Estimating demand elasticities in the recent crises

Size: px
Start display at page:

Download "Estimating demand elasticities in the recent crises"

Transcription

1 Estimating demand elasticities in the recent crises Concetta Rondinelli PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. Abstract This paper studies consumer behavior in Italy during the recent recessions by estimating a demand system in which demand depends on income and prices, but also on other factors such as age, education, geographical area and position in the labour market of the household head. I combine Household Budget Survey data with information on prices between 2004 and The results point to a strong negative income effect for each of the expenditure items during the recession; less support is found for the existence of a substitution effect. The proportion of total expenditure geared toward the satisfaction of basic and difficult to compress needs (such as rents) is higher the lower is disposable income. The results suggest that the recovery of disposable income expected in the coming years should result in a significant recomposition of expenditure, towards the composition prevailing before the crisis. Keywords: consumer behavior, demand systems, price and income elasticities. JEL Codes: D12, E21. Bank of Italy, Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy Directorate, via Nazionale, 91, Roma Italy. concetta.rondinelli@bancaditalia.it. I am grateful to A. Brandolini, S. Siviero, R. Zizza and F. Zollino for their helpful comments and suggestions on a preliminary version of the paper. I would also like to thank O. Maizza (Ministero dello Sviluppo) for kindly providing me with price level data from 2004 to The usual disclaimer applies: the opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not involve the Bank of Italy. 1

2 1 Introduction About two thirds of the downturn in Italian GDP recorded between mid 2011 and end 2013 was due to factors affecting domestic demand (Busetti and Cova, 2013). At the end of 2014 Italian household consumption, which had been recovering slowly since the summer of 2013, was still nearly 8 per cent below the pre-crises level. Two consecutive recessions in five years may have induced Italian households not only to reduce their expenditure level, but also to adjust its composition. These adjustments stem from several mechanisms: a) the shift in the budget constrain determined by the fall in real disposable income (through unemployment, pay cuts, lower return from asset holdings; Rodano and Rondinelli, 2014); b) variations in the slope of the budget constraint due to changes in relative prices (Faiella and Mistretta, 2015); c) changes in preferences (Pozzolo, 2011). The severe contraction in income (-8.3% in , experienced over the recent years) is likely to have induced a re-composition in consumption: in order to minimize the impact of the fall of income on basic, not-easy-to compress expenses (such as rents and health which are inelastic to income), households may have reduced their consumption for leisure items, such as clothing and footwear, furniture and household services (Rondinelli et al., 2014). The crises may have also induced a change in households preferences, with a reduction in the quality of purchased goods and a more widespread recourse to discounts. Pozzolo (2011), for example, finds that during the Global Financial crisis Italian families consumed more chicken, reducing the quantity of veal, and preferred cheaper outlet types, such as discounts. As to the outlet type dimension, Lamey et al. (2007) show that during a recession consumers substitute towards private label products, similarly to what is expected for an inferior good if income falls. However, unlike what is expected for an inferior good, consumers continue to buy private label products after the economic recovery begins, resulting in a permanent increase in private label market share. The asymmetry in the response of the sales of private label products to the business cycle may arise because of differences between the perceived and intrinsic quality of private label goods. 1 1 Richardson et al. (1994) show that consumers perceive private label products to be of lower quality because of extrinsic cues such as branding or low prices. 2

3 Research on how consumer adjust their purchasing behavior across the business cycle has been (primarily) developed in the field of marketing, focussing on sales and profitability of individual firms. Deleersnyder et al. (2004) for example show that consumer behavior over the business cycle depends on both the rate of economic growth or decline and the size of the peaks and troughs, i.e. sales fall much quicker during contractions than they recover during economic expansions. Similarly, Gordon et al. (2013) find that price sensitivity is countercyclical: it rises when the economy weakens. Using the sharp changes in fuel prices to estimate the impact of short run changes in disposable income, Gicheva et al. (2010) find that consumers who experience a fall in income substitute toward lower-cost food and toward on-sale items. Coibon et al. (2012), using store level data, show that the average prices paid by consumers decline significantly with higher unemployment, by means of outlet substitution. Kamakura and Du (2012) suggest that these cyclical variations in consumption patterns are not exclusively a function of changes in the budget constraint but rather due to changes in the preferences of consumers. They state that during a recession, as consumers see others spending less on positional categories (i.e.purchases that signal a higher social status), they also adapt by reducing their expenditure on these categories as they can do so and still maintain their relative social standing. This paper studies consumer behavior in Italy during the recent recessions by estimating a demand system in which demand depends on income and prices, but also on other factors such as age, education, geographical area and position in the labour market of the household head. My contribution to the existing literature is twofold. The paper builds a novel dataset matching Household Budget Survey data and information on price levels to estimate whether over the recent Italian crises the consumption pattern of different expenditure components may have reflected (1) an income effect, (2) a change in the relative prices or both of them. In practice I estimate a set of equations describing how households with given characteristics allocate their total expenditure across different goods/services, given their price and households income. To the best of my knowledge, it is the first paper dealing with this issue for Italy. Secondly, given the evidence of possible non linearity of Engel curves for Italy, I allow the original Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS; Deaton and Muellbauer 1980) to include 3

4 a quadratic term in log(expenditure) (QUAIDS as in Banks, Blundell, and Lewbel, 1997), so that the demand system depends on income, both linearly and quadratically. Adding demographic variables and obtaining price and expenditure elasticities in these models is not an easy goal, as it requires a modification in the likelihood function (see Poi 2012), subject to parameter constraints, that makes the achievement of a maximum very difficult. The results point to a strong negative income effect for each of the expenditure items during the recession; less support is found for the existence of a substitution effect. This may also be due to the high degree of commodity aggregation into commodity bundles. The proportion of total expenditure geared toward the satisfaction of basic and difficult to compress needs (such as rents) is higher the lower is disposable income. The reminder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 I present the micro data on consumption and prices used to estimate the demand system, while Section 3 provides a descriptive analysis of the drop in consumption neglecting relative prices. Section 4 illustrates the estimation procedure and the main results. Section 5 wraps up the main findings of the paper discussing possible policy implications. 2 Data In this paper I construct a novel dataset matching survey data on consumption (Household Budget Survey) with price level data (underlining the construction of the Consumer Price Index). The matching is based on the regional dimension. 2.1 The Household Budget Survey The Household Budget Survey (HBS) is an annual survey conducted by the National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT). It provides information on the patterns and the level of consumption of Italian resident households according to various demographic and social characteristics. It is a continuous survey, involving approximately 28,000 households each year, sampled at random from the residence records of the municipalities involved in the Survey. The data is collected for 278 elementary consumption items, providing a very detailed picture of con- 4

5 sumption patterns. Sampling weights allow to expand the sample to the whole population. 2 Real consumption measures are obtained by deflating elementary nominal consumption items with the corresponding price indices from the Consumer Price Index (CPI). There have been several discussion about the quality of survey data and their ability to reproduce the movements in aggregate consumption from National Accounts (see Seslnick 1992 and Paulin et al for USA data; Banks and Johnson 1997 for UK). The studies stress that aggregate individual data and National Accounts (NA) are expected to diverge given 1. the different definition of goods and services, 2. the reference population and 3. measurement errors. For Italy, using a COICOP 3 classification (i.e. Classification of Individual Consumption by Purpose), Rondinelli et al. (2014) find that the main consumption aggregates in NA and HBS show differences in levels but similar dynamics, once the definition of households and the classification of services and goods in the two datasets are harmonized. Consequently, the results obtained from studying the evolution of expenditure on the basis of micro data may be viewed as consistent with the evolution of macro data. In Table 1 I regressed each of the expenditure components on a linear trend, a dummy variable for the crises (i.e. taking the value one over the years ) and some demographic characteristics of the household. It emerges that monthly total expenditure for durable goods was lower than in the pre-crises period by 2% on average, reflecting mainly the contraction of motoring. From official statistics (ACI, 2014) we know that new car registrations fell on average by 24% in the period , compared to Durable 2 The survey is based on three questionnaires: (1) dairy that records daily expenses, such as the amount spent for food (bread, pasta, meat, etc...) and current goods and services (newspapers, tobacco, bus tickets, etc...). (2) self-consumption, that records self-produced and auto-consumed goods, during the reference period (one week); (3) summary of expenditure, compiled by the interviewer at the beginning of the month following the period of reference. On this occasion the interviewer also records the socio-demographic characteristics of the households, expenses for housing, the cost of furniture and equipments, clothing and footwear, health, transport and communications, leisure, entertainment and education, other goods and services. 3 The 12 COICOP chapters are (1) food and non-alcoholic beverages; (2) alcoholic beverages and tobacco; (3) clothing and footwear; (4) housing, water, electricity and fuel; (5) furniture, and household services; (6) health services and health expenditures; (7) transport; (8) communications; (9) recreation, entertainment and culture; (10) education; (11) accommodation services and restaurants; (12) other goods and services. 5

