Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Similar documents
Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Business Cycle Dynamics under Rational Inattention

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Rational Inattention

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

The New Keynesian Model

1 The Basic RBC Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Endogenous Information Choice

The Smets-Wouters Model

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Macroeconomics Theory II

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Endogenous information acquisition

Advanced Macroeconomics

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Problem 1 (30 points)

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Macroeconomics Theory II

Inflation Stabilization and Welfare: The Case of a Distorted Steady State

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

Learning and Global Dynamics

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Macroeconomics Theory II

Discouraging Deviant Behavior in Monetary. Economics

Relative Deep Habits

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Robustly Optimal Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Y t = log (employment t )

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

optimal simple nonlinear rules for monetary policy in a new-keynesian model

Implementable Fiscal Policy Rules

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Sticky Leverage. João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke. September 28, 2013

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Transcription:

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy Luigi Paciello Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance Mirko Wiederholt Northwestern University March 200 Abstract Should the central bank care whether slow adjustment of the price level is due to adjustment costs as in the standard New Keynesian model or due to imperfect information? Most of the analysis of optimal monetary policy is conducted in the Calvo model This paper studies optimal monetary policy in a model with exogenous dispersed information and in a rational inattention model JEL: E3,E5,D8 Keywords: imperfect information, nominal rigidities, Ramsey problem

Introduction To be written 2 Model The economy is populated by a representative household, firms and a government Household: There is a representative household The household s preferences in period t over sequences of composite consumption and labor supply {C t+τ,l t+τ } τ=0 are given by " Ã X C γ E t β τ t+τ!# γ L+ψ t+τ, () +ψ τ=0 where C t+τ is composite consumption and L t+τ is labor supply in period t+τ The operator E t is the expectation operator conditioned on the entire history of the economy up to and including period t The parameter β (0, ) is the discount factor The parameter γ > 0 is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and the parameter ψ 0 is the inverse of the Frisch elasticity of labor supply Composite consumption in period t is given by a Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator C t = Ã I IX C i= +Λ t i,t! +Λt, (2) where C i,t is consumption of good i in period t ThereareI different consumption goods The elasticity of substitution between consumption goods equals ( + /Λ t ) in period t Since Λ t will equal the desired markup by firms, we call Λ t the desired markup We assume that the log of the desired markup follows a Gaussian first-order autoregressive process ln (Λ t )=( ρ λ )ln(λ)+ρ λ ln (Λ t )+ν t, (3) where the parameter Λ > 0, the parameter ρ λ [0, ), and the innovation ν t is iidn 0,σ 2 ν The flow budget constraint of the representative household in period t reads Ã! IX M t + B t = R t B t + W t L t + D t T t + M t P i,t C i,t, (4) where B t are the household s holdings of nominal government bonds between period t and period t, R t is the nominal gross interest rate on those bond holdings, W t is 2 i=

the nominal wage rate, D t are nominal aggregate profits, and T t are nominal lump-sum taxes in period t The term in brackets on the right-hand side of equation (4) are unspent nominal money balances carried over from period t to period t The household can allocate his pre-consumption wealth in period t (ie the right-hand side of equation (4)) between nominal money balances, M t, and nominal bond holdings, B t We assume that the representative household faces the following cash-in-advance constraint in every period IX P i,t C i,t = M t (5) i= Furthermore, the representative household faces a no-ponzi-scheme condition In every period, the representative household chooses a consumption vector, labor supply, nominal money balances, and nominal bond holdings The representative household takes as given the prices of all consumption goods, the nominal interest rate, the nominal wage rate, nominal aggregate profits, and nominal lump-sum taxes Firms: There are I firms Firm i supplies good i The technology of firm i is given by Y i,t = A t L i,t, (6) where Y i,t is output and L i,t is labor input of firm i in period t The parameter (0, ] is the elasticity of output with respect to labor input The variable A t denotes aggregate productivity in period t The log of aggregate productivity follows a Gaussian first-order autoregressive process ln (A t )=ρ a ln (A t )+ε t, (7) where the parameter ρ a [0, ) and the aggregate technology shock ε t is iidn 0,σ 2 ε The process {A t } is independent of the process {Λ t } Nominal profits of firm i in period t equal ( + τ p ) P i,t Y i,t W t L i,t, (8) where τ p is a production subsidy paid by the government In every period, each firm sets a price and commits to supply any quantity at that price The firm takes as given the representative household s composite consumption, the nominal 3

