Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models

Similar documents
Inference for Identifiable Parameters in Partially Identified Econometric Models

Math 494: Mathematical Statistics

STAT 135 Lab 5 Bootstrapping and Hypothesis Testing

INFERENCE BASED ON MANY CONDITIONAL MOMENT INEQUALITIES. Donald W. K. Andrews and Xiaoxia Shi. July 2015 Revised April 2016

Hypothesis Testing. 1 Definitions of test statistics. CB: chapter 8; section 10.3

Asymptotic Statistics-III. Changliang Zou

Lecture 13: Subsampling vs Bootstrap. Dimitris N. Politis, Joseph P. Romano, Michael Wolf

A Course in Applied Econometrics. Lecture 10. Partial Identification. Outline. 1. Introduction. 2. Example I: Missing Data

Econometric Analysis of Games 1

large number of i.i.d. observations from P. For concreteness, suppose

Lecture 21. Hypothesis Testing II

Inference for Subsets of Parameters in Partially Identified Models

LECTURE 5. Introduction to Econometrics. Hypothesis testing

Fall 2017 STAT 532 Homework Peter Hoff. 1. Let P be a probability measure on a collection of sets A.

STATS 200: Introduction to Statistical Inference. Lecture 29: Course review

Statistical Inference

Economics 241B Review of Limit Theorems for Sequences of Random Variables

Lecture 13: p-values and union intersection tests

Spring 2012 Math 541B Exam 1

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

Statistics Ph.D. Qualifying Exam

Review. December 4 th, Review

Semi and Nonparametric Models in Econometrics

Spring 2016 Network Science. Solution of Quiz I

Statistics - Lecture One. Outline. Charlotte Wickham 1. Basic ideas about estimation

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

Statistical Inference

Non-parametric Inference and Resampling

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics

Applied Statistics Lecture Notes

Introductory Econometrics

Stochastic Convergence, Delta Method & Moment Estimators

Lecture 4: September Reminder: convergence of sequences

Lecture 2: Consistency of M-estimators

Obtaining Critical Values for Test of Markov Regime Switching

MTMS Mathematical Statistics

Notes on Blackwell s Comparison of Experiments Tilman Börgers, June 29, 2009

parameter space Θ, depending only on X, such that Note: it is not θ that is random, but the set C(X).

On the Power of Tests for Regime Switching

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. Appendix C: Fundamentals of mathematical statistics

Statistical inference

14.30 Introduction to Statistical Methods in Economics Spring 2009

Asymptotic Distortions in Locally Misspecified Moment Inequality Models

Lecture 3 Consistency of Extremum Estimators 1

Political Science 236 Hypothesis Testing: Review and Bootstrapping

Cherry Blossom run (1) The credit union Cherry Blossom Run is a 10 mile race that takes place every year in D.C. In 2009 there were participants

Supplement to Quantile-Based Nonparametric Inference for First-Price Auctions

Robust Predictions in Games with Incomplete Information

Inference for identifiable parameters in partially identified econometric models

Lecture 7 Introduction to Statistical Decision Theory

δ -method and M-estimation

Lecture 8: Information Theory and Statistics

Asymptotic Statistics-VI. Changliang Zou

SOLUTIONS Problem Set 2: Static Entry Games

Sequential Procedure for Testing Hypothesis about Mean of Latent Gaussian Process

Introduction to Estimation Methods for Time Series models Lecture 2

Uncertainty and Disagreement in Equilibrium Models

Exact and Approximate Stepdown Methods For Multiple Hypothesis Testing

EC212: Introduction to Econometrics Review Materials (Wooldridge, Appendix)

SIMILAR-ON-THE-BOUNDARY TESTS FOR MOMENT INEQUALITIES EXIST, BUT HAVE POOR POWER. Donald W. K. Andrews. August 2011

Lecture 11 Weak IV. Econ 715

Nonparametric Inference Based on Conditional Moment Inequalities

Likelihood-based inference with missing data under missing-at-random

Players as Serial or Parallel Random Access Machines. Timothy Van Zandt. INSEAD (France)

H 2 : otherwise. that is simply the proportion of the sample points below level x. For any fixed point x the law of large numbers gives that

STAT 461/561- Assignments, Year 2015

VALIDITY OF SUBSAMPLING AND PLUG-IN ASYMPTOTIC INFERENCE FOR PARAMETERS DEFINED BY MOMENT INEQUALITIES

Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals (Part 2): Cohen s d, Logic of Testing, and Confidence Intervals

Confidence Intervals for Population Mean

Chapter 4. Theory of Tests. 4.1 Introduction

Probabilities & Statistics Revision

Lecture Notes 3 Convergence (Chapter 5)