6 Table 1: Average increase in expenditure in Coef. Std. errors Total expenditure (1.070) Durables *** (0.503) Household goods (0.0412) Leisure goods (0.252) Motoring *** (0.424) Semi-durables (0.515) Clothing and footwear (0.153) Housing 1.331*** (0.369) Non durables (0.317) Food (0.178) Alcohol *** (0.0245) Tobacco (0.0263) Energy 0.483*** (0.0674) Goods *** (0.0244) Medicines (0.0475) Fuel *** (0.0793) Leisure items ** (0.0418) Personal goods ** (0.0284) Notes: Author s calculation from the HBS, monthly data. Sample weights included. Each row reports the estimated coefficients obtained from regressing the different expenditure items on a dummy variable for the crises (taking value 1 in the years ), controlling also for a linear trend, age, geographical area, occupation, education of the household head and housing tenure. Durable expenditure includes household goods (washing machine, refrigerator, dishwashing), leisure goods (furniture, tv, suitcases, costume jewelry) and motoring (car, motorcycle); housing covers actual and imputed rents of the main and secondary house and maintenance; non durable expenses incorporate food, alcohol and tobacco, energy (bills like electricity, water, gas), goods (paper towels), medicines, fuels (petrol, diesel fuel), leisure items (newspapers, magazines) and personal goods (shampoo, soap, toothpaste). Standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. goods were seriously affected by the recession: they mainly represent luxuries, which are easier to postpone than necessities (see Browning and Crossley, 2000 and Crossley et al., 2012). Among non durables, leisure items (like newspapers and magazines) and fuels contributed to the drop in household consumption, the latter mainly reflecting the overall increase in Brent quotation observed over that period. Housing expenditure and payment of bills (mainly electricity and gas tariffs) went up during the crises. 2.2 Price levels The second dataset used in the paper includes price levels from Osservatorio Prezzi (OP, Ministero dello sviluppo). They are obtained from elementary items collected from the municipal offices of statistics within the construction of Consumer Price Index (CPI); these prices are available for each Italian province (NUTS3 level) as a minimum, maximum and average price. Since region (NUTS2) is the most detailed geographical dimension available 6

7 in HBS and OP, I evaluate mean price for goods for each of the 20 Italian regions. 4 Sampled goods, that include food, alcohol, clothing and footwear, rents, fuels, restaurant and other goods and services, represent about 17% of the items included in the official CPI by the National Institute of Statistics (see Rondinelli and Veronese, 2007). I checked that the selected goods were representative of the main COICOP aggregates. 5 Food products include meat, fruit and vegetables, milk, fish, oil and fats, bread and cereals accounting for about 80% of the processed and unprocessed foods covered in the CPI. To proxy COICOP 2 (alcoholic beverages and tobacco) wine and beer were included in the alcohol category; washing and ironing dresses for men and women is used to mimic the evolution of clothing and footwear (COICOP 3). The fuel class includes diesel and gasoline, while other goods and services (COICOP 12) include groceries such as shampoo, shower gel, toothpaste, laundry detergents, diapers and hair cut (for ladies and gentleman). Restaurant was verified to proxy the evolution over time of COICOP 11 and includes coffee, cappuccino, panini, etc. To proxy COICOP4, I enrich the OP dataset with actual rent prices at the provincial level recovered from the Consulente Immobiliare (CI), a semiannual survey conducted for a special review published by Il Sole 24 Ore media group: along with new house prices it collects data on new contract rents for a very large sample of Italian municipalities. In each sampled town, CI provides estimates of the average rent level (per square meter) of an apartment located in three areas: center, semi-center and suburbs. Rents are further distinguished into new and renewed contracts, the latter defined as contracts negotiated with previously sitting tenants upon contract expiration (see also Rondinelli and Veronese, 2011). 4 To recover the regional dimension I aggregated observations weighted by the resident population in each province. 5 Results are available upon request. 7

8 Table 2: Average price levels in the Italian regions. Food Alcohol Cloth. Rents Fuel Rest. Other Food Alcohol Cloth. Rents Fuel Rest. Other Food Alcohol Cloth. Rents Fuel Rest. Other Piemonte Valle d Lombardia Trentino Veneto Friuli Liguria Emilia Toscana Umbria Marche Lazio Abruzzi Molise Campania Puglia Basilicata Calabria Sicilia Sardegna Source: Author s calculation from OP and Consulente Immobiliare. Unit of measure is kg for food, liter for alcohol and fuel, one piece for clothing, restaurants and other goods and services, square meters for rents. 8

9 I will focus on the period to conduct a comparison before and after the recession (see also Fabiani and Porqueddu, 2014 for a description of price durations in the latest years). Price levels for selected years and across the Italian regions are reported in Table 2. I observe a general increase in price levels between 2005 and 2012 common to all Italian regions and products. Except for fuel, the highest increase has occurred between 2005 and Since the beginning of the recession food and fuel prices have almost doubled in all Italian regions; the latter reflected the rapid rise experienced by oil quotations in that years. Prices for other goods and services went up by 40% between 2005 and 2012; rents increased by 10% on average, the highest rise has been observed in Lazio. A downward trend was marked by clothing between 2005 and 2009, especially in Northern regions; a slight increase was observed between 2009 and Prices for coffee, cappuccino, panini, which are included in the restaurant category, increased by one quarter during the recession. 3 Neglecting relative prices in the expenditure drop To understand the role of the recent crises in consumption fall, I split the households along four dimensions, i.e. age, education, ownership of the household and geographical area. I first exploit the age dimension of the household head: the young (those aged less than 44), the middle aged (those aged 45 or greater and less than aged 64), and the old (those aged 65 or older). I estimate the following equation in which, for the time being, the effects of variation in relative prices are ignored: c it = α i + f(t) + β 1 crises + β 2 crises age it + β 3 age it + γz it + ɛ it (1) where c it indicates real expenditure for different items (food, energy, housing, etc...), Z it accounts for the main socio-demographic characteristics of the household head (age, education, geographical area and housing tenure), crises is a dummy variable taking value one for the years and f(t) is a linear trend capturing common trend in consumption. In Table 3 I show that during the crises monthly total expenditure was lower than in the pre-crises period by 3% on average for young households and by 5% for old ones, while higher by 17% for middle aged: the test of equality indicates that the three values, taken 9