wage rate, and the following price index à IX! Λt (9) P t = I +Λ t i= P Λ t i,t Government: There is a monetary authority and a fiscal authority The monetary authority commits to set the money supply according to the following rule ln (M s t )=F t (L) ε t + G t (L) ν t, (0) where Mt s denotes the money supply in period t and F t (L) and G t (L) are infinite-order lag polynomials which can depend on t The last equation simply says that the log of the money supply in period t can be any linear function of the sequence of shocks up to and including period t We will ask the question which linear function is optimal How is money injected into the economy and how does the money market clear? The household can transform any fraction of his pre-consumption wealth in period t into nominal money balances in period t See equation (4) In equilibrium, the price level and the nominal interest rate will adjust such that the demand for nominal money balances by the representative household will equal the supply of nominal money balances by the monetary authority (ie M t = Mt s ) The government budget constraint in period t reads à IX! T t + B t = R t B t + τ p P i,t Y i,t () i= The government has to finance interest on nominal government bonds and the production subsidy The government can collect lump-sum taxes or issue new nominal government bonds We assume that the government pursues a Ricardian fiscal policy In particular, for easeofexposition,weassumethatthefiscal authority fixes nominal government bonds at some non-negative level B t = B 0 (2) Dixit and Stiglitz (977), in their original article, also assumed that there is a finite number of goods and that firms take as given the price index Moreover, it seems to be a good description of the US economy that there is a finite number of physical consumption goods and that firms take the consumer price index as given 4

We assume that the fiscal authority sets the production subsidy so as to correct, in the non-stochastic steady state, the distortion arising from firms market power in the goods market Formally, τ p = Λ (3) Alternatively, one could assume that the fiscal authority sets the production subsidy so as to correct fully at each point in time the distortion arising from firms market power in the goods market Formally, τ p,t = Λ t (4) However, since in the United States fiscal policy has to be approved by Congress while monetary policy decisions by the Federal Reserve are implemented directly, we find it more realistic to assume that the fiscal authority cannot adjust the production subsidy quickly while the monetary authority can adjust the money supply quickly Information: The information set of the price setter of firm i in period t is given by any initial information that the price setter may have as well as the sequence of all signals that the price setter has received up to and including period t I i,t = I i, {s i,0,s i,,,s i,t }, (5) where I i, is the initial information set of the price setter of firm i in period minus one and s i,t is the signal that the price setter of firm i receives in period t Weassumethat,in every period t 0, the price setter of firm i receives a two-dimensional signal consisting of noisy signals about aggregate productivity and the desired markup: s i,t = ln (A t)+η i,t ln (Λ t /Λ)+ζ i,t, (6) where the noise in the signal has the following properties: (i) the stochastic processes ª η i,t and ª ζ i,t are independent of the stochastic processes {At } and {Λ t }, (ii) the stochastic processes ª ª η i,t and ζi,t are independent across firms and independent of each other, and (iii) the noise η i,t is iidn ³ 0,σ 2 η and the noise ζi,t is iidn 0,σ 2 ζ Wealsoassumethat the number of firms is sufficiently large so that I IX η i,t = I i= 5 IX ζ i,t =0 (7) i=

Two remarks are in place before we proceed First, we think of the noise in the signal as being due to limited attention by decision-makers in firms Therefore, we find it reasonable to assume that the noise in the signal is idiosyncratic and will wash out in the aggregate Second, the case of noisy signals about aggregate productivity and the desired markup will turn out to be a useful benchmark Later we will also consider the case of noisy signals about other variables We assume that the monetary authority and the representative household have perfect information (ie in every period t 0, the monetary authority and the representative household know the entire history of the economy up to and including period t) We assume that the monetary authority has perfect information because we are interested in the optimal conduct of monetary policy We assume that the representative household has perfect information to isolate the implications of imperfect information by price setters for the optimal conduct of monetary policy Note that the monetary authority, which has perfect information, could announce in every period the entire history of the economy It is important to point out that this would make no difference so long as we interpret the noise in the signal as arising from limited attention by decision-makers in firms rather than lack of publicly available information 3 Objective of the central bank In this section, we state the central bank s objective and we characterize the feasible allocation that maximizes the central bank s objective We also derive a log-quadratic approximation to the central bank s objective We assume that the monetary authority aims to maximize expected utility of the representative household: where " # X E β t U (C t,l t ), (8) U (C t,l t )= C γ t γ C t = Ã I IX C i= +Λ t i,t L+ψ t +ψ, (9)! +Λt, (20) 6

