A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION"

Transcription

1 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION RAFA L M. LOCHOWSKI, NICOLAS PERKOWSKI, AND DAVID J. PRÖMEL Abstract. Using Vov s outer measure, which corresponds to a minimal superhedging price, the existence of quadratic variation is shown for typical price paths in the space of nonnegative càdlàg functions. In particular, this implies the existence of quadratic variation in the sense of Föllmer quasi surely under all martingale measures. Based on the robust existence of quadratic variation and a certain topology which is induced by Vov s outer measure, model-free Itô integration is developed on the space of continuous paths, of non-negative càdlàg paths and of càdlàg paths with mildly restricted jumps. Keywords: càdlàg path, model-independent finance, quadratic variation, pathwise stochastic calculus, stochastic integration, Vov s outer measure. Mathematics Subject Classification 21): 6H5, 91G Introduction In a recent series of papers [Vov9, Vov12, Vov15], Vov introduced a model-free, hedgingbased approach to mathematical finance that uses arbitrage considerations to examine which path properties are satisfied by typical price paths. For this purpose an outer measure P is introduced, which corresponds to a superhedging price, and a statement A) is said to hold for typical price paths if A) is true except a null set under P. Let us also refer to [SV1] and [TKT9] for related settings. As a nice consequence all results proven for typical price paths hold quasi surely under all martingale measures and even more generally quasi surely under all semimartingale measures for which the coordinate process satisfies the classical condition of no arbitrage of the first ind, also nown as no unbounded profit with bounded ris. Considering typical price paths belonging to the space C[, T ], R d ) of continuous functions, their path properties are already rather well-studied. Vov proved that the path regularity of typical price paths is similar to that of semimartingales see [Vov8]), i.e. non-constant typical price paths have infinite p-variation for p < 2 but finite p-variation for p > 2, and they possess a quadratic variation see [Vov12]). More advanced path properties such as the existence of an associated local time or an Itô rough path were shown in [PP15] and [PP16]. All these results give a robust justification for taing auxiliary properties of continuous semimartingales as an underlying assumption in model-independent finance or mathematical finance under Knightian uncertainty. However, while in financial modeling stochastic processes allowing for jumps play a central role, typical price paths belonging to the space D[, T ], R d ) of càdlàg functions are not Date: September 7, 216. The present wor is a replacement of the technical report [ Loc15] and an unpublished wor the second and third author. 1

2 2 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL well-understood yet. This turns out to be a more delicate business because of particular two reasons: First there exists no canonical extension of Vov s outer measure P to the whole space D[, T ], R d ) as discussed in Remar 2.2 and thus we need to wor with suitable subspaces. Second, the class of admissible strategies gets smaller if the class of possible price trajectories gets bigger. The main motivation of the presented article is to develop a rather complete picture of stochastic Itô integration of adapted càglàd integrands with respect to typical price paths. For this purpose we consider the underlying spaces of continuous functions C[, T ], R d ), of non-negative càdlàg functions D[, T ], R d +), and of càdlàg functions with mildly restrict jumps Ω ψ, that is the subset of all ω D[, T ], R d ) such that ) ωt) ωt ) ψ sup ωs) s [,t), t, T ], where ωt ) := lim s t, s<t ωs) and ψ: R + R + is a fixed non-decreasing function. The financial interpretation of this last space is discussed in detail in [Vov15]. Our first contribution is to prove the existence of quadratic variation for typical nonnegative càdlàg price paths, which is constructed as the uniform limit of discrete versions of the quadratic variation. For the precise result we refer to Theorem 3.2 and Corollary Intuitively, this means that it should be possible to mae an arbitrarily large profit by investing in those paths where the convergence of the discrete quadratic variation fails. Let us emphasize once again that this, in particular, justifies to assume the existence of the quadratic variation in model-free financial mathematics. In the case of continuous paths or càdlàg paths with restricted jumps, the existence of the quadratic variation for typical price paths has been shown by Vov in [Vov12] and [Vov15], respectively. However, the case of non-negative càdlàg paths stayed open as it is rather tricy in the sense that here no short-selling is allowed and therefore a priori the arguments used in [Vov12, Vov15] brea down. The existence of the quadratic variation is not only a crucial ingredient to develop a modelfree Itô integration, it is also a powerful assumption in robust and model-independent financial mathematics since it allows to use Föllmer s pathwise Itô integral [Föl79] and thus to construct f ωs)) dωs) for f C 2 or more generally for path-dependent functionals in the sense of Dupire [Dup9] as shown by Cont and Fournié [CF1]. Föllmer integration has a long history of applications in mathematical finance going as least bac to Bic and Willinger [BW94] and Lyons [Lyo95] and is still a frequently used tool as one can see in many recent wors, e.g. [DOR14, SV15, Rig16] and the references therein. Our second contribution is the development of a model-free Itô integration theory for adapted càglàd integrands with respect to typical price paths, see Theorem 4.2. Compared to the rich list of pathwise constructions of stochastic integrals, e.g. [Bic81], [WT88], [WT89], [Kar95], [Nut12], the presented construction complements the previous wors in three aspects: 1) It wors without any tools from probability theory at all and is entirely based on pathwise superhedging arguments. 2) The non-existence of the Itô integral comes with a natural arbitrage interpretation, that is, it is possible to achieve an arbitrage opportunity of the first ind if the Itô integral does not exist. 3) The model-free Itô integral possesses good continuity estimates in a topology induced by Vov s outer measure P ).

3 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 3 In the case of continuous paths the main ingredient for our construction is a continuity estimate for the pathwise Itô integral of a step function, see Lemma 4.3. This estimate is based on Vov s pathwise Hoeffding inequality [Vov12, Theorem A.1]) and the existence of the quadratic variation. In this context, we recover essentially the results of [PP16, Theorem 3.5]. However, in [PP16] we wored with the uniform topology on the space of integrands while here we are able to strengthen our results and to replace the uniform distance with a rather natural distance that depends only on the integral of the squared integrand against the quadratic variation. In the case of càdlàg paths the constructions of the model-free Itô integral also rely on continuity estimates for the integral of a step functions, see Lemmas 4.5 and 4.7, but this time the estimates require completely different techniques compared to the continuous case. In particular, Vov s pathwise Hoeffding inequality needs to be replaced by a pathwise version of the Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality due to Beiglböc and Siorpaes [BS15], which again taes for granted the existence of the quadratic variation. Organization of the paper. Section 2 introduces Vov s model-free and hedging-based approach to mathematical finance. In Section 3 the existence of quadratic variation for typical non-negative càdlàg price paths is shown. The model-free Itô integration is developed in Section 4. Appendix A collects some auxiliary results concerning Vov s outer measure. Acnowledgment. N.P. and D.J.P. are grateful for the excellent hospitality of the Hausdorff Research Institute for Mathematics HIM), where the wor was partly initiated. D.J.P. gratefully acnowledges financial support of the Swiss National Foundation under Grant No Superhedging and typical price paths Vov s model-free and hedging-based approach to mathematical finance allows for determining sample path properties of typical price paths. For this purpose he introduces a notion of outer measure which is based on purely pathwise arbitrage considerations, see for example [Vov12]. Following a slightly modified framewor as introduced in [PP16, PP15], we briefly set up the notation and definitions. For d N and a real number T, ) we consider the following three different sample) spaces of possible price paths: Ω c := C[, T ], R d ) stands for the space of all continuous functions ω: [, T ] R d. Ω + := D S [, T ], R d +) is the space of all non-negative càdlàg functions ω: [, T ] R d + such that ω) = S for some fixed S R d + and R + := [, ). Ω ψ denotes the subset of all càdlàg functions ω: [, T ] R d such that ) ωt) ωt ) ψ sup ωs), t, T ], s [,t) where ωt ) := lim s t, s<t ωs) and ψ: R + R + is a fixed non-decreasing function. In the subsequent we sometimes just write Ω meaning that it is possible to chose Ω as any of the above sample spaces Ω c, Ω + or Ω ψ. The space of all càdlàg functions ω: [, T ] R d is denoted by D[, T ], R d ). For each t [, T ], Ft is defined to be the smallest σ-algebra Ω that maes all functions ω ωs), s [, t], measurable and F t is defined to be the universal completion of Ft. An event is an element of the σ-algebra F T. Stopping times τ: Ω [, T ] { with respect

4 4 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL to the filtration F t ) t [,T ] and the corresponding σ-algebras F τ are defined as usual. The coordinate process on Ω is denoted by S, i.e. S t ω) := ωt) for ω Ω and t [, T ]. The indicator function of a set A, for A R or A Ω, is denoted by 1 A and for two real vectors x, y R d we write xy = x y for the inner product on R d, ), where denotes the Euclidean norm. Furthermore, we set s t := min{s, t and s t := max{s, t for s, t R +. A process H: Ω [, T ] R d is a simple trading) strategy if there exist a sequence of stopping times = τ < τ 1 <..., and F τn -measurable bounded functions h n : Ω R d, such that for every ω Ω, τ n ω) = τ n+1 ω) =... [, ] from some n on, and such that H t ω) = h n ω)1 τnω),τn+1 ω)]t), t [, T ]. n= Therefore, for a simple strategy H the corresponding integral process H S) t ω) := h n ω) S τn+1 tω) S τn tω)) = h n ω)s τn t,τn+1 tω) n= is well-defined for all ω Ω and all t [, T ]; here we introduced the notation S u,v := S v S u for u, v [, T ]. For λ > a simple strategy H is called strongly) λ-admissible if H S) t ω) λ for all ω Ω and all t [, T ]. The set of strongly λ-admissible simple strategies is denoted by H λ. In the next definition we introduce an outer measure P, which is very similar to the one used by Vov [Vov12], but not quite the same. We refer to [PP16, Section 2.3] for a detailed discussion of the relation between our slightly modified outer measure and the original one due to Vov. Definition 2.1. Vov s outer measure P of a set A Ω is defined as the minimal superhedging price for 1 A, that is { P A) := inf λ > : H n ) n N H λ s.t. ω Ω : lim inf λ + n Hn S) T ω)) 1 A ω). A set A Ω is called a null set if it has outer measure zero. A property P) holds for typical price paths if the set A where P) is violated is a null set. Remar 2.2. Even if it might be desirable to consider the more general sample space Ω = D[, T ], R d ) of all càdlàg functions as possible price paths, there seems to be no natural extension of Vov s outer measure to this setting. Therefore, it is necessary to distinguish between the space Ω ψ of càdlàg functions with mildly restricted jumps and the space Ω + of non-negative càdlàg functions starting from a fixed initial value. Indeed, as in [Vov12, Lemma 4.1] or [PP16, Lemma 2.3], it is straightforward to verify that P fulfills all properties of an outer measure. Lemma 2.3. P is an outer measure, i.e. a non-negative set function defined on the subsets of Ω such that P ) =, P A) P B) for A B Ω, and P n A n ) n P A n) for every sequence of subsets A n ) n N Ω. One of the main reasons why Vov s outer measure P is of such great interest in modelindependent financial mathematics, is that it dominates simultaneously all local martingale measures on the sample space Ω cf. [Vov12, Lemma 6.3] and [PP16, Proposition 2.6]). In other words, a null set under P turns out to be a null set simultaneously under all local martingale measures on Ω. n=