10 pairwise, are not statistically equivalent at 1% level. The drop in durable goods, common to all age groups, has been more severe for retired households (about 6%), due to a fall in both leisure goods and, especially, motoring (values for young and old and for middle aged and old households are not statistically equivalent at 1% level). Semidurable and nondurable goods were higher for middle aged household; for them household bills were higher than in the precrises period by 2% on average compared to 1.5% for old households (t-stat of equality=0.06). Fuel expenditure (petrol and diesel fuel) was lower by 0.6% for young households and by 3% household aged 65 and over, possibly reflecting their reduced need of cars (to go to work, for example; see also Faiella and Mistretta, 2015). As to the leisure items, their consumption was higher for household aged 45 and over, while adjusting downwards for Table 3: Average effect of the crises. Crises X 0-44 Crises X Crises X 65+ Crises X Low Crises X Medium Crises X High Crises X Owner (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Total expenditure ** *** *** *** *** *** *** Durables *** *** *** *** *** 1.61 *** 2.61 *** Household goods *** 0.41 *** Leisure goods *** *** *** *** 1.82 *** Motoring *** *** *** *** *** Semi-durables * 7.93 *** *** *** ** *** *** Clothing and footwear *** *** *** *** 3.77 *** Housing 1.55 *** 1.72 *** 3.18 *** *** 1.41 *** *** *** Non durables *** 1.18 *** *** *** *** *** Food *** 2.08 *** *** *** *** 4.57 *** Alcohol *** 0.08 ** *** *** *** Tobacco *** *** *** *** *** Energy 0.48 *** 2.19 *** 1.50 *** *** 0.60 *** 0.65 *** 2.48 *** Goods 0.12 *** 0.33 *** 0.14 *** *** *** Medicines *** 1.13 *** ** * *** Fuel *** 0.53 *** *** *** *** *** 2.03 *** Leisure *** 0.86 *** 0.28 *** *** *** 0.63 *** 0.50 *** Personal *** ** *** *** 0.35 *** Notes: Author s calculation from the HBS. Sample weights included. Columns (1)-(3) report the estimated coefficients obtained regressing the expenditure categories on age, education, occupation, geographical area of the household head, housing tenure, a linear trend, a dummy variable taking value one over the years and the interaction of the dummy variable with age. Column (4)-(6) report the estimated coefficients obtained regressing the expenditure categories on age, education, occupation, geographical area of the household head, housing tenure, a linear trend, a dummy variable taking value one over the years and the interaction of the dummy variable with education. Durable expenditure includes household goods (washing machine, refrigerator, dishwashing), leisure goods (furniture, tv, suitcases, costume jewelry) and motoring (car, motorcycle); housing covers actual and imputed rents of the main and secondary house and maintenance; non durable expenses incorporate food, alcohol and tobacco, energy (bills like electricity, water, gas), goods (paper towels), medicines, fuels (petrol, diesel fuel), leisure items (newspapers, magazines) and personal goods (shampoo, soap, toothpaste). *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. I repeated the same exercise looking at the effect of the recession across three educational levels: low (including none and primary school), medium and high education (Table 3, 10

11 columns (4)-(6)). Over the period total monthly expenditure was lower than in the pre-crises period by 30% on average for low educated households, while higher by 35% for high educated (t-stat on equality=0.000). The fall in durable goods has been concentrated among households with medium or low education. Among non durable goods, food expenditure decreased more for low educated, by about 4% (two times more than high educated); also the reduction of fuel consumption was concentrated in the lowest part of the education distribution. The expenditure for leisure items was higher than in the pre-crises period by about 1% for high educated, while lower (by the same amount) for low ones (test of equality of coefficient reject that the two coefficients are statistically equivalent). House expenditure significantly reduced for low educated households, reflecting a compression of maintenance expenditure in a period of a downward trend in house prices; compared to renters housing tenure constituted an insurance against the drop in total consumption and its main components (Table 3, column (7)). As to the geographical dimension, the effect of the crises was less perceived in Northern regions, compared to Southern ones. 6 All in all, younger, and to a less extent older, households were most affected by the economic downturn; those middle aged, living in Northern regions, high educated and owners of a house could instead easily cope with the recession. In Figure 1 I plotted the empirical non parametric Engel curve, representing the relationship between the budget share for good i and household expenditure, for the seven COICOP aggregation as illustrated in Section Although the linear formulation appears a reasonable approximation for the food share curve, a clear nonlinear behavior is evident, in the raw data, for alcohol, clothing, restaurant and other goods and services. Notice also that the Engel curve as a clear positive slope for fuel, suggesting that petrol and diesel are luxury goods, and a negative one for food, indicating it is a necessary item. 6 Results available upon request. 7 Notice that, to proxy COICOP 2 (alcoholic beverages and tobacco) wine and beer were included in the alcohol category; washing and ironing dresses for men and women is used to mimic the evolution of clothing and footwear (COICOP 3). The fuel class is composite of diesel and gasoline, while other goods and services (COICOP 12) include groceries like shampoo, shower gel, toothpaste, laundry detergents, diapers and hair cut (for ladies and gentleman). Restaurant was verified to proxy the evolution over time for COICOP 11 and include coffee, cappuccino, panini, etc. To proxy COICOP4, I use actual rents. 11

12 Though the exercise presented in the Section is telling about the distributive effect of the recession, it neglects that the reduction in expenditure operated by households may also be due to a variation in relative prices. Between 2009 and 2012 indeed brent quotation increased by 80%, given that fuel prices impact on expenditure for heating, private transport and electricity we could expect that to cope with the increase in energy prices households adjusted the composition of the expenditure of the remaining items. At the same time, house and rent prices decreased. To account for these issues I estimate a system of demand equations in the next Section. 4 Estimating demand elasticities 4.1 Model Specification One of the most widely used specifications in applied demand analysis is the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) model proposed by Deaton and Muellbauer (1980). The model features budget shares as dependent variables and logarithm of prices and real expenditure/income as regressors. Although AIDS model allows for a linear approximation in prices and expenditure it is not easy to be fitted with commonly used software (like STATA), as it requires to write a function evaluator program as illustrated in Poi (2008). Additionally, various empirical Engel curve studies suggest that further terms in income may be required to achieve reliable estimations. Banks, Blundell, and Lewbel (1997) show that although the linear approximation is a reasonable approximation for the food and fuel share curves, for alcohol and clothing a non linear specification is more reliable. The original AIDS model was subsequently extended to permit non-linear Engel curves. The resulting model, proposed by Banks, Blundell, and Lewbel (1997), is the Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System (QUAIDS). Under QUAIDS, the i th budget share (w i ) equation for household h is given by w ih = α i + n j=1 where i = 1,..., n indicates good i, w ih = p ih q ih /x h and { } xh γ ij lnp j + β i ln + λ [ { }] 2 i xh ln (2) a(p) b(p) a(p) 12

13 ln(a(p)) = α 0 + n α k lnp k k=1 n k=1 j=1 n γ kj lnp k lnp j where p i is the price of good i and x stands for the total consumption expenditure; b(p) is the Cobb-Douglas price aggregator b(p) = We need to estimate αs, βs, γs and λs. n k=1 From the utility maximization problem under a budget constraint we need to impose the following restrictions: p β k k n n α i = 1; γ ij = 0; i=1 i=1,j=1 i=1 n β j = 0; i λ i = 0 (3) γ ij = 0 (4) j γ ij = γ ij (5) The equalities in (3) are the adding-up restrictions. They express the property that the sum of the budget shares equals 1 (i.e. ih w ih = 1). The restriction in (4) accounts for the prediction that the demand functions are homogenous of degree zero in prices and income. Satisfaction of the restriction in (5) ensures that Slutsky symmetry would hold true. 8 Appendix A I prove how to generalize equation 2 to allow for the demographic characteristic of the household. 8 The Slutsky equation decomposes the change in demand for good i in response to a change in the price of good j into two terms, a substitution and an income effect: x i (p, w) = h i(p, w) x i(p, w) x j (p, w) p j p j w In 13

