Economic transition following an emission tax in a RBC model with endogenous growth. EC-IILS JOINT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 17

Similar documents
Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Macroeconomics

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Problem 1 (30 points)

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

1 The Basic RBC Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Advanced Macroeconomics

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Macroeconomics Theory II

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

A Summary of Economic Methodology

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Expanding Variety Models

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Relative Deep Habits

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Macroeconomics Theory II

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Schumpeterian Growth Models

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

A Global Economy-Climate Model with High Regional Resolution

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Blocking Development

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011

Endogenous information acquisition

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Directed Technological Change

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Labor Union and the Wealth-Income Ratio

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Transcription:

International Labour Organization European Union International Institute for Labour Studies Economic transition following an emission tax in a RBC model with endogenous growth EC-IILS JOINT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 17

ECONOMIC TRANSITION FOLLOWING AN EMISSION TAX IN A RBC MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS GROWTH

ECONOMIC TRANSITION FOLLOWING AN EMISSION TAX IN A RBC MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS GROWTH INTERNATIONAL LABOUR ORGANIZATION INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR LABOUR STUDIES

Abstract This paper is part of a series of discussion papers that have been prepared by the International Institute for Labour Studies IILS) within the framework of the joint project Addressing European labour market and social challenges for a sustainable globalization, which has been carried out by the European Commission EC) and the International Labour Organization ILO). The discussion paper series provides background information and in-depth analysis for two concluding synthesis reports that summarize the main findings of the project. This paper relates to the second part of the project Preparing European labour markets to adapt to the long-run challenge of ensuring the joint social and environmental sustainability of globalization and the concluding synthesis report Towards a Greener Economy: The Social Dimensions. This paper investigates the short run and long run effects of introducing an emission tax. The model endogenises both the effect of damage by pollution as well as of emission tax distortions on macroeconomic variables, most importantly on economic growth. As such, it not only allows an analysis of economic fluctuations at business cycle frequency, but also a long run comparison between different environmental policy scenarios. We find that an emission tax, if its receipts are used to cut wage taxes, has a positive effect on employment and on the share of income attributed to workers. Green policy produces net distortions in the economy that will initially reduce output and growth compared to a business as usual scenario. However, accumulating environmental damages in the business as usual scenario eventually reduces its growth rate so much that the green scenario delivers net benefits. In our baseline calibration, the maximum negative net output effect of green policy is around 8%, while the effect turns positive after 90 years.

TABLE OF CONTENTS Main findings 1 1 Introduction 3 2 Literature Review 7 3 The Model 9 Technology and Pollution............................ 10 Households.................................... 13 Final goods producers.............................. 14 Intermediate goods producers......................... 14 Government budget............................... 17 Market clearing.................................. 17 Equilibrium.................................... 17 4 Quantitative Analysis 17 Calibration and steady states.......................... 18 Simulation Setup................................. 22 Simulation exercises............................... 22 5 Results 24 Baseline calibration............................... 24 The importance of endogenous growth..................... 27 No Double Dividend............................... 29 Changing the half-life time of pollution..................... 30 Lower marginal efficiency of abatement spending............... 31 Phasing-in the emission tax........................... 34 6 Discussion on optimal policy 37 Steady state analysis.............................. 37 Outlining optimization under the ideal price instrument............ 38 Pollution in utility................................. 38 i

7 Conclusion 39 A Mathematical Appendix 41 Household optimization problem........................ 41 Optimization of final goods producers..................... 42 Firm Optimization................................ 44 Equilibrium.................................... 47 Optimal Policy.................................. 51 ii

ECONOMIC TRANSITION FOLLOWING AN EMISSION TAX IN A RBC MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS GROWTH Main findings This paper addresses the intertemporal costs and benefits of an environmental tax reform in a dynamic general equilibrium model featuring endogenous growth. It highlights how changing circumstances affect the beneficial impact of green policy. The business as usual scenario assumes that as emissions remain high and pollution continues to accumulate, environmental damages become so large that they negatively impact total factor productivity and thus economic performance and growth. Whereas the introduction of environmental tax reforms would incentivise firms to engage in abatement spending, thus reducing emissions and pollution with limited effect on growth. There are five main results. First, the introduction of an emission tax creates a distortion in the economy, which immediately lowers consumption and growth. 1

As such, there is, a large relative output gap compared to the business as usual case accumulates during that initial period and can take decades to erase. Second, if the revenues from the emission tax are used to cut taxes on labour, it reduces the distortions on the labour market, thereby increasing employment, output and growth. This significantly lowers the size and duration of the relative output gap vis-a-vis the business-as-usual scenario. Third, taxes should be imposed on emissions that can be abated rather easily. While the tax revenue collected will be smaller, the size of the tax required to achieve a certain emission target will be smaller as well. This implies smaller distortions, which is especially important when tax revenue cannot fully be used to cut labour taxes. Fourth, a gradual introduction of the emission tax into the economy can have sizeable benefits in terms of the size and the time length of the relative output gap vis-a-vis the business-as-usual scenario. The cost in terms of output could be reduced by 50%. However, it comes at the cost of having a temporary increase in the pollution stock, as environmental policy is not fully effective from the outset. Interestingly, the additional increase of the pollution stock represents only a relatively small fraction of the eventual increase of the pollution stock in the business as usual scenario, around 20 parts per million in CO2. 2