Comprehensive Examination Quantitative Methods Spring, 2018

Performance Evaluation and Comparison

Review. DS GA 1002 Statistical and Mathematical Models. Carlos Fernandez-Granda

Estimation of Games with Ordered Actions: An Application to Chain-Store Entry

Lecture 14 More on structural estimation

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

INFERENCE FOR PARAMETERS DEFINED BY MOMENT INEQUALITIES USING GENERALIZED MOMENT SELECTION. DONALD W. K. ANDREWS and GUSTAVO SOARES

More Empirical Process Theory

Inference for Parameters Defined by Moment Inequalities: A Recommended Moment Selection Procedure

Bootstrap - theoretical problems

Economics 583: Econometric Theory I A Primer on Asymptotics: Hypothesis Testing

INFERENCE FOR PARAMETERS DEFINED BY MOMENT INEQUALITIES: A RECOMMENDED MOMENT SELECTION PROCEDURE. Donald W. K. Andrews and Panle Jia Barwick

A Note on Demand Estimation with Supply Information. in Non-Linear Models

Partial Identification and Confidence Intervals

Mean-field equilibrium: An approximation approach for large dynamic games

Business Statistics. Lecture 10: Course Review

Controlling the False Discovery Rate: Understanding and Extending the Benjamini-Hochberg Method

Stat 710: Mathematical Statistics Lecture 31

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Probability and Statistics Notes

Visual interpretation with normal approximation

MS&E 226: Small Data

CSE 312 Final Review: Section AA

arxiv: v3 [stat.me] 26 Sep 2017

Incentives Work: Getting Teachers to Come to School. Esther Duflo, Rema Hanna, and Stephen Ryan. Web Appendix

LECTURE 5 HYPOTHESIS TESTING

Game Theory Fall 2003

Iterated Strict Dominance in Pure Strategies

Transcription:

Lecture 8 Inequality Testing and Moment Inequality Models Inequality Testing In the previous lecture, we discussed how to test the nonlinear hypothesis H 0 : h(θ 0 ) 0 when the sample information comes from an asymptotically normal estimator ˆθ n of θ 0. Now we lay out a more general inequality testing problem. Let W be our observables. Let F be the true joint distribution of W. Any statistical hypothesis can be thought of as a restriction on F. A generic finite dimensional inequality hypothesis can be written as H 0 : h F 0, (1) where h F = (h F,1,..., h F,r ) R r is a parameter determined by F. To test H 0, one can make use of an estimator ĥn of h F based on an i.i.d. sample of W : W 1,..., W n. Typically, this estimator satisfies n( ĥ n h F ) d N(0, Σ F ), (2) under F, for some variance matrix Σ F. Suppose that we also have an estimator Σ n for Σ F. Similar to the previous lecture, we can construct a Wald-type test statistic: This statistic can be thought of a QLR statistic because W n = min n(ĥn t) Σ 1 n (ĥn t). (3) ( W n = n min ˆQ n (t) min t R r ) ˆQn (t), (4) for ˆQ n (t) = (ĥn t) Σ 1 n (ĥn t). We would like to choose a critical value c n (1 α) such that the asymptotic significance level of the test is correct: [ ] Asy.Sz := lim sup Pr F (W n > c n (1 α)) n F F:h F 0 α, (5) where F is the space of F. This space F is sometimes called the maintained hypothesis because assumptions that defines F are maintained no matter wether H 0 is true or false. Some teminologies on general hypothesis tests may be useful and we define them here. When the holds with equality, the test is called asymptotically size exact. When it holds with strict Xiaoxia Shi Page: 1

inequality, the test is asymptotically conservative. The test is called asymptotically similar if it is asymptotically size exact and at the same time [ ] lim inf Pr F (W n > c n (1 α)) n F F:h F 0 = α. (6) The Wald, LM and QLR tests for the equality constraints that we discussed before are asymptotically similar. But in inequality testing, asymptotic similarity is too much to ask for. 1 The tests we discussed in the previous lecture and also below are either asymptotically size exact or asymptotically conservative. Let us consider two types of data-dependent critical values: the PA and the GMS. The PA critical value is defined as the 1 α conditional quantile of J Σn,0 := min 1/2 ( Σ n Z 0 t) Σ 1 n ( Σ 1/2 n Z 0 t), (7) where Z 0 N(0, I r ). This quantile can be obtained by drawing S independent draws of Z 0, compute J Σn,0 for each draw and take the 1 α quantile of the resulting S-vector. The GMS critical value is defined as the 1 α conditional quantile of J Σn,ϕ n := min where Z 0 N(0, I r ) and ϕ n,j = element of Σ n. 1/2 ( Σ n { Z 0 + ϕ n t) Σ 1 n ( Σ 1/2 0 if nĥn,j/σ n,j κ n if nĥn,j/σ n,j < κ n and σ 2 n,j n Z 0 + ϕ n t), (8) is the jth diagonal Now let s derive the asymptotic size of the tests using the PA critical value (the QLR/PA test) and that using the GMS critical value (the QLR/GMS test). Define the null space of F to be: F 0 = {F F : h F 0}. Assumption 8.1 (a) Under any F F 0, n(ĥn h F ) d N(0, Σ F ) and Σ n p Σ F. (b) There exists constants C and c such that each element of Σ F is bounded above by C and the determinant of Σ F is bounded from below by c for all F F 0. (c) For any sequence {F n } n 1 such that F n F 0 for all n and Σ Fn Σ, under this sequence of {F n }, n(ĥn h Fn ) d N(0, Σ) and Σ n p Σ. (d) When the GMS critical value is considered, κ n. Theorem 8.1. Under Assumption 8.1, if α < 1/2, (5) holds with c n (1 α) being the PA or the GMS critical value. 1 This doesn t mean that asymptotically similar tests do not exists. They exist but typically have poor power as demonstrated in Andrews (2012) for moment inequality models. For example, a test that always rejects with α probability is an asymptotically similar test, but it also always has trivial power. Xiaoxia Shi Page: 2

