Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003

Similar documents
Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

14.05 Lecture Notes Crises and Multiple Equilibria

International Macro Finance

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Advanced Macroeconomics

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

The Dornbusch overshooting model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Lars Svensson 10/2/05. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

The transmission mechanism How the monetary-policy instrument affects the economy and the target variables

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

Problem 1 (30 points)

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Introduction to Game Theory

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Lecture 3: Dynamics of small open economies

Learning and Global Dynamics

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Macroeconomics Theory II

Advanced Macroeconomics

Test code: ME I/ME II, 2004 Syllabus for ME I. Matrix Algebra: Matrices and Vectors, Matrix Operations, Determinants,

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Growth Theory: Review

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

TABLE OF CONTENTS. Page. Statistical Bulletin, June 2011 INTRODUCTORY NOTES SUMMARISED ACCOUNTS OF THE BANKING SYSTEM

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Small Open Economy. Lawrence Christiano. Department of Economics, Northwestern University

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Chaotic Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Growth Theory: Review

Transcription:

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics Problem Set 3 May 15, 2003 Due: Thu, June 5, 2003 Instructor: Marc-Andreas Muendler E-mail: muendler@ucsd.edu 1 Trending Fundamentals in a Target Zone Model (Froot and Obstfeld 1991) Suppose the exchange rate follows the fundamental equation e t = k t + η h E t [de t+h ], where k t is the fundamental value. As opposed to the model in class, suppose the change in the fundamental value follows the trending process dk t+h = µh + h 1/2 νdz t+h, where dz t+h is drawn from a mean-zero i.i.d. normal distribution with unit variance. Under a free float e t = k t. Suppose the Home and Foreign central bank announce a target zone for the exchange rate: e t (e, e). This problem asks you to show step by step that the equilibrium exchange rate process must satisfy which has a solution of the form e = G(k) + ηµg (k) + ην2 2 G (k), (1-1) G(k) = k + ηµ + +ηµg (k) + ην2 2 G (k), (1-2) 1. Suppose that e = G(k) is a solution, where G( ) is twice continuously differentiable. Show that G(k t ) = k t + η h E t [G(k t+h ) G(k t )] 2. Use a second-order Taylor approximation of E t [G(k t+h ) G(k t )] at k t+1 = k t to show that E t [dg (k t+h )] = µhg (k t ) + hv2 2 G (k t ). [Hint: Show that E t [G (k t )dk t+h ] = µhg (k t ).] 1

3. Using these results, show that is the solution. G(k) = k + ηµ + +ηµg (k) + ην2 2 G (k). 4. A general solution to a second-order differential equation of this form is G(k) = k + α + b 1 exp(λ 1 k) + b 2 exp(λ 2 k) for some constants b 1, b 2. Show that the previous results imply G(k) = k + ηµ + +ηµg (k) + ην2 2 G (k). What quadratic equation determines the values λ 1, λ 2. 5. A particular solution to the general solution (1-2) can be found by imposing restrictions that e must satisfy at the limits of the band. Describe how the particular solution can be derived. [You do not need to derive it.] 2 Open-economy Bank Runs The Diamond-Dybvig model of bank runs is extended to an open-economy setting, in which international borrowing and lending at a gross interest rate 1 is possible (net real interest rate 0). There are three periods and domestic agents have measure 1. Agents do not discount future consumption in their decision but face uncertainty as to what their preferences will be in the intermediate period 1. Patient agents do not derive any utility from consumption after the intermediate period 1, whereas impatient agents are indifferent between consumption in period 1 or 2. 1. Assume there are no banks, and no international borrowing or lending. In period 0, domestic agents invest their endowment z in the domestic technology, which yields a gross return r after one period and a gross return R after two periods. In period 1, each agent learns if he or she is impatient, which occurs with probability π, or patient, which happens with probability 1 π. Impatient agents liquidate their investments immediately for a gross return of r < 1 (a net return r 1 < 0) and consume. Patient types let their investments mature until period 2 and consume zr units then, where R > 1. An agent derives utility u(c) from consumption of c at any period and there is no discounting. What is the expected utility of a representative agent? What is expected output in periods 1 and 2? 2. Introduce a perfectly competitive banking sector, which earns zero profits in equilibrium. Banks have the ability to borrow and lend abroad at the net interest rate of 0 but their debt to foreign lenders can never exceed the limit f. Assume that nonbank domestic residents have no direct access to the international capital market, only through banks. In period 0, 2