5 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 5 Proposition 2.4. Let P be a probability measure on Ω, F), such that the coordinate process S is a P-local martingale, and let A F T. Then PA) P A). A second reason is that sets with outer measure zero come with a natural arbitrage interpretation from classical mathematical finance. Roughly speaing, a null set leads to a pathwise arbitrage opportunity of the first ind NA1), see [Vov12, p. 564] and [PP16, Lemma 2.4]. Proposition 2.5. A set A Ω is a null set if and only if there exists a constant K, ) and a sequence of K-admissible simple strategies H n ) n N H K such that 1) lim inf n K + Hn S) T ω)) 1 A ω) with the conventions = and 1 =. As the proofs of Proposition 2.4 and Proposition 2.5 wor exactly as in the case of continuous price paths, they are postponed to the Appendix A Auxiliary set function for non-negative paths. In order to prove the existence of the quadratic variation for typical non-negative price paths, we need to introduce a relaxed version of admissibility. Throughout this subsection we only consider Ω + = D S [, T ], R d +). A trading strategy H is called a wealy λ-admissible strategy if H is a simple strategy such that H S) t ω) λ1 + 1 S ρλ H)ω)1 [ρλ H)ω),T ]t)) with 1 := 1,..., 1) R d and H t ω) = H t ω)1 [,ρλ H)ω) T ]t), where ρ λ H)ω) := inf {t [, T ] : H S) t ω) < λ, for all t, ω) [, T ] Ω +, with the conventions inf :=, [, T ] := and S ω) :=. We write G λ for the set of wealy λ-admissible strategies. Expressed verbally, this means that wealy λ-admissible strategies must give a payoff larger than λ at all times, except that they can lose all their previous gains plus λ1 + 1 S t ) through one large jump; however, in that case they must instantly stop trading and may not try to bounce up again. Based on the notion of wea admissibility, we define an auxiliary set function Q via the minimal superhedging price using this lager class of trading strategies. Definition 2.6. The set function Q is given by { QA) := inf λ > : H n ) n N G λ s.t. ω Ω + : lim inf n λ + Hn S) T ω) + λ1 S ρλ H n )ω)1 {ρλ H n )< ω)) 1 A ω) where {ρ λ H n ) < := {ω Ω + : ρ λ H n )ω) <. Remar 2.7. Note that Q is not an outer measure since it fails to be even finitely subadditive. However, it will be a useful tool to show the existence of the quadratic variation for typical non-negative càdlàg price paths, and the following lemma Lemma 2.8) shows that it is nearly subadditive: Q n A n ) P n A n ) n P A n ) S ) n QA n ), for every sequence A n ) n N Ω +. Hence, in the particular case where QA n ) = for all n N we still get the countable subadditivity.,

6 6 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL Lemma 2.8. We have QA) P A) S )QA) for all A Ω +. Proof. The first inequality is clear. For the second one, assume that QA) < λ for A Ω +. Then there exists a sequence G n ) n N G λ such that 2) lim inf n λ + Gn S) T + λ1 S ρλ G n )1 {ρλ G n )< ) 1 A. Then the strategy H n := 1,ρλ G n )]λ1 + G n satisfies for t < ρ λ G n ) λ1 + 1 S ) + H n S) t = λ1 + 1 S ) + G n S) t + λ1 S t S ) λ1 S t, and for t = ρ λ G n ) λ1 + 1 S ) + H n S) ρλ G n ) = λ1 + 1 S ) + G n S) ρλ G n ) + λ1 S ρλ G n ) S ) λ λ1 + 1 S ρλ G n )) + λ1 S ρλ G n ) =, which then extends to ρ λ G n ), T ] because both G n and 1 [,ρλ G n )] vanish on that interval. This implies H n H λ1+1 S ), and moreover from 2) we get lim inf n λ1 + 1 S )+H n S) T ) = lim inf n λ1 + 1 S ) + G n S) T + λ1 S ρλ G n ) T S )) 1 A. Hence, P A) S )λ, which proves our claim. 3. Quadratic variation for non-negative càdlàg price paths The existence of quadratic variation for typical price paths is the crucial ingredient in the construction of model-free Itô integration. While the existence was already proven by Vov in the case of continuous price paths and price paths with mildly restricted jumps see [Vov12] and [Vov15]), the situation for non-negative càdlàg price paths was completely unclear so far. In this section we show that the quadratic variation along suitable sequences of partitions exists for typical non-negative price paths without any restriction on the allowed jumps. We first restrict our considerations to one-dimensional paths and consider Ω + = D S [, T ], R + ). The extension to Ω + = D S [, T ], R d +) for arbitrary d N is given in Subsection 3.1. Definition 3.1. Let n N and let D n := {2 n : Z be the dyadic numbers. For a real-valued càdlàg function ω: [, T ] R its Lebesgue partition π n ω) := {τ n ω) : is given by the sequence of stopping times τ nω)) N inductively defined by and for every N we further set τ n ω) := and D n ω) := supd n, S ω)]), τ n ω) := inf{t [τ 1 n ω), T ] : S τ n ω) 1 ω), S t ω) D n \ {D 1 n ω)), D n ω) := argmin D S τ n 1 ω)ω),s τ n ω)ω) D n \{D 1 n ω)) D S τ n ω)ω), with the convention inf = and u, v := { [u, v] if u v, [v, u] if u > v.

7 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 7 Notice that D nω), N, are F τ n -measurable functions and they are uniquely determined since D nω) is a one-element set for each N. In the following we often just write τ n and π n instead of τ nω) and π n, respectively. Along the sequence of Lebesgue partitions we obtain the existence of quadratic variation for typical non-negative price paths. Theorem 3.2. For typical price paths ω Ω + = D S [, T ], R + ) the discrete quadratic variation 3) Q n t ω) := S τ n tω) S τ n 1 tω)) 2, t [, T ], =1 along the Lebesgue partitions π n ω)) n N converges in the uniform metric to a function [S]ω) D[, T ], R + ). Remar 3.3. Since by [Vov15, Lemma 3] the sequence of partitions π n ) n N is increasing and exhausts Sω), [Vov15, Lemma 2] states that the limit [S]ω) will be a non-decreasing càdlàg function satisfying [S] ω) = and [S] t ω) = S t ω)) 2 for all t, T ] and all ω Ω + for which the convergence in Theorem 3.2 holds. Here we used the notation f t := f t lim s t, s<t f s for f D[, T ], R). In order to prove Theorem 3.2, we first analyze the crossings behavior of typical price paths with respect to the dyadic levels D n. To be more precise, we introduce the number of upcrossings resp. downcrossings) of a function f over an open interval a, b) R. Definition 3.4. Let f: [, T ] R be a càdlàg function, a, b) R be an open non-empty interval and t [, T ]. The number U a,b) t f) of upcrossings of the interval a, b) by the function f during the time interval [, t] is given by n f) := sup sup Ifs i ), ft i )), where U a,b) t Ifs i ), ft i )) := n N s 1 <t 1 < <s n<t n t i=1 { 1 if fs i ) a and ft i ) b, if otherwise. The number D a,b) t f) of downcrossings is analogously defined as the number of upcrossings. For each h > we also introduce the accumulated number of upcrossing resp. downcrossings by U t f, h) := U h,+1)h) t f) and D t f, h) := D h,+1)h) t f). Z Z In order to provide a deterministic inequality in the spirit of Doob s upcrossing lemma, we use the stopping times γ K ω) := inf{t [, T ] : S t ω) K for ω Ω + and K N. Lemma 3.5. Let K N. For each n N, there exists a strongly 1-admissible simple strategy H n H 1 such that 1 + H n S) t γk ω) 2 2n K 2 U t γk ω, 2 n ) for all t [, T ] and every ω Ω + = D S [, T ], R + ).

