q 2 ))/ q1 2 < 0andπ 1(q, m(a, q 2,Q 2 )) < 0ifq 1 >q 0, π 1 (q, m(a, q 2,Q 2 )) attains a maximum at a unique real r(q 2 ), player 1 s best response to m(a, q 2,Q 2 ). Now allow q 2 to vary. By the continuity of π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q 1 assumed in A7, r(q 2 ) is a continuous function of q 2. If a =0thenr(q 2 )=q M for all q 2. To see that r(q 2 ) is differentiable when a 0andr(q 2 ) 0,letF (q 1,q 2 )= π 1 (q 1,m(a, q 2,Q 2 ))/ q 1. Then for all q 2 with r(q 2 ) > 0 F (r(q 2 ),q 2 )=0 (7) 14

16 For small h 0 [F (r(q 2 + h),q 2 + h) F (r(q 2 ),q 2 )]/h = (F (r(q 2 + h),q 2 + h) F (r(q 2 ),q 2 + h))/h +(F (r(q 2 ),q 2 + h) F (r(q 2 ),q 2 ))/h =0 (8) For small h the second term of (8) is approximately F 2 (r(q 2 ),q 2 )=a 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q 2 q 1 q1 =r(q 2 )< 0byA7. Therefore the first term of (8) is non-zero so that r(q 2 + h) r(q 2 ) and we can write the first term of (8) as [ (F (r(q2 + h),q 2 + h) F (r(q 2 ),q 2 + h)) / (r(q 2 + h) r(q 2 )) ][ (r(q 2 + h) r(q 2 ))/h ] F 2 (r(q 2 ),q 2 ). (9) Since r is continuous, the Mean Value Theorem and the continuity of 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q1 2 can be used to prove that the first factor on the left hand side of (9) converges to F 1 (r(q 2 ),q 2 ) as h 0. Therefore the second factor converges; that is, r (q 2 )existsand r (q 2 )= F 2 (r(q 2 ),q 2 )/F 1 (r(q 2 ),q 2 )= / a 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q 2 q 1 (a q1 2 π 1 (q 1,q 2 )/ q 2 1 a)π =r(q 2 ) q1 =r(q 2 )+(1 (r(q 2 ))) Therefore, if a 0andr(q 2 ) 0thenr (q 2 ) < 0. If a =0,r(q 2 )=q M for all q 2. In either case the graph of q 1 = r(q 2 ) intersects the graph of q 1 = q 2 in a single point q (a) q 0. We then have q (a) =r(q (a)) so that q (a) is a bounded function of a and for each a [0, 1] q (a) is the unique market 1 quantity such that Thus half of A6 is satisfied. π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))). q By a similar argument in market 2, the other half of A6 holds, and we can invoke Proposition 4 which has the same conclusion as Proposition 5. 15

17 Example 1 continued. Recall that we have already shown that Example 1 satisfies the conditions specified at the beginning of this section, the existence and uniqueness of q D, q M, Q D and Q M. We also showed that π 1 (q D,q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (q M,q M )fromwhichis follows that π(q M ) >π 1 (q D,q D )andπ(q M ) >π 1 (q M,q M ) >π(q M ) >π 1 (q D,q D ). Since p(q) =(q+1) 3 and P (Q) =(1 Q)/5, Example 1 satisfies A5. It is easy to show that P (Q) satisfies A7. For Q 1,Q 2 [0, + ), π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )=(Q 1 Q 2 1 Q 1Q 2 )/5, π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 1 = (1 2Q 1 Q 2 )/5, 2 π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 2 1 = 2/5 < 0and 2 π 1 (Q 1,Q 2 )/ Q 2 Q 1 = 1/5 < 0. Unfortunately p(q) =(q +1) 3 does not satisfy A7, nor does any nonnegative price function with a q M. We will instead show that p(q) satisfies A6. Step 1. For q [0, + ) anda [0, 1], there is a unique value of q that maximizes π 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a))). With a and q fixed, differentiate π 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a))) = aq(q + q +1) 3 +(1 a)q(q +1) 3 and set equal to zero dπ 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a)))/dq = a(q+ q+1) 4 ( 2q+ q+1)+(1 a)(q+1) 4 ( 2q+1) = 0 (10) Then dπ 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a)))/dq is a continuous function of q on [0, + ). It is positive if q<1/2and negative if q>1/2+ q/2. By the Intermediate Value Theorem, there exists q (a, m(a, q, Q (a))) [1/2, 1/2+ q/2] such that (10) holds for q = q (a, m(a, q, Q(a ))). Since d 2 π 1 (q, m(a, q, Q(a )))/dq 2 = a(q+ q+1) 5 (6q 6 q 6)+(1 a)(q+1) 5 (6q 6) < 0ifq<1+ q and dπ 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a)))/dq is negative if q>1/2+ q/2, q (a, m(a, q, Q (a))) is the unique solution to (10) and the unique value of q that maximizes π 1 (q, m(a, q, Q (a))). Step 2. For a [0, 1], there exists q (a) such that In (10) replace q by q: π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))) q a(1 q)(2q +1) 4 +(1 a)(1 2q)(q +1) 4 = 0 (11) Let f(q) denote the left side of (11). Then f(q) is continuous on [0, + ), f(q) > 0ifq<1/2 and f(q) < 0ifq>1. By the Intermediate Value Theorem there exists q (a) [1/2, 1] 16