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth 1 Introduction In recent years a large consensus has emerged that economic activity has a strong impact on the environment. It has become clear that a continuation of economic activity as we have seen in the past will lead to unsustainable increases in environmental pollution. Furthermore, there is also consensus that environmental degradation will eventually impact on economic performance and development, even though the precise size of this impact is very hard to estimate. On the other hand, there are voices calling that stringent environmental policies will cost too much in terms of output, jobs and growth, and that such policy should be avoided due to the high uncertainty of eventual negative effects of environmental damage. This paper investigates the costs and benefits of environmental policy using a macroeconomic modelling approach that takes emissions, pollution, environmental damages, taxation and also abatement spending into account. By applying a general equilibrium approach, the impact of environmental policy on various markets as well as the feedback mechanisms between these markets is analysed. The starting point of this paper is that the government aims to transform the economy to a green economy. In UNEP 2011) a detailed discussion of what constitutes a green economy is made. Specifically, green policy requires fixing market failures and often does not even require actual resource investments. In this paper, based on a modelling framework, we focus on environmental investments that require resources. This paper develops a modelling approach that takes both the eventual environmental damage on the economy as well as the distortion of environmental regulation into account. Environmental degradation and environmental policy both involve high uncertainty with respect to the effects they have. As such, precise predictions for the coming decades are not possible, but will always involve large confidence intervals. Therefore, the aim of this paper is not so much to make a precise prediction but 3

rather to show the qualitative impact of different estimates surrounding the effects of environmental degradation. Furthermore, this paper focuses on the general equilibrium effects of green policy. Specifically, it focuses on the resource cost of environmental spending and potential distortions from introducing environmental incentives. In a one-sector economy, economic activity generates greenhouse gas emissions. These accumulate over time in the atmosphere. As the concentration of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere gets too high, there will be damaging effects on the economy. These damages can either have a direct detrimental impact on total factor productivity, or an indirect effect through resources required to be spent to cope with environmental damage. This paper focuses on the direct effect. Since the polluters are atomistic, they do not take the impact of their emissions on total pollution into account. Thus, the accumulating environmental damage is clearly a market failure. Furthermore, environmental damage also distorts the market outcome due to its negative impact on productivity. Green policy in this paper is represented by a tax to be levied on firms emissions. Faced with this tax, firms will engage in abatement spending to reduce the size of their emissions and thus their tax payments. It is optimal for firms to spend as much on abatement to equalize the marginal savings in tax payments due to reduced emissions with the marginal cost of abatement spending. As such, abatement spending will be higher the higher is the marginal efficiency of abatement spending, or the higher is the tax rate on emissions. The paper does not consider exhaustible resources for example overfishing) or other related aspects. In general, it should be clear that each market failure which leads to environmental degradation should be investigated individually. Fixing these market failures can range from creating property rights to regulations. Not all solutions to market failures will fall in the category of green policy we investigate in this paper. However, this paper considers green policy that causes both a market distortion at the impact of taxation as well as a resource cost. If anything, a range of solutions to market failures will have a smaller negative impact on economic performance, and could even have a positive influence. Two scenarios are compared. One scenario considers the business as usual 4

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth case, where no environmental policy is enacted. Emissions remain high and pollution continues to accumulate. At some point, environmental damage from pollution becomes so strong that productivity is strongly affected. In line with the estimates quoted in Nordhaus 2010), we set the eventual maximum environmental damage in the business-as-usual case at 8 The second scenario introduces a tax on emissions. This green policy has two effects. The first effect is a reduction in emissions. This, in turn, leads to a lower accumulation of pollution and thereby eventually lowers the damaging effect of environmental degradation on the economy. The second effect concerns the immediate impact of the emission tax. Since emission is related to production, a tax on emissions distorts the relative prices the factors of production receive. Specifically, a rise in the emission tax will cause tax payments by firms to rise, while payments to capital, labour and profits fall. We model a simple Walrasian labour market with endogenous labour supply. The introduction of the emission tax will lead to an inward shift of the labour demand curve, and therefore to a lower equilibrium wage and employment. Due to the fact that the paper applies a one-sector economy and focuses on the resource effects of green policy, not much value will be gained by modelling a labour market with equilibrium unemployment. The paper compares the business-as-usual scenario with its long-run damage due to environmental degradation with the green scenario with its immediate short term repercussions on economic activity. There are two main questions. First, when, if ever, does the green economy have a higher output than the BAU economy? Second, what is the maximum relative output loss of pursuing a green policy? Furthermore, this paper endogenizes growth. This is done in a simple framework whereby technological progress is related to output being produced. It could be argued that green policy has positive effects on technological progress as it is a new field where new technologies are discovered more quickly. However, one could also argue that green policy lowers technological progress since polluting technologies will be less researched. Therefore, this model refrains from attaching a specific growth effect to green policy but keeps the simple framework. There are five main results. First, the introduction of an emission tax creates a 5

