American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings"

Transcription

1 American Law & Economics Association Annual Meetings Year 2004 Paper 48 What You Don t See Can t Hurt You: An Economic Analysis of Philip A. Curry Simon Fraser University Steeve Mongrain Simon Fraser University This working paper site is hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress) and may not be commercially reproduced without the publisher s permission. Copyright c 2004 by the authors.

2 What You Don t See Can t Hurt You: An Economic Analysis of Morality Laws Phil Curry Simon Fraser University Steeve Mongrain Simon Fraser University April 30, 2004 Preliminary Abstract A common justification for morality laws, such as the regulation of drug use and prostitution, is that the government is protecting individuals from themselves. Needless to say, this explanation does not sit well with economists. This paper provides an alternate explanation motivated by the observation that the design of these laws often promotes discretion by the people engaging in the activity in question. We propose that morality laws can be best explained by considering the proscribed activities to impose a negative externality that can be reduced through hiding. In such a case, efficiency requires discretion on behalf of the individual who engages in such activities. Since discretion is often difficult to regulate, the activities are instead proscribed thereby giving individuals incentive to hide their actions from others. In addition, since some level of activity is efficient, the optimal sanctions are not maximal. Key Words: Crime; Externality; Laws; Morality; Enforcement JEL: K42; K32; H32 We would like to thank David Andolfatto for many interesting conversations that culminated in this paper. We also thank Scott Skjei for excellent research assistance. Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

3 1 Introduction Morality laws include prohibitions against exchanging sexual favors for money and the use of narcotics. A common justification for such laws is that the government is protecting individuals from themselves. Needless to say, this explanation does not sit well with economists. This paper offers an explanation for morality laws that is consistent with a number of observations about these laws. First, the design of these laws often promote discretion by the people engaging in the activity in question. For example, prostitution is legal in Canada, while solicitation is not. In other words, it is legal to exchange money for sexual favors in Canada, it is just not legal to discuss it in public 1. The second observation is that the majority the activities covered by morality laws are completely banned. For other forms of externalities, like pollution, a positive legal level or quota is usually set. Finally, the typical penalty for the infraction of these laws seems unusually low. For example, in the city of Vancouver, the maximum penalty for excessive noise while cleaning your carpet with a vehicle mounted cleaner on a Sunday before noon is $2000 while the maximum sentence for a first offense of cocaine possession is six months in prison and $1000. more importantly, the expected penalty does not appear to provide much deterrence. The Alcohol and Other Drugs Survey of 1994 found that 23% of Canadians had tried marijuana at least once 2 In the United States, the National Task Force on Prostitution estimates that over 1 million people and 1% of American women have been employed as prostitutes 3. An estimated 2.7 million Americans were chronic cocaine users in 2000, and an additional 3 million Americans were recreational users. In 1990, Americans consumed $69.9 billion (US), or 447 metric tons worth of cocaine 4. In comparison, an estimated $23 billion (US) 1 The Canadian Criminal Code states that every person who in a public place or in any place open to public view (a) stops or attempts to stop any motor vehicle, (b) impedes the free flow of pedestrian or vehicular traffic or ingress to or egress from premises adjacent to that place, or (c) stops or attempts to stop any person or in any manner communicates or attempts to communicate with any person for the purpose of engaging in prostitution or of obtaining the sexual services of a prostitute is guilty of an offence punishable on summary conviction. 2 Taken from Canada s 2002 Report of Senate Special Committee on Illegal Drugs (p.91). 3 Taken from Prostitutes Education Network, 4 Taken from the Office of National Drug Control Policy webpage, 1

4 worth of merchandise is shoplifted on an annual basis 5. This paper proposes that these stylized facts about morality laws can be best explained by considering the proscribed activities to impose a negative externality that can be reduced through hiding behaviors. In such a case, efficiency requires discretion on behalf of the individual who engages in such activities. Since discretion is often difficult to regulate, the activities are instead proscribed thereby giving individuals incentive to hide their actions from others (including the police). It should be noted that it is not always case that regulations about discretion cannot be implemented. For example, many counties in the United States allow alcohol consumption in public, non-licensed areas, as long as the alcohol is hidden. As mentioned above, prostitution is legal in Canada, however solicitation is not. Optimal policy in the presence of negative externalities has been well studied in economics. One of the most commonly used policies is that of a quota and enforcement consisting of monitoring and sanctions. Examples of quotas include speed limits, blood/alcohol levels while driving, emission of pollutants or noise curfews. On the other hand, some activities that impose negative externalities, such as murder or the emission of deadly pollutants, are banned altogether. This is not surprising as it seems clear that the marginal costs to such activities always outweigh the marginal benefits. Included on the list of activities that are outright banned, however, are prostitution and the consumption of drugs. In these cases, it is not so obvious that the marginal costs exceed the marginal benefits at zero consumption. It should also be noted that if the socially efficient level of consumption were zero, then the penalties associated with morality laws seem to provide an unusually low level of deterrence. For example, in 2000, there were an estimated 14 million current users of marijuana. 6 We demonstrate that the optimal policy may be to proscribe such activities altogether even when the marginal benefits outweigh the marginal costs for some positive levels of consumption. We construct a model in which an agent, called the injurer, chooses the level of consumption for a good which causes harm to another agent, called the victim. 5 Taken from 6 Taken from Canada s 2002 Report of Senate Special Committee on Illegal Drugs (p.101). 2 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

5 This harm may or may not be reducible through hiding behavior on behalf of the injurer. In the absence of legislation, the injurer will choose to consume until the marginal benefit equals the private marginal cost, leading to consumption greater than the socially efficient level. The government is assumed to have three instruments with which it can affect the injurer s consumption. First, it can set a legal limit to consumption. Second, it can choose a penalty, or sanction, for consumption above the legal limit. Finally, it chooses a level of effort in enforcing the quota, which affects the probability that the injurer is caught when consuming a proscribed level. However, this probability can also be affected by the injurer. The injurer is assumed to be able to reduce the probability of detection through costly hiding. The implications of hiding for social welfare depends on whether it merely reduces the probability of being caught or also reduces the harm incurred by the victim. When the externality is conventional (not affected by the injurer s hiding), hiding is a wasteful activity. The only effect in this case is to reduce the probability of detection of illegal consumption. Consequently, it is always welfare reducing. When hiding reduces the harm of the externality, some level of hiding may be socially efficient. We refer to this situation as a damage reducible externality. It should be noted that an injurer will chose to hide her consumption only if part of this consumption is illegal. That is, if an injurer does not consume above a quota, then they have no incentive to engage in hiding. As a result, the government will wish to set the quota below the socially efficient level but choose sanctions and enforcement such that the injurer will choose to consumer a proscribed level and engage in socially beneficial hiding. It should further be noted that this implies that a certain level of crime is socially desirable. Hiding on behalf of criminals has already been examined in the literature to some extent. Malik (1990) shows that when criminals can invest effort in hiding their crimes, maximal sanctions may be sub-optimal even when sanctions are costless. Higher sanctions increase the incentive to hide, which is welfare reducing. This result also arises in our framework. Since this result is already known, we restrict our analysis to an environment in which this effect is not present. This allows us to focus on additional reasons for the non-optimality of maximal sanctions. First, the government may face a tradeoff between enforcement costs and social costs associated 3