and L t = IX i= µ Ci,t A t (2) Equation (9) is the period utility function, equation (20) is the definition of composite consumption, and equation (2) is the feasibility constraint stating that the representative household has to supply the labor that is required to produce the consumption vector By substituting equations (20) and (2) into the period utility function (9), one can express period utility as a function only of the consumption vector in period t and the two exogenous variables A t and Λ t More specifically, it will be convenient to express period utility as a function only of composite consumption in period t, relative consumption of I goods in period t, anda t and Λ t In the following, Ĉ i,t =(C i,t /C t ) denotes relative consumption of good i in period t One can write equation (20) as = I IX Ĉ i= +Λ t i,t Rearranging yields à XI Ĉ I,t = I Ĉ i= +Λ t i,t! +Λt (22) Substituting equations (2) and (22) into the period utility function (9) yields the following expression for expected utility of the representative household: " X ³ E β t V C t, Ĉ,t, Ĉ2,t,,ĈI,t,A t, Λ t #, (23) with V ³C t, Ĉ,t, Ĉ2,t,,ĈI,t,A t, Λ t = C γ t γ +ψ µ Ct A t X (+ψ) I i= Ĉ i,t + à XI I Ĉ i= +Λ t i,t! (+Λ t) +ψ (24) Equation (24) gives period utility as a function only of composite consumption in period t, the consumption mix in period t, and the two exogenous variables A t and Λ t Definition An efficientallocationinperiodt is a vector R I ++ that maximizes expression (24), where Ĉi,t =(C i,t /C t ) 7 ³ C t, Ĉ,t, Ĉ2,t,,ĈI,t

and Maximizing expression (24) yields that the unique efficient allocation in period t is C t = ³ I +ψ (+ψ) γ + (+ψ) γ + A (+ψ) t, (25) i =, 2,,I :Ĉ i,t = (26) The efficient composite consumption in period t is increasing in aggregate productivity in period t Theefficient consumption mix in period t is to consume an equal amount of each good The efficient allocation in period t does not depend on Λ t In Sections 5-7, we work with a log-quadratic approximation to the central bank s objective (23)-(24) We compute the log-quadratic approximation around the non-stochastic steady state, where a non-stochastic steady state is defined as an equilibrium of the nonstochastic version of the economy with the property that real quantities, relative prices, the nominal interest rate and inflation are constant over time Let variables without time subscript denote values in the non-stochastic steady state It is straightforward to show that due to the subsidy (3) we have C = C and Ĉi = Ĉ i, that is, in the non-stochastic steady state the equilibrium allocation equals the efficient allocation Let small variables denote log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state, that is, c t =ln(c t /C), ĉ i,t =ln ³Ĉi,t, a t =ln(a t ) and λ t =ln(λ t /Λ) Expressing the function V given by equation (24) in terms of log-deviations from the non-stochastic steady state and using C = C and equation (25) yields the following expression for period utility at time t v (c t, ĉ,t, ĉ 2,t,,ĉ I,t,a t,λ t ) = C γ e ( γ)c t γ Ã C γ e (+ψ)(ct at) XI e ĉi,t + XI I ( + ψ) I I i= i= eĉi,t +Λe λ t! (+Λe λ t ) +ψ (27) Computing a second-order Taylor approximation to the function v around the origin yields the following proposition Proposition (Objective of the central bank) Let v denote the period utility function given by equation (27) Let ṽ denote the second-order Taylor approximation to v at the origin 8

Let E denote the unconditional expectation operator Let x t, z t and ω t denote the following vectors x 0 t = z 0 t = ω 0 t = ³ ³ ³ c t ĉ,t ĉ I,t, (28) a t λ t, (29) x 0 t zt 0, (30) and let ω n,t and ω k,t denote the nth and kth element of ω t Suppose that there exist two constants δ<(/β) and φ R such that, for each period t 0 and for all n and k, E ω n,t ω k,t <δ t φ (3) Then " # " X # X E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) = X β t E 2 (x t x t ) 0 H (x t x t ), (32) where the matrix H is given by γ + ( + ψ) 0 0 0 2 +Λ +Λ +Λ I(+Λ) I(+Λ) I(+Λ) H = C γ +Λ I(+Λ) +Λ I(+Λ) +Λ +Λ 0 I(+Λ) I(+Λ) 2 +Λ I(+Λ) and the vector x t is given by and c t =, (33) ( + ψ) γ + ( + ψ)a t, (34) ĉ i,t =0 (35) Proof See Appendix A After the quadratic approximation to the period utility function (27), the efficient composite consumption in period t is given by equation (34) and the efficient consumption mix in period t is given by equation (35) In addition, the loss in utility in period t in the case of a deviation from the efficient allocation is given by the quadratic form in square brackets 9

on the right-hand side of equation (32) The upper-left element of the matrix H determines the loss in utility in the case of inefficient composite consumption The lower-right block of the matrix H determines the loss in utility in the case of an inefficient consumption mix The condition (3) ensures that, in the expression for the expected discounted sum of period utility, after the quadratic approximation to the period utility function (27), one can change the order of integration and summation and the infinite sum converges 4 Statement of the optimal policy problem In this section, we state the central bank s optimal policy problem under commitment We state the problem for the economy described in Section 2 ( exogenous dispersed information ) and for an economy that is identical apart from the fact that price setters in firms choose the precision of the signal (6) subject to a cost function ( rational inattention ) In the rational inattention model, we start from the assumption that price setters make their information choice after the central bank has committed to a policy and the policy has become common knowledge 2 4 Exogenous dispersed information When the central bank can commit, the central bank solves " X ³ max E β t V C t, Ĉ,t, Ĉ2,t,,ĈI,t,A t, Λ t #, (36) {F t(l),g t(l)} subject to (i) the household s optimality conditions C i,t = P t C t = M t, (37) à P i,t I P t à IX! + Λ t C t, (38)! Λt, (39) P t = I +Λ t i= P Λ t i,t W t P t = Lψ t C γ t, (40) 2 We think it would be interesting to study the firms incentive to learn the central bank s policy choice 0