18 such that f(q (a)) = 0. Therefore q = q (a) satisfies (10) when q = q (a). As was shown in Step 1, this implies that π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))). q We know from Step 1 that there is no q q (a) that maximizes π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))), but is there a q q (a) thatmaximizesπ 1 (q, m(a, q,q (a))? Step 3. For a [0, 1] there is a unique q (a) such that π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))). q Since f (q) =a(2q +1) 5 (6q 6) + (1 a)(q +1) 5 (6q 6) < 0ifq<1, f(q) > 0if q<1/2 andf(q) < 0ifq>1, there is a unique q (a) that satisfies (11) and therefore a unique q (a) such that π 1 (q (a),m(a, q (a),q (a))) = max π 1 (q, m(a, q (a),q (a))) q Finally, in Step 2 it was shown that for a [0, 1], q (a) 1. Therefore p(q) satisfies A6. Since P (Q) was shown to satisfy A7, by the proof of Proposition 5 it also satisfies A6. By Proposition 4, Example 1 possesses a symmetric, semi-pure strategy equilibrium. The following Proposition combines Propositions 3,4 and 5. Proposition 6. If a two-market duopoly game with quantity competition satisfies A5 and each market satisfies A6 or A7, then it possesses a symmetric Nash equilibrium in pure or semi-pure strategies. Proof. If there is a q 0 such that π 1 (q D,q D ) < π(q M ) < π 1 (q 0,q M ), then π(q M ) > π 1 (q D,q D )andπ(q M ) π 1 (q 0,q M ) > π(q M ) π 1 (Q D,Q D ). Apply Propositions 4 and/or 5. If there is a Q 0 such that π 1 (Q D,Q D ) <π(q M ) <π 1 (Q 0,Q M ), Propositions 4 and/or 5 apply by a similar argument. If there is no such q 0 and no such Q 0, then apply Proposition 3. 17

19 5. Profit Levels. How do two-market Bertrand equilibrium profits compare with two-market Cournot equilibrium profits? We start with an example. Example 2. q(p) =1 p and Q(P )=1 P. There are unique monopoly profit maximizing prices in both markets. They are p M =1/2 andp M =1/2. Then (p M,P M ) is a purestrategy Nash equilibrium for two-market Bertrand duopoly, and equilibrium profits are π i (p M,P M )=1/4 fori =1, 2. For two-market Cournot duopoly we have p(q) =1 q and P (Q) =1 Q. Then q M =1/2, q D =1/3, Q M =1/2, Q D =1/3 as was seen in the discussion of Example 1. Then π(q M )=1/4 > 1/9 =π 1 (q D,q D )andπ(q M ) >π 1 (Q D,Q D )sothatbyproposition 6 there is a semi-pure strategy Nash equilibrium of two-market Cournot duopoly. Let s find it. Since the two markets have identical demand functions, let s try a =1/2. π 1 (q, m(1/2,q (1/2),Q (1/2))) = (1/2)π(q)+(1/2)π 1 (q, q (1/2)) =(1/2)(q q 2 )+(1/2)(q q 2 qq (1/2)) = q q 2 (1/2)qq (1/2). dπ 1 (q, m(1/2,q (1/2),Q (1/2)))/dq =1 2q (1/2)q (1/2) = 0. Setting q = q (1/2), 2 5q (1/2) = 0. Solving, q (1/2) = 2/5 =Q (1/2). In equilibrium Cournot profits are π 1 (m(1/2, 2/5, 2/5),m(1/2, 2/5, 2/5)) = π 1 (q, m(1/2, 2/5, 2/5)) for q = 2/5 =(1/2)(2/5)(1 2/5) + (1/2)(2/5)(1 4/5) = 3/25 + 1/25 = 4/25. We have found a Bertrand equilibrium and a Cournot equilibrium such that Bertrand equilibrium profits are greater than Cournot equilibrium profits. Of course we have started with the special case when a pure-strategy Bertrand equilibrium exists and compared the better of the two Bertrand equilibria (there is also a Proposition 2 equilibrium with profit 1/8 for each firm) with the worse of two Cournot equilibria (there is also a pure-strategy equilibrium (q M,Q M )withprofit1/4for each firm). There remains the question of whether it can happen that the worst Bertrand equilibrium profits are greater than the best Cournot equilibrium profits. We discuss one case. 18