distortion in the economy, which immediately lowers consumption and growth. As the business-as-usual scenario remains on a high growth path until environmental damages to the economy are eventually large enough to lower growth, there will be an initial period of lower growth in the green economy, which accumulates to a large relative output gap compared to the business as usual case. The closing of this output gap can take a very long time, more than 100 years. Second, using the revenues from the emission tax to cut wage taxes has several benefits. It reduces the distortions on the labour market, thereby increasing employment, output and growth. This significantly lowers the size and duration of the negative relative output gap vis-a-vis the business-as-usual scenario. Lower growth for 35 years accumulates to a relative output differential of 4%. Afterwards, environmental damages in the business-as-usual scenario are so large that the growth rate in that scenario falls below the growth rate in the emission tax scenario, and the relative gap eventually reverses after 70 years. Consumption and investment are lower since a significant part of output 2.5%) is used for abatement spending. Furthermore, the share of income in the economy attributed to wage earners rises by 2.4%, while profits and capital returns fall by that amount. Third, the time for the business-as-usual scenario to reach its steady state has important consequences for when the positive effects of a green transition materialize. If this time is long, then environmental damages depressing the economy appear only very late, and thus investments made in the green scenario take a long time to pay off. Beneficial effects of green policy appear soon if the business-asusual scenario converges quickly to its steady state. In light of currently observed accelerated accumulation of greenhouse gases, the time-frame for economic damages to materialize due to environmental deterioration could shorten significantly. Fourth, taxes should be imposed on emissions that can be abated rather easily. While the tax revenue collected will be smaller, the size of the tax required to achieve a certain emission target will be smaller as well. This implies smaller distortions, which is especially important when tax revenue cannot fully be used to cut labour taxes. Fifth, a gradual introduction of the emission tax into the economy can have sizeable benefits in terms of the size and the time length of the relative output gap vis-a- 6

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth vis the business-as-usual scenario. The cost in terms of output could be reduced by 50%. However, it comes at the cost of having a temporary increase in the pollution stock, as environmental policy is not fully effective from the outset. Interestingly, the additional increase of the pollution stock represents only a relatively small fraction of the eventual increase of the pollution stock in the business as usual scenario, around 20 parts per million in CO2. 2 Literature Review Developed countries already enforce environmental regulation and taxation to varying degrees. For example, tax revenue from environmental taxes, meaning taxes on energy consumption or CO2 emissions, already constitutes a sizable 2.6% of GDP in Europe, while it constitutes 1% of GDP in North America and 1.8% in the OECD average OECD, 2007). Furthermore, private businesses spend 0.55% of GDP on abatement activities OECD average), while the OECD average for public abatement spending is 0.63% of GDP OECD, 2007). However, there is consensus that current environmental activities, especially concerning the amount of abatement spending, will not be sufficient to stop global environmental deterioration. The problem is twofold. On the one hand there is strong economic growth of developing countries; on the other environment protecting activities in developed countries are not extensive enough. Nordhaus 2010) estimates using the DICE economic model that global temperatures will increase by 3.1Â above 1900 levels by 2100 and 5.3Â by 2200 if the world continues on a business-as-usual path. Furthermore, he estimates that there will be significant economic damages from this environmental degradation. In 2100, 3% of annual output will be lost, while this figure rises to 8% in 2200. Koesler 2010) uses a standard Schumpeterian growth model in order to analyze the effect of pollution on economic growth. In this model, pollution is defined as an externality of the production of differentiated intermediate goods. Besides, the quantity of pollution emitted in the economy depends on the level of technological progress. The author shows that pollution slows down the economic growth if the pollution intensity does not decline following an improvement in technological 7

progress. Rezai et al. 2011) use a standard neoclassical growth model to study the effects of global warming on economic activity. In this model, pollution emissions are caused by the production of the final goods. Besides, pollution is assumed to affect negatively the output through a damage function. Rezai et al. 2011) show that pollution leads an over-accumulation of capital and under-investment in mitigation, which in turn imply environmental damages. After several periods, no more capital accumulation is possible because of the damages. It follows that consumption and output decline. Another question that this literature focuses on is the effects of environmental policy on the business cycle. For example, Heutel 2011) points out that environmental policies, designed to fight against climate change, are usually implemented without taking into account the macroeconomic fluctuations. In order to assess whether environmental policy should react to macroeconomic economic fluctuations or not, the author used a real business cycle model in which pollution appears as a negative externality. In this model, the damage of pollution on the efficiency of the production is explicitly modeled. Hence, using the model, the author evaluates how an emission tax rate should respond to a productivity shock. First, he finds that emissions are procyclical. Second, he shows that the emission tax rate should increase during expansions and decline during recessions. Therefore, the emission tax rate comes to dampen the procyclicality of pollution emissions. Fischer & Springborn 2011) consider a real business cycle model in which the production process uses three inputs, being labor, capital, and a polluting intermediate good. The damage caused by pollution is not explicitly modeled. Those authors evaluate three environmental policy instruments that aim at limiting pollution emissions from the intemediate good. These policy instruments are an emission cap fixed quantity of intermediate good), an emission tax, and an intensity target a maximum emissions to output ratio). Fischer & Springborn 2011) find that output is higher when the intensity target policy is considered than when the emission tax or emission cap policy are. This paper follows both Koesler 2010) and Rezai et al. 2011) by explicitly modeling the long-term damaging effects of pollution. It uses a neoclassical growth 8

