Endogenous growth theory. Tom Holden PhD Macroeconomics, Semester 2

Similar documents
14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

The Romer Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. February 7, Econ520

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

The Solow Growth Model

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Expanding Variety Models

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 1

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The Aggregate Implications of Innovative Investment. September 2017

Schumpeterian Growth Models

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

The Real Business Cycle Model

Life Cycle Saving, Bequests, and the Role of Population in R&D based Growth

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

Economic Growth: Lectures 9 and 10, Endogenous Technological Change

Advanced Macroeconomics

Growth and Ideas. Romer (1990) and Jones (2005) Chad Jones Stanford GSB. Romer (1990) and Jones (2005) p. 1

Corporate Profits Tax and Innovative Investments

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Advanced Macroeconomics

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Clarendon Lectures, Lecture 1 Directed Technical Change: Importance, Issues and Approaches

Economic Growth: Lecture 12, Directed Technological Change

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

This process was named creative destruction by Joseph Schumpeter.

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

R&D, Competition and Growth with Human Capital Accumulation : A Comment

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Econ 204A: Section 3

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

The welfare cost of energy insecurity

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

1 The Basic RBC Model

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

004: Macroeconomic Theory

A Three-Sector Endogenous Growth Model with Combined Technological Change: the choice between basic innovations and quality improvements

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 7 and 8 Innovation, Reallocation and Growth

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 1 and 2 Review of Models of Endogenous Technological Change

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Volume 30, Issue 3. Ramsey Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth: A Comment. Jenn-hong Tang Department of Economics, National Tsing-Hua University

14.999: Topics in Inequality, Lecture 4 Endogenous Technology and Automation

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Growth without scale effects due to entropy

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Innovation by Entrants and Incumbents

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Endogenous Growth: Analytical Review of its Generating Mechanisms

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Chapter 10 Skill biased technological change

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Advanced Macroeconomics

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Endogenous Information Choice

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Endogenous IPR and Economic Growth

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Transcription:

Endogenous growth theory Tom Holden http://www.tholden.org/ PhD Macroeconomics, Semester 2

Outline of today s talk First generation endogenous growth models. Semi-endogenous growth models. Second generation endogenous growth models. Deeper micro-foundations for endogenous growth. Quality ladders. Preference for variety.

Reading for today A growth textbook. E.g.: Economic Growth : Barro and Sala-i-Martin The Economics of Growth : Aghion and Howitt Introduction to Modern Economic Growth : Acemoglu Charles Jones: Growth with or without scale effects http://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/aer.89.2.139

Motivation In the models you have seen up to now, all growth was driven by exogenous movements in total factor productivity. But what is total factor productivity? And why should it grow? These are the questions answered by endogenous growth theory. While the welfare consequences of business cycles are generally small, the welfare consequences of even tiny changes in growth rates can be huge. So understanding what we can do to encourage long-run growth is crucial for policy. Example: Suppose C t = e gt+σε t σ 2 2 where ε t ~NIID 0,1, so E t 1 C t = e gt. And suppose household utility is given by U 0 = E 0 t=0 β t log C t. Then U 0 = t=0 β t gt σ 2 2 = βg σ2 1. 1 β 2 2 1 β β 0.99 means U 0 9900g 50σ 2. g is much more important!

The AK model (1/2) Suppose that there are not in fact decreasing returns to capital, holding fixed labour. In particular, set Y = AKL 1 α. (Standard AK model has α = 1.) You might like to think of K as human capital, or the stock of ideas/knowledge. Whereas my factory cannot use your machines, it can use your ideas. Knowledge is non-rival. Suppose labour is supplied inelastically, with each household supplying one unit, and suppose the number of households is given by N t = N 0 e nt. Households maximise: U = 0 N t e ρt head. Then: where ρ ρ σn. U = 0 c t 1 σ 1 σ e ρt N 0 σ C t dt, where c t = N t C t 1 σ 1 σ dt is consumption per As ever, capital evolves according to: K t = I t δk t, where Y t = C t + I t.