20 Comparison: A pure-strategy Cournot equilibrium and the Bertrand equilibrium of Proposition 2. As we saw in the proof of Proposition 3, Cournot profits are π(q M ),π(q M ), π 1 (q D,q D ) π(q M ) or π 1 (Q D,Q D ) π(q M ). As we saw in the comments following the proof of Proposition 2, Bertrand profits are π(q M )π(q M )/(π(q M )+π(q M )) < min{π(q M ),π(q M )}. Bertrand equilibrium profits are lower. The relationship between Bertrand and Cournot profits for a continuous Bertrand equilibrium and Cournot equilibrium composed of semi-pure strategies remains an open question. 19

21 References [1] Allen, B, R. Deneckere, T. Faith and D. Kovenock, (2000) Capacity Precommittment as a Barrier to Entry: A Bertrand Edgeworth Approach, Economic Theory 15(3), [2] d Aspremont, C., J. Gabszewicz and J.-F. Thisse, (1979) On Hotelling s Stability in Competition, Econometrica 17, [3] Dasgupta, P., and E. Maskin, (1986) The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games I:Theory, Review of Economic Studies 53, [4] Elberfeld, W., and E. Wolfstetter, (1999) A Dynamic Model of Bertrand Competition with Entry, International Journal of Industrial Organization 17, [5] Gesrbach, H., and A. Schmutzler, (1999) External Spillovers, Internal Spillovers and the Geography of Production and Innovation, Regional Science and Urban Economics 29, [6] Glicksberg, I. L., (1952) A Further Generalization of the Kakutani Fixed Point Theorem with Applications to Nash Equilibrium Points, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 38, [7] Hamilton, J., J.-F. Thisse and A. Weskamp, (1989) Spatial Discrimination: Bertrand vs. Cournot in a Model of Location Choice, Regional Science and Urban Economics 19, [8] Janssen, M., E. Rasmusen, (2002) Bertrand Competition Under Uncertainty, Journal of Industrial Economics 50, [9] Kreps, D., and J. Scheinkman, (1983) Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes, Bell Journal of Economics 14, [10] Simon, L., (1987) Games with Discontinuous Payoffs, Review of Economic Studies 54,

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics Leonardo Felli EC441: Room D.106, Z.332, D.109 Lecture 8 bis: 24 November 2004 Monopoly Consider now the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing monopolist: a firm that is the only

More information

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition On Hotelling s Stability in Competition Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Manuscript received March, 1978; revision received June, 1978 Abstract The purpose of this

More information

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary July 29, 2005. Appeared in the International Journal

More information

Basics of Game Theory

Basics of Game Theory Basics of Game Theory Giacomo Bacci and Luca Sanguinetti Department of Information Engineering University of Pisa, Pisa, Italy {giacomo.bacci,luca.sanguinetti}@iet.unipi.it April - May, 2010 G. Bacci and

More information

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly Daisuke Hirata Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo March 2008 Abstract This paper investigates a simultaneous move capacity constrained price competition

More information

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games 1/10 Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games May 4, 2014 2/10 Outline 1 Bertrand Market Game 2 Bertrand Paradox 3 Asymmetric Firms 3/10 Bertrand Duopoly Market Game Discontinuous Payoff Functions (1 p

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu, Kostas Bimpikis, and Asuman Ozdaglar October 9, 2007 Abstract We study the efficiency of oligopoly equilibria in a model where firms compete over capacities

More information

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October 23 2011 1 Scores The exam was long. I know this. Final grades will definitely be curved. Here is a rough