(ii) the firms optimality conditions and information sets E ( + τ p) P i,t Λ t Λ t µ +Λ t I P Λ t t C t + +Λ t W t Λ t ³ Pi,t I P t +Λ t Λ t A t Ct I i,t =0, (4) (iii) the labor market clearing condition I i,t = I i, {s i,0,s i,,,s i,t }, (42) s i,t = ln (A t)+η i,t ln (Λ t /Λ)+ζ i,t, (43) L t = IX i= µ Ci,t A t, (44) (iv) the laws of motion for aggregate productivity and the desired markup ln (A t )=ρ a ln (A t )+ε t, (45) and (v) the equation for the money supply ln (Λ t /Λ) =ρ λ ln (Λ t /Λ)+ν t, (46) ln (M t )=F t (L) ε t + G t (L) ν t (47) The function V in objective (36) is given by equation (24), F t (L) and G t (L) in equation (47) are infinite-order lag polynomials that can depend on t, and the innovations ε t, ν t, η i,t and ζ i,t have the properties described in Section 2 A log-quadratic approximation of objective (36) around the non-stochastic steady state and a log-linear approximation of the equilibrium conditions (37)-(4) and (44) around the non-stochastic steady state yields the following linear-quadratic optimal policy problem subject to max {F t (L),G t (L)} X β t C γ 2 E ³ γ + +ψ (c t c t ) 2 Ã! XI I ĉ 2 i,t +ĉ X i,t ĉ k,t + +Λ I(+Λ) i= k=, (48) p t + c t = m t, (49)

p i,t = p t + and + +Λ (w t p t )+ Λ µ c i,t = + (p i,t p t )+c t, (50) Λ p t = I IX p i,t, (5) i= w t p t = ψl t + γc t, (52) p i,t = E p i,t I i,t, (53) + +Λ c t Λ l t = I IX i= + +Λ a t + Λ Λ +Λ + +Λ λ t, (54) Λ (c i,t a t ), (55) where c t is given by equation (34), I i,t is given by equations (42)-(43), and a t, λ t and m t are given by equations (45)-(47) The linear-quadratic optimal policy problem (48)-(55) can be stated more concisely After substituting equations (50)-(5) into objective (48) and after substituting equations (50)-(52) and equation (55) into equation (54), the linear-quadratic optimal policy problem reads subject to max {F t(l),g t(l)} X β t C γ 2 E ³ + +Λ (+Λ) γ + +ψ (c t c t ) 2 + 2 IX Λ I (p i,t p t ) 2 i=, (56) c t = m t p t, (57) p t = I IX p i,t, (58) i= p i,t = E p i,t I i,t, (59) p i,t = p t + φ c c t φ a a t + φ λ λ t, (60) where c t = φ a a t, φ c (6) I i,t = I i, {s i,0,s i,,,s i,t }, (62) s i,t = a t + η i,t λ t + ζ i,t, (63) 2

a t = ρ a a t + ε t, (64) λ t = ρ λ λ t + ν t, (65) m t = F t (L) ε t + G t (L) ν t, (66) and φ c = φ a = φ λ = ψ + γ +, (67) + +Λ Λ ψ + + +Λ Λ Λ +Λ + In Sections 5-6, we characterize the solution to this problem, (68) (69) +Λ Λ 42 Rational inattention In the rational inattention model, the precision of the signals (63) is endogenous assume that firms choose the precision of the signals after the central bank has committed to a policy The attention problem of firm i reads n ω h pi,t i o min (σ 2 η,σ 2 ζ) R 2 2 E p 2 i,t + μκ, (70) + subject to We p i,t = p t + φ c c t φ a a t + φ λ λ t, (7) p i,t = E p i,t s λ,i,t, (72) s i,t = a t + η i,t λ t + ζ i,t, (73) and in each period t 0, 2 log σ2 a s t i 2 σ 2 + 2 log σ2 λ s t i 2 σ 2 κ a s t i λ s t i (74) Here the coefficient ω>0 is a non-linear function of the parameters appearing in the profit function, μ 0 is the per-period marginal cost of attention, and s t i is the sequence of signals received by firm i up to and including period t 3