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth model, as in Rezai et al. 2011), but additionally takes the impact on growth into account, as in Koesler 2010). The model developed could thus be used to study business cycles, as in Heutel 2011). The novel focus of this paper though lies on the study of the transition costs towards a green economy, starting from a business as usual economy. The method employed thus focuses on the relative performance of an economy continuing with business as usual versus an economy where green policy is implemented. A large number of factors affecting the relative performance of these two economies is analyzed. 3 The Model The economy is populated by the government and many atomistic households as well as firms. Households are standard, maximizing intertemporal utility by choosing consumption, hours worked and capital accumulation. Firms hire capital and labour to produce output, which they sell under monopolistic competition on the goods market. However, firm s productive activity produces emissions, which accumulate to increase the stock of pollutants in the air. This stock of pollutants in turn causes environmental damage, which we assume also impacts total factor productivity. Due to the fact that firms are atomistic, their marginal impact on total emissions, and thus on the stock of pollutants, is zero. Hence, they do not consider the effect of their production activity on pollution and damages, thus emission is a true externality. Environmental policy aims to force firms to somehow internalize the externalities they produce. For this reason, we introduce a tax on emissions made by firms. Furthermore, we assume that firms can reduce their emissions by performing abatement activities, which cost resources. Given this setup, firms will find it optimal to spend as much on abatement so that their marginal savings on emission tax paid equals the marginal cost of abatement spending. The presence of abatement spending reduces emissions and pollution accumulation. 9

Technology and Pollution Technology A common claim by papers advocating environmental policy is the existence of a beneficial effect of such policy on the rate of technological progress. Specifically, it is claimed that more stringent regulation or higher costs of emissions leads to more innovation to sustain economic profits, thus accelerating the rate of technology growth. In this paper we apply a standard learning-by-doing technology accumulation process without taking into account the potential innovation-accelerating aspects of environmental regulation or taxes. We motivate this choice with the unknown effect of environmental taxes on technology accumulation, which would introduce another dimension of parameter uncertainty. By relying on a standard mechanism, we can show the basic effects of green policy on growth. However, we acknowledge that a more sophisticated specification of the technology accumulation process, albeit being very difficult, could allow taking such mechanisms into account in an extended version of this model. The aggregate technology is accumulated through aggregate output as follows T t = BT 1 η t 1 Y η t 1) where B is scaling parameter and η is the strength of the endogenous growth effect. Note that η = 0 implies exogenous growth. Let s define the gross growth rate of technology as follows: g T,t T t T t 1. Thus, using equation 1), we can show that the technology gross growth rate is a positive function of aggregate output ) η Yt g T,t = B 2) T t 1 Technology growth is thus determined by the exogenous growth parameter B as well as by the endogenous growth parameter η. An inspection of equation 2) reveals that in a steady state with a constant technology growth rate, the growth rate of output and technology are equal, thus g Y = g T. 10

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth This also means that the term Y T will be stationary. Pollution In order to introduce pollution into the model we need to consider three aspects of pollution: the nature of pollution, the source of pollution, and the effects of pollution on the agents of the economy see Koesler, 2010). With regard to the nature of pollution, we assume that pollution corresponds to greenhouse gases. As a consequence, pollution must be considered as a stock variable see Stokey, 1998). Concerning the source of pollution, we assume that the emissions of pollution arise as an externality of the production of intermediate goods see Koesler, 2010). Finally, aggregate pollution is assumed to affect negatively the production of intermediate goods see Heutel, 2011). These three aspects of pollution are formalized as follows. Emissions occur at the firm level. For each firm i we specify relationship between emissions, E i,t, output, Y i,t, and abatement, S i,t, as ) ) θ2 Si,t E i,t = A E 1 θ 1 Y χ i,t 3) Y i,t This equation shows that a firm can reduce its emissions by spending S i,t on abatement. This specification follows Heutel 2011). Aggregate emissions are simply the sum over all E i,t. Equation 3) shows that in a steady state with a constant share of abatement spending in output, the relationship between the growth rates of emissions and output is given by g E = g χ Y = gχ T. Since Y T is stationary, we can also derive that E T χ is stationary. The stock of pollution, denoted by X t, is accumulated through aggregate emissions, denoted by E t. We consider a linear accumulation process see Heutel, 2011), adjusted for the stationarity requirements of a growing economy. X t = g χ T,t ρ xx t 1 + E t ), 0 < ρ x < 1 4) 11