14 4.2 Estimation Procedure In this Section I estimate demand elasticities by using the HBS integrated with price levels data available from Osservatorio Prezzi, exploiting the regional dimension. I will focus on seven groups of consumer s expenditure. I estimate QUAIDS incorporating demographic variables as in Ray s (1983), as illustrated in the Appendix A. To estimate the parameters of the QUAIDS, I use the maximum likelihood approach (Poi, 2002; Poi, 2008). The results of the estimates for αs, βs, γs and λs of equation (2) with demographic variables, ηs and ρs, are provided in Table 4. Most of the parameters are statistically significant at the 1% level. In particular, the estimates of the parameters λ, that regulate the effect of the second order coefficient on budget shares (thus allowing for nonlinear Engel curves), are statistically significant for most of the seven commodity groups; this confirms the relevance of the quadratic term extension of the linear AIDS. The quadratic term in the logarithm of expenditure is close to zero only in case of restaurants (in 2013, 2012 and 2004) and other goods and services (in 2011, 2008 and 2005). Thus, omitting the quadratic term of the remaining commodities from the analysis would bias the estimates. Even if we are generally interested in income elasticities, I say something on the estimated βs by splitting the population according the equivalised consumption distribution. As changes in real expenditure operates through the βs, in Figure 2 I report the estimated βs from the budget share equation (2) from 2004 to These coefficients add to zero (by construction) and are positive for luxuries and negative for necessities for each year. Excluding 2013, over the last recession we have observed an increase (in absolute value) of the estimated coefficients, particularly marked at the end of the sample. Even if the estimated βs do not change considerably across years, a formal test of equality of means reveals that the estimated coefficients are not statistically different over two consecutive years for alcohol, clothing and footwear and restaurants. If I split the sample considering households below and above the median of the equivalised consumption distribution, I find that clothing, restaurants and other good and services are considered a luxury for poor households. Rents 9 Notice that the βs are different from Table 4, as they are estimated without demographics to allow for a break of the population below and above the median of equivalised distribution. 14

15 are a luxury good for households at the top of the distribution and a necessity for those at the bottom. The same remark applies to fuel. As we are often more interested in the expenditure and price elasticities rather than in the estimated coefficients per se, I present the results in the two Sections below Expenditure elasticities I now consider income elasticities across the relevant characteristics of the households. Income elasticities measure the responsiveness of demand of a specific good to changes in expenditure, i.e. it shows how the quantity purchased changes in response to a change in consumer expenditure, which is a proxy for total household income. 10 The higher the income elasticity, the more sensitive consumer demand is to income changes. 11 In Figure 3 I plot the income elasticities; they are calculated for each individual household and subsequently averaged. Based on the estimates, the commodity bundle of food, alcohol (that includes wine and beer) and housing are necessary goods, as their budget elasticity is positive and below one at the same time. On the contrary, I identified clothing, fuel, restaurants and other goods and services as luxury goods, with income elasticity well above one. Although income elasticities do not change considerably across years, a formal test of 10 Although expenditure is commonly used as a proxy for income, notice that over during the Sovereign Debt crisis consumption initially diminished at about the same pace as income and then, starting in the second quarter of 2013, fell much more steeply, owing in part to the simultaneous drop in household wealth (Rodano and Rondinelli, 2014). Additionally, if total expenditure is jointly determined with the budget shares of the specific commodities in the demand model, total expenditure becomes endogenous in the budget share equations. This may induce inconsistent parameter estimates if not taken care of; Blundell and Robin (1999) illustrate a two step augmented regression technique to solve the problem. First, total expenditure is regressed on a set of exogenous variables including those which may directly influence budget shares. In the second step, the residual from this reduced-form regression is added, as an explanatory variable in the budget share equations together with total expenditure. This extension is left for future research. 11 A good is called a normal good if its budget elasticity is positive. Specifically, so-called normal necessities have an income elasticity between 0 and 1; demand for such goods increases with income, but their budget share decreases. Luxury goods are goods with income elasticity of demand above 1; demand is highly sensitive to any change in income and the budget share increases with income. Finally, inferior goods have negative income elasticity. Thus, demand for this type of good falls as income rises. 15

16 equality of means reveals that means are statistically different from each other at any level greater or equal than 1% for the years before and after the recession. This evidence confirms the importance of the income effect for each of the seven expenditure items. Before the crisis started, a 10% increase in income would have induced an increase of 4% in food expenditure for youngest households and of 7% for oldest ones; I observe a gradual convergence of all age groups to a value of 6% in 2013 (Figure 4). Looking at the distribution of equivalised income we notice that poorer households are more sensitive than richer ones to a change in income: a 10% increase in income would induce food expenditure to raise by 4% for high income households and by 8% for low ones; however I do not find any significant change in the recession. No relevant variation is found for housing. More interestingly, the estimated expenditure elasticity for clothing and footwear remained roughly unchanged for households heads aged less than 44 and decreased for retired ones, meaning that cloth expenditure became for them less sensitive to an income increase. Additionally, an upward trend is observed for restaurant elasticity for households 65 and over from , while a downward for youngest between I also present the fitted Engel curves, once controlling for relative prices and estimating a system of demand equations. The Engel curves in Figure 5 confirm the importance of nonlinearities and suggest that food and rents are necessary goods, while cloths, fuel, restaurants and other goods and services luxuries. More interestingly, the inverse U-shape empirical Engel curve for clothing (Banks et al., 1997), that includes services like the washing and ironing dresses for men and women, turns out to have an upward slope once estimating a QUAIDS model. This suggests, that for high income households the budget share allocated to cloth services is higher than for low income ones, differently from the empirical curves that instead indicate an equal budget share for high and low income. I also notice that during the recession the Engel curve shifted downwards for high income households. The same figure applies to restaurants. For fuel the fitted Engel curve has the same shape than empirical one, although with a downward shift for richer households. There is also evidence that the share allocated to rents decreases with income, while the empirical Engel curve suggests an increase in the budget share for wealthier households. 16

17 Given the severe contraction in income over the recent recession and the importance of the income effect estimated for each of the seven expenditure items, the analysis suggests that the satisfaction of basic needs and difficult to compress in the short term (such as spending on rents) absorbs a larger proportion of total expenditure, especially for poor households Price elasticities In Tables 5 and 6 I provide estimates of compensated 12 and uncompensated 13 price elasticities. Notice that, the own-price elasticities are negative for all commodity groups, as expected; the cross elasticities are higher than the own elasticities. This indicates that individual commodity groups do not have any strong substitutes or complements among the remaining ones; this observation could have been affected by the degree of commodity aggregation into commodity bundles. Using more detailed commodity bundles, one might find a higher degree of substitutability, for example between wine and beer. 14 The use of more aggregated expenditure items, however, helps in solving the problem of zero-expenditure, a common feature of survey consumption data. 15 Based on the size of the own-price elasticities, I found demand for alcohol, clothing, fuel and restaurants to be the most affected by changes in their own prices. In addition, looking only at the substitution effect of a price change, presented in Table 5, fuel and restaurants are classified as goods with price elastic demand: since the commodity bundle of fuels includes 12 The Hicksian demand curve is called the compensated demand curve because consumers are compensated for the price change. That is, when prices change they receive a compensation that allows them to remain on their original indifference curve (substitution effect). 13 Marshallian demand indicates how the quantity of a good changes to a price variation, when income is held constant. 14 A greater detail in the number of goods considered would however compromise the maximization of the likelihood. 15 Apart from imperfect recall, three main reasons for zero-expenditures can be identified: (i) permanent zero expenditure, (ii) zero expenditure during the survey period, (iii) recall bias. Unfortunately, it is not possible to identify which of these reasons is responsible for each of the reported zero-expenditures from HBS data. In presence of zero-expenditure or censored dependent variable, we know that the econometric estimates that neglect censoring (due to a sample selection problem) are biased and inconsistent (Maddala, 1983). However, aggregation over commodities helps in reducing the problem. 17

18 diesel and gasoline, a 1% increase in prices of crude materials reduces household expenditure for fuel by 1.4%. Clothing and alcohol have also a price elasticity close to 1. On the contrary, I find food, housing and other goods to be relatively less affected by changes in prices. The stories told by compensated and uncompensated price elasticities seem to be comparable. Additionally, compared to 2005 during the recession compensated price elasticities increased for food, housing and other goods, while decreasing for the remaining categories. I now simulate a 30% increase in prices of a necessary good (housing) and of a leisure service (restaurant). The results, reported in Table 7, show that a rise in rents would induce a reduction in cloths expenditure both in normal times and, especially (about twice as much), in period of crises; households continue to buy restaurant related items (coffee, cappuccino, etc...) in normal times, while they compress the related consumption in recession. Additionally, an increase in restaurant prices, would result in a rise in housing expenditure in non recessionary periods about twice as much than in recessionary ones; in particular household react increasing (decreasing) cloth services expenditure by about 4% in normal (recession) times. 5 Conclusions This study estimates demand elasticities in Italy. I use the Household Budget Survey and Osservatorio Prezzi dataset to implement the QUAIDS model of Banks et al. (1997), allowing for a detailed analysis of commodities and including characteristics of consumers. I estimate the stochastic version of the demand system for a representative household extended to include demographic variables, such as age, geographical area, education and the position in the labour market of the household head. I focuss on goods representing about 17% of the items included in the official CPI by the National Institute of Statistics; food products as a whole cover about 80% of the processed and unprocessed food in the CPI. I threat the recent recession as a whole episode of downturn and focuss on years to conduct a comparison before and after the recession. The estimated Engel curves appear to be non linear for most of the goods, justifying the relevance of the quadratic term in the logarithm of expenditure. I estimate a downward slope 18