5 Optimal policy response to aggregate productivity shocks In this section, we derive the optimal monetary policy response to aggregate productivity shocks 5 Exogenous dispersed information To derive the optimal monetary policy response to aggregate productivity shocks, note the following First, solving for the optimal policy response to aggregate productivity shocks and solving for the optimal policy response to markup shocks are two independent problems Thus, in this section we can assume without loss of generality that λ t =0in every period Second, suppose that price setters have perfect information Equations (57)-(60) then imply c t = φ a a t φ c p i,t p t = 0 p t = m t φ a a t φ c Note that when price setters have perfect information, the equilibrium allocation equals the efficient allocation Equilibrium composite consumption equals efficient composite consumption and the equilibrium consumption mix equals the efficient consumption mix Furthermore, note that when price setters have perfect information, monetary policy only affects the price level, which has no effect on welfare Third, suppose that price setters have imperfect information and that the central bank chooses m t = φ a φ a t If m t = φ a c φ a t, c the profit-maximizing price (60) does not depend on aggregate productivity and equations (57)-(60) imply c t = φ a a t φ c p i,t p t = 0 p t = 0 Hence, when price setters have imperfect information, the central bank can replicate one of the equilibria with perfect information: the one with stable prices Since the allocation associated with this equilibrium is efficient, the central bank can attain the efficient allocation Fourth, when price setters have imperfect information, no other monetary policy 4

attains the efficient allocation For any other monetary policy the profit-maximizing price (60) depends on aggregate productivity, implying that firms put some weight on the signal (63), which creates price dispersion We arrive at the following proposition Proposition 2 Consider the central bank s optimal policy problem (56)-(69) If σ 2 η > 0, the unique optimal monetary policy response to aggregate productivity shocks is F t (L) ε t = φ a φ c a t (75) Under this policy, the price level does not respond to an aggregate productivity shock The derivation of this result hopefully also makes clear the limitations and the extensions of this result If the equilibrium response to aggregate productivity shocks under perfect information was not efficient (eg, no Dixit-Stiglitz preferences in which case a constant subsidy would no longer be sufficient to correct the distortions due to market power in the goods market), then complete stabilization of the price level in response to an aggregate productivity shock would no longer be optimal On the other hand, consider any shock with the property that the equilibrium response to this shock under perfect information is efficient Complete stabilization of the price level in response to this shock is optimal These examples show that the result stated in Proposition 2 has nothing to do with an aggregate productivity shock being a supply shock rather than a demand shock 52 Rational inattention The same arguments as in Section 5 yield the following proposition Proposition 3 Consider the central bank s optimal policy problem (56)-(69) with (70)- (74) If μ > 0, the unique optimal monetary policy response to aggregate productivity shocks is F t (L) ε t = φ a a t (76) φ c Under this policy, the price level does not respond to an aggregate productivity shock 5

6 Optimal policy response to markup shocks In this section, we study the optimal monetary policy response to markup shocks We are interestedinmarkupshocksbecauseamarkupshockisasimpleexampleofashockwiththe property that the response to this shock under perfect information is not efficient To see this, suppose that price setters have perfect information Equations (57)-(60) then imply c t = φ a φ c a t φ λ φ c λ t p i,t p t = 0 p t = m t µ φa a t φ λ λ t φ c φ c If λ t 6=0, the equilibrium allocation under perfect information differs from the efficient allocation In Section 63, we show that the main results presented in Sections 6-62 about the optimal monetary policy response to markup shocks carry over to other shocks which have the property that the response of the economy to the shock under perfect information is not efficient In this section, we assume without loss of generality that a t =0in every period 6 Exogenous dispersed information In this subsection, we study the optimal monetary policy response to markup shocks in the model with exogenous dispersed information We first solve for the optimal monetary policy analytically in the case of ρ λ =0and then we solve for the optimal monetary policy numericallyinthecaseofρ λ 6=0 Proposition 4 Consider the central bank s optimal monetary policy problem (56)-(69) Suppose σ 2 ε = a =0and suppose ρ λ =0 Consider policies of the form G t (L) ν t = g 0 ν t 6