8 8 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL Proof. Let us start by considering the upcrossings U a,b) t ω) of an interval a, b) [, K]. By buying one unit the first time S t ω) drops below a and selling the next time S t ω) goes above b and continuing in this manner, we obtain a simple strategy H a,b) H a with 4) a + H a,b) S) t ω) b a)u a,b) t ω), t [, T ], ω Ω +. For a formal construction of H a,b) we refer to [Vov15, Lemma 4.5]. Note that we need the non-negativity of the paths in Ω + to guarantee the strong admissibility of H a,b). Set now H n := 2 n K 2 H 2 n,+1)2 n). N, +1)2 n K Since H 2 n,+1)2 n) H 2 n H K for all with + 1)2 n K, we have H n H 1, and 1 + H n S) t ω) 2 2n K 2 U 2 n,+1)2 n ) t ω), t, ω) [, T ] Ω +, N, +1)2 n K which proves the claim because U t γk ω, 2 n ) = N, +1)2 n K U2 n,+1)2 n ) t γ K ω). With this pathwise version of Doob s upcrossing lemma at hand, we can control the number of level crossings of typical non-negative price paths. Corollary 3.6. For typical price paths ω Ω + = D S [, T ], R + ) there exist an Nω) N such that U T ω, 2 n ) n 2 2 2n and D T ω, 2 n ) n 2 2 2n for all n Nω). Proof. Since for each Z, U 2 n,+1)2 n ) t ω) and D 2 n,+1)2 n ) t ω) differ by no more than 1, we have U T ω, 2 n ) D T ω, 2 n ) [, 2 n K] for all n N and for every ω Ω + with sup t [,T ] S t ω) < K. So if we show that P B K ) = for all K N, where B K := m N n m A K,n with { A K,n = ω Ω + : sup S t ω) < K and U T ω, 2 n ) n2 2 2n, t [,T ] 2 then our claim follows from the countable subadditivity of P. But using Lemma 3.5 we immediately obtain that P A K,n ) n 2 2K 2, and since this is summable, it suffices to apply the Borel-Cantelli lemma see Lemma A.1) to see P B K ) =. To prove the convergence of the discrete quadratic variation processes Q n ) n N, we shall show that the sequence Q n ) n N is a Cauchy sequence in the uniform topology on Ω +. For this purpose, we define the auxiliary sequence Z n ) n N by Z n t := Q n t Q n 1 t, t [, T ]. Similarly as in Vov [Vov15], the proof of Theorem 3.2 is based on the sequence of integral processes K n ) n N given by 5) Kt n := n 4 2 2n + n 4 2 n+4 K 2 + Zt n ) 2 Zτ n n t Zτ n 1 n t ) 2, t [, T ], =1

9 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 9 for K N, and the stopping times { 6) σk n := min τ n : Zτ n i n Zτ n i 1 n )2 > n 4 2 2n min {τ n : Zn τ n > K, n N. i=1 The next lemma presents that each K n is indeed an integral process with respect to a wealy admissible simple strategy, cf. [Vov15, Lemma 5]. Lemma 3.7. For each n N and K N, there exists a wealy admissible simple strategy L K,n G n 4 2 2n +n 4 2 n+4 K 2 such that K n γ K σ n K t = n 4 2 2n + n 4 2 n+4 K 2 + L K,n S) t, t [, T ]. Proof. For each K N and each n N [Vov15, Lemma 5] shows the equality for the strategy L K,n t := 1,γK σ n K ] t) 4)Z n τ n S τ n S χ n 1 τ n ) )1 τ n,τ n +1 ] t), t [, T ], where χ n 1 t) := max{τ n 1 : τ n 1 t. Since L K,n is obviously a simple strategy, it remains to prove that L K,n G n 4 2 2n +n 4 2 n+4 K 2. First we observe up to time τ n := max{τ n : τ n < γ K σk n that 7) min t [, τ n ] Kn γ K σ n K t n 4 2 n+4 K 2, which follows directly from the definition of K n and 6). For t τ n, γ K σk n ] notice that 8) S τ n S χ n 1 τ n ) 2 n+2, since we either have τ n π n 1, which implies χ n 1 τ n ) = τ n and S τ n S χ n 1 τ n ) =, or we have τ n / π n 1, which implies 8) as τ n < τ n 1 +1 and S τ n S χ n 1 τ n ) S τ n D n 1 + S χ n 1 τ n ) D n 1 2 n n+1, where is such that χ n 1 τ n ) = τ n 1. Using 8), Z ñ τ n K and S τ n K, we estimate 9) 4Z ñ τ ns τ n S χ n 1 τ n ))S t S τ n) 4K2 n+2 S t S τ n 4K2 n+2 S t + K) n 4 2 n+4 KS t + n 4 2 n+4 K 2, which together with 7) and K K 2 gives us the claimed wea admissibility, L K,n G n 4 2 2n +n 4 2 n+4 K 2. Corollary 3.8. For typical price paths ω Ω + = D S [, T ], R + ) there exist an Nω) N such that K n γ K σ n K t ω) < n 6 2 n, t [, T ], for all n Nω). Proof. Consider the events A n := {ω Ω + : t [, T ] s.t. K nγk σ nk t ω) n 6 2 n, n N. By the Borel-Cantelli lemma see Lemma A.1) the claim follows once we have shown that n P A n) <. To that end, we define the stopping times ρ n := inf {t [, T ] : K n γ K σ n K t n 6 2 n, n N,

10 1 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL so that A n = { ω Ω + : n 6 2 n Kγ n K σk n ρn T ω) 1. Now it follows directly from Lemma 3.7 that QA n ) n 6 2 n n 4 2 2n + n 4 2 n+4 K 2 ) = n 2 2 n + n K 2, which is summable. Since P A n ) 1 + S )QA n ) by Lemma 2.8, the proof is complete. Finally, we have collected all necessary ingredients to prove the main result of this section, namely Theorem 3.2. More precisely, we shall show that Q n Q n 1 ) n N is a Cauchy sequence. This implies Theorem 3.2 since the uniform topology on Ω + is complete. Proof of Theorem 3.2. For K N let us define { A K := ω Ω + : sup S t ω) K and sup Zt n ω) n 3 2 n 2 for infinitely many n N t [,T ] t [,T ] and { B := ω Ω + : Nω) N s.t. Kγ n K σk n t ω) < n 6 2 n, t [, T ], U T ω, 2 n ) n 2 2 2n and D T ω, 2 n ) n 2 2 2n, n Nω). Thans to the countable subadditivity of P it is sufficient to show that P A K ) = for every K N. Moreover, again by the subadditivity of P we see P A K ) P A K B) + P A K B c ). By Corollary 3.6 and Corollary 3.8 it is already nown that P A K B c ) =. In the following we show that A K B =. For this purpose, let us fix an ω B such that sup t [,T ] S t ω) K. Since ω B there exits an Nω) N such that for all m Nω): a) The number of stopping times in π m does not exceed 2m 2 2 2m + 2 3m 2 2 2m. b) The number of stopping times in π m such that S τ m ω) := S τ m ω) lim S s ω) s τ m, s<τ m 2 m+1, τ m π m, is less or equal to 2m 2 2 2m. As sup t [,T ] S t ω) K, notice that γ K ω) = T and that for t [, T ] we have Zτ n +1 n t ω) Zτ n n t ω) = Q n τ+1 n t ω) Q n τ n t ω)) Qτ n 1 +1 n tω) Qn 1 τ n tω)) =S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω)) 2 S τ n +1 tω) S χ n 1 τ n t) ω)) 2 S τ n tω) S χ n 1 τ n t) ω)) 2 ) = 2S τ n tω) S χ n 1 τ n t) ω))s τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω)),

11 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 11 where we recall that χ n 1 t) := max{τ n 1 : τ n 1 t. Therefore, eeping 8) in mind, the infinite sum in 5) can be estimated by 2 Zτ n +1 n t ω) Zτ ω)) n n t = 4 S τ n tω) S χ n 1 τ n t) ω)) 2 S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω)) 2 = 1) = 2 6 2n S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω)) 2. = For n N = Nω) and t [, T ] we observe for the summands in 1) the following bounds, which are similar to the bounds A)-E) in the proof of [Vov15, Theorem 1]: 1) If τ+1 n / π n 1, then one has χ n 1 τ+1 n ) = χn 1 τ n) = τ n 1 for some and thus S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω) S τ n +1 tω) D n 1 + S τ n tω) D n n. The number of such summands is at most 3n 2 2 2n. 2) If τ n +1 π n 1 and S τ n +1 2 n+1, then one has S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω) 2 1 n + 2 n+1 = 2 2 n and the number of such summands is at most 3n 2 2 2n. 3) If τ n +1 π n 1 and S τ n +1 [2 m+1, 2 m+2 ), for some m {N, N + 1,..., n than one has that S τ n +1 tω) S τ n tω) 2 1 n + 2 m+2. and the number of such summands is at most 2m 2 2 2m. 4) If τ n +1 π n 1 and S τ n +1 2 N+2, then one has S τ n +1 tω) S τ n ω) t K and the number of such summand is bounded by a constant C = Cω, K) independent of n. Using the bounds derived in 1)-4), the estimate 1) can be continued by ) 2 Zτ n +1 n t ω) Zτ n n t ω) = 2 6 2n 6n 2 2 2n 2 4 2n + n m=n 2m 2 2 2m 2 1 n + 2 m+2 ) 2 + CK 2 ), and thus there exists an Ñ = Ñω) N such that 2 Zτ n +1 n t ω) Zτ ω)) n n t 2 2n n 4, t [, T ], = for all n Ñ. Combining the last estimate with the definition of Kn cf. 5)), we obtain K n σ n K t ω) Z n σ n K t ω)) 2, t [, T ], for all n Ñ. Moreover, by assumption on ω one has K n σ n K t ω) < n 6 2 n, t [, T ],

12 12 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL for all n N Ñ. In particular, we conclude that sup t [,T ] Zσ n K n γ ω) < K whenever n K t is large enough and thus n 6 2 n > Zt n ω)) 2, t [, T ], for all sufficiently large n. Finally, we have sup t [,T ] Zt n ω) < n 3 2 n 2 for all large n and therefore ω / A K B. Remar 3.9. The existence of quadratic variation in the sense of Theorem 3.2 is equivalent to the existence of quadratic variation in the sense of Föllmer see [Vov15, Proposition 3]). Therefore, Theorem 3.2 opens the door to apply Föllmer s pathwise Itô formula [Föl79] for typical non-negative price paths and in particular to define the pathwise integral f S s ) ds s for f C 2 or more general for path-dependent functionals as shown by Cont and Fournié [CF1], Imeller and Prömel [IP15], and Ananova and Cont [AC16] Extension to multi-dimensional price paths. In order to extend the existence of quadratic variation from one-dimensional to multi-dimensional typical price paths, we consider the sample space Ω + = D[, T ], R d +) and introduce a d-dimensional version of the Lebesgue partitions for d N. Definition 3.1. For n N and a d-dimensional càdlàg function ω: [, T ] R d its Lebesgue partition π n ω) := {τ nω) : is iteratively defined by τ n ω) := and d τ n ω) := min { τ > τ n 1 ω) : τ d i=1 π n ω i ) i,j=1,i j π n ω i + ω j ), N, where ω = ω 1,..., ω d ) and π n ω i ) and π n ω i + ω j ) are the Lebesgue partitions of ω i and ω i + ω j as introduced in Definition 3.1, respectively. To state the existence of quadratic variation for typical price paths in Ω +, we define the canonical projection on Ω + by S i tω) = ω i t) for ω = ω 1,..., ω d ) Ω +, t [, T ] and i = 1,..., d. Corollary Let d N and 1 i, j d. For typical price paths ω Ω + = D[, T ], R d +) the discrete quadratic variation Q i,j,n t ω) := Sτ i n t ω) Sτ i 1 n t ω))s j τ n tω) Sj τ 1 n tω)), t [, T ], =1 converges along the Lebesgue partitions π n ω)) n N in the uniform metric to a function [S i, S j ]ω) D[, T ], R + ). Proof. To show the convergence of Q i,j,n ω) for a path ω Ω +, we observe that 1 2 Si tω) + S j t ω)) Si sω) + S j sω))) 2 S i tω) S i sω)) 2 S j t ω) Sj sω)) 2 ) = S i tω) S i sω))s j t ω) Sj sω)), s, t [, T ], and thus it is sufficient to prove the existence of the quadratic variation of S i ω) and S i ω) + S j ω) for 1 i, j d with i j. For typical price paths this can be done precisely as in the proof of Theorem 3.2 with the only exception that the bounds a)-b) and 1)-4) change by a multiplicative constant depending only on the dimension d.

