+ τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1. = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t )

Similar documents
Eco Spring 2002 Chris Sims OLG EXERCISES

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Seoul National University Mini-Course: Monetary & Fiscal Policy Interactions II

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

1. Money in the utility function (start)

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Money Growth Monitoring and the Taylor Rule

Econ 504, Lecture 1: Transversality and Stochastic Lagrange Multipliers

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Advanced Macroeconomics

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

1 With state-contingent debt

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

An introduction of a simple monetary policy with savings taxation in the overlapping generations model

Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

TheTimeConsistencyof Monetary and Fiscal Policies

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Thetimeconsistencyoffiscal and monetary policies

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Mankiw Chapter 11. Aggregate Demand I. Building the IS-LM Model

Traditional vs. Correct Transversality Conditions, plus answers to problem set due 1/28/99

Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3)

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3) π t = g t 1 + ν t. (4) g t = θ 1θ 0 ω + θ 2 1. (5)

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Extended IS-LM model - construction and analysis of behavior

Adding Production to the Theory

1 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

An approximate consumption function

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

1 Overlapping Generations

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

The representative agent model

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Lars Svensson 10/2/05. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Eco504, Part II Spring 2008 C. Sims POLICY GAMES

Homework 3 - Partial Answers

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Learning and Global Dynamics

Working Paper Series. Liquidity Premiums on Government Debt and the Fiscal Theory of the Price Level. Aleksander Berentsen and Christopher J.

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Dynamic Monetary Economics: Paradoxes and a Non-Ricardian Resolution

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

macroeconomics M. R. Grasselli Research in Options, December 10, 2012

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

macroeconomics M. R. Grasselli University of Technology Sydney, February 21, 2013

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Money, Barter, and Hyperinflation. Kao, Yi-Cheng Department of Business Administration, Chung Yuan Christian University

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Introduction to General Equilibrium

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Problem 1 (30 points)

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

In the benchmark economy, we restrict ourselves to stationary equilibria. The individual

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

University of California Berkeley

Transcription:

Eco504, Part II Spring 2006 C. Sims FTPL WITH MONEY 1. FTPL WITH MONEY This model is that of Sims (1994). Agent: [ ] max E β t log C t {C t,m t,b t } t=0 s.t. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) + M t + B t + τ t R t 1B t 1 + M t 1 P t B t 0, M t 0 P t + Y t v t = P tc t M t. f is transactions costs as a proportion of total consumption. We assume f (v) 0, all v > 0, and f (0) = 0. Additional conditions on f are needed to guarantee existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium under reasonable monetary and fiscal policies. 2. GOVERNMENT GBC: Monetary policy: Fiscal policy: B t + M t = R t 1B t 1 + M t 1 P t P { t M t M R t R { B τ t = φ 0 + φ t 1 P t τ t τ Social Resource Constraint: From private constraint and GBC. C t (1 + γ f (v t )) = Y t. τ t Assume an interior solution. C: B: M: 3. FOC S 1 = λ t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v t ) C t λ t λ = βr t E t+1 t P t P t+1 λ t (1 γ f t v 2 λ t ) = βe t+1 t. P t P t+1 c 2006 by Christopher A. Sims. This document may be reproduced for educational and research purposes, so long as the copies contain this notice and are retained for personal use or distributed free.

2 FTPL WITH MONEY The B and M conditions imply the money demand or liquidity preference relation 1 γ f t v 2 t = R 1 t. 4. EXISTENCE AND UNIQUENESS The C and M equations imply 1 γ f t v2 t P t C t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v2 t ) = βe t [ ] 1 P t+1 C t+1 (1 + γ f t+1 + γ f t+1 v2 t+1 ), M t or, with Z t = P t C t (1 + γ f t + γ f t v2 t ), (1) [ ] Z t (1 γ f t v 2 M t t ) = βe t. ( ) Z t+1 M t+1 5. CASE 1, M t = M Then the M terms in the previous heading s equation in Z cancel out. Note that Z t is a function g( ) of v t alone, and that for many (not all) reasonable f s we can show that (a) g (v) < 0 for all v; (b) g(v) 0 and g(v) v v 0. 6. CONDITIONS FOR EXISTENCE OF STEADY STATE If the model has a steady state with constant v t = v, we will have, from ( ), 1 γ f ( v) v 2 = β. ( ) If f (0) = 0, f absolutely continuous (i.e., differentiable except at a measure-zero set of points and equal to the integral of its derivative) and f (v) is monotone near v = 0, then f (v)v 2 0 as v 0, even if f (v) as v 0. Existence of a stationary equilibrium is therefore determined by whether γ f (v)v 2 can be as large as 1 β. 7. TWO EXAMPLE f S Here and in what follows we will consider two example f s: f l (v) = v f b (v) = v 1 + v. The linear f l implies that as real balances shrink to zero relative to consumption (so v ), consumption goes to zero at any fixed level of Y. The bounded f b implies that as real balances dwindle away, transactions costs approach some fixed fraction γ/(1 + γ) < 1 of endowment.