6 with excessive consumption. Second, the government may wish to encourage crime in order to promote hiding. When externalities are conventional and the government is unconstrained in its choice of sanction, the social optimum is implementable by setting the quota at the socially efficient level and setting the sanction arbitrarily high so that neither crime nor hiding occurs. However, if the government is not able to set the sanction above a certain level, the efficient level of consumption can only be induced by incurring enforcement costs. This paper demonstrates in such a case, the government will allow consumption above the efficient level and use costly enforcement such that the marginal cost of each is equalized. As mentioned above, hiding is a wasteful activity that only occurs when the injurer consumes above the legal limit. Increasing the quota reduces hiding and so the optimal policy entails a legal level which is too high compared to the efficient level. In other words, laws are too permissive. The optimality of permissive laws has received little attention in the crime literature. Boadway and Sato (2000) show that, for the case of tax evasion, permissive laws can be optimal if courts or tax payers can make mistakes concerning taxable income. This paper provides a second case for permissive laws. The case of damage reducible externalities constitutes the central analysis in the paper. As mentioned above, hiding in this context can be socially desirable because it reduces the damage incurred by the victim. The only benefit to injurers from hiding, however, occurs if they are committing crime. If a injurer chooses a consumption level within the legal limits, there is no incentive for the injurer to hide. Consequently, the optimal policy portfolio encourages illegal consumption, thereby promoting hiding. In order to induce the correct amount of consumption the optimal level of sanctions are not maximal. In addition, the government will choose a legal level (or quota) which is less than the efficient level. In other words, morality laws seem to be overly restrictive. In many cases, the optimal legal level for consumption is zero, which is consistent with our observation on drug use or prostitution laws in most countries. Alcohol is one example of an activity for which the legal limit is often not zero, although it should be noted that periods of prohibition have been experienced. As pointed out by Levitt (2003) and MacCoun and Reuter (2001) whenever prohibition has been introduced, sanctions were relatively small. The average punishment was 4 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

7 35 days and a $100 fine, again consistent with our findings. The outline of this paper is as follows. In the next section we present the general model. Section 3 considers the case of conventional externalities. Section 4 analyzes the case of damage reducible externalities. The conclusion follows. Note that all the proofs are in the appendix. 2 The Model Consider the following simple economy with two agents and a government. The first agent, who we call the injurer, I, derives utility from the consumption of a certain good or activity. 7 Denote the injurer s consumption by θ, and let (θ) be the benefit derived from consumption. The marginal benefit is positive, B ( ) > 0, but at a decreasing rate, B ( ) < 0. The second agent we call the victim, V. The victim suffers some disutility from the injurer s consumption. Denote by C (θ) the harm incurred by the victim from the injurer s consumption, where C ( ) > 0 and C ( ) > 0. The injurer and victim have initial wealth m I and m V, respectively. It is assumed that transaction costs are high enough so that bargaining cannot take place. The government maximizes the sum of agents utilities. It does so by choosing a level of legal consumption of the good and through the enforcement of said level. Denote by θ the maximum legal consumption of θ. If the injurer decides to consume more than the legal level, she will be fined with some probability. The probability that illegal consumption is detected is given by p (e, h), where e is the enforcement effort chosen by the government, and h is the effort expended on hiding chosen by the injurer. Hiding effort comes with a marginal cost of one. The cost of enforcement effort is given by κ (e) where κ (e) > 0 and κ (e) 0, it is also assumed that κ (0) = 0. The larger the effort by the government, the larger the probability of being detected (p e ( ) > 0), but at a decreasing rate (p ee ( ) < 0). The injurer s hiding behavior decreases the probability of being caught, p h ( ) < 0, also at a decreasing rate, p hh ( ) > 0. We assume that an increase in the government s monitoring efforts 7 Here we use the example of a consumption externality, but using a production externality will lead to the same results. 5

8 reduces the effectiveness of hiding, so that p he ( ) > 0. Finally, we assume that there exists a small chance that the injurer will get caught when consuming a proscribed amount, even if the government does not expend any enforcement effort. That is, we assume p (0, h) > 0, h 8. The effort of the government is financed through a uniform lump sum tax T. An injurer who gets caught consuming a proscribed level, i.e. θ > θ, receives a sanction S ( θ θ ). The sanction is an increasing function of the difference between the actual consumption and the legal level. To begin, we concentrate our efforts on the case where the sanction is linear and given by S = s [ θ θ ]. In addition, we consider two scenarios. First, we consider the case were there is no limit to the perunit sanction s. We then consider the case in which the government cannot raise the sanction above an certain level, s max. This latter case is introduced to investigate the tradeoffs between the probability of detection and the quota in a second best world. It is assumed that these sanctions can be collected without cost. Finally, the utility of the injurer is given by: { U I m I T + B (θ) h = m I T + B(θ) p(e, h)[θ θ]s h if θ θ if θ > θ The utility of the victim is given by: U V = m V T C (θ) Note that the victim does not make any decisions in this simple model. 2.1 The Injurer s Decision We now characterize the behavior of the injurer for a given set of regulations, { θ, e, s }. The injurer s maximization problem is as follows: { B (θ) h max θ,h B(θ) p(e, h)[θ θ]s h if θ θ if θ > θ 8 This assumption is made purely to simplify the analysis. Without this assumption, attention would be restricted to suprema of the government s objective function as opposed to maxima. 6 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

9 First, note that the injurer s utility is strictly increasing in θ and strictly decreasing in h for all θ < θ. Thus one possible solution to the injurer s maximization problem is θ = θ and h = 0. The injurer may choose θ > θ, however. In this case, the optimal choices for θ and h are characterized by the following first order conditions: B (θ ) = p (e, h ) s (2.1) p h (e, h ) s [ θ θ ] = 1 (2.2) Equation 2.1 states that when the injurer chooses her level of consumption, she equalizes the marginal benefit of consumption with its marginal cost, which is given by the probability of being detected times the marginal sanction. Simultaneously, the injurer chooses the level of hiding to equalize the marginal reduction in the expected sanction, with its marginal cost of one 9. Denote the solution to equations 2.1 and 2.2 by θ and h. Note that these first order conditions characterize the optimal choices of θ and h when B (θ ) p (e, h ) s [ θ θ ] h > B ( θ). 10 It is important for future reference to understand how the injurer s choices of θ and h vary with the different policy tools, both for the solutions characterized by the first order conditions and the for the case where there is only legal consumption. In the latter case, the injurer chooses θ = θ and h = 0. Note that the injurer s preferred level of consumption is invariant to changes in the government s detection effort, e, as well as to changes in the per-unit sanction, s. Further note that consumption varies one-to-one with θ. The effort spent on hiding is independent of all policies. For the solutions characterized by equations 2.1 and 2.2, an increase in θ leads to a decrease in θ and h. The intuition for this result is as follows. First, as the legal level of consumption increases, the marginal benefit from hiding decreases because the total penalty (θ θ) decreases. As the amount of hiding decreases, the (expected) marginal cost of consumption increases. The result is a decrease in both the level 9 The second order will be satisfied as long as B (θ)p hh ( )[θ θ]s+p h ( ) 2 s 2 < 0, which we assume to be the case. 10 It is assumed that in the case that B (θ ) p (e, h ) s [ θ θ ] h = B ( θ), the injurer chooses θ = θ and h = 0 7