More information

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 Bertrand Model of Price Competition Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1 ҧ Bertrand Model of Price Competition Consider: An industry with two firms, 1 and 2, selling a homogeneous product Firms face market

More information

Price and Capacity Competition

Price and Capacity Competition Price and Capacity Competition Daron Acemoglu a, Kostas Bimpikis b Asuman Ozdaglar c a Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, MA b Operations Research Center, MIT, Cambridge, MA c Department of Electrical

More information

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Mixed duopolies with advance production Mixed duopolies with advance production Tamás László Balogh Department of Economic Analysis and Business Informatics, University of Debrecen and Attila Tasnádi MTA-BCE Lendület Strategic Interactions Research

More information

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition 4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Partial equilibrium studies the existence of equilibrium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes its properties. Prices in other markets as well

More information

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Answer Key: Problem Set 3 Answer Key: Problem Set Econ 409 018 Fall Question 1 a This is a standard monopoly problem; using MR = a 4Q, let MR = MC and solve: Q M = a c 4, P M = a + c, πm = (a c) 8 The Lerner index is then L M P

More information

Product differences and prices

Product differences and prices Product differences and prices Claude d Aspremont, Jean Jaskold Gabszewicz and Jacques-François Thisse Abstract Under assumptions following Hotelling s 1929 paper Stability in Competition, the possibility

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar Working Paper 12804 http://www.nber.org/papers/w12804 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts

More information

FORWARD INDUCTION AND SUNK COSTS GIVE AVERAGE COST PRICING. Jean-Pierre Ponssard. Abstract

FORWARD INDUCTION AND SUNK COSTS GIVE AVERAGE COST PRICING. Jean-Pierre Ponssard. Abstract FORWARD INDUCTION AND SUNK COSTS GIVE AVERAGE COST PRICING Jean-Pierre Ponssard Abstract This paper applies the idea of forward induction to a classical economic problem: the existence of an efficient

More information

ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1

ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1 ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1 CRISTIÁN TRONCOSO VALVERDE AND JACQUES ROBERT 3 Abstract. This paper extends the traditional Hotelling s model of spatial competition by allowing

More information

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 Oligopoly Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009 1 Oligopoly A monopoly is an industry consisting a single firm. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two firms. An oligopoly is an industry

More information

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP-1702 A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly Rabah Amir Igor V. Evstigneev February 2017 Economics School of Social Sciences The University of Manchester Manchester

More information

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Quantity-setting games with a dominant MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm Attila Tasnádi Corvinus University of Budapest 24. February 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13612/ MPRA Paper

More information

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Sequential Competition EconS 425 - Sequential Competition Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 47 A Warmup 1 x i x j (x

More information

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010 Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2 Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT October 14, 2009 1 Introduction Outline Mixed Strategies Existence of Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibrium

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools ONLINE APPENDIX Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools T. Andrabi, J. Das, A.I. Khwaja, S. Ozyurt, and N. Singh Contents A Theory A.1 Homogeneous Demand.................................

More information

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples February 24, 2011 Summary: We introduce the Nash Equilibrium: an outcome (action profile) which is stable in the sense that no player

More information

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions Microeconomics for Business Practice Session - Solutions Instructor: Eloisa Campioni TA: Ugo Zannini University of Rome Tor Vergata April 8, 016 Exercise 1 Show that there are no mixed-strategy Nash equilibria

More information

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Journal of Game Theory 2017 6(2): 38-42 DOI: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02 Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship Aika Monden Graduate School

More information

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics - PhD in Part 1: Supermodularity and complementarity in the one-dimensional and Paulo Brito ISEG - Technical University of Lisbon November 24, 2010 1 2 - Supermodular optimization 3 one-dimensional 4 Supermodular

More information

Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm

Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm Attila Tasnádi Department of Mathematics, Corvinus University of Budapest, H-1093 Budapest, Fővám tér 8, Hungary August 17, 2009. Abstract: We consider a possible

More information

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing Jianwei Huang & Lin Gao Network Communications and Economics Lab (NCEL) Information Engineering Department The Chinese University of Hong Kong Huang

More information

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3 6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3 Daron Acemoglu and Asu Ozdaglar MIT October 19, 2009 1 Introduction Outline Existence of Nash Equilibrium in Infinite Games Extensive Form

More information

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!? Mathias Erlei Clausthal University of Technology Julius-Albert-Str. 2, 38678 Clausthal-Zellerfeld, Germany email: m.erlei@tu-clausthal.de Abstract This

More information

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Market Power Economics II: Microeconomics VŠE Praha December 2009 Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39 Microeconomics Consumers: Firms: People. Households. Monopoly. Oligopoly Now Perfect Competition.