and equilibria of the form p t = θλ t The unique equilibrium for given monetary policy is p t = φ cg 0 + φ λ λ t (77) φ c + σ2 ζ c t = σ 2 ζ g σ 2 0 φ λ λ λ t (78) φ c + σ2 ζ p i,t p t = φ cg 0 + φ λ ζ i,t (79) φ c + σ2 ζ If σ 2 ζ > 0, the unique optimal monetary policy is g 0 = γ + +ψ +Λ φ (+Λ)(+ Λ) 2 λ φ c φ λ (80) γ + +ψ σ 2 ζ + φ 2 +Λ (+Λ)(+ Λ) 2 σ 2 c λ Proof See Appendix B In the model with exogenous dispersed information, when ρ λ =0, G t (L) ν t = g 0 ν t and p t = θλ t, complete stabilization of the price level in response to markup shocks is not optimal We will obtain the opposite result in the rational inattention model Next, we solve the central bank s optimal policy problem (56)-(69) numerically in the case of ρ λ 6=0 When we solve the central bank s optimal policy problem (56)-(69) numerically, we turn this infinite-dimensional problem into a finite-dimensional problem by parameterizing the lag polynomial G t (L) as a lag-polynomial of an ARMA(2,2) process and by restricting G t (L) tobethesameineachperiod 3 We solve the problem (56)-(69) for the following benchmark parameter values: β =099, γ =, ψ =0, =2/3, andλ =0 For comparison, we also solve for the optimal monetary policy response to markup shocks in the Calvo model In the Calvo model, firms have perfect information, and any given firm can adjust its price in any given period with an exogenous probability equal to δ 4 Figure depicts the optimal monetary policy response to a markup shock The left panels depict the optimal monetary policy when ρ λ = 0 Therightpanelsdepictthe 3 We also worked with the lag-polynomial of an ARMA(3,3) process We obtained very similar results 4 See chapters 6 and 7 in Woodford (2003) for a detailed description of optimal monetary policy in the Calvo model 7

optimal monetary policy when ρ λ =09 The solid blue lines show the impulse responses of money, output and inflation at the optimal monetary policy in the imperfect information model For comparison, the dashed red lines show the impulse responses of money, output and inflation at the optimal monetary policy with commitment in the Calvo model We obtain the following results First, full stabilization of the price level after a markup shock is not the optimal monetary policy in the imperfect information model Second, whether the optimal monetary policy in the imperfect information model is similar to the optimal monetary policy with commitment in the Calvo model depends on the persistence of the markup shock For ρ λ =09, the two policies appear to be identical, while for ρ λ =0 the two policies are quite different When ρ λ =0, in the imperfect information model it is optimal for the central bank to respond to the shock only in the period of the shock, whereas in the Calvo model it is optimal for the central bank to commit to respond to the shock also in future periods when the shock no longer affects the desired markup 62 Rational inattention Proposition 5 Consider the central bank s optimal policy problem (56)-(69) with (70)- (74) Suppose σ 2 ε = a =0and suppose ρ λ =0 Consider policies of the form G t (L) ν t = g 0 ν t and equilibria of the form p t = θλ t Define v u b t ω 2 (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) 2 μ (8) 2ln(2) If μ>0, the complete set of equilibria for given monetary policy is: (i) if b, the following is an equilibrium c t = g 0 λ t (82) p i,t p t = 0, (83) 8

(ii) if b, the following is an equilibrium c t = " # 2 2κ g 0 ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) λ t (84) 2 2κ p i,t p t = ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) ζ i,t (85) 2 κ = b + p b 2 4φ c ( φ c ) 2φ c, (86) and (iii) if b, b 2φ c and b 2 4φ c ( φ c ), the following is an equilibrium c t = " # 2 2κ g 0 ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) λ t (87) 2 2κ p i,t p t = ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) ζ i,t (88) 2 κ = b p b 2 4φ c ( φ c ) 2φ c (89) Furthermore, if φ c =, the unique optimal monetary policy is to completely stabilize the price level in response to markup shocks Proof See Appendix C 7 The value of commitment There is value of commitment in the Calvo model There is no value of commitment in the model with exogenous dispersed information Finally, there is value of commitment in the rational inattention model, but it is qualitatively and quantitatively different from the value of commitment in the Calvo model 8 Conclusion To be written 9

A Proof of Proposition First, we introduce notation Let x t denote the vector of all arguments of the function v given by equation (27) that are endogenous variables: ³ x 0 t = c t ĉ,t ĉ I,t (90) Let z t denote the vector of all arguments of the function v given by equation (27) that are exogenous variables: ³ zt 0 = a t λ t (9) Second, we compute a log-quadratic approximation to the expression for the expected discounted sum of period utility (23) Let ṽ denote the second-order Taylor approximation to v at the non-stochastic steady state We have " # X E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) " X = E β µv t (0, 0) + h 0 xx t + h 0 zz t + 2 x0 th x x t + x 0 th xz z t + # 2 z0 th z z t, (92) where h x is the vector of first derivatives of v with respect to x t evaluated at the nonstochastic steady state, h z is the vector of first derivatives of v with respect to z t evaluated at the non-stochastic steady state, H x is the matrix of second derivatives of v with respect to x t evaluated at the non-stochastic steady state, H z is the matrix of second derivatives of v with respect to z t evaluated at the non-stochastic steady state, and H xz is the matrix of second derivatives of v with respect to x t and z t evaluated at the non-stochastic steady state Third, we rewrite equation (92) using condition (3) Let ω t denote the following vector ³ ω 0 t = x 0 t z 0 t (93) Let ω n,t and ω k,t denote the nth and kth element of ω t Condition (3) implies that X β t E v (0, 0) + h0 xx t + h 0 zz t + 2 x0 th x x t + x 0 th xz z t + 2 z0 th z z t < (94) 20