FTPL WITH MONEY 3 We can see from ( ) that for f l, a steady state with constant v always exists and that for f b it exists only if γ 1 β. 8. UNIQUENESS To show this equilibrium is unique, we first show that, using f b or f l, with any initial value of Z t above the steady state value Z, E t [Z t+s ] as t, while with any initial value below Z, E t [Z t+s 0] as t. Z t is monotone decreasing in v for both these f s. (Prove this for yourself.) if Z t < Z, E t Z t+1 < θ t Z t for some θ t < 1. This means that P[Z t+1 θ t Z t Z t ] > 0. But then if Z t+1 Z t, we will have E t+1 [Z t+2 ] < θ t Z t+1 therefore that with nonzero conditional probability at t + 1, Z t+2 θ t Z t+1, and therefore that with nonzero conditional probability at t Z t+2 θ 2 t Z t. Continuing this argument recursively, we will have that, with nonzero conditional probability at t, Z t+s θ s t Z t. This implies that for every ε > 0, there is a non-zero probability that eventually Z t < ε. But v t as Z t 0, so With non-zero probability v t becomes arbitrarily large if initially Z t < Z. A symmetric argument shows that if Z t > Z, v t gets arbitrarily close to zero with non-zero probability. 9. CAN WE RULE OUT EQUILIBRIA WITH ARBITRARILY LARGE OR SMALL Z S? If we assume that Y t Ȳ with probability one for all t, The only way we can have v t arbitrarily close to 0 with M fixed is to have P t arbitrarily close to zero. This implies that M t /P t must get arbitrarily large. Suppose the agent contemplates consuming a fraction δ of his real balances. As M/P grows larger, the current utility gain from consuming this fraction of real balances gets arbitrarily large. If the agent contemplates keeping M constant after the initial spending down of real balances, the resources available for consumption spending, C(1 + γ f (v)), will remain constant after the initial period. Since the agent will assume that his own actions have no effect on future prices, and since C under this deviant decision rule will be if anything lower than on the original path, the effect on v at later dates will be to increase it by no more than the ratio 1/(1 δ). But with P and C(1 + γ f ) held fixed, we can calculate d log C d log M = γ f v 1 + γ f. For either of our two example f s, and indeed for any concave f with f (0) = 0, this expression is bounded above by one. Thus the future utility costs generated by the reduction in M by the factor 1 δ, discounted to the current date, remain bounded, no matter how large is current M/P. But the current utility benefits of reducing M by this factor become unboundedly large as M/P increases. So it must be that the agent can increase expected utility by consuming some of his real balances if M/P gets large enough.