More information

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS CEP 14-11 Horizontal Mergers in the Presence of Capacity Constraints Zhiqi Chen Carleton University Gang Li Nanjing University September 2014 CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS Department of Economics 1125 Colonel

More information

Fixed Point Theorems

Fixed Point Theorems Fixed Point Theorems Definition: Let X be a set and let f : X X be a function that maps X into itself. (Such a function is often called an operator, a transformation, or a transform on X, and the notation

More information

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2 EconS 305 - Oligopoly - Part 2 Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu November 29, 2015 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 305 - Lecture 32 November 29, 2015 1 / 28 Introduction Last time,

More information

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS 8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS We have studied competitive markets where there are a large number of rms and each rm takes market prices as given. When a market contain only a few relevant rms, rms may

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Product Differentiation 1 / 57 Introduction We now finally drop the assumption that firms offer homogeneous products.

More information

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Tilburg University On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E. Publication date: 1997 Link to publication General rights Copyright and

More information

Static Models of Oligopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly Static Models of Oligopoly Cournot and Bertrand Models Mateusz Szetela 1 1 Collegium of Economic Analysis Warsaw School of Economics 3 March 2016 Outline 1 Introduction Game Theory and Oligopolies 2 The

More information

RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES

RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES BUDAPEST UNIVERSITY OF ECONOMIC SCIENCES Economics Ph.D. Program Department of Mathematics RATIONING RULES AND BERTRAND-EDGEWORTH OLIGOPOLIES Ph.D. Thesis Main Results Attila Tasnádi Budapest, 1999 Contents

More information

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly Yasuo Sanjo Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University Abstract We investigate a mixed duopoly market by introducing quality choice

More information

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium 3. Imperfect Competition 3. Partial Equilirium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilirium Partial equilirium studies the existence of equilirium in the market of a given commodity and analyzes

More information

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous? Paolo G. Garella University of Bologna 14 July 004 Abstract The present note shows that innocuous Minimum Quality Standards, namely standards that

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium Harsanyi [1967] What happens when players do not know one another s payoffs? Games of incomplete information versus games of imperfect

More information

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of... John Asker Econ 170 Industrial Organization January 23, 2017 1 / 1 We will cover the following topics: with Sequential Moves

More information

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange Overview Consumer Producer Exchange Edgeworth Box All Possible Exchange Points Contract Curve Overview Consumer Producer Exchange (Multiplicity) Walrasian Equilibrium Walrasian Equilibrium Requirements:

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

Game theory and market power

Game theory and market power Game theory and market power Josh Taylor Section 6.1.3, 6.3 in Convex Optimization of Power Systems. 1 Market weaknesses Recall Optimal power flow: minimize p,θ subject to λ i : χ ij 0 : f i (p i ) i p

More information

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with Increasing Returns to Scale Abhijit Sengupta and Yair Tauman February 6, 24 Abstract We consider a Cournot Oligopoly market of firms possessing increasing

More information

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty Duopoly and Project Uncertainty An analysis of the Bertrand and Cournot duopolies under uncertainty for the buyer Draft Master Thesis Rik Bos Student 345327 June 2016 Erasmus School of Economics Master

More information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring 2012 EC941: Game Theory Prof. Francesco Squintani Final Exam Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours. 1. Consider

More information

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Prepared with SEVI S LIDES Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I Antonio Cabrales & Massimo Motta May 25, 2005 Summary Some definitions Efficiency reasons for tying Tying as a price

More information

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage Lecture Notes II- Dynamic Games of Complete Information Extensive Form Representation (Game tree Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium Repeated Games Trigger Strategy Dynamic Games of Complete Information Dynamic

More information

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Trade policy III: Export subsidies The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw June 25, 2015 Overview Overview 1 1 Under perfect competition lead to welfare loss 2 Effects depending on market structures 1 Subsidies to

More information

Verifying Payo Security in the Mixed Extension of Discontinuous Games

Verifying Payo Security in the Mixed Extension of Discontinuous Games Verifying Payo Security in the Mixed Extension of Discontinuous Games Blake A. Allison and Jason J. Lepore ;y October 25, 2014 Abstract We introduce the concept of disjoint payo matching which can be used