The AK model (2/2) We form the current value Hamiltonian: FOCs: H c K, C, λ = N 0 σ C1 σ 1 σ + λ AKN 0 1 α e 1 α nt C δk. ρλ λ = H c,1 K, C, λ = λan 1 σ 0 e 1 α nt λδ 0 = H c,2 K, C, λ = N 0 σ C σ λ So: C C = AN 0 1 σ e 1 α nt δ ρ + n σ Suppose n = 0 or α = 1, then C = AN 0 1 α δ ρ + n, so we have exponential growth, even without growth in A, C providing A is large enough. σ However, if n > 0 and α < 1, then growth rates are increasing over-time, so we have super-exponential (explosive) growth. n = 0 or α = 1 is a knife-edge assumption for endogenous growth. Note also that changes in the level of population (N 0 ) imply counter-factual changes in the rate of consumption growth. This is a strong scale effect in Jones s terminology.

The first generation endogenous growth model (Romer (1986), Lucas (1988), Grossman Helpman (1991), Aghion and Howitt (1992)) (1/2) Clearly, K in the AK model is not physical capital. We are better off preserving the letter K for physical capital then. Is it a good model of the knowledge stock? It is odd to think of knowledge as depreciating at any significant rate. With a few notable exceptions, we have access now to most of the material that has ever been published. It is stranger still to think of knowledge as being produced from physical goods. Instead, we might directly model a productivity production function of the form A = κal A, where L A is the labour devoted to R&D. Abstracting from physical capital, we suppose a production function of the form Y = A ζ L Y, where L A + L Y = N = N 0 e nt. Define s L A as the fraction employed in R&D. N Immediately we have that A A = κsn 0 e nt, so there can only be exponential growth if it happens that the optimal s satisfies s s = n, so the number engaged in R&D aren t growing over time. It is also clear from this that policies designed to promote R&D have a large pay-off in this model, as an increase in s increases the growth rate. We again have strong scale effects too, with N 0 increasing productivity growth rates. We keep household utility as before, though now Y = C.

The first generation endogenous growth model (2/2) We form the current value Hamiltonian: H c A, s, λ = N 0 σ Aζ nt 1 σ 1 s N 0 e 1 σ + λκsan 0 e nt. FOCs: σ ρλ λ = H c,1 A, s, λ = 1 σ ζn 0 Aζ nt 1 σ 1 s N 0 e 1 1 σ A + λκsn 0e nt σ 0 = H c,2 A, s, λ = 1 σ N Aζ nt 1 σ 1 s N 0 e 1 0 1 σ s + λκan 0e nt Hence: Aρλ A λ = A λκsn 0 e nt + ζs λκan 0 e nt = 1 + ζ λκsan 0 e nt. I.e.: λ λ = ρ σn 1 + ζ κsn 0 e nt Then from taking growth rates in the second FOC: 1 σ ζ A A s 1 s + n s s = ρ σn 1 + ζ κsn 0e nt + A A + n Substituting s s = n makes clear this is not consistent with exponential growth in A unless n = 0 or ζ = 0.

The semi-endogenous growth model of Jones (1995b) The key assumption driving growth in first generation endogenous growth models was the linear technology for the production of new ideas. But plausibly, R&D is getting harder over time as all of the obvious ideas have already been thought up. This suggests a knowledge production function of the form: A = κa φ L A, where φ < 1. Then: A A = κsa φ 1 N 0 e nt, so if n = 0 and s is constant, then growth rates are declining over time, and growth is sub-exponential. φ = 1 was another implicit knife-edge assumption in the first generation models. To see the problem with φ = 1 another way, note that along the balanced growth path (bgp), we must have n = 1 φ g A, i.e. g A n 1 φ. Semi-endogenous growth models have very different policy implications, since s no longer appears in the growth rate. Thus policy cannot do much to influence long-run growth (beyond encouraging people to have more children). Since the growth rate of productivity depends on the growth rate of population, we say the model has weak scale effects.