where ρ x is the depreciation rate of pollution. Since E T χ is stationary, so will be X T χ. We adjust 4) by the technology technology growth rate since we require the use of stationary pollution in a damage function. We specify the damage of pollution on the production of intermediate goods, D t, by the following damage function see Rezai et al., 2011) ) X t 1 Xt 1 /T χ D t = D T χ t 1 = 1 x ) 1 γ x x t 1 It is worth noting that this specification of the damage function implies that the stock of pollution is bounded by x lower bound) and x upper bound), and) the damage variable takes value between 0 and 1: D t : [x, x] 0,1), X t 1 X T χ D t 1 t 1 T χ. t 1 γ 5) Emission Tax Given a a constant share of abatement spending in output, a unit percent increase in output increases emissions by χ%. Emission taxes need to grow in line with the size of the economy to have a constraining effect. Indeed, if emissions were to be taxed at a fixed rate, then the tax payable from a unit percent increase in output would also increase by χ%, while the cost of abatement spending increases by 1%, to keep its share in output constant. Thus, with a fixed tax rate on emissions it will not be optimal for firms to spend a stationary share of output on abatement in a growing economy. Rather, this share will eventually be driven to zero. To counter this effect, we assume the following firm emission tax spending M i,t : M i,t = τ E Y 1 χ t E i,t 6) The tax rate on emission is time variable, but not progressive. More specifically, it grows over time with aggregate output, which the firm takes as given, as the tax is set by the government. This is a sensible assumption, since the government cares about the emission constraining effects from its emission tax and thus will adjust the tax to grow in line with the economic output. 12

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth Households The preferences of the representative household over consumption, C t, and leisure, 1 h t where h t denotes the hours worked, are given by the following intertemporal utility function [ U C t,1 h t ) = E 0 Σt=0β t Ct 1 h t ) ψ] 1 σ 7) 1 σ where β denotes the discount factor, ψ the preference for leisure parameter and E the expectation operator. When discussing pollution in an economic model, it is a straightforward idea to also have pollution affect utility. We refrain from doing this here for two reasons. If one were to introduce pollution additively into the utility function, there would be no effect of that on household utility maximization in a decentralized economy as we consider it here since households cannot chose emissions or pollution. In case of a multiplicative introduction of pollution in the household utility function accumulating pollution should negatively affect the marginal utility of consumption and leisure. However, depending on the specification, the impact on the first order conditions could still be minimal. In Section we discuss the impact on optimal policy of allowing for pollution to affect household utility. The intratemporal budget constraint of the household is given by C t + I t + τ t + Π t 1 τ w )W t h t + r t K t 1 8) where I t stands for investment, W t the real wage, τ w the labour tax rate, K t capital stock, and r t the real rental rate of capital. τ t stands for government lump sum transfers and Π t for payouts of firms profits. The household accumulates capital K t = 1 δ)k t 1 + I t 9) where δ is the capital depreciation rate. The households constrained optimization problem is described in Appendix. Households maximize their lifetime utility 7) subject to series of budget constraints 13

8) and the capital accumulation identity 9 by choosing a path for consumption, hours worked and investment. The familiar first order conditions are: C σ t 1 τ w )W t =ψ C t 1 h t 10) 1 h t ) ψ1 σ) =βe t C σ t+1 1 h t+1) ψ1 σ) r t+1 + 1 δ) 11) Final goods producers The final good, Y t, is produced in a competitive market according to the following CES technology: 1 ) 1 µ µ Y t = Yi,t di, µ 1 12) 0 where each input Y i,t is a differentiated intermediate good. The term µ 1 µ indicates the price elasticity of the demand for any intermediate good i. The fact that demand for intermediate goods is price elastic means that each intermediate good i has a downward sloping demand curve given by Y i,t = Pi,t The derivation of 13) is shown in Appendix. P t ) µ 1 µ Yt 13) Intermediate goods producers Intermediate goods are produced by a continuum of firms, indexed by the letter i, operating in a monopolistically competitive market. Each variety of intermediate goods is produced by the following technology, Y i,t = D t F K i,t 1,T t 1 h i,t ) = D t AKi,t 1 α T t 1h i,t ) 1 α 0 < α < 1 14) where K i,t 1 denotes firm s i physical capital stock, h i,t firm s i labor hours worked), and T t 1 the aggregate level of technology, A is a scaling parameter, D t is the pol- 14