More information

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition Luca Lambertini Alessandro Tampieri Quaderni - Working Paper DSE N 750 Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Di erentiated

More information

On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information*

On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information* Journal of Economic Theory 85, 38336 (999) Article ID jeth.998.500, available online at http:www.idealibrary.com on NOTES, COMMENTS, AND LETTERS TO THE EDITOR On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect

More information

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot Class Note: There are supplemental readings, including Werden (008) Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers I: Basic Concepts and Models, that

More information

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012 September 24, 2012 Finding Nash equilibrium Best-response or best-reply functions. We introduced Nash-equilibrium as a profile of actions (an action for each player) such that no player has an incentive

More information

4: Dynamic games. Concordia February 6, 2017

4: Dynamic games. Concordia February 6, 2017 INSE6441 Jia Yuan Yu 4: Dynamic games Concordia February 6, 2017 We introduce dynamic game with non-simultaneous moves. Example 0.1 (Ultimatum game). Divide class into two groups at random: Proposers,

More information

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana Oligopoly Notes Simona Montagnana Question 1. Write down a homogeneous good duopoly model of quantity competition. Using your model, explain the following: (a) the reaction function of the Stackelberg

More information

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6 Prof. Ronaldo CARPIO April 10, 017 Administrative Stuff Homework # is due at the end of class. I will post the solutions on the website later today. The midterm

More information

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure Hiroaki Ino Institute of Intellectual Property and Toshihiro Matsumura Institute of Social Science, University of Tokyo [Preliminary

More information

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21 Supermodular Games Ichiro Obara UCLA February 6, 2012 Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, 2012 1 / 21 We study a class of strategic games called supermodular game, which is useful in many applications

More information

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149 Oligopoly Xiang Sun Wuhan University March 23 April 6, 2016 1/149 Outline 1 Introduction 2 Game theory 3 Oligopoly models 4 Cournot competition Two symmetric firms Two asymmetric firms Many symmetric firms

More information

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies. by Barna Bakó, Attila Tasnádi CEWP 11/2014

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies. by Barna Bakó, Attila Tasnádi CEWP 11/2014 CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS CEWP 11/2014 The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies by Barna Bakó, Attila Tasnádi http://unipub.lib.uni-corvinus.hu/1655 The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

More information

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2)

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2) Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2) Haifeng Huang University of California, Merced Best response functions: example In simple games we can examine

More information

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005 GS/ECON 500 Answers to Assignment 3 W005 Q. What are the market price, and aggregate quantity sold, in long run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market f which the demand function has the equation

More information

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model 1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model Bertrand model: There are two rms and no entry is possible. Homogeneity of product. Single period. Consumers always purchase from the cheapest seller. If the two selllers charge

More information

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation Economic Theory 7, 693 700 (200) Profitability of price quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation Yasuhito Tanaka Faculty of Law, Chuo University, 742-, Higashinakano, Hachioji,

More information

Solutions to Exercises of Section III.1. a (13/4, 3) (22/4, 3/4). b (4, 10/4) (21/4, 2)

Solutions to Exercises of Section III.1. a (13/4, 3) (22/4, 3/4). b (4, 10/4) (21/4, 2) Solutions to Exercises of Section III.1. 1. The bimatrix is c d ( ) a (13/4, 3) (22/4, 3/4). b (4, 10/4) (21/4, 2) 2. (a) Player I s maxmin strategy is (1, 0) (i.e. row 1) guaranteeing him the safety level

More information

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry Claudia Sagastizábal (visiting researcher IMPA) mailto:sagastiz@impa.br http://www.impa.br/~sagastiz ENEC workshop, IPAM, Los Angeles, January

More information

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium Reading EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium Osborne Chapter 3 By the end of this week you should be able to: apply Nash equilibrium to oligopoly games, voting games and other examples.