19 for housing and food expenditure (whose income elasticity is below one) and a positive slope for cloth, fuel, restaurant (income elasticity well above one). In particular, the estimated curves differ from the empirical ones, with a U-shaped reverse, for clothing and footwear and restaurants, especially for the wealthiest families. In addition, the satisfaction of basic needs and difficult to compress in the short term (such as spending on rents) absorbs, following to a reduction in income, a larger proportion of total expenditure. I find that households tend to promptly adjust their fuel consumption due to a change in price of diesel and gasoline; however we do not point out any particular substitution effect across the seven group of items considered, possibly due to the high degree of commodity aggregation into commodity bundles. The estimates of a system of demand equation show a strong negative income effect during the recent crises for each of the expenditure items. It is also possible that the income effect masks a change in household s preferences with a reduction in the quality of purchased goods, a more widespread recourse to discounts or an extension in the mean duration of durable goods, that I cannot control with these models. Given the fall in the purchasing power of households in the course of the recession, this paper documents a greater difficulty of poorer households in addressing basic needs. The recovery of disposable income expected in the coming years should result in a significant recomposition of expenditure, towards the composition prevailing before the crisis. 19

20 Table 4: Estimated coefficients for the budget share equation Coef. Std. Coef. Std. Coef. Std. Coef. Std. Coef. Std. Coef. Std. alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda alpha lambda beta eta beta etaage beta etaage beta etaage beta etaage beta etaage beta etaage beta etaage gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaeduc gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaoccup gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma etaarea gamma rho gamma rhoage gamma rhoeduc gamma rhooccup gamma rhoarea gamma gamma gamma Source: Author s calculation from the HBS and PO. 1=food, 2=alcohol, 3=clothing, 4=rents, 5=fuel, 6=restaurant, 7=other goods and services. Age, educ, occup and area are the age, educational level, occupation and geographical area of residence of the household head. 20

21 Table 5: Compensated price elasticity Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Notes: Author s calculation from the HBS and PO. The entry in row i, column j informs about a percentage change in quantity demanded for a good in row i as price of a good in column j increases by 1%. Table 6: Uncompensated price elasticity Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Source: Author s calculation from the HBS and PO. The entry in row i, column j informs about a percentage change in quantity demanded for a good in row i as price of a good in column j increases by 1%. 21

22 Table 7: A simulation exercise. 30% increase in rent prices 30% increase in restaurant prices Food Alcohol Clothing Rents Fuel Restaurant Other goods Notes: Author s calculation from the HBS and PO. The entry in row i informs about a percentage change in quantity demanded for a good i as prices of rents and restaurant increase by 30%. 22

23 Budget Share Budget Share Budget Share Budget Share Budget Share Budget Share.2.4 Budget Share Figure 1: Non parametric empirical Engel curves Food Alcol Log (expenditure) Log (expenditure) Cloth Rents Log (expenditure) Log (expenditure) Fuel Rest Log (expenditure) Log (expenditure) Other Log (expenditure) Notes: My calculation from HBS 23

24 Figure 2: Estimated betas Notes: My calculation from HBS and OP. Estimated βs for total population and households below and above median of equivalised distribution (QUAIDS estimated without demographics). 24

25 Figure 3: Income elasticities Notes: My calculation from HBS and OP. 25

Published by the Stationery Office, Dublin, Ireland.

Published by the Stationery Office, Dublin, Ireland. An Phríomh-Oifig Staidrimh Central Statistics Office Published by the Stationery Office, Dublin, Ireland. Available from the: Central Statistics Office, Information Section, Skehard Road, Cork October

More information

MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS

MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS CPI SERI 2 EDITION ONE ISSUE www.dne.mof.gov.tl MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA

More information

MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS

MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA DIRECÇÃO NACIONAL DE ESTATÍSTICA ECONOMICAS E SOCIAIS CPI SERI 2 EDITION THIRD ISSUE www.dne.mof.gov.tl MINISTÉRIO DAS FINANÇAS DIRECÇÃO GERAL DE ESTATÍSTICA

More information

BRITISH VIRGIN ISLANDS SECTORAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT MARKET PRICES (current prices) (US$M)

BRITISH VIRGIN ISLANDS SECTORAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT MARKET PRICES (current prices) (US$M) SECTORAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT MARKET PRICES (current prices) Sector 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000r 2001r 2002r 2003r 2004r 2005e Agriculture, Hunting & Forestry 1.36 1.50 1.63 1.77

More information

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II Economics 5113 Microeconomic Theory Kam Yu Winter 2018 Outline 1 Introduction to Duality Theory Indirect Utility and Expenditure Functions Ordinary and Compensated Demand

More information

Press Release Consumer Price Index March 2018

Press Release Consumer Price Index March 2018 Consumer Price Index, base period December 2006 March 2018 The Central Bureau of Statistics presents the most important findings for the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the month of March 2018. The CPI

More information

Sub-national PPPs: Country case studies. Publications, experiments and projects on the computation of spatial price level differences in Italy

Sub-national PPPs: Country case studies. Publications, experiments and projects on the computation of spatial price level differences in Italy 3rd Meeting of the Country Operational Guidelines Task Force Sub-national PPPs: Country case studies Publications, experiments and projects on the computation of spatial price level differences in Italy

More information

Press Release Consumer Price Index October 2017

Press Release Consumer Price Index October 2017 Consumer Price Index, base period December 2006 October 2017 The Central Bureau of Statistics presents the most important findings for the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the month of October 2017. The

More information

Press Release Consumer Price Index April 2018

Press Release Consumer Price Index April 2018 [Type text] Press Release Consumer Price Index April 2018 Consumer Price Index, base period December 2006 April 2018 The Central Bureau of Statistics presents the most important findings for the Consumer

More information

Press Release Consumer Price Index December 2014

Press Release Consumer Price Index December 2014 Consumer Price Index, base period December 2006 December 2014 The Central Bureau of Statistics presents the most important findings for the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the month of December 2014. The

More information

Press Release Consumer Price Index December 2018

Press Release Consumer Price Index December 2018 [Type text] Press Release Consumer Price Index December 2018 Consumer Price Index, base period December 2006 December 2018 The Central Bureau of Statistics presents the most important findings for the

More information

Econometrics Lecture 10: Applied Demand Analysis

Econometrics Lecture 10: Applied Demand Analysis Econometrics Lecture 10: Applied Demand Analysis R. G. Pierse 1 Introduction In this lecture we look at the estimation of systems of demand equations. Demand equations were some of the earliest economic

More information

Special Release (2006=100) (2006=100)

Special Release (2006=100) (2006=100) Special Release PHILIPPINE STATISTICS AUTHORITY PROVINCE OF AKLAN Volume IV Number 12 January 2016 INQUIRIES: For more information write or call: Philippine Statistics Authority N. Roldan St., Poblacion,

More information

Special Release (2006=100) (2006=100)

Special Release (2006=100) (2006=100) Special Release PHILIPPINE STATISTICS AUTHORITY PROVINCE OF AKLAN Volume IV Number 7 August INQUIRIES: For more information write or call: Philippine Statistics Authority N. Roldan St., Poblacion, Kalibo,

More information

Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100)

Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100) Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100) Food and non alcoholic beverages Alcoholic beverages and tobacco Clothing and footwear Housing water Furniture, electricity gas household and other fuels equipment

More information

Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100)

Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100) Consumer Price Index (December 2012=100) Food and non alcoholic beverages Alcoholic beverages and tobacco Clothing and footwear Housing water Furniture, electricity gas household and other fuels equipment

More information

Measuring Poverty. Introduction

Measuring Poverty. Introduction Measuring Poverty Introduction To measure something, we need to provide answers to the following basic questions: 1. What are we going to measure? Poverty? So, what is poverty? 2. Who wants to measure

More information

Directorate C: National Accounts, Prices and Key Indicators Unit C.3: Statistics for administrative purposes

Directorate C: National Accounts, Prices and Key Indicators Unit C.3: Statistics for administrative purposes EUROPEAN COMMISSION EUROSTAT Directorate C: National Accounts, Prices and Key Indicators Unit C.3: Statistics for administrative purposes Luxembourg, 17 th November 2017 Doc. A6465/18/04 version 1.2 Meeting

More information

JULY 2017 RESEARCH SERVICES DEPARTMENT RESEARCH AND ECONOMIC PROGRAMMING DIVISION

JULY 2017 RESEARCH SERVICES DEPARTMENT RESEARCH AND ECONOMIC PROGRAMMING DIVISION Short-term Inflation analysis and forecasts JULY 2017 RESEARCH SERVICES DEPARTMENT RESEARCH AND ECONOMIC PROGRAMMING DIVISION c 2017 Bank of Jamaica Nethersole Place Kingston Jamaica Telephone: (876) 922

More information

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES University of Wisconsin-Madison March 1996 No. 393 On Market Equilibrium Analysis By Jean-Paul Chavas and Thomas L. Cox AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES Copyright 1996 by Jean-Paul Chavas and

More information

Welfare Comparisons, Economies of Scale and Indifference Scale in Time Use

Welfare Comparisons, Economies of Scale and Indifference Scale in Time Use Welfare Comparisons, Economies of Scale and Indifference Scale in Time Use Crem, University of Rennes I May 7, 2013 Equivalence Scale for Welfare Comparisons Equivalence scales= tools to make interpersonal

More information

Economics th April 2011

Economics th April 2011 Economics 401 8th April 2011 Instructions: Answer 7 of the following 9 questions. All questions are of equal weight. Indicate clearly on the first page which questions you want marked. 1. Answer both parts.

More information

How Geography Affects Consumer Behaviour The automobile example

How Geography Affects Consumer Behaviour The automobile example How Geography Affects Consumer Behaviour The automobile example Murtaza Haider, PhD Chuck Chakrapani, Ph.D. We all know that where a consumer lives influences his or her consumption patterns and behaviours.

More information

Practice exam questions

Practice exam questions Practice exam questions Nathaniel Higgins nhiggins@jhu.edu, nhiggins@ers.usda.gov 1. The following question is based on the model y = β 0 + β 1 x 1 + β 2 x 2 + β 3 x 3 + u. Discuss the following two hypotheses.

More information

Introduction to Forecasting

Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Introduction to Forecasting Predicting the future Not an exact science but instead consists of a set of statistical tools and techniques that are supported by human judgment

More information

Energy Use in Homes. A series of reports on domestic energy use in England. Energy Efficiency

Energy Use in Homes. A series of reports on domestic energy use in England. Energy Efficiency Energy Use in Homes A series of reports on domestic energy use in England Energy Efficiency Energy Use in Homes A series of reports on domestic energy use in England This is one of a series of three reports

More information

Economic Impacts of Heritage Tourism in St. Johns County, Florida, by Tom Stevens, Alan Hodges and David Mulkey.

Economic Impacts of Heritage Tourism in St. Johns County, Florida, by Tom Stevens, Alan Hodges and David Mulkey. Economic Impacts of Heritage Tourism in St. Johns County, Florida, 2001-02 by Tom Stevens, Alan Hodges and David Mulkey University of Florida, Institute of Food and Agricultural Sciences, Food and Resource

More information

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014 Warwick Business School Forecasting System Summary Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 21 The main objective of the Warwick Business School Forecasting System is to provide competitive

More information

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter 013 Test 1 February 1, 013 Answer ALL Questions Time Allowed: 1 hour 0 min Attention: Please write your answers on the answer book provided Use the right-side pages

More information

SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODEL

SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODEL SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODEL ONE Equation Model (revisited) Characteristics: One dependent variable (Y): as a regressand One ore more independent variables (X): as regressors One way causality relationship:

More information

University of California at Berkeley Fall Introductory Applied Econometrics Final examination. Scores add up to 125 points

University of California at Berkeley Fall Introductory Applied Econometrics Final examination. Scores add up to 125 points EEP 118 / IAS 118 Elisabeth Sadoulet and Kelly Jones University of California at Berkeley Fall 2008 Introductory Applied Econometrics Final examination Scores add up to 125 points Your name: SID: 1 1.

More information

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT REALLY HAPPENED TO CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY IN THE US? Orazio Attanasio Erich Battistin Hidehiko Ichimura

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT REALLY HAPPENED TO CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY IN THE US? Orazio Attanasio Erich Battistin Hidehiko Ichimura NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHAT REALLY HAPPENED TO CONSUMPTION INEQUALITY IN THE US? Orazio Attanasio Erich Battistin Hidehiko Ichimura Working Paper 10338 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10338 NATIONAL BUREAU

More information

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999) The question we are asking is: What are the consequences of a monetary policy shock a shock which is purely related to monetary conditions

More information

DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY

DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY CHAPTER 3 DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY In the present chapter, sources of database used and methodology applied for the empirical analysis has been presented The whole chapter has been divided into three sections

More information

Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV

Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV Keynes and the Classics Notes on the Monetary Theory of Production Formelsammlung zu Wirtschaftstheorie IV Social production, value and distribution (436-445) The starting point is a Leontief price system:

More information

APPLICATION OF THE COUNTRY PRODUCT DUMMY METHOD TO CONSTRUCT SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL PRICE INDICES FOR SRI LANKA

APPLICATION OF THE COUNTRY PRODUCT DUMMY METHOD TO CONSTRUCT SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL PRICE INDICES FOR SRI LANKA APPLICATION OF THE COUNTRY PRODUCT DUMMY METHOD TO CONSTRUCT SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL PRICE INDICES FOR SRI LANKA Sri Lanka Journal of Economic Research Volume 2 (1) June 2014: 38-52 Sri Lanka Forum of University

More information

Making sense of Econometrics: Basics

Making sense of Econometrics: Basics Making sense of Econometrics: Basics Lecture 4: Qualitative influences and Heteroskedasticity Egypt Scholars Economic Society November 1, 2014 Assignment & feedback enter classroom at http://b.socrative.com/login/student/

More information

Exercices for Applied Econometrics A

Exercices for Applied Econometrics A QEM F. Gardes-C. Starzec-M.A. Diaye Exercices for Applied Econometrics A I. Exercice: The panel of households expenditures in Poland, for years 1997 to 2000, gives the following statistics for the whole

More information

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Neoclassical Business Cycle Model Prof. Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2015 1 / 36 Production Economy Last time: studied equilibrium in an endowment economy Now: study equilibrium in an economy

More information

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by, Dirk Bergemann Department of Economics Yale University Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/12 1. (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by, (x 1 + 2)

More information

Just a Few Keystrokes Away

Just a Few Keystrokes Away 0 8/8/2018 Financial Literacy Just a Few Keystrokes Away 1 Table of Contents Page 0 Page 1 Page 2 Page 3 Page 4 Page 5 Page 6 Page 7 Page 8 Page 9 Page 10 Page 11 Page 12 Page 13 Page 14 Page 1518 Cover

More information

Input-Output Accounting

Input-Output Accounting Input-Output Accounting UNSD SEEA Training of Trainers Seminar July 7-10, 2014, New York Joe St. Lawrence Statistics Canada The Economy and The Environment -Natural Resources -Ecosystem Services Stocks

More information

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection V. J. Hotz Rev. May 26, 2007 More on Roy Model of Self-Selection Results drawn on Heckman and Sedlacek JPE, 1985 and Heckman and Honoré, Econometrica, 1986. Two-sector model in which: Agents are income