domestic agents deposit their endowments in banks. Banks can borrow and lend abroad, and invest in domestic technology. Suppose the banks simply lend πz abroad in period 0, drawing on these funds to pay off impatient depositors in period 1. Show that the expected utility of a representative agent is higher than in part 1. Why? 3. Banks can do better than the arrangement of part 2. Let x denote the (period 1) consumption of an impatient type and y the (period 2) consumption of a patient type. x and y denote first-best consumption levels. Suppose banks guarantee each impatient depositor x in period 1 and each patient depositor y in period 2. To do this, they borrow (or lend) the amount f πx in period 0 and invest k = z + f πx in the domestic technology. They draw on foreign balances to disburse πx in period 1, thereby paying off impatient depositors. In period 2 they repay any net borrowing from periods 0 and 1 and pay patient depositors a total of (1 π)y. Show that, under this banking arrangement, the economy faces the intertemporal budget constraint Rπx + (1 π)y = f(r 1) + zr Rw. 4. Consider iso-elastic utility u(c) = c 1 ρ 1/1 ρ. By maximizing expected utility in period 0, show that a representative domestic agent consumes the first-best levels x and y where x = θw π θ = and πr ρ 1 πr ρ 1 ρ y = ρ + (1 π). (1 θ)rw, 1 π 5. Verify that y x is always satisfies so that patient depositors have no incentive to pretend they are impatient. 6. Show that, by the beginning of period 2, banks will always have borrowed up to their foreign credit limit f. 7. Now consider bank runs in period 1. Let l be the amount of the investment k that banks must liquidate to pay off depositors who withdraw their funds in period 1. Suppose that banks can pre-commit to suspending domestic convertibility of their deposits once period 1 withdrawals force them to liquidate sufficient amounts of their investment that R(k l) = f. So, foreign creditors can be certain of being repaid in full, even if there is a run by domestic depositors and the banks close their doors to them. Let ˆl satisfy R(k ˆl) = f. Show that a run on the first-best banking arrangement is possible if x > πx + rˆl. 3

Here, x represents the bank s total potential short-term obligations, which it would be liable to satisfy if all investors claimed to be impatient. Calculate x and k and show that a sufficient condition for a run to be possible is that ρ 1. 3 Exchange Rate Overshooting Suppose money demand takes the Cagan-like form m d t p t = φy d t η i t+1 with φ, η > 0 where m d t denotes the natural logarithm of nominal money demand, p t the log price level, y d t log aggregate demand and i t+1 the nominal interest rate (ln(1+i t+1 )). Money supply is constant m s t = m. Suppose the uncovered interest parity condition holds and i t+1 = i t+1 + e t+1 e t, where e t is the log nominal exchange rate. By definition, the real exchange rate is q t = e t + p t p t. Suppose aggregate demand increases when the real exchange rate depreciates so that y d t = δq t with δ (0, 1 φ ) The full-employment level of aggregate supply is y s t = ȳ. Finally, suppose in Keynesian style, that prices are not immediately set to the expected equilibrium level, but adjusted slowly. In particular, prices obey the response function p t+1 p t = π(y d t y s t ). Standardize all foreign variables to constants p t = i t+1 = 0, and suppose that money markets clear instantaneously: m d t = m s t = m. 1. Show that, under these assumption, a Dornbusch model can be built from three equations: m p t = φy d t η(e t+1 e t ), (3-1) yt d = δ(e t p t ) δ (0, 1 φ ), (3-2) p t+1 p t = π(y d t ȳ). (3-3) 2. Find the steady-state values of the exchange rate and the price level (e t+1 = e t = ē, p t+1 = p t = p). 3. Express both (e t+1 e t ) and (p t+1 p t ) as functions of e t, p t and exogenous variables. Find the two functional relationships between p t and e t that satisfy e t+1 e t = 0 and p t+1 p t = 0. Draw them in a phase diagram with p t on the y-axis and e t on the x-axis. Complete the phase diagram 4