13 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION Model-free Itô integration The ey problem of stochastic integration with respect to typical price paths is, unsurprisingly, that they are not of bounded variation. The model-free Itô integral presented in this section is a pathwise construction and comes with two natural interpretations in financial mathematics: in the case of existence the integral has a natural interpretation as the capital process of an adapted trading strategy and the set of paths where the integral does not exists allows for a model-free arbitrage opportunity of the first ind cf. Proposition 2.5). Roughly speaing, the construction of the model-free Itô integral is based on the existence of the quadratic variation for typical price paths and on an application of the pathwise Hoeffding inequality due to Vov [Vov12] in the case of continuous price trajectories, and of the pathwise Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality due to Beiglböc and Siorpaes [BS15] in the case of price paths with jumps. Similarly as in classical stochastic integration, first we define the Itô integral for simple integrands and extend it via an approximation scheme to a larger class of integrands. Our simple integrands are the step functions: A process F : Ω [, T ] R d is called step function if F is of the form 11) F t := F 1 { t) + F σi 1 σi,σ i+1 ]t), t [, T ], i= where σ i ) i N is an increasing sequence of stopping times such that for each ω Ω there exists an Nω) N with σ i ω) = σ i+1 ω) for all i Nω), F R d and F σi : Ω R d is F σi -measurable. For such a step function F the corresponding integral process is well-defined for all ω Ω and is given by 12) F S) t := F σi S σi t,σ i+1 t, t [, T ]. i= Throughout the whole section we denote by π n ω)) n N the sequence of Lebesgue partitions consisting of the stopping times τ n ω)) N as introduced in Definition 3.1 for ω Ω, and the quadratic variation matrix of ω along π n ω)) n N is given by [S] t ω) := [S i, S j ] t ω)) 1 i,j d, t [, T ], where we recall that S i tω) := ω i t) for ω = ω 1,..., ω d ) and we refer to Corollary 3.11 for the definition of [S i, S j ] t ω). Recall that if the quadratic variation exists as a uniform limit, then it exists also in the sense of Föllmer along the same sequence of partitions see [Vov15, Proposition 3]). Hence, t F 2 s d[s] s := d i,j=1 t F i sf j s d[s i, S j ] s := lim inf n = i,j=1 t [, T ], is actually a true limit for typical price paths. d Fτ i nf j τ n Sτ i n t,τ +1 n t S j τ n t,τ +1 n t, Remar 4.1. The existence of quadratic variation along the Lebesgue partitions is ensured for typical price paths belonging to the path spaces Ω {Ω c, Ω +, Ω ψ under consideration. Indeed, in the case of Ω + we refer to Corollary 3.11 and the existence results in the case of Ω c and Ω ψ were established by Vov [Vov12, Lemma 8.1] and [Vov15, Theorem 2]).

14 14 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL In the following we identify two functionals X, Y : Ω [, T ] R d if for typical price paths we have X t = Y t for all t [, T ], and we write L R d ) for the resulting space of equivalence classes which is equipped with the distance 13) d X, Y ) := E[ X Y 1], where f := sup t [,T ] ft) for f: [, T ] R d denotes the supremum norm and E denotes an expectation operator defined for Z: Ω [, ] by { E[Z] := inf λ > : H n ) n N H λ s.t. ω Ω : lim inf λ + n Hn S) T ω)) Zω). As in [PP16, Lemma 2.11] it can be shown that L R d ), d ) is a complete metric space and DR d ), d ) is a closed subspace, where DR d ) are those functionals in L R d ) which have a càdlàg representative. The main result of this section is the following meta-theorem about model-free Itô integration. Theorem 4.2. Let Ω {Ω c, Ω +, Ω ψ. Then there exists a complete metric space H, d H ) such that the equivalence classes of) step functions are dense in H and such that the map F F S), defined for step functions in 12), has a continuous extension that maps from H, d H ) to DR), d ). Moreover, H contains at least the càglàd adapted processes and if F n ) H is a sequence such that sup ω Ω F n ω) F ω), then there exists a subsequence F n ) with lim F n S)ω) F S)ω) = for typical price paths ω. To prove this theorem, we will derive in the following subsections suitable continuity estimates for the integrals of step functions. Given these continuity estimates, the proof of Theorem 4.2 follows directly by approximating general integrands by step functions Integration for continuous paths. In this subsection we focus on the sample space Ω c = C[, T ], R d ) consisting of continuous paths ω: [, T ] R d. The existence of the quadratic variation along the Lebesgue partitions for typical continuous price paths is ensured by [Vov12, Lemma 8.1] or [Vov15, Theorem 2]. We recover essentially the results of [PP16, Theorem 3.5] and are able to construct our integral for càglàd adapted integrands. However, in [PP16] we wored with the uniform topology on the space of integrands while here we are able to strengthen our results and to replace the uniform distance with a rather natural distance that depends only on the integral of the squared integrand against the quadratic variation. We are able to show that the closure of the step functions in this new distance contains the càglàd adapted processes. However, in principle this closure might contain a wider class of integrands. The main ingredient in our construction is the following continuity estimate for the pathwise stochastic integral of a step function. It is based on Vov s pathwise Hoeffding inequality. Lemma 4.3 Model-free concentration of measure, continuous version). Let F : Ω c [, T ] R d be a step function. Then we have for all a, b > P { F S) a { T ) b Fs 2 d[s] s b 2 exp a 2 /2).

15 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 15 Proof. Let F t = F 1 t) + m= F m1 σm,σ m+1 ]t). For n N we define the stopping times ζ n :=, ζ n +1 := inf{t ζn : F S) ζ n,t = 2 n, and also τ n :=, τ n +1 := inf{t τ n : S τ n,t = 2 n. We then write ρ n :=, ρ n +1 := inf{t > ρn : t = ζ2n i or t = τ n i or t = σ i for some i for the union of the ζ 2n) and τ n) and σ m ) m. By definition of the times ρ n ) we have sup F S) ρ n t,ρ n +1 t 2 2n t [,T ] and F is constant on ρ n, ρn +1 ] for all, and therefore Vov s pathwise Hoeffding inequality, [Vov12, Theorem A.1] or [PP16, Lemma A.1], gives us for every λ R a strongly 1-admissible simple strategy H λ,n H 1 such that 14) 1 + H λ,n S) t exp λf S) t λ2 2 ) 2 4n 1 {ρ n t Next, observe that for all i = 1,..., d sup Sρ i n1 [ρ n,ρn +1 ) t) St i 2 n, t [,T ] = = =: E λ,n t, t [, T ]. so since 2 n decays faster than logarithmically, [PP16, Corollary 3.6] shows that for typical price paths we have for i, j = 1,..., d lim sup Sρ i n t,ρn +1 t S j ρ n t,ρn +1 t [Si, S j ] t =, n t [,T ] = and using that F ω) is piecewise constant for all ω Ω c, we also get 15) lim sup t Fρ i n F j + ρ n Sρ i n + t,ρn +1 t S j ρ n t,ρn +1 t FsF i s j d[s i, S j ] s = n t [,T ] = for typical price paths, where Fρ i n is simply the value that F i attains on ρ n +, ρn +1 ]. We proceed by estimating for 2 2n F S) ρ n,ρ n n 1 {ρ n or ρ n +1 =τ n i or σ i for some i, which together with 15) leads to lim sup 2 4n 1 {ρ n n t lim sup F S) ρ n t,ρ n +1 n t 2 = = = lim sup n = t F 2 s n { : σ t + { : τ n t ) ) = i,j=1 d Fρ i n F j + ρ n +Sρ i n t,ρn +1 t S j ρ n t,ρn +1 t n { : τ n t ) d[s] s + lim sup 3 2 4n { : τ n t n

16 16 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL for typical price paths. For typical price paths we also have lim n 2 2n { : τ n t = d i=1 [Si, S i ] t, and consequently 16) lim sup n 2 4n 1 {ρ n t = t F 2 s d[s] s, t [, T ]. Plugging 16) into 14), we get for typical price paths on the set { F S) a b { T d[s] s b that F s 2 lim inf n sup E λ,n t t [,T ] + E λ,n t exp λa ) b λ2 2 b. Taing λ = a/ b, the right hand side becomes 1/2 expa 2 /2). Our claim then follows from [PP16, Remar 2.2] which states that it suffices to superhedge with the time-supremum rather than at the terminal time. Remar 4.4. No part of the proof was based on the fact that we are in a finite-dimensional setting, and the same arguments extend without problems to the case where we have a countable number of assets S i ) i N or even an uncountable number S i ) i I but an integrand F with F i only for countably many i I which is needed to have d[s] s well-defined). F s 2 Our next aim is to extend the stochastic integral from step functions to more general integrands. For that purpose we define H 2 := { F : Ω c [, T ] R d : T Fs 2 d[s] s < for typical price paths, we identify F, G H 2 if T F s G s ) 2 d[s] s = for typical price paths, and we write H 2 for the space of equivalence classes, which we equip with the distance [ T ] 17) d QV F, G) := E F t G t ) 2 d[s] t 1. Arguing as in [PP16, Lemma 2.11] it is straightforward to show that H 2, d QV ) is a complete metric space. If now F and G are step functions, for any ε, δ > we obtain from Lemma 4.3 the following estimate d F S), G S)) P F G) S) ε) + ε { T ) P { F G) S) ε F t G t ) 2 d[s] t δ T ) + P F t G t ) 2 d[s] t > δ + ε ) 2 exp ε2 + d QVF, G) + ε. 2δ δ Hence, setting δ := d QV F, G) 2/3 and ε := δ log δ we get d F S), H S)) 2δ 1/2 + d QV F, G) 1/3 + δ log δ d QV F, G) 1/3 logd QV F, G)).