More information

The Central Bank of Iceland forecasting record

The Central Bank of Iceland forecasting record Forecasting errors are inevitable. Some stem from errors in the models used for forecasting, others are due to inaccurate information on the economic variables on which the models are based measurement

More information

Energy Use in Homes 2007

Energy Use in Homes 2007 Energy Use in Homes 2007 A series of reports on domestic energy use in England Space and Water Heating Energy Use in Homes 2007 A series of reports on domestic energy use in England This is one of a series

More information

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam? Jean Louis Brillet, France For presentation at the LINK 2014 Conference New York, 22nd 24th October, 2014 Advertisement!!! The model uses EViews The

More information

Economic Theory of Spatial Costs. of Living Indices with. Application to Thailand

Economic Theory of Spatial Costs. of Living Indices with. Application to Thailand Economic Theory of Spatial Costs of Living Indices with Application to Thailand spatial 5/10/97 ECONOMIC THEORY OF SPATIAL COSTS OF LIVING INDICES WITH APPLICATION TO THAILAND by N.Kakwani* School of Economics

More information

The cover page of the Encyclopedia of Health Economics (2014) Introduction to Econometric Application in Health Economics

The cover page of the Encyclopedia of Health Economics (2014) Introduction to Econometric Application in Health Economics PHPM110062 Teaching Demo The cover page of the Encyclopedia of Health Economics (2014) Introduction to Econometric Application in Health Economics Instructor: Mengcen Qian School of Public Health What

More information

Spatial Variation in Prices and Expenditure Inequalities in Australia

Spatial Variation in Prices and Expenditure Inequalities in Australia DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ISSN 1441-5429 DISCUSSION PAPER 34/13 Spatial Variation in Prices and Expenditure Inequalities in Ankita Mishra and Ranjan Ray 1 Abstract This paper extends the recent literature

More information

Volume 30, Issue 1. Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan

Volume 30, Issue 1. Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan Volume 30, Issue 1 Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan Akihiko Noda Graduate School of Business and Commerce, Keio University Shunsuke Sugiyama

More information

Chapter 10 Nonlinear Models

Chapter 10 Nonlinear Models Chapter 10 Nonlinear Models Nonlinear models can be classified into two categories. In the first category are models that are nonlinear in the variables, but still linear in terms of the unknown parameters.

More information

Demand analysis is one of the rst topics come to in economics. Very important especially in the Keynesian paradigm.

Demand analysis is one of the rst topics come to in economics. Very important especially in the Keynesian paradigm. 1 Demand Analysis Demand analysis is one of the rst topics come to in economics. Very important especially in the Keynesian paradigm. Very important for companies: mainstay of consultancies As have seen

More information

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances Johannes Brumm University of Zurich Georgios Georgiadis European Central Bank Johannes Gräb European Central Bank Fabian Trottner Princeton

More information

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated Chapter 4 The Consumer Exercise 4.1 You observe a consumer in two situations: with an income of $100 he buys 5 units of good 1 at a price of $10 per unit and 10 units of good 2 at a price of $5 per unit.

More information

Euro-indicators Working Group

Euro-indicators Working Group Euro-indicators Working Group Luxembourg, 9 th & 10 th June 2011 Item 9.3 of the Agenda Towards an early warning system for the Euro area By Gian Luigi Mazzi Doc 308/11 Introduction Clear picture of economic

More information

Re-estimating Euler Equations

Re-estimating Euler Equations Re-estimating Euler Equations Olga Gorbachev September 1, 2016 Abstract I estimate an extended version of the incomplete markets consumption model allowing for heterogeneity in discount factors, nonseparable

More information

CHAPTER 18. Time Series Analysis and Forecasting

CHAPTER 18. Time Series Analysis and Forecasting CHAPTER 18 Time Series Analysis and Forecasting CONTENTS STATISTICS IN PRACTICE: NEVADA OCCUPATIONAL HEALTH CLINIC 18.1 TIME SERIES PATTERNS Horizontal Pattern Trend Pattern Seasonal Pattern Trend and

More information

Chapter 2: Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs

Chapter 2: Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs Microeconomics Canadian 15th Edition Ragan SOLUTIONS MANUAL Full clear download at: https://testbankreal.com/download/microeconomics-canadian-15th-editionragan-solutions-manual-2/ Microeconomics Canadian

More information

Response Errors and Interviewer Characteristics: A Multidimensional Analysis

Response Errors and Interviewer Characteristics: A Multidimensional Analysis Proceedings of Q2008 European Conference on Quality in Survey Statistics Response Errors and Interviewer Characteristics: A Multidimensional Analysis Massimo Greco, Matteo Mazziotta, Adriano Pareto 1 Keywords:

More information

Information Bulletin 9/2011

Information Bulletin 9/2011 Information Bulletin 9/2011 Warsaw, 2011 Compiled from NBP materials by the Department of Statistics as at November 1, 2011. Design: Oliwka s.c. Cover photo: Corbis/Free Layout and print: NBP Printshop

More information

Econometrics (60 points) as the multivariate regression of Y on X 1 and X 2? [6 points]

Econometrics (60 points) as the multivariate regression of Y on X 1 and X 2? [6 points] Econometrics (60 points) Question 7: Short Answers (30 points) Answer parts 1-6 with a brief explanation. 1. Suppose the model of interest is Y i = 0 + 1 X 1i + 2 X 2i + u i, where E(u X)=0 and E(u 2 X)=

More information

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics

Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Applied Microeconometrics (L5): Panel Data-Basics Nicholas Giannakopoulos University of Patras Department of Economics ngias@upatras.gr November 10, 2015 Nicholas Giannakopoulos (UPatras) MSc Applied Economics

More information

Energy Use in Homes 2004

Energy Use in Homes 2004 Energy Use in Homes 2004 A series of reports on domestic energy use in England Space and Water Heating Energy Use in Homes 2004 A series of reports on domestic energy use in England This is one of a series

More information

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE LECTURE 3. POLICY INTERACTIONS WITH TAX DISTORTIONS Eric M. Leeper Indiana University September 2008 THE MESSAGES Will study three models with distorting taxes First draws

More information

Marketing Research Session 10 Hypothesis Testing with Simple Random samples (Chapter 12)

Marketing Research Session 10 Hypothesis Testing with Simple Random samples (Chapter 12) Marketing Research Session 10 Hypothesis Testing with Simple Random samples (Chapter 12) Remember: Z.05 = 1.645, Z.01 = 2.33 We will only cover one-sided hypothesis testing (cases 12.3, 12.4.2, 12.5.2,

More information

4.1 Exponential Functions. For Formula 1, the value of n is based on the frequency of compounding. Common frequencies include:

4.1 Exponential Functions. For Formula 1, the value of n is based on the frequency of compounding. Common frequencies include: Hartfield MATH 2040 Unit 4 Page 1 4.1 Exponential Functions Recall from algebra the formulas for Compound Interest: Formula 1 For Discretely Compounded Interest 1 A t P r n nt Formula 2 Continuously Compounded

More information

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A Rice University Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall 006 ECON 50: Advanced Microeconomic Theory Part A. Consider the following expenditure function. e (p ; p ; p 3 ; u) = (p + p ) u + p 3 State

More information

Constrained optimization.