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth lution damage function 5), and α is the capital share. Here we assume that intermediate goods producers are not aware that their production activities affect the aggregate levels of pollution and technology. In other words, firms take D t and T t as given. P i,t P t Intermediate goods producer i sells the proceeds of its output at relative) price out of which it pays its wage bill, W t h i,t, rental costs of capital, r t K i,t 1, the emission tax, M i,t, and abatement spending, S i,t. It selects optimally its production, price, capital outlays, working hours and abatement according to the following dynamic optimization problem: max P i,t,k i,t 1,h i,t,s i,t E 0 Σ t=0ζ t [ ) ) ] P θ2 i,t Y i,t W t h i,t r t K i,t 1 τ E Yt 1 χ Si,t A E 1 θ 1 Y χ i,t P t Y S i,t i,t subject to 3), 13) and 14). ζ t is the endogenous discount factor. We can derive the following first order conditions see Appendix ). r t =λ i,t α Y i,t K i,t 1 15) W t =λ i,t 1 α) Y i,t 16) h i,t λ i,t = P ) 1 χ ) [ θ2 ) ]) θ2 i,t Yt Si,t Si,t µ i,t τ E A E θ 1 θ 2 + χ 1 θ 1 17) P t Y i,t Y i,t Y i,t Si,t ) 1 θ2 =τ E A E θ 1 θ 2 Yt ) 1 χ 18) Y i,t Y i,t λ i,t is the Lagrange multiplier on the production function. Distortions We see that when λ i,t < 1, there is a distortion which causes the factors of production to be paid less than their marginal product, and which consequently tends to reduce the employment of these factors. In a flexible price equilibrium, we can solve for µ i,t = 1 µ µ by optimizing with respect to P i,t. Without an emission tax, the distortion will then be the familiar distortion from monopolistic competition of size λ i,t 1 µ. From 15

now on, we will define the aggregate distortion as κ t = λ i,t. Equation 17) shows that with an emission tax, there will be an additional distortion. This counters the claims of other literature on environmental policy [CITATIONS NEEDED] that an emission tax is a pure source of revenues and does not produce dostortions. However, the emission tax as introduced in this paper serves to provide incentives to change the behavior of economic agents, and thus will alter the use of factors of production. Specifically, there are two dimensions along which the existence of tax payments, given by τ E A E, affects the firm s decision. The first, given by the first term in the bracket in 17), relates to the fact that firms can engage in abatement spending to avoid spending on the tax. This term disappears when abatement spending is inefficient, thus when θ 1 = 0 of θ 2 = 0. The second term relates to the fact that the firm can reduce its output to avoid emission tax spending. Marginal costs In Appendix, we also derive real marginal costs of a firm. These will be given by ) 1 α mc i,t = 1 Wt T t 1 r α t D t α α 1 α) 1 α + τ EA E = P i,t P t µ i,t Yt Y i,t ) 1 χ θ 1 θ 2 Si,t Y i,t ) θ2 + χ [ 1 θ 1 Si,t Y i,t ) θ2 ]) Equation 20) is in fact the same as in a standard model of monopolistic competition. Firms charge a price as a mark-up on their marginal costs. However, these marginal costs are higher when there is an emission tax, which produces a larger wedge in the economy. The flexible price equilibrium is given by symmetric firms, thus by mc i,t = mc t and P i,t = P t. In that case, we obtain the familiar mc t = 1 µ. 19) 20) 16

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth Government budget Since we study a long-run model, we assume that the government cannot rely on debt financing. To keep notation as simple as possible, we only specify the aspects of the government budget we are interested in. Specifically, the government collects emission taxes and can redistribute these either as lump-sum payments to households or can use them to cut labour taxes. We therefore specify τ E Y 1 χ t E t = τ t τ w h t W t 21) Market clearing The economy s aggregate resource constraint is given by Y t = C t + I t + S t 22) This also coincides with the bond-market equilibrium as well as with the households aggregated budget constraint. Equilibrium Due to the fact that the model has a positive technology growth rate, it has a nonlinear non-stationary equilibrium described in Appendix. In order to solve the model with available mathematical tools, we need to make it stationary. This is done by dividing non-stationary variables by a common co-integrating factor, in our case by technology T. By doing this, we can derive the non-linear stationary equilibrium, which is described in Appendix. 4 Quantitative Analysis 17

Calibration and steady states In order to solve the model, we need to assign values to the parameters and compute the steady state. The model has 17 structural parameters, namely β, α, δ, µ, σ, η, B, ρ x, γ, θ 1, θ 2, A, A E, x, x and ψ. There are also the tax parameters τ E,τ w and τ, where the lump sum tax τ remains endogenous to fulfill the budget constraint. Furthermore, there are 13 non time-varying variables y, c, i, h, k, w, r, d, x, e, g T, κ and y s. The steady state values of the variables will be uniquely determined by the structural as well as the tax parameters. However, we proceed in the calibration process by calibrating target values for h, g, d, y s and the half-life time of pollution decay ν. This way, we determine 5 parameters, A, ψ A E, θ 1, and ρ x endogenously. Table 1 shows the parameter restrictions imposed. Most of the parameters are standard. The motivation for the parameter choice related to pollution is taken from Heutel 2011). The choice for damages in the BAU scenario is taken from Nordhaus 2010). The current OECD environmental raxes and expenditure report OECD, 2007) states an average private abatement spending of 0.55% of GDP for OECD countries. The target abatement spending in the green scenario of 2.5% is taken from UNEP 2011), and represents a fivefold increase in private abatement spending. The technology scaling parameter B is chosen to allow 2% annual steady state growth if growth were exogenous. We perform sensitivity analysis for the choice of η. The steady state equations are the following g T k = 1 δ)k + i 1 τ w )w = ψ c 1 h c σ 1 h) ψ1 σ) = β g T c) σ 1 h) ψ1 σ) r + 1 δ) y = zdak α h 1 α r = κα y k 23a) 23b) 23c) 23d) 23e) 18