17 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 17 So we can extend the stochastic integral to the closure of the step functions in H 2, d QV ). Since we do not understand this closure very well we introduce a localized version of d QV, as in [PP16]: For c > we define [ T ) ] 18) d QV,c F, G) := E F t G t ) 2 d[s] t 1 1 { [S] T c, where we wrote [S] T := d i,j=1 [Si, S j ] 2 T )1/2. We also set 19) d,c F, G) := E[ F G 1)1 { [S] T c]. Then the same computation as before shows that d,c F S), H S)) d QV,c F, G) 1/3 logd QV,c F, G)) for all step functions F and G and all c >. From here the same approximation scheme as in [PP16, Theorem 3.5] shows that the closure of the step functions in the metric d QV,loc := n 2 n d QV,n 1) contains at least the càglàd adapted processes Integration for non-negative càdlàg paths. The construction of model-free Itô integrals with respect to càdlàg price paths requires different techniques compared to those used in Subsection 4.1 for continuous price paths. While there, using the Lebesgue stopping times, we had a very precise control of the fluctuations of continuous price paths, this is not possible anymore in the presence of jumps as now price paths could have a big jump at any time. In particular, this prevents us from applying Vov s pathwise Hoeffding inequality. Here we consider the sample space Ω + = D S [, T ], R d ) of non-negative càdlàg paths starting from S R d +. Based on the pathwise Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality due to Beiglböc and Siorpaes [BS15], we obtain the following model-free bound on the magnitude of the pathwise stochastic integral. Lemma 4.5 Integral estimate, non-negative càdlàg version). For a step function F : Ω + [, T ] R d and for a, b, c > one has { T ) Q { F S) a Ft 2 d[s] t b { F c 6 b + 2c, a where Q denotes the set function of Definition 2.6. As a foundation for the proof let us briefly recall the pathwise version of the Burholder- Davis-Gundy inequality [BS15, Theorem 2.1]: If n N, =,..., n, x R and x := max l x l, then n 1 2) max x ) 1 6 x 2 + x +1 x h x)n, n where = n 1 21) h x) n := h x +1 x ) with h := = x [x] + x) )2 and with the convention =. With this purely deterministic inequality at hand we are ready to prove Lemma 4.5.

18 18 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL Proof of Lemma 4.5. Let F : Ω + [, T ] R d be a step function of the form 11), i.e. F t := F 1 { t) + F σi 1 σi,σ i+1 ]t), t [, T ], i= for some sequence of stopping times σ i ) i N. For n N we recall that τj n) j N is the sequence of Lebesgue stopping times defined in Definition 3.1 and denote by ρ n ) N the union of σ i ) i N and τj n) j N with redundancies deleted. Setting ρ n := max{σn l σl n) l N : σl n τ n for N, it is straightforward to see that F t = Ft n := F 1 { t) + F ρ n 1 ρ n,ρ n +1 ] t), t [, T ], and thus F S) t = F σi S σi t,σ i+1 t = i= = F ρ n S ρ n t,ρ n +1 t = F n S) t, t [, T ]. = In order to apply the pathwise Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality 2), we define iteratively x n := and x n +1 := xn + F ρ S ρ n T,ρ n +1 T, N, and therefore 2) yields ) 1 sup x = sup F S) ρ n T 6 F ρ n S ρ n T,ρ n +1 N N ) hn x) T. = Due to the definition of the Lebesgue stopping times τj n) j N, this leads to the continuous time estimate d ) 1 sup F n S) t 6 Fρ ĩ nf j ρ n Sρ i n t [,T ] T,ρn +1 T S j 2 ρ + n T,ρn +1 T 2φn S) T + F 2 n = i,j=1 where F = F 1,..., F d ) and φ n is the adapted simple trading strategy given by the position φ n := hn F ρ n with hn defined as in 21). To turn φn into a wealy admissible strategy, we introduce the stopping time { d ϑ n := inf t : Fρ ĩ nf j ρ n Sρ i n T,ρn +1 T S j ρ n T,ρn +1 T > b inf{t : F t c T = i,j=1 for n N. Thus, we have sup F n S) t t [,ϑ n ] 6 d = i,j=1 ) 1 Fρ ĩ nf j ρ n Sρ i 2 n ϑn,ρ n +1 ϑnsj ρ n ϑn,ρ + n 21[,ϑ +1 ϑn n ]φ n S) T + c2 n and in particular 1 [,ϑ n ]2φ n is wealy 6 b+2 n c+2c)-admissible since φ n F for every n N. Taing the limit inferior as n, one gets T ) 1 lim inf sup F S) t 6 F 2 2 n t d[s] t + 2 lim inf 1 [,ϑ t [,ϑ n ] n n ]φ n S) T.

19 A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 19 Hence, we deduce { T Q { F S) a ) Ft 2 d[s] t b { F c 6 b + 2c. a Corollary 4.6. For a, b, c > and any step function F : Ω + R d one has P { F S) a { F c { [S] T b) S ) 6 b + 2)c, a where we recall that 1 = 1,..., 1) R d and [S] T = d i,j=1 [Si, S j ] 2 T )1/2. Proof. Using the monotonicity of P, Lemma 2.8 and the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, we get P { F S) a { F c { [S] T b) { T ) P { F S) a Ft 2 d[s] t bc 2 { F c { T ) S )Q { F S) a Ft 2 d[s] t bc 2 { F c. Combing this estimate with Lemma 4.5 gives the assertion. As in 13) and 19) we introduce the pseudo-)distances d and d,c on the equivalence classes) of processes from Ω + [, T ] to R d. For two step functions F and G and a, b, c > Corollary 4.6 gives d,b F S), G S)) P { F G) S) a { [S] T b) + a P { F G) S) a { F G c { [S] T b) + P { F G c { [S] T b) + a S ) 6 b + 2)c a Setting a := d,b F, G) 1 3 and c := d,b F, G) 2 3 leads to + 1 c d,bf, G) + a. 22) d,b F S), G S)) S )6 b + 4)d,b F, G) 1 3. Based on this observation we can use the same ideas as in [PP16, pp ] to construct the model-free Itô integral of càglàd integrands with respect to non-negative price paths Integration for paths with mildly restricted jumps. In this subsection we consider the space Ω ψ of càdlàg paths with mildly restricted jumps, which completes the picture of Itô integration with respect to typical price paths. For this purpose we again establish a modelfree bound for the integrals against step functions, which can be seen as the counterpart to Lemma 4.5 and its proof also replies on the pathwise Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality due to Beiglböc and Siorpaes [BS15].

20 2 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL Lemma 4.7 Integral estimate, càdlàg version for mildly restricted jumps). Let F : Ω ψ [, T ] R d be a step function. For a, b, m, M > the following estimate holds { T P { F S) a ) Ft 2 d[s] t b { F m { S M 6 a 2b + 2m2 ψm) 2. Proof. The proof goes along the same lines as the proof of Lemma 4.5 and thus we eep it very short. Let F : Ω ψ [, T ] R d be a step function of the form 11). For n N we recall that τj n) j N is the sequence of Lebesgue stopping times as defined in Definition 3.1 and denote by ρ n ) N the union of σ i ) i N and τj n) j N with redundancies deleted. Setting ρ n := max{σn l σl n) l N : σl n τ n for N, it is straightforward to see that F t = F n t := F 1 t) + F ρ n 1 ρ n,ρ n +1 ] t), t [, T ]. = Now let us define the following stopping time τ n b,m,m := inf {t : F ρ n j S ρ n j t,ρ n j+1 t ) 2 b or S t M or F t m T. j= Using the pathwise Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality 2) we get ) 1/2 sup F n S) t 6 F ρ n t [,τb,m,m n ] S ρ n j τb,m,m n ρn j+1 τ b,m,m n )2 + 2φ n 1 [,τ n b,m ] S) T j= for some sequence of simple trading strategies φ n ) n N. From the definition of τb,m,m n and the fact that S τ n b,m,m ψm) we see that the strategy 2φ n 1 [,τ n b,m,m ] is 62b + 2m 2 ψm) 2 ) 1/2 - admissible. Proceeding to the limit, similarly as in the proof of Lemma 4.5, completes the proof. Corollary 4.8. For a, b, m, M > and any step function F : Ω ψ [, T ] R d one has P { F S) a { [S] T b { F m { S M) 6m a 2b + 2ψM) 2, where we recall that [S] T := d i,j=1 [Si, S j ] 2 T )1/2. As in 13) and 19) we introduce the pseudo-)distance d on the space of equivalence classes) of adapted processes from Ω ψ [, T ] to R d and set d c,m X, Y ) := E[ X Y 1)1 Ωc,M ] for c, M > and Ω c,m := { [S] T c and S M.