10 of hiding and the level of consumption. 11 Note that criminal activity (consumption above the legal limit) and hiding are strategic complements. Second, an increase in detection efforts, e, increases the expected cost of consumption above the legal limit, and so θ decreases. In addition, since it has been assumed that the government s monitoring reduces the effectiveness of hiding, we also have that h decreases. 12 Finally, as the per-unit sanction, s increases, the effect on consumption and hiding is ambiguous. As noted above, as the sanction increases, the expected cost to consumption above the legal limit increases (holding the level of hiding fixed). However, the benefit to hiding also increases (holding the level of consumption fixed). The effect of the increase in the per-unit sanction thus depends on which effect dominates. For the purposes of this paper we will focus on the more standard case in which the amount of illegal activity and the level of hiding are decreasing in the sanction Consumption, Quotas and Hiding We will start by looking at the case where the harm caused to the victim by the injurer s consumption is unaffected by hiding. Pollution is the classic example of such an externality. In this case, the efficient levels of consumption and hiding are found by solving max B (θ) C (θ) h θ,h Note that the efficient level of hiding is zero. When consumption produces an externality independent of whether the victim observes the injurer s level of consumption, 11 The actual derivatives are given by: θ θ = [p h( )s] 2 soc < 0 and h θ = B (θ)p h ( )s soc < 0 respectively, where soc denotes the relevant second order condition as stated in the previous paragraph. 12 θ The derivatives are given by: e = [p h( )p he ( ) p e( )p hh ( )][θ θ]s 2 soc < 0 and h e = B (θ)p he (θ θ)s+p e( )p h ( )s 2 < 0 respectively. soc 13 The derivatives are given by: θ = [p h( ) 2 p( )p hh ( )][θ θ]s soc and h = B (θ)p h (θ θ)+p( )p h ( )s soc. A sufficient condition for both derivatives to be decreasing in s is p h( ) p( ) decreasing in h. Malik (1990) notes that when the amount of illegal activity increases as the sanction increases maximal sanctions are no longer optimal. In this paper, the non-optimality of maximal sanctions arises as a result of damage reducible externalities. This is discussed in section 4. 8 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

11 hiding is a waste of resources. The efficient level of consumption, denoted by θ o, is characterized by B (θ o ) = C (θ o ). We will now look at how the government can affect the level of consumption as well as the injurer s hiding efforts. 3.1 The Government s Problem The instruments available to the government are the quota on legal consumption, θ, the per-unit sanction on consumption above the legal level, s, and the effort in monitoring, e. The problem faced by the government is the following: max B ( θ ( θ, )) ( ( θ, )) ( θ, ) e, s C θ e, s κ(e) h e, s θ,e,s In this scenario, the socially efficient level of consumption and hiding, θ o zero respectively, are implementable as the government has a sufficient number of instruments. This is demonstrated formally below. Result 1: When consumption by the injurer imposes a conventional externality on the victim, the optimal policy is for the government to set θ = θ o, e = 0 and s arbitrarily large. This will induce the injurer to choose θ = θ o and h = 0, the socially efficient levels of consumption and hiding, respectively. The intuition for this result is straightforward. When the expected penalty to consumption above the proscribed limit is high enough, the injurer will choose to consume the quota and no more. Given that the sanction is costless and p (0, h) > 0, h, the government can set arbitrarily high expected penalties while incurring no costs from monitoring effort. As such, the government can set the quota at any level and costlessly induce the injurer to consume that amount. The optimal choice for the quota is the efficient level of consumption, θ o. and 3.2 Constrained Sanctions It may be the case that the government cannot choose arbitrarily large sanctions. This is, it may be that for political, technological or constitutional reasons there exists a limit to the per unit sanction level that can be imposed on illegal consumption. 9

12 Denote this limit to the per unit sanction by s max. In particular, we consider the case where s max is not sufficient to deter the injurer from consuming above the quota when θ = θ o and e = 0. In this case, the government faces a tradeoff between the costs of monitoring, and the social costs of activity above the efficient level plus any resources expended on hiding. The optimal choice for the government is to incur both enforcement effort costs and to allow consumption above θ o. This can be seen as follows. Since θ h θ θ < 0 and < 0 when θ > θ, the government can reduce both crime and hiding by increasing the quota, which is costless. Thus the optimal policy for the government is to choose θ and e such that the injurer chooses to consume the quota and such that the marginal cost of monitoring is equal to the marginal social cost of consumption above θ o. This is demonstrated formally in the following result. Result 2: Suppose that consumption by the injurer imposes a conventional externality on the victim and the government is constrained in the level of the per unit sanction that it can choose. In this case, the optimal policy for the government is to set the sanction to the maximal level and to choose the enforcement effort and quota such that the agent fully complies. Further, the quota and level of effort will be such that the marginal social cost of consumption is equal to the marginal cost of enforcement. It should be noted that when consumption imposes a conventional externality on the victim, any optimal policy entails full compliance. That is, the quota and expected penalty are chosen so that the injurer will not exceed the quota. When the government is unconstrained in its choice of sanction, then the quota is set at the socially efficient level. When the government is constrained in the sanction it can set, however, then the quota may exceed the efficient level. 4 Damage Reducible Externalities We now consider the case in which hiding effort by the injurer reduces not only the probability with which the injurer is caught, but also reduces the harm incurred by the victim. This may occur in cases where it is the observation of the activity that causes disutility to the victim, or where the concept of responsible consumption 10 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

13 applies. Specifically, we consider the case where the victim s utility is given by U V = m V T C (θ, h) where C θ > 0 and C θθ > 0 as before, but C h < 0 and C hh > 0 so that hiding on behalf of the injurer benefits the victim, but with decreasing returns. We further assume that C θh < 0. Note that the injurer s preferences do not change and so the effect of the quota, θ, enforcement effort, e, and per-unit sanction, s, remains the same as above. What does change, however, is the socially efficient level of consumption and hiding. 4.1 Efficiency When hiding reduces the harm incurred by the victim, it now becomes socially optimal for some hiding to take place. The efficient levels of consumption and hiding are found by solving The first order conditions are max B (θ) C (θ, h) h θ,h B (θ) C θ (θ, h) = 0 C h (θ, h) 1 = 0 Denote the efficient levels of consumption and hiding by θ DR and h DR, respectively. Noted that h DR > 0 = h o and θ DR > θ o. 4.2 The Government s Problem It should first be noted that if the government can legislate the injurer s hiding behavior, then the optimal policy would be to set the quota at θ DR, require that the injurer choose h DR and enforce each law by choosing arbitrarily high sanctions and zero enforcement effort. This section examines the case in which legislation on hiding behavior is not possible. 11

14 Recall that the injurer s behavior changes in precisely the same way as noted above when analyzing consumption externalities. The government s instruments therefore have the same effect, although the objective function is now changed to accommodate the change in the victim s utility. The government s problem is given by max B ( θ ( θ, )) ( ( θ, ) ( θ, )) ( θ, ) e, s C θ e, s, h e, s h e, s κ(e) θ,e,s The first order conditions are [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ θ [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h = 0 θ (4.1) [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ e [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h e κ (e) = 0 (4.2) [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h = 0 (4.3) It should first be noted that it is no longer optimal for the government to set the quota at the efficient level, θ DR and to completely deter consumption over that level. Recall that the injurer never engages in hiding unless also committing crime (consuming above the quota). Such a policy would therefore lead the injurer to choose θ = θ DR and h = 0. A policy that induces the injurer to consume above the quota would constitute an improvement because of the hiding that accompanies crime. The following result demonstrates this formally. Result 3: When externalities are damage reducible, the government s optimal policy, { θ, e, s}, is such that there is crime in equilibrium (θ > θ). A corollary to this result is that the optimal sanction is not maximal. Since the solution involves the injurer choosing θ > θ, the sanction s has to be set to a finite value even though it is costless. This provides another example of the non-optimality of maximal sanctions to complement the results of Andreoni (1991), Malik (1990) and Shavell (1991). Also of interest is the fact that efficiency requires crime to be committed even though it is costless to deter it. To our knowledge, this paper provides the first example of such a result. We now consider the set of policies that induce crime and characterize the optimal one. An obvious candidate for the solution would be one such that the injurer chooses θ = θ DR > θ and accompanies the illegal activity with a degree of hiding equal to 12 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

