Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Similar documents
Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Comovement of East and West Stock Market Indexes

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited

Cross-regional Spillover Effects in the Korean Housing Market

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

A New Nonlinear Unit Root Test with Fourier Function

Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

New Information Response Functions

TOPICS IN ADVANCED ECONOMETRICS: SVAR MODELS PART I LESSON 2. Luca Fanelli. University of Bologna.

Is there a flight to quality due to inflation uncertainty?

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract

ECON 4160, Autumn term 2017 Lecture 9

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

Discrete Time or Continuous Time, That is the Question: the Case of Samuelson s Multiplier-Accelerator Model

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Long- versus Medium-Run Identification in Fractionally Integrated VAR Models

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

Foreign and Domestic Growth Drivers in Eastern Europe

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

Bias Correction and Out of Sample Forecast Accuracy

ARDL Cointegration Tests for Beginner

Stock Prices, News, and Economic Fluctuations: Comment

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

1. Shocks. This version: February 15, Nr. 1

Are PPP Tests Erratically Behaved? Some Panel Evidence

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

Volume 29, Issue 1. On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates

MFx Macroeconomic Forecasting

Research Statement. Zhongwen Liang

Unit Roots, Nonlinear Cointegration and Purchasing Power Parity

Multivariate forecasting with VAR models

Macroeconometric Modelling

Shyh-Wei Chen Department of Finance, Dayeh University. Abstract

Identification of Economic Shocks by Inequality Constraints in Bayesian Structural Vector Autoregression

Examining the Evidence for Purchasing Power Parity Under the. Current Float by Recursive Mean Adjustment

Are US Output Expectations Unbiased? A Cointegrated VAR Analysis in Real Time

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.9-1 (2009)

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

A. Recursively orthogonalized. VARs

Bayesian Graphical Models for Structural Vector AutoregressiveMarch Processes 21, / 1

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Nonlinear Relation of Inflation and Nominal Interest Rates A Local Nonparametric Investigation

Lecture 4: Bayesian VAR

Factor models. March 13, 2017

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER

TRINITY COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER 15-08

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Purchasing power parity over two centuries: strengthening the case for real exchange rate stability A reply to Cuddington and Liang

Asymmetric Exchange Rate Pass-through: Evidence from Nonlinear SVARs

Government expense, Consumer Price Index and Economic Growth in Cameroon

Joint Confidence Sets for Structural Impulse Responses

ERC Working Papers in Economics 01/05 November Dynamics of the Trade Balance: The Turkish J-Curve

Stationarity and cointegration tests: Comparison of Engle - Granger and Johansen methodologies

Stargazing with Structural VARs: Shock Identification via Independent Component Analysis

The Geometric Meaning of the Notion of Joint Unpredictability of a Bivariate VAR(1) Stochastic Process

Vector autoregressions, VAR

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession?

Bootstrap tests of multiple inequality restrictions on variance ratios

Forecasting Levels of log Variables in Vector Autoregressions

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15)

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS

The Contribution of Growth and Interest Rate Differentials to the Persistence of Real Exchange Rates

Nonlinear Effects of Exchange Rate Changes on the South African Bilateral Trade Balance

Financial Econometrics

Vector Autoregression Analysis: Estimation and Interpretation

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

growth in a time of debt evidence from the uk

Structural Inference With. Long-run Recursive Empirical Models

Structural Vector Autoregressions with Markov Switching. Markku Lanne University of Helsinki. Helmut Lütkepohl European University Institute, Florence

Introduction to Macroeconomics

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

Purchasing power parity: A nonlinear multivariate perspective. Abstract

Using all observations when forecasting under structural breaks

Time scale regression analysis of oil and interest rate on the exchange rate: a case study for the Czech Republic

A primer on Structural VARs

Financial Econometrics

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Do Long Run Restrictions Identify Supply and Demand Disturbances?

Finite Sample Properties of Impulse Response Intervals in SVECMs with Long-Run Identifying Restrictions

Asymmetry cointegration and the J-curve: New evidence from Korean bilateral trade balance models with her 14 partners

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? Kim Hyeongwoo Auburn University April 2009 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/17014/ MPRA Paper No. 17014, posted 31. August 2009 14:32 UTC

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? Hyeongwoo Kim Auburn University April 2009 Abstract This note discusses a pitfall of using the generalized impulse response function (GIRF) in vector autoregressive (VAR) models (Pesaran and Shin, 1998). The GIRF is general because it is invariant to the ordering of the variables in the VAR. The GIRF, in fact, is extreme because it yields a set of response functions that are based on extreme identifying assumptions that contradict each other, unless the covariance matrix is diagonal. With an empirical example, the present note demonstrates that the GIRF may yield quite misleading economic inferences. Keywords: Generalized Impulse Response Function, Orthogonalized Impulse Response Function, Vector Autoregressive Models JEL Classification: C13, C32, C51 I am grateful to Michael Stern for helpful comments. Department of Economics, Auburn University, 415 W. Magnolia Ave., Auburn, AL 36849. Tel: 334-844-2928. Fax: 334-844-4615. Email: gmmkim@gmail.com 1