21 From Corollary 4.8 we get A SUPERHEDGING APPROACH TO STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION 21 d c,m F S), G S)) P { F G) S) a Ω c,m ) + a P { F G) S) a { F G m Ω c,m ) + P { F G) S) a { F G m Ω c,m ) + a 6m 2c + 2ψM) a 2 + d c,mf, G) + a m for step functions F, G and a, c, m, M >. Setting we deduce that 23) a := d c,m F, G) 1/3 and m := d c,m F, G) 2/3, d c,m F S), G S)) 6 2c + 2ψM) 2 + 2)d c,m F, G) 1/3. Based on this observation we can again extent the construction of the model-free Itô integral from simple integrands to càglàd integrands with respect to typical càdlàg price paths with mildly restricted jumps. Notice, that we cannot simply tae c = M for the extension since ψ could grow arbitrarily fast. Remar 4.9. In the very recent wor [Vov16] Vov introduces a slightly generalized version of the space Ω ψ which allows to have two independent predicable bounds for the jumps of possible price paths, i.e. a bound for jumps going upwards and a second bound for jumps going downwards. In his note, Vov also obtains the convergence of non-anticipating Riemann sums along a fixed sequence of partitions, which thus results in a model-free Itô integral. However, this construction currently provides only a preliminary version of stochastic integration in a model-free stetting since it might depend on the sequence of partitions and no continuity estimates are given. Furthermore, it wors with different techniques compared to the present wor. Appendix A. Properties of Vov s outer measure This appendix collects postponed proofs from the previous sections and an elementary result Borel-Cantelli lemma) which was used for the construction of the quadratic variation and the model-free Itô integrals. Proof of Proposition 2.4. Let λ > and let H n ) n N H λ be such that lim inf n λ + H n S) T ) 1 A. Then PA) E P [lim infλ + H n S) T )] lim inf E P [λ + H n S) T ] λ, n n where in the last step we used that λ + H n S) is a non-negative càdlàg P-local martingale with E P [ λ + H n S) ] < and thus a P-supermartingale. Proof of Proposition 2.5. If P A) =, then for every n N there exists a sequence of simple strategies H n,m ) m N H 2 n 1 such that 2 n 1 + lim inf m H n,m S) T ω) 1 A ω) for all ω Ω. For K, ) set G m := K m n= Hn,m, and thus G m H K. For every N one gets lim inf m K + Gm S) T ) 2 n 1 K + lim inf m Hn,m S) T ) + 1)K1 A. n= Because the left hand side does not depend on, the sequence G m ) satisfies 1).

22 22 LOCHOWSKI, PERKOWSKI, AND PRÖMEL Conversely, if there exist a constant K, ) and a sequence of K-admissible simple strategies H n ) n N H K satisfying 1), then we can scale it down by an arbitrary factor ε > to obtain a sequence of strategies in H ε that superhedge 1 A, which implies P A) =. As the proof of the classical Borel-Cantelli lemma requires only countable subadditivity, Vov s outer measure allows for a version of the Borel-Cantelli lemma. Lemma A.1. Let A j ) j N Ω be a sequence of events. If j=1 P A j) <, then ) P A j lim inf P ) A j lim inf P A j ) =. i i i=1 j=i j=i References [AC16] Anna Ananova and Rama Cont, Pathwise integration with respect to paths of finite quadratic variation, Preprint arxiv: ). [Bic81] Klaus Bichteler, Stochastic Integration and L p -Theory of Semimartingales, Ann. Probab. 1981), [BS15] Mathias Beiglböc and Pietro Siorpaes, Pathwise versions of the Burholder-Davis-Gundy inequality, Bernoulli ), no. 1, [BW94] Avi Bic and Walter Willinger, Dynamic spanning without probabilities, Stochastic Process. Appl. [CF1] ), no. 2, Rama Cont and David-Antoine Fournié, Change of variable formulas for non-anticipative functionals on path space, J. Funct. Anal ), no. 4, [DOR14] Mar Davis, Jan Ob lój, and Vimal Raval, Arbitrage bounds for prices of weighted variance swaps, Math. Finance ), no. 4, [Dup9] Bruno Dupire, Functional Itô calculus, Bloomberg portfolio research paper 29), no [Föl79] Hans Föllmer, Calcul d Itô sans probabilités, Séminaire de Probabilités XV ), [IP15] Peter Imeller and David J. Prömel, Existence of Lévy s area and pathwise integration, Commun. Stoch. Anal ), no. 1, [Kar95] Rajeeva L. Karandiar, On pathwise stochastic integration, Stochastic Process. Appl ), no. 1, [ Loc15] Rafa l M. Lochowsi, Integration with respect to model-free price paths with jumps, Preprint arxiv: v2 215). [Lyo95] Terry J. Lyons, Uncertain volatility and the ris-free synthesis of derivatives, Appl. Math. Finance ), no. 2, [Nut12] Marcel Nutz, Pathwise construction of stochastic integrals, Electron. Commun. Probab ), no. 24, 1 7. [PP15] Nicolas Perowsi and David J. Prömel, Local times for typical price paths and pathwise Tanaa formulas, Electron. J. Probab. 215), no. 46, [PP16], Pathwise stochastic integrals for model free finance, Bernoulli ), no. 4, [Rig16] Candia Riga, A pathwise approach to continuous-time trading, Peprint arxiv: ). [SV1] Glenn Shafer and Vladimir Vov, Probability and finance, Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics. Financial Engineering Section, Wiley-Interscience, New Yor, 21, It s only a game! [SV15] Alexander Schied and Iryna Voloshcheno, Pathwise no-arbitage in a class of Delta hedging strategies, Peprint arxiv: ). [TKT9] Kei Taeuchi, Masayui Kumon, and Aimichi Taemura, A new formulation of asset trading games [Vov8] in continuous time with essential forcing of variation exponent, Bernoulli 15 29), no. 4, Vladimir Vov, Continuous-time trading and the emergence of volatility, Electron. Commun. Probab ), [Vov9], Continuous-time trading and the emergence of randomness, Stochastics 81 29), no. 5, [Vov12], Continuous-time trading and the emergence of probability, Finance Stoch ), no. 4, j=i

Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance

Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance Recent results in game theoretic mathematical finance Nicolas Perkowski Humboldt Universität zu Berlin May 31st, 2017 Thera Stochastics In Honor of Ioannis Karatzas s 65th Birthday Based on joint work

More information

On pathwise stochastic integration

On pathwise stochastic integration On pathwise stochastic integration Rafa l Marcin Lochowski Afican Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Warsaw School of Economics UWC seminar Rafa l Marcin Lochowski (AIMS, WSE) On pathwise stochastic

More information

Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals

Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals Marcel Nutz First version: August 14, 211. This version: June 12, 212. Abstract We propose a method to construct the stochastic integral simultaneously under

More information

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Title Author(s) Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 4() P.493-P.54 Issue Date 3-6 Text

More information

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes BMS Basic Course Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III Michael Scheutzow Lecture Notes Technische Universität Berlin Sommersemester 218 preliminary version October 12th 218 Contents

More information

Stochastic calculus without probability: Pathwise integration and functional calculus for functionals of paths with arbitrary Hölder regularity

Stochastic calculus without probability: Pathwise integration and functional calculus for functionals of paths with arbitrary Hölder regularity Stochastic calculus without probability: Pathwise integration and functional calculus for functionals of paths with arbitrary Hölder regularity Rama Cont Joint work with: Anna ANANOVA (Imperial) Nicolas

More information

Game-theoretic probability in continuous time

Game-theoretic probability in continuous time Game-theoretic probability in continuous time Vladimir Vovk Department of Computer Science Royal Holloway, University of London Workshop on game-theoretic probability and related topics February 28, 2008

More information

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales Prakash Balachandran Department of Mathematics Duke University April 2, 2008 1 Review of Discrete-Time

More information

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Stochastic Processes Winter Term 2016-2017 Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik Contents 1 Preliminaries 5 1.1 Uniform integrability.............................. 5 1.2

More information

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1)

n [ F (b j ) F (a j ) ], n j=1(a j, b j ] E (4.1) 1.4. CONSTRUCTION OF LEBESGUE-STIELTJES MEASURES In this section we shall put to use the Carathéodory-Hahn theory, in order to construct measures with certain desirable properties first on the real line

More information

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration Sebastian Ferrando, Department of Mathematics, Ryerson University, Toronto, Canada Alfredo Gonzalez and Sebastian Ferrando Trajectorial

More information

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Probability Surveys Vol. 3 (26) 345 412 ISSN: 1549-5787 DOI: 1.1214/1549578614 An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes Ashkan Nikeghbali ETHZ Departement Mathematik, Rämistrasse 11, HG G16

More information

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Lecture 21: Representations of Martingales 1 of 11 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales Right-continuous inverses Let

More information

arxiv: v3 [math.pr] 5 Jun 2011

arxiv: v3 [math.pr] 5 Jun 2011 arxiv:0905.0254v3 [math.pr] 5 Jun 2011 Lévy s zero-one law in game-theoretic probability Glenn Shafer, Vladimir Vovk, and Akimichi Takemura The Game-Theoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper

More information

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, 2014 1 Introduction Definition. If A, B are sets and there exists a bijection A B, they have the same cardinality, which we write as A, #A. If there exists

More information

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries

Chapter 1. Measure Spaces. 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets Notation and preliminaries Chapter 1 Measure Spaces 1.1 Algebras and σ algebras of sets 1.1.1 Notation and preliminaries We shall denote by X a nonempty set, by P(X) the set of all parts (i.e., subsets) of X, and by the empty set.

More information

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann

Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Mathematical finance (extended from lectures of Fall 2012 by Martin Schweizer transcribed by Peter Gracar and Thomas Hille) Josef Teichmann Contents Chapter 1. Arbitrage Theory 5 1. Stochastic Integration

More information

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij Stochastic integration P.J.C. Spreij this version: April 22, 29 Contents 1 Stochastic processes 1 1.1 General theory............................... 1 1.2 Stopping times...............................

More information

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions

Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Supermartingales as Radon-Nikodym Densities and Related Measure Extensions Nicolas Perkowski Institut für Mathematik Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Johannes Ruf Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance

More information

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Brownian motion Samy Tindel Purdue University Probability Theory 2 - MA 539 Mostly taken from Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus by I. Karatzas and S. Shreve Samy T. Brownian motion Probability Theory

More information

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing.