Second generation endogenous growth models (Young (1998), Peretto (1998), Aghion and Howitt (1998), Dinopoulos and Thompson (1998), Li (2000, 2002)) Suppose the final consumption good is produced using C = I 1+ν 1 1 I Yi 1+μ di I 0 ν controls the returns to variety. ν = 0 and ν = μ are common choices. Suppose that product i is produced using the linear technology Y i = A i L Y,i, where A i = κa i φ A I ψ AL A,i. And suppose that I grows over time according to I = γ sup i 0,I A i φ I 1 I ψ IL I. We assume resources are equally allocated across varieties, and that initial conditions are identical, so we drop i subscripts in the following. Let L A = 1 I s A 1 s I N, L Y = 1 I 1 s A 1 s I N, L I = s I N, where the share parameters are constant along the bgp. Hence, C = I 1+ν AL Y = I ν A 1 s A 1 s I N, so g C = νg I + g A + g N. Also, on the bgp (if it exists): 0 = φ A 1 g A + ψ A 1 g I + n and 0 = ψ I 1 g I + φ I 1 g A + n, from the laws of motion for A and I. I.e. 1 φ A 1 ψ A 1 φ I 1 ψ I g A g I = n n. If φ A φ I or ψ A ψ I, then we can (probably) invert the matrix on the LHS, to find g A, g I n (i.e. this is semi-endogenous growth). A A If φ A = φ I = φ and ψ A = ψ I = ψ then = I I = A φ 1 I ψ 1 N κs A 1 s I γs 0 e nt φ 1 ψ 1 = A I 0 I0 N0, so R&D shares again matter, and exponential productivity growth persists whether or not population growth is zero (i.e. this is endogenous growth). 1+μ.

Microfoundations of endogenous growth In order to understand whether the knife edge assumptions behind endogenous growth are plausible, it is important to understand the mechanisms behind growth a bit more carefully. There are three broad classes: Schumpeterian/creative destruction/quality-ladder models, used by Aghion and Howitt. Variety expansion models, used by Romer. Incremental improvement models, used by Peretto (and me!). The second generation model we presented previously was of this class, with a production function for technology in each industry. Various combinations of these classes are possible.

Quality ladder models (1/7) Let C = 0 1 Yi 1 1+μ di 1+μ Then from the aggregators FOC, P i = C 1+μ Hence, Y i = P μ i C.. μ μ 1+μY i 1+μ where P i is the price of good i. Suppose that there are J i firms in industry i, and that firm j in industry i has the production technology Y i,j = A i,j L Y,i,j. We suppose that there is free entry of firms to the industry, with zero entry cost. Again, zero entry cost is a very special assumption. Suppose firms in each industry compete in price (Bertrand). Let A i max A i,j, j i arg max A i,j and A i max A i,j j 1,, J i, j j i. j 1,,J i j 1,,J i As standard, if J i = 1, P i = 1 + μ W A i, where W is the wage. If J i > 1, P i = min 1 + μ W A i, W A i and only the firm j i for which A i,ji = A i will produce anything.

Quality ladder models (2/7) Suppose that if firm j in industry i devotes L R,i,j units of labour to research during the interval t, t + dt, the probability that they come up with a productivity improvement in that period is φ κl R,i,j dt. We will simplify by taking φ = 1 in the below, but remember that without φ = 1 things can be quite different. Suppose further that when firm j comes up with such an improvement, its new productivity is 1 + γ times the old A i. Hence A i = A i 1+γ. Let γ min γ, μ, then P i = 1 + γ W A i, so 1 = 0 1 Pi 1μ di = 1 + γ 1 μw 1 μ 0 1 Ai 1 μ di. I.e. W = 1 1 1 Ai μ di 1+ γ 0 μ. And the profit flow to the incumbent in industry i with productivity A is: π t A γ 1 + γ 1+μ μ W t A 1 μ C t