15 the socially optimal level, h = h DR. The following result demonstrates that it can be feasible to implement the social optimum without cost. Result 4: Suppose that consumption by the injurer imposes a damage reducible externality on the victim. In this case, the optimal policy for the government is to set a quota below the socially efficient level, choose zero enforcement, and set the sanction less than maximally. In particular, the quota and sanction will be such that the injurer chooses θ = θ DR and h = h DR. This is implementable as long as where ɛ ph (0, h DR ) = hdr p h (0,h DR ) p(0,h DR ). B (θ DR )ɛ ph (0, h DR ) hdr θ DR, As mentioned in the result, such a policy can be implemented only under certain circumstances. Loosely, it will not be implementable when hiding is effective at reducing harm ( hdr is high), but hiding is not very effective at reducing the probability θ DR of getting caught (ɛ ph (0, h DR ) is low). In this case, it is socially optimal to have a high level of hiding, but the injurer does not choose to invest much because it is not productive. In such a case, since hiding and crime are complements, the injurer would have to commit a large amount of crime (i.e. consume far above the legal limit) to induce the appropriate level of hiding. However, since hdr is high, then it is possible θ DR that the amount of crime necessary to induce h DR is greater than the socially efficient level of consumption. In other words, the government would have to set a negative quota. In this case, the government will be unable to induce the socially efficient levels of consumption and hiding without incurring costs. Since this situation arises when the government cannot get enough hiding when inducing the injurer to consume the efficient level, θ DR, the government must now tradeoff the costs of enforcement with the social costs associated with excessive consumption and too little hiding. optimal policy in this case entails a positive level of enforcement effort and finite sanctions. As alluded to above, the injurer is induced to consume greater than the efficient level of consumption θ > θ DR and hide less than the efficient level h < h DR. Result 5: Suppose that consumption by the injurer imposes a damage reducible ex- The 13

16 ternality on the victim and that B (θ DR )ɛ ph (0, h DR ) hdr θ DR. In this case, the optimal policy for the government is to set the quota equal to zero, choose zero enforcement, and set the per unit sanction less than maximally. injurer then chooses θ > θ DR and h < h DR. We thus have that in the presence of damage reducible externalities, we should expect to see low quotas, possibly even zero, accompanied by low penalties and enforcement. In particular, the expected penalty should be low enough that a significant amount of crime happens. These predictions correspond well with the stylized facts on morality laws. Further, this model predicts that the government may choose to legislate hiding behaviors when possible. This is something that does occur, with examples including Canada s legalization of prostitution but proscription of solicitation and pervasive laws that limit alcohol consumption to licensed areas. The 14 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

17 5 Conclusion This paper provides an explanation for morality laws that does not require the government to be protecting individuals from themselves. We assume that the proscribed activities impose a negative externality on others that can be reduced by engaging in hiding behaviors. This assumption seems natural given the presence of legislation aimed at the promotion of discretion on behalf of individuals engaging in these activities. The results of this assumption include the optimality of non-maximal sanctions and the presence of restrictive laws accompanied by seemingly low expected penalties. 15

18 6 Appendix Proof to Result 1: The first order conditions for the government s maximization problem are as follows: [B (θ ) C (θ )] θ h = 0 θ θ (6.1) [B (θ ) C (θ )] θ e κ (e) h e = 0 (6.2) [B (θ ) C (θ )] θ h = 0 (6.3) where all partial derivatives of θ and h are as described in the section on the injurer s problem above. First, note that if the injurer chooses θ = θ, then h = 0 and θ θ h = 1 and = 0. θ In this case, the first order condition for the quota, equation 6.1, is satisfied when θ is such that B ( θ) ( θ) C = 0, which occurs at θ = θ o. In addition, when θ = θ, then θ e = 0, h = 0, θ = 0 and h = 0. In this case, the marginal return to e monitoring effort, e, is zero when e = 0 and negative for all positive levels of effort. Finally, the marginal effect of a change in s is zero as long as s is sufficient to deter the injurer from consuming above θ. This must be a global maximum since θ = θ o and h = 0 maximizes B (θ) C (θ) h as noted in the section on efficiency. As a result, the optimal policy for the government is to set the quota at θ o, e to zero and s arbitrarily large 14. Proof to Result 2: We begin by demonstrating that it is optimal for the government to choose s = s max. Recall that the first order conditions for the government s problem are given by equations 6.1, 6.2 and 6.3. To begin with we can see that, for every e and s, the government would never choose θ such that θ > θ, θ o. In such a case, the government would prefer to raise the quota, as this has the effect of reducing the level of consumption and hiding. This can be seen from the partial derivative with respect to θ since [B (θ ) C (θ )] < 0 when θ > θ o. [B (θ ) C (θ )] θ h θ θ > 0 In addition, suppose that θ is chosen such that θ = θ > θ o. In this case, the government would like to lower θ as long as the injurer would still comply with this 14 Or, at least large enough to induce the injurer to consume the quota and no more. 16 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

19 new lower quota. This can be seen by noting that the partial derivative with respect to θ is negative. [B (θ ) C (θ )] < 0 Now consider the case where θ is such that lowering the quota means that the injurer would no longer comply. Denote this quota by θ. Then we are in a situation where the partial derivative to the right is negative, and the partial derivative is positive at all θ < θ and so θ maximizes welfare given e and s. There are, however, different levels of θ depending on e and s. First, it should be noted that if a given θ arises from multiple pairs (e, s), then the pair with the lowest e is preferred by the government since e is costly and s is not. This implies that the government will be choosing between different θ such that s = s max. Thus for every θ there exists a unique e and the government s maximization problem can therefore be reformulated as follows. max B ( θ ) C (θ ) κ ( )) e ( θ θ Note that there are no hiding costs because the injurer chooses to comply and not hide at θ. The first order condition is B ( θ ) C ( θ ) e θ κ (e) = 0 In other words, the marginal social cost of consumption is set equal to the marginal cost of enforcement. Proof to Result 3: The solution to the government maximization problem is given by the set of policies { θ, e, s} which satisfy equations 4.1, 4.2 and 4.3. Policies may be of two types. The first type of policy induces the injurer to comply with the quota. That is, { θ, e, s} are such that θ = θ, then h = 0. The second type of policy leads the injurer to commit crime. In other words, { θ, e, s} are such that θ > θ. In this case, it will also be that h > 0. Consider policies of the first type. The only solution that satisfies all the first order conditions is θ = θ DR, s arbitrary large and e = 0. However such solution is not a maximum, but a saddle point. Since the Hessian is only negative semi-definite at the point, the SOC are inconclusive. If h is fixed at zero, any change in θ would lead to reduction in the objective function, however an increase in h, starting from h = 0, leads to an increase in the objective function. The optimal policy is therefore of the second type. 17