It follows that one can change the order of integration and summation on the right-hand side of equation (92): " # X E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) = X β t E v (0, 0) + h 0xx t + h 0zz t + 2 x0th x x t + x 0tH xz z t + 2 z0th z z t (95) See Rao (973), p Condition (3) also implies that the infinite sum on the right-hand side of equation (95) converges to an element in R Fourth, we define the vector x t Ineach period t 0, the vector x t is defined by h x + H x x t + H xz z t =0 (96) We will show below that H x is an invertible matrix equation as Therefore, one can write the last x t = Hx h x Hx H xz z t (97) Hence, x t is uniquely determined and the vector ω t with x t = x t satisfies condition (3) Fifth, equation (95) implies that " X # " X # E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) = X β t E h 0 x (x t x t )+ 2 x0 th x x t 2 x 0 t H x x t +(x t x t ) 0 H xz z t (98) Using equation (96) to substitute for H xz z t in the last equation and rearranging yields " # " X # X E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) E β t ṽ (x t,z t ) = X β t E 2 (x t x t ) 0 H x (x t x t ) (99) Sixth, we compute the vector of first derivatives and the matrices of second derivatives appearing in equations (97) and (99) We obtain h x =0, (00) 2

H x = C γ and γ + ( + ψ) 0 0 0 2 +Λ +Λ I(+Λ) +Λ I(+Λ) +Λ I(+Λ) I(+Λ) +Λ I(+Λ) 0 +Λ I(+Λ) +Λ I(+Λ) H xz = C γ ( + ψ) 0 0 0 0 0 2 +Λ I(+Λ), (0) (02) Seventh, substituting equations (00)-(02) into equation (96) yields the following system of I equations: and, for all i =,,I, c t = ( + ψ) γ + ( + ψ)a t, (03) XI ĉ i,t + k= ĉ k,t =0 (04) Finally, we rewrite equation (04) Summing equation (04) over all i 6= I yields Substituting the last equation back into equation (04) yields XI ĉ i,t =0 (05) i= ĉ i,t =0 (06) Collecting equations (99), (0), (03) and (06), we arrive at Proposition B Proof of Proposition 4 Step : Substituting a t =0, the cash-in-advance constraint c t = m t p t, the monetary policy m t = g 0 λ t,andp t = θλ t into the equation for the profit-maximizing price (60) yields p i,t =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] λ t 22

The price set by firm i in period t then equals p i,t = [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] E [λ t I i,t ] = [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] + σ2 ζ λt + ζ i,t The price level in period t is then given by p t =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] + λ t σ2 ζ Thus, the unique rational expectations equilibrium of the form p t = θλ t isgivenbythe solution to the equation Rearranging yields θ =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] + σ2 ζ θ = (φ c g 0 + φ λ ) ( φ c ) +σ2 ζ +σ2 ζ = φ cg 0 + φ λ φ c + σ2 ζ Hence, p t = φ cg 0 + φ λ λ t (07) φ c + σ2 ζ c t = σ 2 ζ g σ 2 0 φ λ λ λ t (08) φ c + σ2 ζ p i,t p t = φ cg 0 + φ λ ζ i,t (09) φ c + σ2 ζ Step 2: Substituting equations (08)-(09), equation (6) and a t =0into the central bank s objective (56) yields C γ β 2 ³ γ + +ψ σ 2 ζ + +Λ (+Λ) + 2 Λ 23 g 0 φ λ φ c + σ2 ζ φ c g 0+φ λ φ c + σ2 ζ 2 2 σ 2 ζ

If σ 2 ζ > 0, theg 0 that maximizes this expression is g 0 = γ + +ψ +Λ φ (+Λ)(+ Λ) 2 λ φ c φ λ (0) γ + +ψ σ 2 ζ + φ 2 +Λ (+Λ)(+ Λ) 2 σ 2 c λ C Proof of Proposition 5 Step : Substituting a t =0, the cash-in-advance constraint c t = m t p t, the monetary policy m t = g 0 λ t, and the guess p t = θλ t into the equation for the profit-maximizing price yields p i,t =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] λ t The attention problem of firm i reads n ω h pi,t min κ R + 2 E p i o 2 i,t + μκ, subject to p i,t =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] λ t, p i,t = E p i,t s λ,i,t, s λ,i,t = λ t + ζ i,t, and Ã! 2 log 2 σ 2 κ, λ s λ where the coefficient ω>0is a non-linear function of the parameters appearing in the profit function and μ 0 is the per-period marginal cost of attention The solution to this attention problem is κ = 2 log 2 µ ω 2 [( φ c )θ+φ c g 0+φ λ ] 2 μ 2ln(2) The price set by firm i in period t then equals 0 otherwise if ω 2 [( φ c )θ+φ c g 0+φ λ ] 2 μ 2ln(2) p i,t = [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] E [λ t s λ,i,t ] σ 2 λ = [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] + λt + ζ i,t σ2 ζ ³ 2κ = [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] 2 λt + ζ i,t, () 24