Quality ladder models (3/7) When they are displaced, by the free entry condition, their present discounted value must be 0, so the total value of being the incumbent in industry i at t, with productivity A is: V i t A = π t A dt W t L R,i,ji t dt + 1 r t dt 1 κl i t dt κl R,i,ji t dt V i t + dt A + κl i t dt 0

Quality ladder models (4/7) Let O i,j t 0 be the value of firm j in industry i when j j i. Then: O i,j t = W t L R,i,j t dt + 1 r t dt 1 κl R,i,j t dt O i,j t + dt + κl R,i,j t dt V i t + dt A i t 1 + γ + ω i,j t L R,i,j t dt I.e. W t = κv i t A i t 1 + γ + ω i,j t. Hence, from the FOC for L R,i,ji t, ω i,ji t = κv i t A i t + ω i,j t > 0, so L R,i,ji t = 0. This implies that: V i t A = π t A dt + 1 r t dt 1 κl i t dt V i t + dt A Hence: κl i t V i t A π t A = V i t A r t V i t A I.e., if ω i,j t = 0: L i t W t π t A i t 1 + γ = 1 κ W t r t W t So: L i t = 1 κ W t W t r t 1+μ + γ 1 + γ μ W t 1+μ μ A i t 1 + γ 1 μ C t Note, L i t is increasing in A i t, so differences in initial conditions get amplified over time, and there is no convergence across industries.

Quality ladder models (5/7) To close the model, we specify households as maximising: U = Subject to the budget constraint: Current value Hamiltonian: FOCs: 0 e ρt log C t 1 1 + ν L t 1+ν dt WL + rb + Π = C + B H c B, C, L, λ = log C 1 1 + ν L t 1+ν + λ WL + rb + Π C So λ λ = C C = ρ r, and W C = Lν. ρλ λ = H c,1 B, C, L, λ = λr 0 = H c,2(1) B, C, L, λ = 1 C λ 0 = H c,2(2) B, C, L, λ = L ν + λw

Quality ladder models (6/7) Suppose that A i 0 = 1 for all i 0,1, then for any i 0,1 : W t = 1 1 + γ k=0 1 + γ k μ Pr A i t = 1 + γ k μ Although each individual industry has stochastic output, aggregate output will not be stochastic. In the limit as μ, this becomes: log W t = log 1 + γ + k=1 k log 1 + γ Pr A i t = 1 + γ k Now, a nice property of Poisson processes is that the number of times their event happens in a fixed interval is Poisson distributed with parameter given by the integral of the rate over that time, i.e. : Pr A i t = 1 + γ k = 1 t k! e κ 0 Li τ dτ κ 0 t L i τ dτ k

Quality ladder models (7/7) We solve the tractable case in which μ =, since in this case L i t is not a function of i (so, in particular, it is not a function of A i t ). In fact: L t L i t = 1 κ W t W t r t + γ C t 1+γ W t t t So: log W t = κ 0 L τ dτ e κ 0 L τ dτ κ t k 1 0 L τ dτ k=1 1 log 1 + γ k 1! Now, on the bgp, r ρ = C = W = g and L = L (g, L are constants), thus providing these variables converge to C W the bgp quickly enough, κ t Li τ dτ κ γ t 0 1+γ L ν ρ, so: log W t t κ γ 1 + γ L ν ρ e Hence g = γ t κ 1+γ L ν ρ t κ γ 1 + γ L ν ρ k=0 k! k γ t κ e 1+γ L ν ρ log W t t κ γ 1 + γ L ν ρ log 1 + γ 0 as t κ γ 1+γ L ν ρ log 1 + γ. Exponential growth! Note cross sectional variance of log productivity is increasing over time. Plausible? log 1 + γ 0 as t