More information

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices Kenji Fujiwara School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University Abstract We develop the following Stackelberg game model of

More information

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty

Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Heterogenous Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Behavioral Uncertainty Akio Matsumoto Department of Systems Industrial Engineering Univesity of Arizona, USA Department of Economics Chuo University,

More information

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies Barna Bakó Attila Tasnádi April 9, 2015 Abstract In this paper we extend the results of Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) to mixedduopolies. We show that quantity

More information

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies Barna Bakó Attila Tasnádi February 17, 2014 Abstract In this paper we generalize the results of Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) to mixedduopolies. We show that

More information

Online Appendix. (S,S) for v v1. (F,F) for v1 S < v

Online Appendix. (S,S) for v v1. (F,F) for v1 S < v Article submitted to Production & Operations Management 1 Online Appendix Appendix F: When the Retailers Can Decide Whether to Adopt QR Here we describe what happens when the retailers can simultaneously

More information

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Free Entry Bertrand Competition MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Free Entry Bertrand Competition Prabal Roy Chowdhury Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi Center October 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/17837/ MPRA Paper

More information

A theory of recommended price dispersion

A theory of recommended price dispersion A theory of recommended price dispersion Marco Haan Pim Heijnen Martin Obradovits January 3, 017 WORK IN PROGRESS DO NOT CITE Abstract This paper contributes to the theory of recommended retail prices

More information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016 1 Modelling incomplete information So far, we have studied games in which information was complete,

More information

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly.

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly. will begin next period less effective in deterring a deviation this period. Nonetheless, players can do better than just repeat the Nash equilibrium of the constituent game. 3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely

More information

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1 SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER Milan Horniaček 1 CERGE-EI, Charles University and Academy of Sciences of Czech Republic, Prague We use the requirement of

More information

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria

Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria appearing in Australian Economic Papers, vol. 46(1) Hotelling s Beach with Linear and Quadratic Transportation Costs: Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria Alain Egli University of Bern Abstract In Hotelling

More information

A Stochastic Multiple Leader Stackelberg Model: Analysis, Computation, and Application

A Stochastic Multiple Leader Stackelberg Model: Analysis, Computation, and Application Submitted to Operations Research manuscript OPRE-2006-10-412.R2 A Stochastic Multiple Leader Stackelberg Model: Analysis, Computation, and Application Victor DeMiguel Department of Management Science and

More information

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016 More on strategic games and extensive games with perfect information Block 2 Jun 12, 2016 Food for thought LUPI Many players

More information

A Note on Profitable Mergers. in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model

A Note on Profitable Mergers. in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model Working Paper Series No.80, Faculty of Economics, Niigata University A Note on Profitable Mergers in a Hierarchical Stackelberg Model Kojun Hamada Series No.80 Address: 8050 Ikarashi 2-no-cho, Niigata

More information

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013 SF2972 Game Theory Exam with s March 5, 203 Part A Classical Game Theory Jörgen Weibull and Mark Voorneveld. (a) What are N, S and u in the definition of a finite normal-form (or, equivalently, strategic-form)

More information

QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY

QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY QUANTITY PRECOMMITMENT AND BERTRAND COMPETITION YIELD COURNOT OUTCOMES: A CASE WITH PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION: REPLY XIANGKANG YIN La Trobe University YEW-KWANG NG Monash University Since the publication

More information

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory Nicolas Schutz Nicolas Schutz Game Theory 1 / 43 Introduction Why game theory? In the introductory lecture, we defined Industrial Organization as the economics

More information

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395 ANSWER KEY GAME THEORY, ECON 95 PROFESSOR A. JOSEPH GUSE (1) (Gibbons 1.6) Consider again the Cournot duopoly model with demand given by the marginal willingness to pay function: P(Q) = a Q, but this time

More information

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly Rabah Amir Department of Economics, University of Arizona Giuseppe De Feo y CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain February 2007 Abstract This paper addresses the issue

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 2012

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 2012 Efficiency Loss in a Cournot Oligopoly with Convex Market Demand arxiv:123.6675v1 [math.oc] 29 Mar 212 John N. Tsitsiklis and Yunjian Xu Laboratory or Information and Decision Systems, MIT, Cambridge,

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

REPEATED GAMES. Jörgen Weibull. April 13, 2010

REPEATED GAMES. Jörgen Weibull. April 13, 2010 REPEATED GAMES Jörgen Weibull April 13, 2010 Q1: Can repetition induce cooperation? Peace and war Oligopolistic collusion Cooperation in the tragedy of the commons Q2: Can a game be repeated? Game protocols

More information

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access Tobias Harks 1 and Max Klimm 2 1 Department of Quantitative Economics, Maastricht University, the Netherlands. t.harks@maastrichtuniversity.nl 2 Department

More information

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game Marco Guerrazzi Departmento of Economics, University of Genoa November 0 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/476/ MPRA Paper

More information