1 A Pitfall of the GIRF Notwithstanding its popularity, the orthogonalized impulse response function (OIRF; Sims, 1980) analysis of structural vector autoregressive (VAR) models is subject to the so-called Wold-ordering problem. 1 That is, when one changes the order of the VAR with an alternative identifying assumption, she may obtain dramatically different response functions (Lütkepohl, 1991). Pesaran and Shin (1998) propose an ordering-invariant approach, the generalized impulse response function (GIRF), based on the work of Koop et al. (1996). The GIRF has been employed by many researches, to name a few, Boyd et al. (2001), Cheung et al. (2004), and Huang et al. (2008). However, it is important to recognize that there is a pitfall of using the GIRF. Let ψy g j (n) and ψy o j (n) denote the GIRF and the OIRF at time t + n, respectively, when there is one standard error shock at time t to the j th variable in an m-variate VAR with y t = [y 1,t y 2,t y m,t ]. Pesaran and Shin s (1998) Proposition 3.1 implies ψ g y 1 (n) = ψ o y 1 (n). 2 Define ψ o y j (n) as the OIRF when y j,t is ordered first in y t. Then, ψ g y 1 (n) = ψ o y 1 (n). Now re-order the vector so that y t = [y 2,t y 1,t y m,t ], which yields ψ g y 2 (n) = ψ o y 2 (n) by the proposition and because the GIRF is invariant to the ordering of the variables in y t. Repeat this procedure until we get ψ g y m (n) = ψ o y m (n). Collecting these response functions, then, the GIRF for the entire system is, { ψ g (n) = ψo y1 (n) ψ } y o 2 (n) ψo ym (n) The GIRF, therefore, is not general in effect because it employs extreme identifying assumptions that each variable is ordered first. More seriously, ψo yi (n) and ψ o y j (n) are not consistent with each other when i j if the covariance matrix is non-diagonal. 3,4 Hence, the GIRFs conflict each other. This result trivially applies to vector error correction models also. In next section, I show that such inconsistency may lead to misleading economic inferences. 1 The OIRF recursively identifies the structural shocks by using the Choleski decomposition of the covariance matrix, which yields a unique lower triangular matrix. This scheme, therefore, assumes that the variable ordered first in the VAR is contemporaneously unaffected by all other variables. 2 The GIRF and the OIRF coincide for the first variable in y t. 3 ψo yi (n) assumes y i,t is not contemporaneously affected by all other variables including y j,t, while ψ o y j (n) needs an assumption that y j,t is not contemporaneously affected by all other variables including y i,t. 4 If it is diagonal, there is no gain of using a structural VAR model, because it coincides with a reduced-form VAR, in other words, equation-by-equation least squares estimations. 2

2 An Empirical Illustration This section provides an empirical illustration to compare the implications of the GIRF with those of the OIRF. I use a trivariate VAR model of the US per capita investment (i), consumption (c), and real GDP (y), measured in logarithms, as Pesaran and Shin (1998) did. The data frequency is quarterly and observations span from 1947Q1 to 2008Q4, obtained from the Federal Reserve of St. Louis FRED data bank. Note that the GIRFs to (one standard error) investment shock (Panel 1-a in Figure 1) coincide with the OIRFs to an i-shock when i is assumed to be contemporaneously unaffected by other two variables, c and y (Panel 1-b). Note also that under this assumption, the OIRFs to a y-shock are very different from the corresponding GIRFs. However, the GIRFs to a y-shock are identical to the OIRFs when y is ordered first in the VAR (Panel 1-d) by construction. Again, the other OIRFs under that assumption are quite different from the corresponding GIRFs. Likewise, the GIRFs to a c-shock are identical only to the OIRFs to a c-shock when c is ordered first (Panel 1-c). What I claim here is that one has to estimate and report response functions based on her economic model. For example, if one interprets y-shocks as an output (supply) shock, while i- shocks and c-shocks are treated as expenditure (demand) shocks, she may employ an ordering [y i c] assuming that y does not contemporaneously respond to demand shocks. Then, she will report the response functions to an i-shock, for instance, that are very different from the GIRFs both quantitatively and qualitatively. If one believes that i is primarily driven by animal spirit, she may employ [i y c] instead and reports quite smaller responses of i to a y-shock than the corresponding GIRF. The responses of i to a c-shock are again a lot different in Panels 1-b and 1-d as i exhibits delayed overshooting for a year, while the GIRF produces bigger responses of i to a c-shock and delayed overshooting persists only for a half year. I am not claiming that the OIRF is better than the GIRF because there are many other alternative options available. 5 It seems more reasonable to me to use an identifying assumption that consistently describes the underlying economic models rather than to use the GIRF with a combination of extreme assumptions that conflict with each other. 5 For example, one may employ over-identified or partially identified systems. A just-identified non-recursive system can also be considered. 3

3 Conclusion This note points out that there is a pitfall of using the GIRF. Economic inferences based on the GIRF can be misleading because the GIRF employs a set of extreme identifying assumptions that contradict each other unless the covariance matrix is diagonal. Our empirical example demonstrates that this is by no means a negligible matter. 4

References Boyd, D., G. M. Caporale, R. Smith, 2001. Real Exchange Rate Effects on the Balance of Trade: Cointegration and the Marshall-Lerner Condition. International Journal of Finance and Economics 6, 187 200. Cheung, Y.-W., K. S. Lai, M. Bergman, 2004. Dissecting the PPP Puzzle: The Unconventional Roles of Nominal Exchange Rate and Price Adjustments. Journal of International Economics 64, 135 150. Huang, Y., S. N. Neftci, F. Guo, 2008. Swap Curve Dynamics Across Markets: Case of US Dollar versus HK Dollar. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money 18, 79 93. Koop, G., M. H. Pesaran, S. Potter, 1996. Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate Models. Journal of Econometrics 74. Lütkephol, H., 1991. Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, Germany. Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, 1998. Generalized Impulse Response Analysis in Linear Multivariate Models. Economics Letters 58, 17 29. Sims, C., 1980. Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica 48, 1 48. 5

Firgue 1. Impulse Response Function to One Standard Error Shock 6