5 Measure theory II. (or. lim. Prove the proposition. 5. For fixed F A and φ M define the restriction of φ on F by writing. 5 Measure theory II 1. Charges (signed measures). Let (Ω, A) be a σ -algebra. A map φ: A R is called a charge, (or signed measure or σ -additive set function) if φ = φ(a j ) (5.1) A j for any disjoint

More information

SUPERMARTINGALES AS RADON-NIKODYM DENSITIES AND RELATED MEASURE EXTENSIONS

SUPERMARTINGALES AS RADON-NIKODYM DENSITIES AND RELATED MEASURE EXTENSIONS Submitted to the Annals of Probability SUPERMARTINGALES AS RADON-NIKODYM DENSITIES AND RELATED MEASURE EXTENSIONS By Nicolas Perkowski and Johannes Ruf Université Paris Dauphine and University College

More information

A Direct Proof of the Bichteler-Dellacherie Theorem and Connections to Arbitrage

A Direct Proof of the Bichteler-Dellacherie Theorem and Connections to Arbitrage A Direct Proof of the Bichteler-Dellacherie Theorem and Connections to Arbitrage Bezirgen Veliyev, University of Vienna (joint with Mathias Beiglböck and Walter Schachermayer) August 23, 2010 Paris, European

More information

FOUNDATIONS OF MARTINGALE THEORY AND STOCHASTIC CALCULUS FROM A FINANCE PERSPECTIVE

FOUNDATIONS OF MARTINGALE THEORY AND STOCHASTIC CALCULUS FROM A FINANCE PERSPECTIVE FOUNDATIONS OF MARTINGALE THEORY AND STOCHASTIC CALCULUS FROM A FINANCE PERSPECTIVE JOSEF TEICHMANN 1. Introduction The language of mathematical Finance allows to express many results of martingale theory

More information

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication)

Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Appendix B for The Evolution of Strategic Sophistication (Intended for Online Publication) Nikolaus Robalino and Arthur Robson Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 2 This appendix contains the proof of Theorem

More information

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series

Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Estimates for probabilities of independent events and infinite series Jürgen Grahl and Shahar evo September 9, 06 arxiv:609.0894v [math.pr] 8 Sep 06 Abstract This paper deals with finite or infinite sequences

More information

Introduction and Preliminaries

Introduction and Preliminaries Chapter 1 Introduction and Preliminaries This chapter serves two purposes. The first purpose is to prepare the readers for the more systematic development in later chapters of methods of real analysis

More information

The Lebesgue Integral

The Lebesgue Integral The Lebesgue Integral Brent Nelson In these notes we give an introduction to the Lebesgue integral, assuming only a knowledge of metric spaces and the iemann integral. For more details see [1, Chapters

More information

The strictly 1/2-stable example

The strictly 1/2-stable example The strictly 1/2-stable example 1 Direct approach: building a Lévy pure jump process on R Bert Fristedt provided key mathematical facts for this example. A pure jump Lévy process X is a Lévy process such

More information

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation H. Mete Soner Nizar Touzi Jianfeng Zhang March 7, 21 Abstract This paper is on developing stochastic analysis simultaneously under a general family of

More information

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals Bérard Bergery Blandine, Vallois Pierre IECN, Nancy-Université, CNRS, INRIA, Boulevard des Aiguillettes B.P. 239 F-5456

More information

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t Lecture 12 1 Brownian motion: the Markov property Let C := C(0, ), R) be the space of continuous functions mapping from 0, ) to R, in which a Brownian motion (B t ) t 0 almost surely takes its value. Let

More information

Lecture 2. We now introduce some fundamental tools in martingale theory, which are useful in controlling the fluctuation of martingales.

Lecture 2. We now introduce some fundamental tools in martingale theory, which are useful in controlling the fluctuation of martingales. Lecture 2 1 Martingales We now introduce some fundamental tools in martingale theory, which are useful in controlling the fluctuation of martingales. 1.1 Doob s inequality We have the following maximal

More information

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond

Measure Theory on Topological Spaces. Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond Measure Theory on Topological Spaces Course: Prof. Tony Dorlas 2010 Typset: Cathal Ormond May 22, 2011 Contents 1 Introduction 2 1.1 The Riemann Integral........................................ 2 1.2 Measurable..............................................

More information

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales Martin Schweizer Universität Bonn Institut für Angewandte Mathematik Wegelerstraße 6 D 53 Bonn 1 (Stochastics and Stochastics Reports 3 (199, 123 131 2

More information

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions

4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Prof. Dr. Rainer Dahlhaus Probability Theory Summer term 017 4th Preparation Sheet - Solutions Remark: Throughout the exercise sheet we use the two equivalent definitions of separability of a metric space

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 May 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 May 2018 arxiv:185.965v1 [math.pr] 4 May 18 STOCHASTIC INTEGRATION AND DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR TYPICAL PATHS DANIEL BARTL, MICHAEL KUPPER, AND ARIEL NEUFELD + Abstract. The goal of this paper is to define stochastic

More information

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory Part V 7 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets Lebesgue Integration Theory Definition 7. (Preliminary). A measure on a set is a function :2 [ ] such that. () = 2. If { } = is a finite

More information

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define 1 Measures 1.1 Jordan content in R N II - REAL ANALYSIS Let I be an interval in R. Then its 1-content is defined as c 1 (I) := b a if I is bounded with endpoints a, b. If I is unbounded, we define c 1

More information

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES

EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES EQUIVALENCE OF TOPOLOGIES AND BOREL FIELDS FOR COUNTABLY-HILBERT SPACES JEREMY J. BECNEL Abstract. We examine the main topologies wea, strong, and inductive placed on the dual of a countably-normed space

More information

LOCALLY INTEGRABLE PROCESSES WITH RESPECT TO LOCALLY ADDITIVE SUMMABLE PROCESSES

LOCALLY INTEGRABLE PROCESSES WITH RESPECT TO LOCALLY ADDITIVE SUMMABLE PROCESSES LOCALLY INTEGRABLE PROCESSES WITH RESPECT TO LOCALLY ADDITIVE SUMMABLE PROCESSES OANA MOCIOALCA Abstract. In [MD] we defined and studied a class of summable processes, called additive summable processes,

More information

Metric Spaces and Topology

Metric Spaces and Topology Chapter 2 Metric Spaces and Topology From an engineering perspective, the most important way to construct a topology on a set is to define the topology in terms of a metric on the set. This approach underlies

More information

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets Tim Leung 1, Qingshuo Song 2, and Jie Yang 3 1 Columbia University, New York, USA; leung@ieor.columbia.edu 2 City

More information

(B(t i+1 ) B(t i )) 2

(B(t i+1 ) B(t i )) 2 ltcc5.tex Week 5 29 October 213 Ch. V. ITÔ (STOCHASTIC) CALCULUS. WEAK CONVERGENCE. 1. Quadratic Variation. A partition π n of [, t] is a finite set of points t ni such that = t n < t n1

More information

PROBLEMS. (b) (Polarization Identity) Show that in any inner product space

PROBLEMS. (b) (Polarization Identity) Show that in any inner product space 1 Professor Carl Cowen Math 54600 Fall 09 PROBLEMS 1. (Geometry in Inner Product Spaces) (a) (Parallelogram Law) Show that in any inner product space x + y 2 + x y 2 = 2( x 2 + y 2 ). (b) (Polarization

More information

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition David pplebaum Probability and Statistics Department,

More information

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem Gaoyue Guo Xiaolu Tan Nizar Touzi June 10, 2015 Abstract This is a continuation of our accompanying paper [18]. We provide an alternative

More information

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs Lecture Notes by Walter Schachermayer Nachdiplom-Vorlesung, ETH Zürich, WS 15/16 1 Models on Finite Probability Spaces In this section we consider a stock price

More information

Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics

Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics Almost sure limit theorems for U-statistics Hajo Holzmann, Susanne Koch and Alesey Min 3 Institut für Mathematische Stochasti Georg-August-Universität Göttingen Maschmühlenweg 8 0 37073 Göttingen Germany

More information

Superreplication under Volatility Uncertainty for Measurable Claims

Superreplication under Volatility Uncertainty for Measurable Claims Superreplication under Volatility Uncertainty for Measurable Claims Ariel Neufeld Marcel Nutz April 14, 213 Abstract We establish the duality formula for the superreplication price in a setting of volatility

More information

1.1. MEASURES AND INTEGRALS

1.1. MEASURES AND INTEGRALS CHAPTER 1: MEASURE THEORY In this chapter we define the notion of measure µ on a space, construct integrals on this space, and establish their basic properties under limits. The measure µ(e) will be defined

More information

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s Stochastic Calculus Example sheet - Lent 15 Michael Tehranchi Problem 1. Let X be a local martingale. Prove that X is a uniformly integrable martingale if and only X is of class D. Solution 1. If If direction:

More information

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS

GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS Di Girolami, C. and Russo, F. Osaka J. Math. 51 (214), 729 783 GENERALIZED COVARIATION FOR BANACH SPACE VALUED PROCESSES, ITÔ FORMULA AND APPLICATIONS CRISTINA DI GIROLAMI and FRANCESCO RUSSO (Received

More information

The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny

The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny Johannes Ruf Department of Mathematics University College London May 1, 2015 Abstract Let X be a progressively measurable, almost

More information

Topological properties

Topological properties CHAPTER 4 Topological properties 1. Connectedness Definitions and examples Basic properties Connected components Connected versus path connected, again 2. Compactness Definition and first examples Topological

More information

PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE

PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE MATHIAS BEIGLBÖCK, ALEXANDER M. G. COX, MARTIN HUESMANN, NICOLAS PERKOWSKI, AND DAVID J. PRÖMEL Abstract. Since Hobson s seminal paper [19] the connection

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 26 Mar 2008

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 26 Mar 2008 arxiv:0803.3679v1 [math.pr] 26 Mar 2008 The game-theoretic martingales behind the zero-one laws Akimichi Takemura 1 takemura@stat.t.u-tokyo.ac.jp, http://www.e.u-tokyo.ac.jp/ takemura Vladimir Vovk 2 vovk@cs.rhul.ac.uk,

More information

Reducing subspaces. Rowan Killip 1 and Christian Remling 2 January 16, (to appear in J. Funct. Anal.)

Reducing subspaces. Rowan Killip 1 and Christian Remling 2 January 16, (to appear in J. Funct. Anal.) Reducing subspaces Rowan Killip 1 and Christian Remling 2 January 16, 2001 (to appear in J. Funct. Anal.) 1. University of Pennsylvania, 209 South 33rd Street, Philadelphia PA 19104-6395, USA. On leave

More information

Measure and integration

Measure and integration Chapter 5 Measure and integration In calculus you have learned how to calculate the size of different kinds of sets: the length of a curve, the area of a region or a surface, the volume or mass of a solid.