where σ 2 ζ =2 2κ The price level and composite consumption in period t are then given by p t =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] ³ 2κ 2 λ t, (2) and c t = h ³ 2κ i g 0 [( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] 2 λ t (3) Thus, the set of rational expectations equilibria of the form p t = θλ t is given by the solutions to the following two equations θ =[( φ c ) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] ³ 2κ 2, (4) and κ = 2 log 2 µ ω 2 [( φ c )θ+φ c g 0+φ λ ] 2 μ 2ln(2) 0 otherwise if ω 2 [( φ c )θ+φ c g 0+φ λ ] 2 μ 2ln(2) (5) Step 2: Corner solution We now study under which conditions there exists a solution to equations (4)-(5) with the property κ =0 It follows from equation (4) that κ =0 implies θ =0 It follows from equation (5) that for θ =0we have κ =0ifandonlyif ω 2 [φ c g 0 + φ λ ] 2 μ 2ln(2) (6) Hence, there exists a rational expectations equilibrium of the form p t = θλ t with κ =0if and only if the weak inequality (6) is satisfied Furthermore, equations ()-(3) imply that in this equilibrium and p i,t = p t =0, (7) c t = g 0 λ t (8) Step 3: Interior solutions Next we study under which conditions there exists a solution to equations (4)-(5) with the property κ > 0 Solving equation (4) for θ yields θ = (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) 2 2κ ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) (9) 25

Furthermore, in the case of an interior solution equation (5) reads à κ = ω 2 log 2 [( φ! c) θ + φ c g 0 + φ λ ] 2 2 Combining the last two equations yields κ = 2 log 2 μ 2ln(2) " (φ ω c g 0 +φ λ )( φ c ) 2 2κ 2 ( φ c )( 2 2κ ) μ 2ln(2) # 2 + φ c g 0 + φ λ Rearranging this equation yields a quadratic equation in 2 κ v u 2 2κ φ c 2 κ t ω 2 (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) 2 μ +( φ c )=0 (20) 2ln(2) An interior solution has to satisfy the last equation as well as: 2 κ R, 2 κ and ω 2 (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) 2 μ 2ln(2) The two solutions to the quadratic equation (20) are h ³ 2κ i 2 ( φ c ) 2 (2) x = b + p b 2 4φ c ( φ c ) 2φ c, (22) and where x = b p b 2 4φ c ( φ c ) 2φ c, (23) x 2 κ, and v u b t ω 2 (φ cg 0 + φ λ ) 2 μ 2ln(2) These two solutions are real if and only if b 2 4φ c ( φ c ) Furthermore, when b 2 4φ c ( φ c ), the larger solution (22) satisfies x ifandonlyif b, 26

and the smaller solution (23) satisfies x ifandonlyif Finally, when x, condition (2) reads b 2φ c and b 0 φ c x 2 bx 2 + φ c Using the fact that φ c x 2 bx +( φ c )=0 yields x 2 x Thus, when x, condition (2) is always satisfied In summary, when b, there exists an interior solution which is given by equation (22) When b, b 2φ c and b 2 4φ c ( φ c ), there exists an interior solution which is given by equation (23) Otherwise there exists no interior solution Step 4: Optimal policy To be written 27

References [] Woodford, Michael (2002): Imperfect Common Knowledge and the Effects of Monetary Policy In Knowledge, Information, and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund S Phelps, ed Philippe Aghion et al Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press [2] Woodford, Michael (2003): Interest and Prices Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press 28

0 m 0 y 004 π 005 005 003 0 0 002 ρ = 0 005 0 05 02 005 0 05 02 00 0 00 025 025 002 03 ICK Calvo 035 0 5 0 5 20 quarters 03 035 0 5 0 5 20 quarters 003 004 0 5 0 5 20 quarters 0 m 0 y 005 π 0 0 004 02 02 003 ρ = 09 03 04 03 04 002 05 05 00 06 06 0 07 0 5 0 5 20 quarters 07 0 5 0 5 20 quarters 00 0 5 0 5 20 quarters

0 g 0 Commitment Kappa Commitment 00 05 002 003 0 004 05 005 006 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5 45 x 0 4 Welfare Loss 4 Commitment 35 3 25 2 5 05 0 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5

0 00 g 0 Commitment Discretion 6 5 Kappa Commitment Discretion 002 4 003 3 004 2 005 006 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5 0 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5 0035 003 Welfare Loss Commitment Discretion 0025 002 005 00 0005 0 0 05 5 2 25 μ /w x 0 5