Variety expansion models (1/4) We have already seen the basic idea behind variety expansion models. Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators incorporate a preference for variety, so the introduction of new products raises productivity. The literature using variety expansion for growth often places the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator on the production side. For a bit of variety, we present a version with investment specific technological change. In particular, suppose the final good is produced in a perfectly competitive industry using the technology Y = K α L 1 α. Let W be the wage and r K the rental rate of capital. Then W = 1 α Y L and r K = α Y K. Also suppose household capital K evolves according to K = I δk, where the investment good is produced from intermediate goods M i 0, I using the technology: I = 0 I M i 1 1+μ di 1+μ. Suppose that inventing a new intermediate good requires a fixed cost of Y F I θ units of the final good, and that once invented, the inventor is the only person who can produce that intermediate good, one for one from the final good. Market clearing requires Y = C + IY F I θ I + Mi 0 di.

Variety expansion models (2/4) As ever, for all i [0, I]: M i = P i 1+μ μ P P is the price of the aggregate investment good in units of the consumption good. Since intermediate produces have marginal costs of 1: P i = 1 + μ. Hence: P = 0 I Pi 1 μ di μ I. = 1 + μ I μ, and P P = μ I I. The price of the investment good is unambiguously decreasing in I. Then firm profits at t are: π t = μ 1 + μ 1+μ μ P t 1+μ μ I t = μi t 1+μ I t Free entry of inventors at t implies: Y F I t θ = π t dt + 1 r t dt Y F I t + dt θ Hence: ry F I θ = π + θy F I θ 1 I = μi 1+μ I + θy F I θ 1 I I.e. ry F θy F I I = μi 1+μ+θ I.

Variety expansion models (3/4) To close the model, we specify households as maximising: U = e ρt log C t 1 1 + ν L t 1+ν dt 0 Subject to the budget constraint: WL + r K K + rb + Π = C + PI + B. And the capital accumulation constraint: K = I δk. Current value Hamiltonian: FOCs: H c B, K, C, L, I, λ = log C 1 1 + ν L t 1+ν + λ B WL + r K K + rb + Π C PI + λ K I δk ρλ B λ B = H c,1 1 ρλ K λ K = H c,1 2 B, K, C, L, I, λ = λ B r B, K, C, L, I, λ = λ B r K δλ K So λ B λ B = C C = ρ r, and W C = Lν. 0 = H c,2(1) B, K, C, L, I, λ = 1 C λ B 0 = H c,2(2) B, K, C, L, I, λ = L ν + λ B W 0 = H c,2(3) B, K, C, L, I, λ = Pλ B + λ K Also: ρpλ B P λ B Pλ B = λ B r K δpλ B, so r = r K P δ + P P = r K P δ μ I I.

Variety expansion models (4/4) Now, on the bgp, r = r, L = L and I I = g I. r = r K δ μg P I, thus r K = P = μg r K P I. But r K = αk α 1 L 1 α, hence μg I = r K r K = α 1 K K. I.e. K K = μg I 1 α, so Y Y = α 1 α μg I. W = L ν implies W = C = r ρ, so as W = 1 α C W C Kα L α, W = W W = C = r ρ = α W C μg 1 α I, so r = ρ + α μg 1 α I. α 1 α μg I, we have that Y Y = Finally, since ry F θy F g I = μi 1+μ+θ I, we must have 0 = 1 + μ + θ g I + K K, i.e. 1 + μ + θ = μ 1 α, so growth requires a further knife edge assumption on e.g. θ. This is related to the result of Huffman (2007). Including population growth would also do the trick, but would turn the model into a semiendogenous growth one.

An immodest slide In my own work, I build an endogenous growth model in which there is true competition in each industry, with multiple firms producing each product, at each point in time. There is both free entry into an industry, and free entry of new industries, while growth comes from incremental productivity improvements performed by individual firms. These two margins of entry prove crucial for generating robust endogenous growth, and they allow me both to match the absence of a unit root in GDP, and to generate exponential growth even with asymmetric spill-overs from product to process innovation.