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth Structural parameters Table 1: Restrictions. Discount factor β = 1.03 1 4 Technology scale B = 1.005 Capital share α = 0.3 Capital depreciation rate δ = 0.025 Relative risk aversion parameter σ = 1 Technology parameter η = 0.05 Emission parameter χ = 0.696 Damage parameters γ = 0.5 Damage parameter x = 800 Damage parameter x = 300 Efficiency of abatement spending θ 2 = 0.5 Target Values Steady state growth rate target g T = 1.005 Steady state labour supply target h = 0.6 Abatement spending share in green scenario s y G) = 0.025 Damage in green scenario dg) = 1 Abatement spending share in BAU scenario s y B) = 0.0055 Damage in BAU scenario db) = 0.92 Half life time of pollution in years ν = 80 19

w = κ 1 α) y h g T = By η x = ρ x x + e ) ) s θ2 e = A E 1 θ 1 y y χ 23f) 23g) 23h) 23i) d = 1 ) 1 ) γ x x γ 23j) x x y = c + i + S Y y 23k) ) s 1 θ2 = τ E A E θ 1 θ 2 23l) y κ = 1 [ s θ2 ) ]) s θ2 µ τ EA E θ 1 θ 2 + χ 1 θ 1 y) y 23m) The above system of equations is not block-recursive and hence cannot be solved in a step-wise analytical way due to many interdependencies. Moreover, we want to calibrate the model in a way that we can obtain certain target values for g, h, y s, d and ν. We use the following procedure to solve for the structural parameters A, ψ, θ 1, AE and ρ x. Calibrating the structural parameters using targets The first parameter we calibrate is pollution depreciation ρ x. By specifying a targeted half life time ν, the computation is straightforward: ρ x = 0.5 ν 1 24) When calibrating an endogenous growth model, it is useful to specify the targeted 20

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth steady state growth rate, and set B = g T. From this, it follows immediately that y = 1. Then using equation 23c) we get the steady state value of real rental rate of capital r = gσ T β 1 + δ 25) Using equation 23j), we get the steady state value of capital k = κ α r y 26) To solve this we need to make an assumption on κ belonging to our targeted g T. For the calibration of our parameters belonging to the scenario g T = B, we assume a case where there are no distortions from emission taxation, and thus κ = 1 µ. Furthermore, we assume in this calibration scenario that there is non-distortionary abatement spending such that a green economy is reached meaning y s = 0.25), and thus that there is no damage to the economy, so that d = 1. Using this information, we can calibrate A A = y dk α h 1 α 27) Using equation 23a) we get the steady state value of investment i = g T 1 + δ)k 28) Using equation 23k) we get the steady state value of consumption c = y i s y y 29) Combining 23b) and 23f), we can solve for the next structural parameter ψ = κ1 α) y 1 h c h 30) Investigating equation 23i), [ we see ] that to specify the parameters θ 1 and A E we require a set of target variables y,e, y s for two different scenarios. The first scenario 21

is the one described above, while the second scenario is the business as usual scenario. Given the structural parameters as well as our assumed target damage, we can solve for y in that scenario. Furthermore, using the implied damages in equations 23j) and 23h), we can solve for targeted emissions e. Using the targeted abatement spending shares, we can then solve to θ 1 and A E. Simulation Setup We will compare different scenarios by targeting a certain abatement spending and determining the corresponding emission tax using equation 23l). When the government imposes a tax on emissions, it not only induces more abatement spending by firms, it also obtains revenues. These can either be redistributed in a lump-sum fashion to households, or they can be used to cut other taxes. Here, we investigate a cut in the wage tax. A balanced budget approach would suggest the following relationship Using 23f) and 23i), we obtain τ E A E τ E Y 1 χ t E t = τ w h t W t 31) 1 θ 1 S Y ) θ2 ) Y = τ w κ1 α)y 32) This directly allows the calculation of the wage tax given the emission tax. Given the full specification of all structural parameters as well as an emission and wage tax rate, we can simulate scenarios in which all variables will be determined endogenously, including these variables that are used as target values in the calibration section. Simulation exercises Our main interest lies in comparing the effect of a business-as-usual BAU) scenario to a green scenario. For that aim, we define the BAU scenario as a scenario where 22