20 Proof to Result 4: The solution to the government s maximization problem is given by the set of policies { θ, e, s} which satisfy equation 4.1, 4.2 and 4.3. Note that the first order conditions with respect to the quota and sanction, 4.1 and 4.3, are satisfied when θ = θ DR and h = h DR. Moreover, the first order condition with respect to effort is satisfied at this level of consumption and hiding as long as e = 0. This means that the government effectively has two instruments, the sanction and the quota, with which to induce the injurer to choose θ DR and h DR. This is feasible, as can be seen as follows. The injurer chooses θ and h to solve the first order conditions 2.1 and 2.2. Suppose that the injurer chooses θ = θ DR and h = h DR. Then it must be that B (θ DR ) = p(0, h DR )s and p h (0, h DR )[θ DR θ]s = 1. This will occur when s = B (θ DR ), and p(0,h DR ) h θ = DR ɛ ph (0,h DR )B (θ DR ) θdr, where ɛ ph (0, h DR ) = p h(0,h DR ) p(0,h DR ) hdr. It is only possible to find a positive θ that will induce h DR and θ DR if B (θ DR )ɛ ph (0, h DR ) hdr. θ DR Proof to Result 5: We first show that the solution entails s > 0 and e, θ = 0. Evaluating the government s first order conditions at the optimum would then yield [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ θ [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h θ 0 [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ e [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h e κ (0) 0 [B (θ ) C θ (θ, h )] θ [C h (θ, h ) + 1] h = 0 Note that condition 6.4 can be rewritten as B (θ ) C θ (θ, h ) C h (θ, h ) + 1 = h θ Note that h θ > 0 and so it must that B (θ ) C θ (θ, h ) and C h (θ, h ) + 1 have the same sign. If both are positive, then there is too little consumption and too much hiding. If both are negative, then there is too much consumption and too little hiding. Condition 6.4 can similarly be rewritten as B (θ ) C θ (θ,h ) C h (θ, h ) Since B (θ ) C θ (θ,h ) C h (θ,h )+1 = h θ C h (θ, h )+1 0. It can be shown that h θ C h (θ,h )+1, we have that h θ < h θ θ θ h θ θ θ h θ θ θ if and only if if and only if by substituting in the expressions 18 Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

21 for the partial derivatives: B (θ)p h ( ) θ + p( )p h ( )s [p h ( ) 2 p( )p hh ( )] θs B (θ)p h ( ) 2 θs + p( )p h ( ) 2 s [p h ( ) 2 p( )p hh ( )] θs < B (θ) p h ( ) s p h ( ) 2 s 2 > B (θ) Recall that [p h ( ) 2 p( )p hh ( )] θs is negative by assumption. Thus we have that B (θ)p h ( ) 2 θs + p( )p h ( ) 2 s < B (θ) [ p h ( ) 2 p( )p hh ( ) ] θs p h ( ) 2 s + B (θ) p h h ( ) θ < 0 This is satisfied from the second order condition for the injurer s decision of θ and h. Thus we have that C h (θ, h ) + 1 < 0 which occurs at levels of hiding lower than h HD. Thus it must also be that B (θ ) C θ (θ, h ) < 0, and so there is too much consumption. h θ Finally, the optimal level of e is zero if and only if B (θ ) C θ (θ,h ) h e θ. Substituting in yields e C h (θ,h )+1 h e θ, or e B (θ)p h ( ) θ + p( )p h ( )s B (θ) p he ( ) θs + p e ( ) p h ( ) s 2 [p h ( ) 2 p( )p hh ( )] θs [p h ( ) p he ( ) p e ( ) p hh ( )] θs 2 p ( ) p he ( ) [ p h ( ) 2 s + B (θ) p hh ( ) θ ] p e ( ) p h ( ) [ p h ( ) 2 s + B (θ) p hh ( ) θ ] p ( ) p he ( ) p e ( ) p h ( ) Since the left hand side is positive and the right hand side is negative, this is satisfied. 19

22 7 Bibliography Andreoni, J (1991), Reasonable Doubt and the Optimal Magnitude of Fines: Should the Penalty Fit the Crime? Rand Journal of Economics 22, Decker, G.S. (1968), Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach, Journal of Political Economy 76, Boadway R, N. Marceau and S. Mongrain (2002), Joint Tax Evasion, Canadian Journal of Economics, 35, Boadway, R. and M. Sato (2000), The Optimality of Punishing only the Innocent: The Case of Tax Evasion, International Tax and Public Finance 7, Levitt, S.D. (2003), Review of Drug War Heresies by MacCoun and Reuter, Journal of Economic Literature 41, MacCoun, R.J. and P. Reuter (2001), Drug War Heresies: Learning from Other Vices, Times, and Places, Cambridge University Press. Malik, A.S. (1990), Avoidance, Screening and Optimum Enforcement, RAND Journal of Economics 21, Senate Canada (2002), Cannabis: Our Position for a Canadian Public Policy, Report of the Senate Special Committee on Illegal Drugs, Ottawa. Shavell, S. (1991), Specific Versus General Enforcement of Law, Journal of Political Economy 99, Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Externalities Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good

More information

THE RIGHT OF RETURN: THE BIBLICAL LAW OF THEFT. Eliakim Katz and Jacob Rosenberg ABSTRACT

THE RIGHT OF RETURN: THE BIBLICAL LAW OF THEFT. Eliakim Katz and Jacob Rosenberg ABSTRACT 1 THE RIGHT OF RETURN: THE BIBLICAL LAW OF THEFT Eliakim Katz and Jacob Rosenberg ABSTRACT According to Jewish Law, a thief who is caught and found guilty must return the stolen article and, in addition,

More information

5. Externalities and Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods 5. Externalities and Public Goods Welfare properties of Walrasian Equilibria rely on the hidden assumption of private goods: the consumption of the good by one person has no effect on other people s utility,

More information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers September 6, 016 ONLINE APPENDIX In this Appendix we present in full additional results and extensions which are only mentioned in the paper. In the exposition

More information

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620 May 16, 2006 Philip Bond 1 Are cheap talk and hard evidence both needed in the courtroom? Abstract: In a recent paper, Bull and Watson (2004) present a formal model of verifiability in which cheap messages

More information

Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260

Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260 1 Suggested solutions to the 6 th seminar, ECON4260 Problem 1 a) What is a public good game? See, for example, Camerer (2003), Fehr and Schmidt (1999) p.836, and/or lecture notes, lecture 1 of Topic 3.