4 FTPL WITH MONEY 10. PROVING DOWNWARD EXPLOSION OF Z IS NOT POSSIBLE If Z explodes downward, v approaches infinity for either of our two example f s. But referring again to ( ), we see that if f v 2 increases with Z, ( ) may eventually may be impossible to satisfy, because the factor 1 γ f v 2 turns negative. In other words, at high enough v, the marginal value of additional real balances in this case becomes so large that no level of expected inflation, no matter how high, can leave agents satisfied not to invest in larger real balances. For our example f l (v) = v, f v 2 = v 2, so clearly the downward explosions are impossible. For f b (v) = v/(1 + v), f v 2 = v 2 /(1 + v) 2, which approaches one as v. So for this case, downward explosion can be ruled out only if γ > 1. The conclusion is that the initial price level is unique and equal to the unique price level consistent with the unique steady-state v value for f l or for f b with γ > 1. But for f b with γ < 1, any price level above the unique steady-state v value is an equilibrium value. The higher initial price level corresponds to equilibria in which expected future inflation explodes and real balances shrink toward zero. In other words, they are equilibria that converge to a non-monetary, barter steady state. The case 0 < γ < 1 β is a special case. Under this condition there is no steady state. Then every initial price level is consistent with equilibrium, and all the equilibria converge to the barter steady state. 11. GOVERNMENT DEBT Stopping the analysis here, ignoring fiscal policy, was the mistake of the earlier literature. Dividing the government budget constraint by C t, we arrive at B t P = R t 1 C t 1 B t 1 t 1 τ t P t C t P t C t P t 1 C t 1 C t If we substitute the policy rule for τ t into this equation and, using the bond first order condition, take its expectation as of t 1, we get E t 1 B t B t 1 = (β 1 φ 1 ) + φ 0 (1 + v)e[y t 1 ], P t C t P t 1 C t 1 a stable difference equation in expected B/PC so long as φ 1 > β 1 1. But if φ 1 is smaller than this, expected real debt (and thus with positive probability actual real debt) explodes exponentially up or down. Under the natural assumption that the government can hold at most a bounded amount of private sector real assets, the downward explosion (which would entail negative government debt) is impossible. The upward explosion might be

FTPL WITH MONEY 5 possible if it is not too rapid, but with φ 0, it can be shown that such paths would violate transversality. Thus the unique equilibrium price level we have found with constant M does not actually correspond to an equilibrium unless the constant-m policy is acccompanied by a fiscal policy drawn from a restricted class. This is the point of Sargent and Wallace s Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic paper. 12. EQUILIBRIUM WITH R CONSTANT With R constant it is immediate from the liquidity preference relation that v is constant also, assuming the model has a steady state. With f l, a steadystate value for v exists for any R > 1. With f b, such a v exists for any R < 1/(1 γ). Larger values of R correspond to higher values of steady state inflation. If that is too high, people cannot be motivated to hold stable real balances with f = f b. Knowing a unique equilibrium value for v does let us solve for a unique level of real balances m = M/P, but this is not enough to give us a unique initial price level. 13. INITIAL P WITH R CONSTANT With the φ 1 > β 1 1 fiscal policy, the government budget constraint will make real debt follow a stable path. Though we do not check this in detail here, this case makes equilibrium non-unique with R constant. If instead τ is constant the government budget constraint, divided through by C t and passed thorugh the E t 1 operator, becomes E t 1 [ Bt + M t P t C t ] = β 1 B t 1 + M t 1 R 1 τ E t 1. P t 1 C t 1 v C t Note the appearance of a seignorage term here, because M is not constant. This is an unstable difference equation in expected (B + M)/PC. Its unique stable solution is B t + M t P t C t = R 1 β 1 1 ( v 1 + (1 + v)τe[y t 1 ] ) Ā 14. INITIAL P FROM INITIAL (B + M)/P Now go back to the budget constraint in its original form, in the initial period: B 0 + M 0 P 0 = R B 1 P 0 + M 1 P 0 τ. Using our unique equilibrium values Ā and v, we can rewrite this as ĀY 0 1 + v = R B 1 + M 1 τ. P 0 P 0

6 FTPL WITH MONEY There is only one thing in this equation that can adjust to create equilibrium at time 0: the P 0 on the right-hand side. So there is a uniquely determined initial price level with positive initial total government liabilities, unless RB 1 = M 1 = 0 or Ā 0. 15. ARE Ā AND B 0 POSITIVE? Ā could be zero or negative only if R 1, as can be seen from the definition of Ā. To check for positivity of B 0, we can write Ā = B 0 + v 1 = R 1 ( v 1 P 0 C 0 β 1 + (1 + v)τe[y t 1 ] ) 1 If R = β 1 (non-inflationary equilibrium), positive debt is sustained if and only if τ > 0. If R > β 1, seignorage revenue allows larger real debt, indeed allows positive real debt with zero taxes. If R < β 1, taxation is being used to retire money balances and create a positive real return on money. Positive interest-bearing debt requires an excess of taxes over the amount required to sustain the chosen rate of shrinkage in money balances (which is also the rate of deflation). REFERENCES SIMS, C. A. (1994): A Simple Model for Study of the Determination of the Price Level and the Interaction of Monetary and Fiscal Policy, Economic Theory, 4, 381 99.