indicating the motion of the system (using the conditions for e t+1 e t 0 and p t+1 p t 0). Finally, add a line to the diagram that obeys a no-arbitrage condition as mandated by UIP: p t p = ˆθ (e t ē) for some ˆθ > 0. (The ˆθ is not quite the same as in the original Dornbusch model since there is no uncertainty in the present setup.) 4. Is the steady-state stable? If not, what is the unique stable ( saddle ) path given a steady-state of p and ē? 5. Suppose all variables except for p t immediately respond to a monetary shock. What is the new steady-state? Draw a no-arbitrage line through it. What happens to e t right after an unanticipated reduction in the monetary base from m to m < m? How do e t+s and p t+s evolve over time? 6. Now consider the dynamics of the model around its steady-state. Using (3-2) and the steady-states of ē and p that you found in part 1, express y d t ȳ as a function of e t ē and p t p. 7. Using (3-1) along with the results in parts 1 and 6, express e t+1 ē as a function of 1 η (e t ē) and 1 η (p t p). 8. Using (3-2) and (3-3) along with the results in part 1, express p t+1 p as a weighted sum of e t ē and p t p. From now on, assume that π = 1 η and φ = 3 for simplicity. 9. Write your findings from 7 and 8 into a system of two difference equations that takes the form ( ) ( ) et+1 ē et ē = A. (3-4) p t+1 p p t p Find the eigenvalues and eigenvectors of the system. [Hint: An intermediate result is tr(a) = 2(δ+η) η and det(a) = 1 (1 2η)δ η 2.] 10. Is the system stable? That is, do the exchange rate and price levels converge to the steady-state? If not, set the coefficient of the unstable root to zero. Then, using the simplified system in part 9 and the results from 6, express p t+1 as a function of e t+1 and exogenous variables. Draw this function into the phase diagram from part 5 so that it passes through the steady-state. (You can safely pretend that ȳ 0. Also, remember that δ < 1 φ.) What did you just find? What is the intuition for the fact that the economy obeys this relationship? 5

4 Small-country Redux The small-country case of a standard open-economy redux model can be derived without solving the intricacies of the full two-country model. Assume that the small country consumes only a single imported good and a single exported good, over which it has some monopoly power. In particular, the demand curve that the small country faces is y d = p θ C W, where p is the relative world price of the domestic good and C W is the exogenous level of world demand. This price p has a negligible (no) effect on the foreign commodity price index P. The small country faces an exogenous own-rate of interest r on the imported good. The small country has no effect on world prices or world aggregate variables. Assume that absolute Purchasing Power Parity P = EP and the Fisher Parity 1 + i t+1 = (1 + r) P t+1 P t hold. 1. Let p y be the home-currency price of the single exported good and P the home-currency price of the imported good. Verify that world-demand can then be rewritten as ( y d py ) θ = C W. P 2. Suppose the representative agent maximizes U t = s=t [ β s t ln C s + χ ln M s κ ] P s 2 y2 s, where C is consumption of the single imported good. The period budget constraint is P t B t+1 + M t = (1+r)P t B t + M t 1 + p y,t y t P t C t P t τ. Assume that (1+r)β = 1, and suppose the steady-state levels of the following variables satisfy p y = EP, C = C W so that p y = P. Standardize log variables to be c w = p = 0 so that e t = p t. Derive the agent s first-order conditions, log-linearize around the steady state, and show that c t+1 = c t (4-1) m t e t = c t 1 r (e t+1 e t ) (4-2) (θ + 1)y t = θc t. (4-3) 3. Show that y t = θ(e t p y,t ) under the assumptions made so that b t+1 = (1+r)b t + (θ 1)(e t p y,t ) c t. 6

4. Assume that the small-country-currency price p y,t of the export good is set one period in advance, and reverts to its flexible-price level after a single period absent new shocks. Show that the equilibrium exchange rate must satisfy r(1 + θ) + 2θ e = θr(1 + θ) + 2θ m. [Hint: Show that e = e, b = (θ 1)e c and e = r(1+θ)+2θ r(θ 2 1) c.] 7