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth there is only a very small tax rate on emissions, so that the abatement spending share specified in Table 1 is obtained. The alternative scenario is a green scenario, where the emission tax rate is set to such a level that the green abatement spending share specified in Table 1 is obtained. There are two basic simulation exercises we can perform. The first is a standard impulse response analysis to a productivity shock, comparing the response of a green to that of a BAU economy. However, there is only a minimal difference in terms of economic volatility. A positive productivity shock increases output, which increases emissions. In the BAU economy the increase in emissions and pollution will be somewhat larger since there is less abatement spending. This means that there will be a slightly larger negative medium run effect as damage is somewhat higher. However, the effect on damage is very small, being 0.025% of its steady state value in the green scenario and 0.027% of its steady state value in the BAU scenario. The similarity of these two scenarios stems from the fact that this simulation performs a productivity shock around the steady state, at which point the transition equations of both scenarios are almost identical. The second simulation exercise is a transition analysis: We assume that the BAU scenario has not reached its final steady state in pollution levels and damages. We can therefore compare the development of the economy over time when we impose an emission tax and compare it to the development of BAU. In these scenarios, we run the simulation starting from initial values representing the current status of the economy, meaning a low value of emission spending, but also a still) low level of pollution and damages. For simplicity, we will assume that in the green scenario the emission tax will be high enough to keep pollution in check so that the current level is also the steady state level. We set up the initial situation by setting damages to zero, and solving for the corresponding pollution level. Furthermore, we set the amount of abatement spending to the current BAU scenario. Using this, we can obtain the emission tax rate and the real marginal costs. With these variables, we can solve for the equilibrium values of the other variables, where we assume that they are as if in steady state since the only variables not in steady state the pollution level and damage actually will take a very long time to reach steady state and thus intertemporal influences on 23

equilibrium determination should be very small. 5 Results This section presents the results from introducing an emission tax in the baseline calibration as well as in alternative calibrations. In the baseline calibration, we utilize the parameters specified in Table 1 and also assume that all tax revenue of the emission tax is used to cut wage taxes. Baseline calibration Figure 1 presents the development of output in the business as usual scenario as well as in the scenario with a high emission tax under the baseline calibration. Since we perform our analysis in a growing economy, both lines slope upwards. After the introduction of the emission tax in Year zero there is a widening gap between the two scenarios, which then starts to close again after around 40 years, while after around 70 years output in the green scenario surpasses that in the business as usual scenario. In the following, we will continue by presenting variables as a percentage difference between the green scenario and the BAU scenario. Specifically, we will present graphs showing Y green Y BAU )/Y BAU, with the exception of technology growth rates, where we present their actual values. Figure 2 shows the relative path of output, consumption, investment and labour supply in our baseline calibration. The introduction of the emission tax has two major effects on the economy. On the one hand, it creates a distortion in the product market, similar to the price markup, which tends to reduce real payments to the factors of production. On the other hand, the emission tax also serves as a demand shock as now firms have to spend resources on abatement. In the periods immediately following the tax increase, when capital is still "fixed", the demand shock dominates the mark-up shock. Households smooth consumption, which leads to a large fall in investment. Over time around 10 years in the simulation), the production structure of the economy adjusts to the new situation and the economy grows at its new steady state growth 24

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth Figure 1: The development of output in two scenarios. Figure 2: The net effect of higher emission taxes in the baseline calibration. 25

rate see Figure 3). Figure 3: The net effect of higher emission taxes on growth. The growth rate in the business as usual scenario falls slowly as pollution accumulates further, thus causing further damage. However, the convergence of the growth rate to its final steady state value, represented by the intersection of the y- axis with the x-axis, takes a very long time. In fact, the green economy already has a superior performance in terms of growth, but also in terms of damages in relation to distortions caused by the emission tax, after 40 years. Nevertheless, 40 years of lower growth accumulate to a large relative output gap, which takes a long time of superior growth to catch up. Discussion on factor shares The simulation of the baseline calibration shows that there is actually a positive employment effect from the introduction of an emission tax. However, we also note that the emission tax creates an distortion that reduces the payments to factors of production see equations 15 and 16), or the demand for them. Contrasting this is 26

Economic Transition following an Emission Tax in a RBC Model with Endogenous Growth the rise in labour supply due to the fall in consumption and also the fall in the wage tax, which raises net incomes of households. We can calculate that payments to labour fall from 50.4% to 48.7% of output, while the payments to capital fall from 28.6% to 27.4%. The emission tax payments as a share of output are 4.1%, which actually also implies that firm s profits fall. However, once we consider that the emission tax payments come to the benefit of wage earners, we can see that the effect for wage earners of the emission tax increase is an increase in their net income share of output by 2.4%. As we discuss later, the size of tax receipts, and thereby the change in net wage income, depends on the marginal efficiency of abatement spending. The importance of endogenous growth In this section we highlight the importance of endogenizing growth. Figure 4 shows a model with exogenous growth, meaning η = 0. When one ignores endogenous growth, one would draw the conclusion that the green economy delivers a superior performance much earlier than when one takes growth into account. The temporarily worse performance of the economy has no lasting effects in terms of path dependence. On the other hand, changing the strength of endogenous growth to η = 0.5 does not alter the conclusions of the model too much see Figure 5). The timespan until the green economy surpasses the BAU economy is somewhat longer, but the sensitivity to a parameter change in η is quite low. We stress again that the endogenous growth framework in this model uses a simple learning-by-doing setup depending on output. If one were to specify a framework whereby environmental policy changed the incentive structure in the R&D sector, then there could be further forces changing the endogenous rate of technology growth. The outcomes of such changes can easily be derived from the results in this section. 27

Figure 4: The net effect of higher emission taxes under exogenous growth. Figure 5: The net effect of higher emission taxes with η = 0.5. 28