More information

Focusing Law Enforcement When Offenders Can Choose Location. Tim Friehe. Thomas J. Miceli. University of Bonn. University of Connecticut

Focusing Law Enforcement When Offenders Can Choose Location. Tim Friehe. Thomas J. Miceli. University of Bonn. University of Connecticut Focusing Law Enforcement When Offenders Can Choose Location Tim Friehe University of Bonn Thomas J. Miceli University of Connecticut Working Paper 2014-15 July 2014 365 Fairfield Way, Unit 1063 Storrs,

More information

Introduction to Game Theory

Introduction to Game Theory COMP323 Introduction to Computational Game Theory Introduction to Game Theory Paul G. Spirakis Department of Computer Science University of Liverpool Paul G. Spirakis (U. Liverpool) Introduction to Game

More information

Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, A. Spatial issues

Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, A. Spatial issues Page 1 of 6 Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, 2009 A. Spatial issues 1. Spatial issues and the South African economy Spatial concentration of economic

More information

Vulnerability and Cooperation: The Role of Social Policy in the Promotion of Trade

Vulnerability and Cooperation: The Role of Social Policy in the Promotion of Trade Vulnerability and Cooperation: The Role of Social Policy in the Promotion of Trade PRELIMINARY DRAFT Chris Bidner Ken Jackson December 15, 2010 Abstract Cooperation in the face of moral hazard is a critical

More information

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation Ismail Saglam Ipek University 4 May 2016 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/71090/

More information

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Ris Christopher S. Tang S. Alex Yang Jing Wu Appendix A: Proofs Proof of Lemma 1. In a centralized chain, the system

More information

Fiscal Rules and Discretion under Self-Enforcement

Fiscal Rules and Discretion under Self-Enforcement Fiscal Rules and Discretion under Self-Enforcement Marina Halac and Pierre Yared Columbia University May 2018 Motivation Countries impose rules to constrain governments policy decisions Fiscal rules in

More information

Theft, Gift-Giving, and Trustworthiness: Honesty is Its Own Reward in Rural Paraguay Laura Schechter

Theft, Gift-Giving, and Trustworthiness: Honesty is Its Own Reward in Rural Paraguay Laura Schechter Theft, Gift-Giving, and Trustworthiness: Honesty is Its Own Reward in Rural Paraguay Laura Schechter 1 Outline of the Presentation Motivation Previous literature Model Data Empirics 2 Motivation 50% of

More information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM Discussion Papers in Economics Discussion Paper No. 0/06 CONSISTENT FIRM CHOICE AND THE THEORY OF SUPPLY by Indraneel Dasgupta July 00 DP 0/06 ISSN 1360-438 UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM

More information

The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal

The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal The More Abstract the Better? Raising Education Cost for the Less Able when Education is a Signal Timothy Perri* Revised May 13, 2013 Abstract More able individuals may over-invest in education when education

More information

Terms and conditions for non-commercial end-use 1. General

Terms and conditions for non-commercial end-use 1. General Terms and conditions for non-commercial end-use 1. General 1.1. Lantmäteriet provides the licensed geodata products Nedladdning uttag (Download once) and Nedladdning abonnemang (Download subscription)

More information

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018 Moral Hazard: Part 1 April 9, 2018 Introduction In a standard moral hazard problem, the agent A is characterized by only one type. As with adverse selection, the principal P wants to engage in an economic

More information

The New Palgrave: Separability

The New Palgrave: Separability The New Palgrave: Separability Charles Blackorby Daniel Primont R. Robert Russell 1. Introduction July 29, 2006 Separability, as discussed here, refers to certain restrictions on functional representations

More information

AAEC 6524: Environmental Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Theory of Externalities and Public Goods. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2019.

AAEC 6524: Environmental Theory and Policy Analysis. Outline. Theory of Externalities and Public Goods. Klaus Moeltner Spring 2019. AAEC 6524: Theory and Policy Analysis Theory of Externalities and Public Goods Klaus Moeltner Spring 2019 January 21, 2019 Outline Overarching and Related Fields and Microeconomics (consumer, firm, s)

More information

Eco Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES

Eco Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES Eco 504.2 Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES (1) Suppose in our overlapping generations model the utility function is U ( C 1 (t), ) = log ( C 1 (t) ). Suppose also that instead of being endowed with

More information

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

September Math Course: First Order Derivative September Math Course: First Order Derivative Arina Nikandrova Functions Function y = f (x), where x is either be a scalar or a vector of several variables (x,..., x n ), can be thought of as a rule which

More information

- Geography is important when studying crime because when a crime happens it always has a location, a time and a reason.

- Geography is important when studying crime because when a crime happens it always has a location, a time and a reason. - Geography is important when studying crime because when a crime happens it always has a location, a time and a reason. - Crime figures are collected from the number of crime incidents reported to the

More information

Why on earth did you do that?!

Why on earth did you do that?! Why on earth did you do that?! A simple model of obfuscation-based choice Caspar 9-5-2018 Chorus http://behave.tbm.tudelft.nl/ Delft University of Technology Challenge the future Background: models of

More information

Blocking Development

Blocking Development Blocking Development Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology October 11, 2005 Taking Stock Lecture 1: Institutions matter. Social conflict view, a useful perspective

More information

Optimal Mirrleesian Income Taxation with Tax Avoidance

Optimal Mirrleesian Income Taxation with Tax Avoidance Optimal Mirrleesian Income Taxation with Tax Avoidance Daniel Moncayo January 30, 2014 Introduction People have more than one way to respond to taxation. The labor supply elasticity alone can t explain

More information

The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement

The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement Climatic Change (202) 0:499 505 DOI 0007/s0584-0-034-5 The effect of learning on membership and welfare in an International Environmental Agreement Larry Karp Received: 7 March 200 / Accepted: 20 April

More information

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007 Costly Expertise Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz Current Version: December, 007 In many environments expertise is costly. Costs can manifest themselves in numerous ways, ranging from the time that is required

More information

Review of Optimization Methods

Review of Optimization Methods Review of Optimization Methods Prof. Manuela Pedio 20550 Quantitative Methods for Finance August 2018 Outline of the Course Lectures 1 and 2 (3 hours, in class): Linear and non-linear functions on Limits,

More information

Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements

Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements Bård Harstad ECON 4910 March 2016 Bård Harstad (ECON 4910) Self-enforcing agreements March 2016 1 / 34 1. Motivation Many environmental problems are international

More information

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem BGPE Intensive Course: Contracts and Asymmetric Information Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem Anke Kessler Anke Kessler p. 1/?? Introduction standard neoclassical economic theory

More information

Optimal Delegation of Enforcement: Centralization versus Decentralization

Optimal Delegation of Enforcement: Centralization versus Decentralization Optimal Delegation of Enforcement: Centralization versus Decentralization CESifo & OECD Conference on Regulation: Political Economy, Measurement and E ects on Performance Jing Xu UAB 30/08/2009 Jing Xu

More information

Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games by Ross Cressman. Reviewed by William H. Sandholm *

Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games by Ross Cressman. Reviewed by William H. Sandholm * Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games by Ross Cressman Reviewed by William H. Sandholm * Noncooperative game theory is one of a handful of fundamental frameworks used for economic modeling. It

More information

Correlated Equilibrium in Games with Incomplete Information

Correlated Equilibrium in Games with Incomplete Information Correlated Equilibrium in Games with Incomplete Information Dirk Bergemann and Stephen Morris Econometric Society Summer Meeting June 2012 Robust Predictions Agenda game theoretic predictions are very

More information

Choked By Red Tape? The Political Economy of Wasteful Trade Barriers

Choked By Red Tape? The Political Economy of Wasteful Trade Barriers Choked By Red Tape? The Political Economy of Wasteful Trade Barriers Giovanni Maggi, Monika Mrázová and J. Peter Neary Yale, Geneva and Oxford Research Workshop on the Economics of International Trade

More information

Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements

Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements Lecture Notes: Self-enforcing agreements Bård Harstad ECON 4910 April 2017 Bård Harstad (ECON 4910) Self-enforcing agreements April 2017 1 / 15 Outline for today Motivation a. Concepts b. Repeated games

More information

The Condorcet Jur(ies) Theorem

The Condorcet Jur(ies) Theorem The Condorcet Jur(ies) Theorem David S. Ahn University of California, Berkeley Santiago Oliveros Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley September 2010 Abstract Two issues can be decided in a single election

More information

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-111 Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors NAGAMACHI Kohei Kagawa University The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry

More information

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. What is market design? Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them. This requires different tools and ideas than neoclassical economics, which

More information

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations 14.452 Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations Daron Acemoglu MIT November 20, 2018 Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Economic Growth Lecture 8 November 20, 2018 1 / 46 Growth with Overlapping Generations

More information

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case Mariagiovanna Baccara Leeat Yariv August 19, 2012 1 Introduction In this Appendix we study the information sharing application analyzed

More information

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility Toker Doganoglu and Julian Wright July 19, 2005 We would like to thank two anonymous referees and our editor, Simon Anderson, for their very helpful

More information

Sustainable tourism in for Sustaibale Danang

Sustainable tourism in for Sustaibale Danang Sustainable tourism in for Sustaibale Danang A case study of Balearic Ecotax in Spain toward Sustainable tourism Miki Yoshizumi Associate Professor College of Gastronomy Management Ritsumeikan University

More information

Strategic Abuse and Accuser Credibility

Strategic Abuse and Accuser Credibility 1 / 33 Strategic Abuse and Accuser Credibility HARRY PEI and BRUNO STRULOVICI Department of Economics, Northwestern University November 16th, 2018 Montréal, Canada 2 / 33 Motivation Many crimes/abuses

More information

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions Shaili Jain 1 and David C. Parkes 2 1 Yale University, New Haven, CT shaili.jain@yale.edu 2 Harvard University, Cambridge, MA parkes@eecs.harvard.edu Abstract.

More information

Costly Social Learning and Rational Inattention

Costly Social Learning and Rational Inattention Costly Social Learning and Rational Inattention Srijita Ghosh Dept. of Economics, NYU September 19, 2016 Abstract We consider a rationally inattentive agent with Shannon s relative entropy cost function.

More information

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance. Laura Veldkamp New York University, Stern School of Business, CEPR and NBER Spring 2009 1 Veldkamp What information consumes is rather obvious: It consumes

More information

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? APPENIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital? Santanu Chatterjee epartment of Economics Terry College of Business University of eorgia Appendix A The appendix describes the optimization problem

More information

Why on earth did you do that?!

Why on earth did you do that?! Why on earth did you do that?! A formal model of obfuscation-based choice Caspar 5-4-218 Chorus http://behave.tbm.tudelft.nl/ Delft University of Technology Challenge the future Background: models of decision-making

More information

The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1)

The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1) 183 The Role of Pre-trial Settlement in International Trade Disputes (1) Jee-Hyeong Park To analyze the role of pre-trial settlement in international trade dispute resolutions, this paper develops a simple

More information

Opportunities and challenges of HCMC in the process of development

Opportunities and challenges of HCMC in the process of development Opportunities and challenges of HCMC in the process of development Lê Văn Thành HIDS HCMC, Sept. 16-17, 2009 Contents The city starting point Achievement and difficulties Development perspective and goals

More information

Social Studies 3 Vocabulary Cards. century. History 1. period of 100 years

Social Studies 3 Vocabulary Cards. century. History 1. period of 100 years century History 1 period of 100 years chronological History 1 in order of time decade History 1 period of 10 years timeline History 1 list of important events in the order in which they happened year History

More information

Field Exam: Advanced Theory

Field Exam: Advanced Theory Field Exam: Advanced Theory There are two questions on this exam, one for Econ 219A and another for Economics 206. Answer all parts for both questions. Exercise 1: Consider a n-player all-pay auction auction

More information

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership Kazuhiko Kato and Leonard F.S. Wang December 29, 2012 Abstract The paper compares an emission tax and an emission quota in a

More information

Dynamic Games in Environmental Economics PhD minicourse Part I: Repeated Games and Self-Enforcing Agreements

Dynamic Games in Environmental Economics PhD minicourse Part I: Repeated Games and Self-Enforcing Agreements Dynamic Games in Environmental Economics PhD minicourse Part I: Repeated Games and Self-Enforcing Agreements Bård Harstad UiO December 2017 Bård Harstad (UiO) Repeated Games and SPE December 2017 1 / 48

More information

Online Appendix for "Affi rmative Action: One Size Does Not. Fit All"

Online Appendix for Affi rmative Action: One Size Does Not. Fit All Online ppendix for "ffi rmative ction: One Size Does Not Fit ll" Kala Krishna The Pennsylvania State University, CESifo and NBER lexander Tarasov University of Munich ugust 15 ppendix For Online Publication

More information

Costly Rehabilitation and Deterrence

Costly Rehabilitation and Deterrence Costly Rehabilitation and Deterrence Siddhartha Bandyopadhyay a and Nigar Hashimzade b,c a University of Birmingham; b Durham University; c CESifo 26 June 2017 SB & NH (Birmingham&Durham&CESifo) Rehabilitation

More information

3. When a researcher wants to identify particular types of cases for in-depth investigation; purpose less to generalize to larger population than to g

3. When a researcher wants to identify particular types of cases for in-depth investigation; purpose less to generalize to larger population than to g Chapter 7: Qualitative and Quantitative Sampling Introduction Quantitative researchers more concerned with sampling; primary goal to get a representative sample (smaller set of cases a researcher selects

More information

Hyperbolic Punishment Function

Hyperbolic Punishment Function Hyperbolic Punishment Function Ali al-nowaihi Sanjit Dhami 23 August 2011 Abstract All models in Law and Economics use punishment functions (PF) that incorporates a trade-off between probability of detection,

More information

MS&E 246: Lecture 18 Network routing. Ramesh Johari

MS&E 246: Lecture 18 Network routing. Ramesh Johari MS&E 246: Lecture 18 Network routing Ramesh Johari Network routing Last lecture: a model where N is finite Now: assume N is very large Formally: Represent the set of users as a continuous interval, [0,

More information

What do you do when you can t use money to solve your problems?

What do you do when you can t use money to solve your problems? Markets without money What do you do when you can t use money to solve your problems? Matching: heterosexual men and women marrying in a small town, students matching to universities, workers to jobs where

More information

Analysis of Violent Crime in Los Angeles County

Analysis of Violent Crime in Los Angeles County Analysis of Violent Crime in Los Angeles County Xiaohong Huang UID: 004693375 March 20, 2017 Abstract Violent crime can have a negative impact to the victims and the neighborhoods. It can affect people

More information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information Introduction to Games Normal (or Strategic) Form Representation Teoria dos Jogos - Filomena Garcia 1 Outline of Static Games of Complete Information

More information

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters Satoshi HONMA Abstract We study asymmetric pollution taxation on identical polluting oligopolists engaged in Cournot

More information

Sharing a Polluted River

Sharing a Polluted River Sharing a Polluted River Debing Ni School of Management University of Electronic Science and Technology of China Chengdu, Sichuan, P.R. China, 610054 Yuntong Wang Department of Economics University of

More information

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection Geethanjali Selvaretnam Abstract This model takes into consideration the fact that depositors

More information

6 Evolution of Networks

6 Evolution of Networks last revised: March 2008 WARNING for Soc 376 students: This draft adopts the demography convention for transition matrices (i.e., transitions from column to row). 6 Evolution of Networks 6. Strategic network

More information

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics 7. Special-interest politics Motivation Why do some groups in society receive more generous support than other (e.g. farmers)? Homogeneity in interests which allows more efficient organization of lobby

More information

Protocol between London MAPPA Strategic Management Board (SMB) and (Name of Borough) Local Safeguarding Children Board