Constrained optimization. ams/econ 11b supplementary notes ucsc Constrained optimization. c 2016, Yonatan Katznelson 1. Constraints In many of the optimization problems that arise in economics, there are restrictions on the values

More information

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Endogenous Growth with Human Capital Consider the following endogenous growth model with both physical capital (k (t)) and human capital (h (t)) in continuous time. The representative household solves

More information

LEO Catchment Profile (LCP) Key Data for Enterprise Strategy

LEO Catchment Profile (LCP) Key Data for Enterprise Strategy Laois...Portarlington LEO Catchment Profile (LCP) Key Data for Enterprise Strategy Laois Local Enterprise Office Address: Business Support Unit, County Hall, Portlaoise, County Laois Web: https://www.localenterprise.ie/laois/

More information

Residential Demographic Multipliers

Residential Demographic Multipliers Rutgers University, Center for Urban Policy Research Residential Demographic Multipliers Estimates of the Occupants of New Housing (Residents, School-Age Children, Public School-Age Children) by State,

More information

Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012

Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012 Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012 1. I+S effects Recognize that the utility function U =min{2x 1,4x 2 } represents perfect complements, and that the goods will be consumed

More information

Enriching income data with expenditure information: a semiparametric

Enriching income data with expenditure information: a semiparametric Enriching income data with expenditure information: a semiparametric imputation technique by André DECOSTER Kris DE SWERDT Public Economics Center for Economic Studies Discussions Paper Series (DPS) 08.11

More information

Consumer Demand and the Cost of Living

Consumer Demand and the Cost of Living Consumer Demand and the Cost of Living Krishna Pendakur May 24, 2015 Krishna Pendakur () Demand is Awesome May 24, 2015 1 / 26 Consumer demand systems? A consumer demand system is the relationship w j

More information

PRIMA. Planning for Retailing in Metropolitan Areas

PRIMA. Planning for Retailing in Metropolitan Areas PRIMA Planning for Retailing in Metropolitan Areas Metropolitan Dimension to sustainable retailing futures Metropolitan strategies Retailing in city and town centres will be a primary component of any

More information

or through any bookseller.

or through any bookseller. Published by the Stationery Office, Dublin, Ireland. Available from the: Central Statistics Office, Information Section, Skehard Road, Cork, Government Publications Sales Office, Sun Alliance House, Molesworth

More information

Economics - Canadian Edition, 15e (Ragan) Chapter 2 Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs. 2.1 Positive and Normative Statements

Economics - Canadian Edition, 15e (Ragan) Chapter 2 Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs. 2.1 Positive and Normative Statements Economics - Canadian Edition, 15e (Ragan) Chapter 2 Economic Theories, Data, and Graphs 2.1 Positive and Normative Statements 1) Disagreements over positive statements A) cannot arise because positive

More information

EEE-05, Series 05. Time. 3 hours Maximum marks General Instructions: Please read the following instructions carefully

EEE-05, Series 05. Time. 3 hours Maximum marks General Instructions: Please read the following instructions carefully EEE-05, 2015 Series 05 Time. 3 hours Maximum marks. 100 General Instructions: Please read the following instructions carefully Check that you have a bubble-sheet and an answer book accompanying this examination

More information

Advanced Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics Advanced Macroeconomics The Ramsey Model Marcin Kolasa Warsaw School of Economics Marcin Kolasa (WSE) Ad. Macro - Ramsey model 1 / 30 Introduction Authors: Frank Ramsey (1928), David Cass (1965) and Tjalling

More information

ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output

ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output David Byrne, Kieran McQuinn and Ciara Morley Research Notes are short papers on focused research issues. Nowcasting

More information

CHAPTER 5 FUNCTIONAL FORMS OF REGRESSION MODELS

CHAPTER 5 FUNCTIONAL FORMS OF REGRESSION MODELS CHAPTER 5 FUNCTIONAL FORMS OF REGRESSION MODELS QUESTIONS 5.1. (a) In a log-log model the dependent and all explanatory variables are in the logarithmic form. (b) In the log-lin model the dependent variable

More information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming 1. Government Purchases and Endogenous Growth Consider the following endogenous growth model with government purchases (G) in continuous time. Government purchases enhance production, and the production

More information

Information Bulletin 11/2011

Information Bulletin 11/2011 Information Bulletin 11/2011 Warsaw, 2012 Compiled from NBP materials by the Department of Statistics as at January 13, 2012. Design: Oliwka s.c. Cover photo: Corbis/Free Layout and print: NBP Printshop

More information

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: October 21, 2016

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: October 21, 2016 NOWCASTING REPORT Updated: October 21, 216 The FRBNY Staff Nowcast stands at 2.2% for 216:Q3 and 1.4% for 216:Q4. Overall this week s news had a negative effect on the nowcast. The most notable developments

More information

Entrance Examination for M. A. Economics, Option A (Series 01) Time. 3 hours Maximum marks. 100

Entrance Examination for M. A. Economics, Option A (Series 01) Time. 3 hours Maximum marks. 100 Entrance Examination for M. A. Economics, 2014 Option A (Series 01) Time. 3 hours Maximum marks. 100 General Instructions. Please read the following instructions carefully: Check that you have a bubble-sheet

More information

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory variables in a regression model is simultaneity: that is, one

More information

Information Bulletin 12/2003

Information Bulletin 12/2003 Information Bulletin 12/2003 Warsaw, April 2003 Compiled from NBP materials by the Department of Statistics as at March 15, 2004. Design: Oliwka s.c. Cover photo: Corbis/Free Layout and print: NBP Printshop

More information

Avoiding aggregation in estimating marginal utilities

Avoiding aggregation in estimating marginal utilities Avoiding aggregation in estimating marginal utilities Ethan Ligon June 24, 2014 Dynamics of consumer behavior In just about any model of dynamic consumer behavior we get restrictions on the evolution of

More information

Chapter 6. Exploring Data: Relationships. Solutions. Exercises:

Chapter 6. Exploring Data: Relationships. Solutions. Exercises: Chapter 6 Exploring Data: Relationships Solutions Exercises: 1. (a) It is more reasonable to explore study time as an explanatory variable and the exam grade as the response variable. (b) It is more reasonable

More information

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies: Explorations with a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings based on Heckman, Lochner and Taber, Review of Economic

More information

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Karl Whelan School of Economics, UCD Autumn 2014 Karl Whelan (UCD) Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model Autumn 2014 1 / 38 Beyond IS-LM We have reviewed the

More information

STAT 212 Business Statistics II 1

STAT 212 Business Statistics II 1 STAT 1 Business Statistics II 1 KING FAHD UNIVERSITY OF PETROLEUM & MINERALS DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES DHAHRAN, SAUDI ARABIA STAT 1: BUSINESS STATISTICS II Semester 091 Final Exam Thursday Feb

More information

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara Title: Past trend versus future expectation: test of exchange rate volatility Author: Sengupta, Jati K., University of California, Santa Barbara Sfeir, Raymond,

More information

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation Econ 2100 Fall 2017 Lecture 6, September 14 Outline 1 Applications of Envelope Theorem 2 Hicksian Demand 3 Duality 4 Connections between

More information

2012 AND ESTIMATE FOR Q1, 2013 GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT FOR NIGERIA

2012 AND ESTIMATE FOR Q1, 2013 GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT FOR NIGERIA FEDERAL REPUBLIC OF NIGERIA (THE PRESIDENCY) 2012 AND ESTIMATE FOR Q1, 2013 GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT FOR NIGERIA National Bureau of Statistics Plot 762, Independence Avenue, Central Business District, Abuja

More information

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009 Department of Agricultural Economics PhD Qualifier Examination May 009 Instructions: The exam consists of six questions. You must answer all questions. If you need an assumption to complete a question,

More information

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: September 23, 2016

NOWCASTING REPORT. Updated: September 23, 2016 NOWCASTING REPORT Updated: September 23, 216 The FRBNY Staff Nowcast stands at 2.3% and 1.2% for 216:Q3 and 216:Q4, respectively. Negative news since the report was last published two weeks ago pushed

More information

Chapter 10: Multiple Regression Analysis Introduction

Chapter 10: Multiple Regression Analysis Introduction Chapter 10: Multiple Regression Analysis Introduction Chapter 10 Outline Simple versus Multiple Regression Analysis Goal of Multiple Regression Analysis A One-Tailed Test: Downward Sloping Demand Theory

More information

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants, Test code: ME I/ME II, 004 Syllabus for ME I Matri Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matri Operations, Determinants, Nonsingularity, Inversion, Cramer s rule. Calculus: Limits, Continuity, Differentiation

More information

Forecasting ability of theory-constrained two-stage demand systems

Forecasting ability of theory-constrained two-stage demand systems European Review of Agricultural Economics Vol 30 (4) (2003) pp. 539 558 Forecasting ability of theory-constrained two-stage demand systems Geir Wæhler Gustavsen Norwegian Agricultural Economics Research

More information