More information

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces

Chapter 4. Measure Theory. 1. Measure Spaces Chapter 4. Measure Theory 1. Measure Spaces Let X be a nonempty set. A collection S of subsets of X is said to be an algebra on X if S has the following properties: 1. X S; 2. if A S, then A c S; 3. if

More information

Lebesgue Measure on R n

Lebesgue Measure on R n CHAPTER 2 Lebesgue Measure on R n Our goal is to construct a notion of the volume, or Lebesgue measure, of rather general subsets of R n that reduces to the usual volume of elementary geometrical sets

More information

Measurable Choice Functions

Measurable Choice Functions (January 19, 2013) Measurable Choice Functions Paul Garrett garrett@math.umn.edu http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/ [This document is http://www.math.umn.edu/ garrett/m/fun/choice functions.pdf] This note

More information

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE Research Paper 241 December 2008 Viability of Markets with an Infinite Number of Assets Constantinos Kardaras ISSN 1441-8010 VIABILITY

More information

Another example of duality between game-theoretic and measure-theoretic probability

Another example of duality between game-theoretic and measure-theoretic probability Another example of duality between game-theoretic and measure-theoretic probability Vladimir Vovk The Game-Theoretic Probability and Finance Project Working Paper #46 Last revised August 9, 2016. First

More information

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3 Brownian Motion Contents 1 Definition 2 1.1 Brownian Motion................................. 2 1.2 Wiener measure.................................. 3 2 Construction 4 2.1 Gaussian process.................................

More information

NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES

NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES NOTES ON EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS THEOREMS FOR ODES JONATHAN LUK These notes discuss theorems on the existence, uniqueness and extension of solutions for ODEs. None of these results are original. The proofs

More information

Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon Measures

Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon Measures 2 1 Borel Regular Measures We now state and prove an important regularity property of Borel regular outer measures: Stanford Mathematics Department Math 205A Lecture Supplement #4 Borel Regular & Radon

More information

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval

The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval Krzysztof Burdzy, Weining Kang and Kavita Ramanan University of Washington and Carnegie Mellon University Abstract: We consider the Skorokhod problem

More information

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS JASON MILLER AND VITTORIA SILVESTRI

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS JASON MILLER AND VITTORIA SILVESTRI STOCHASTIC CALCULUS JASON MILLER AND VITTORIA SILVESTRI Contents Preface 1 1. Introduction 1 2. Preliminaries 4 3. Local martingales 1 4. The stochastic integral 16 5. Stochastic calculus 36 6. Applications

More information

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I

Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Notes 1 : Measure-theoretic foundations I Math 733-734: Theory of Probability Lecturer: Sebastien Roch References: [Wil91, Section 1.0-1.8, 2.1-2.3, 3.1-3.11], [Fel68, Sections 7.2, 8.1, 9.6], [Dur10,

More information

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets Anna Aksamit The University of Sydney based on joint work with Shuoqing Deng, Jan Ob lój and Xiaolu Tan Robust Techniques

More information

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games Marcel Nutz Jianfeng Zhang First version: December 7, 2012. This version: July 21, 2014 Abstract We study the existence of optimal

More information

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure? MA 645-4A (Real Analysis), Dr. Chernov Homework assignment 1 (Due ). Show that the open disk x 2 + y 2 < 1 is a countable union of planar elementary sets. Show that the closed disk x 2 + y 2 1 is a countable

More information

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9 MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES PROFESSOR: JOHN QUIGG SEMESTER: FALL 204 Contents. Sets 2 2. Functions 5 3. Countability 7 4. Axiom of choice 8 5. Equivalence relations 9 6. Real numbers 9 7. Extended

More information

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Lecture 17: Brownian motion as a Markov process 1 of 14 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 2015 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process Brownian motion is

More information

MA651 Topology. Lecture 9. Compactness 2.

MA651 Topology. Lecture 9. Compactness 2. MA651 Topology. Lecture 9. Compactness 2. This text is based on the following books: Topology by James Dugundgji Fundamental concepts of topology by Peter O Neil Elements of Mathematics: General Topology

More information

Lecture 9. d N(0, 1). Now we fix n and think of a SRW on [0,1]. We take the k th step at time k n. and our increments are ± 1

Lecture 9. d N(0, 1). Now we fix n and think of a SRW on [0,1]. We take the k th step at time k n. and our increments are ± 1 Random Walks and Brownian Motion Tel Aviv University Spring 011 Lecture date: May 0, 011 Lecture 9 Instructor: Ron Peled Scribe: Jonathan Hermon In today s lecture we present the Brownian motion (BM).

More information

Lebesgue Measure on R n

Lebesgue Measure on R n 8 CHAPTER 2 Lebesgue Measure on R n Our goal is to construct a notion of the volume, or Lebesgue measure, of rather general subsets of R n that reduces to the usual volume of elementary geometrical sets

More information

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework Anna Aksamit based on joint work with Zhaoxu Hou and Jan Ob lój London - Paris Bachelier Workshop on Mathematical Finance Paris, September

More information

ONLINE APPENDIX TO: NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION OF THE MIXED HAZARD MODEL USING MARTINGALE-BASED MOMENTS

ONLINE APPENDIX TO: NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION OF THE MIXED HAZARD MODEL USING MARTINGALE-BASED MOMENTS ONLINE APPENDIX TO: NONPARAMETRIC IDENTIFICATION OF THE MIXED HAZARD MODEL USING MARTINGALE-BASED MOMENTS JOHANNES RUF AND JAMES LEWIS WOLTER Appendix B. The Proofs of Theorem. and Proposition.3 The proof

More information

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability... Functional Analysis Franck Sueur 2018-2019 Contents 1 Metric spaces 1 1.1 Definitions........................................ 1 1.2 Completeness...................................... 3 1.3 Compactness......................................

More information

Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration

Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration Lecture 19: L 2 -Stochastic integration 1 of 12 Course: Theory of Probability II Term: Spring 215 Instructor: Gordan Zitkovic Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration The stochastic integral for processes

More information

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past.

Lecture 5. If we interpret the index n 0 as time, then a Markov chain simply requires that the future depends only on the present and not on the past. 1 Markov chain: definition Lecture 5 Definition 1.1 Markov chain] A sequence of random variables (X n ) n 0 taking values in a measurable state space (S, S) is called a (discrete time) Markov chain, if

More information

Random G -Expectations

Random G -Expectations Random G -Expectations Marcel Nutz ETH Zurich New advances in Backward SDEs for nancial engineering applications Tamerza, Tunisia, 28.10.2010 Marcel Nutz (ETH) Random G-Expectations 1 / 17 Outline 1 Random

More information

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels. Advanced Financial Models Example sheet - Michaelmas 208 Michael Tehranchi Problem. Consider a two-asset model with prices given by (P, P 2 ) (3, 9) /4 (4, 6) (6, 8) /4 /2 (6, 4) Is there arbitrage in

More information

A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES

A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES STEFAN TAPPE Abstract. In a work of van Gaans (25a) stochastic integrals are regarded as L 2 -curves. In Filipović and Tappe (28) we have shown the connection

More information

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results)

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results) Ehrhard Behrends Abstract A metric space (M, d) is said to have the small ball property (sbp) if for every ε 0 > 0 there exists a sequence

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.fa] 14 Jul 2018

arxiv: v1 [math.fa] 14 Jul 2018 Construction of Regular Non-Atomic arxiv:180705437v1 [mathfa] 14 Jul 2018 Strictly-Positive Measures in Second-Countable Locally Compact Non-Atomic Hausdorff Spaces Abstract Jason Bentley Department of

More information

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis

An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis An introduction to some aspects of functional analysis Stephen Semmes Rice University Abstract These informal notes deal with some very basic objects in functional analysis, including norms and seminorms

More information

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 14 Nov 2018

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 14 Nov 2018 arxiv:1702.03573v2 [math.pr] 14 Nov 2018 Stochastic Exponentials and Logarithms on Stochastic Intervals A Survey Martin Larsson Johannes Ruf November 16, 2018 Abstract Stochastic exponentials are defined

More information

17. Convergence of Random Variables

17. Convergence of Random Variables 7. Convergence of Random Variables In elementary mathematics courses (such as Calculus) one speaks of the convergence of functions: f n : R R, then lim f n = f if lim f n (x) = f(x) for all x in R. This

More information

Martingales, standard filtrations, and stopping times

Martingales, standard filtrations, and stopping times Project 4 Martingales, standard filtrations, and stopping times Throughout this Project the index set T is taken to equal R +, unless explicitly noted otherwise. Some things you might want to explain in

More information

4 Sums of Independent Random Variables

4 Sums of Independent Random Variables 4 Sums of Independent Random Variables Standing Assumptions: Assume throughout this section that (,F,P) is a fixed probability space and that X 1, X 2, X 3,... are independent real-valued random variables

More information

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations Michael Röckner Reference: C. Prevot, M. Röckner: Springer LN in Math. 1905, Berlin (2007) And see the references therein for the original

More information

STAT 7032 Probability Spring Wlodek Bryc

STAT 7032 Probability Spring Wlodek Bryc STAT 7032 Probability Spring 2018 Wlodek Bryc Created: Friday, Jan 2, 2014 Revised for Spring 2018 Printed: January 9, 2018 File: Grad-Prob-2018.TEX Department of Mathematical Sciences, University of Cincinnati,

More information

Continued fractions for complex numbers and values of binary quadratic forms

Continued fractions for complex numbers and values of binary quadratic forms arxiv:110.3754v1 [math.nt] 18 Feb 011 Continued fractions for complex numbers and values of binary quadratic forms S.G. Dani and Arnaldo Nogueira February 1, 011 Abstract We describe various properties

More information

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem Koichiro TAKAOKA Dept of Applied Physics, Tokyo Institute of Technology Abstract M Yor constructed a family

More information

OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION

OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION OPTIMAL TRANSPORTATION PLANS AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION J.A. Cuesta-Albertos 1, C. Matrán 2 and A. Tuero-Díaz 1 1 Departamento de Matemáticas, Estadística y Computación. Universidad de Cantabria.

More information

The main results about probability measures are the following two facts:

The main results about probability measures are the following two facts: Chapter 2 Probability measures The main results about probability measures are the following two facts: Theorem 2.1 (extension). If P is a (continuous) probability measure on a field F 0 then it has a

More information

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents

MATH MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS. Contents MATH 3969 - MEASURE THEORY AND FOURIER ANALYSIS ANDREW TULLOCH Contents 1. Measure Theory 2 1.1. Properties of Measures 3 1.2. Constructing σ-algebras and measures 3 1.3. Properties of the Lebesgue measure

More information