Protocol between London MAPPA Strategic Management Board (SMB) and (Name of Borough) Local Safeguarding Children Board LONDON MULTI-AGENCY PUBLIC PROTECTION ARRANGEMENTS (MAPPA) Protocol between London MAPPA Strategic Management Board (SMB) and (Name of Borough) Local Safeguarding Children Board This protocol has been

More information

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation Yongmin Chen and David Sappington University of Colorado and University of Florida February 2016 1 / 32 1. Introduction Patent policy: patent protection

More information

Notes on Mechanism Designy

Notes on Mechanism Designy Notes on Mechanism Designy ECON 20B - Game Theory Guillermo Ordoñez UCLA February 0, 2006 Mechanism Design. Informal discussion. Mechanisms are particular types of games of incomplete (or asymmetric) information

More information

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems

How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems How to Characterize Solutions to Constrained Optimization Problems Michael Peters September 25, 2005 1 Introduction A common technique for characterizing maximum and minimum points in math is to use first

More information

1 Web Appendix: Equilibrium outcome under collusion (multiple types-multiple contracts)

1 Web Appendix: Equilibrium outcome under collusion (multiple types-multiple contracts) 1 Web Appendix: Equilibrium outcome under collusion (multiple types-multiple contracts) We extend our setup by allowing more than two types of agent. The agent s type is now β {β 1, β 2,..., β N }, where

More information

Lecturers: Jan Boone (ANR: ) and Clemens Fiedler

Lecturers: Jan Boone (ANR: ) and Clemens Fiedler cover page for a written examination/test Name of subject: Competition Policy and Regulation Subject code: 30L303 Date of examination: 8-06-016 Length of examination: 3 hours Lecturers: Jan Boone (ANR:

More information

Supervision, Collusion, and Optimal Contract Design with Costly Information Acquisition

Supervision, Collusion, and Optimal Contract Design with Costly Information Acquisition Supervision, Collusion, and Optimal Contract Design with Costly Information Acquisition XiaoGang Che Guanxi Yi PRELIMINARY and INCOMPLETE November 2014 Abstract In this paper, we study the impacts of costly

More information

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t )

+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t ) Eco504, Part II Spring 2006 C. Sims FTPL WITH MONEY 1. FTPL WITH MONEY This model is that of Sims (1994). Agent: [ ] max E β t log C t {C t,m t,b t } t=0 s.t. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) + M t + B t + τ t R t

More information

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM Perold: The CAPM Perold starts with a historical background, the development of portfolio theory and the CAPM. Points out that until 1950 there was no theory to describe the equilibrium determination of

More information

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation Roland Bénabou Jean Tirole. Review of Economic Studies 2003 Bénabou and Tirole Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation 1 / 30 Motivation Should a child be rewarded for passing

More information

Definitions and Proofs

Definitions and Proofs Giving Advice vs. Making Decisions: Transparency, Information, and Delegation Online Appendix A Definitions and Proofs A. The Informational Environment The set of states of nature is denoted by = [, ],

More information

Notes on General Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium Notes on General Equilibrium Alejandro Saporiti Alejandro Saporiti (Copyright) General Equilibrium 1 / 42 General equilibrium Reference: Jehle and Reny, Advanced Microeconomic Theory, 3rd ed., Pearson

More information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * ANNALS OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE 16-1, 231 253 (2015) Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption * Hongkun Ma School of Economics, Shandong University,

More information

A Summary of Economic Methodology

A Summary of Economic Methodology A Summary of Economic Methodology I. The Methodology of Theoretical Economics All economic analysis begins with theory, based in part on intuitive insights that naturally spring from certain stylized facts,

More information

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract Entry under an Information-Gathering onopoly Alex Barrachina* June 2016 Abstract The effects of information-gathering activities on a basic entry model with asymmetric information are analyzed. In the

More information

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ). University of California, Davis Date: August 24, 2017 Department of Economics Time: 5 hours Microeconomics Reading Time: 20 minutes PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D. DEGREE Please answer any three

More information

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES KYOTO INSTITUTE OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Discussion Paper No.992 Intertemporal efficiency does not imply a common price forecast: a leading example Shurojit Chatterji, Atsushi

More information

Chapter 9. Hypothesis testing. 9.1 Introduction

Chapter 9. Hypothesis testing. 9.1 Introduction Chapter 9 Hypothesis testing 9.1 Introduction Confidence intervals are one of the two most common types of statistical inference. Use them when our goal is to estimate a population parameter. The second

More information

Advanced Quantitative Research Methodology Lecture Notes: January Ecological 28, 2012 Inference1 / 38

Advanced Quantitative Research Methodology Lecture Notes: January Ecological 28, 2012 Inference1 / 38 Advanced Quantitative Research Methodology Lecture Notes: Ecological Inference 1 Gary King http://gking.harvard.edu January 28, 2012 1 c Copyright 2008 Gary King, All Rights Reserved. Gary King http://gking.harvard.edu

More information

Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium.

Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium. Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium. Social welfare function: assigns social welfare value (real number) to each profile of utility levels (u 1,u 2,...u I ): W (u 1,u 2,...u I ) (Utilitarian welfare).

More information

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 28 Jun 2016 On the Inefficiency of Forward Markets in Leader-Follower Competition Desmond Cai, Anish Agarwal, Adam Wierman arxiv:66.864v [math.oc] 8 Jun 6 June 9, 6 Abstract Motivated by electricity markets, this

More information

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information) Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan 200 Good luck!!! Question (duopoly games with imperfect information) Consider a duopoly game in which the inverse demand function is linear where it is positive

More information

Preliminary Statistics Lecture 5: Hypothesis Testing (Outline)

Preliminary Statistics Lecture 5: Hypothesis Testing (Outline) 1 School of Oriental and African Studies September 2015 Department of Economics Preliminary Statistics Lecture 5: Hypothesis Testing (Outline) Gujarati D. Basic Econometrics, Appendix A.8 Barrow M. Statistics

More information

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization 14.773 Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization Daron Acemoglu MIT March 5, 2013. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Political Economy Lecture 8 March 5,

More information

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction Susumu Sato July 9, 2018 I study a monopoly regulation in the setting where consumers can engage in demand-reducing investments. I first

More information

Cumulative Harm, Products Liability, and Bilateral Care* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum

Cumulative Harm, Products Liability, and Bilateral Care* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum Cumulative Harm, Products Liability, and Bilateral Care* 1 Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum Names, affiliations, and email addresses of authors: Andrew F. Daughety, Department of Economics

More information

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) subject to for all t Jonathan Heathcote updated, March 2006 1. The household s problem max E β t u (c t ) t=0 c t + a t+1

More information

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers joint work with Frederic Murphy Climate Policy and Long Term Decisions-Investment and R&D, Bocconi University, Milan,

More information

1. Money in the utility function (start)

1. Money in the utility function (start) Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 1/3 2012 Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen 1. Money in the utility function (start) a. The basic money-in-the-utility function model b. Optimal

More information

Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation. Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University

Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation. Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University 1 Outline Motivation The Model Discussion Extension Conclusion 2 Motivation 3 Economist

More information

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory variables in a regression model is simultaneity: that is, one

More information

The Time Consistency Problem - Theory and Applications

The Time Consistency Problem - Theory and Applications The Time Consistency Problem - Theory and Applications Nils Adler and Jan Störger Seminar on Dynamic Fiscal Policy Dr. Alexander Ludwig November 30, 2006 Universität Mannheim Outline 1. Introduction 1.1

More information