Proof. Example: Stochastic Dominance. Let W = X, Y. Both X and Y are discrete random variables whose supports are subsets of x 1,..., x r. Suppose that an interesting null hypothesis is that the distribution of X stochastically dominates that of Y. Let F X denote the cdf of X and F Y that of Y, both are marginals of the joint distribution F of W. Then the null hypothesis can be written as H 0 : F X (x j ) F Y (x j ) 0 for all j = 1,..., r. (9) Here h F = (F X (x 1 ) F Y (x 1 ),..., F X (x r ) F Y (x r )). Suppose that we have a random sample {(X 1, Y 1 ),..., (X n, Y n )}. We can use ĥn = ( ˆF X,n (x 1 ) ˆF Y,n (x 1 ),..., ˆF X,n (x r ) ˆF Y,n (x r )), where ˆF X,n ( ) is the empirical distribution of X and ˆF Y,n ( ) that of Y. Suppose that X and Y are independent and suppose (x 1,..., x r ) are in ascending order. Then the first part of Assumption 8.1(a) holds by CLT with the (j, k)th element of Σ F is F X (x j x k )(1 F X (x k x j )) + F Y (x j x k )(1 F Y (x k x j )) for j k. A natural estimator of Σ F that satisfies Assumption 8.1(a) is the sample analogue of it. Assumption 8.1(b) requires F X (x j ) or F Y (x j ) c 1 j = 1,..., r. for some constant c 1 > 0. Assumptioun 8.1(c) is satisfied without any additional assumption for this particular example, by a triangular array CLT and a triangular array LLN. Moment Inequality Models Moment inequality models are a popular type of partially identified models. They come in the form of inequality restrictions on the first moment of a vector of random functions: E F [m(w, θ 0 )] 0, (10) where W is still our observables, θ 0 is the true value of the model parameter which belongs to a space Θ, m is a known R k valued function and F is the distribution of W (or in other words, the data generating process). For any data generating process, the inequalities do not necessarily pin down θ 0 to a point. In this sense, the model is potentially partially identified. A missing data example of moment inequality model has already been given in Lecture 5. Here we give a couple of other examples. Example: Simple Discrete Game with Multiple Equilibria. Consider a small number (M) of players each with an action space of J elements: (a m,1,..., a m,j ). Each of them have a payoff function π m = f m (a 1,..., a M, X, θ 0, ɛ m ), where a 1,..., a M are an action profile of the players, X is some observed characteristics, and ɛ 1,..., ɛ M are factors unobserved to the econometrician but common knowledge for the players. Suppose that the players play pure strategy Nash equilibrium. Xiaoxia Shi Page: 3

Then we have a map from X, θ 0, ɛ 1,..., ɛ m to a set of equilibria. Parametrize the distribution of ɛ 1,..., ɛ M by some distribution G(, λ 0, X), then we can compute the max probability of an action profile being played given X and θ 0, λ 0, as well as the min probability of an action profile being played. Denote those by p max (a 1,..., a M, X, θ 0, λ 0 ) and p min (a 1,..., a M, X, θ 0, λ 0 ). (11) Then a moment inequality model can be formed: E[p max (a 1,..., a M, X, θ 0, λ 0 ) 1{(A 1,..., A M ) = (a 1,..., a M )}] 0 E[1{(A 1,..., A M ) = (a 1,..., a M )} p min (a 1,..., a M, X, θ 0, λ 0 )] 0 (a 1,..., a M ) Π M m=1{a m,1,..., a m,j }, (12) where (A 1,..., A M ) is the actual action profile observable in the data. Example: Revealed Preference. (Pakes, Porter, Ho and Ishii, 2012) Consider a single agent decision problem. Suppose an agent tries to choose an action a to maximizes expectation of utility u = f(a, X, θ 0 ) + ɛ given the information provided by variables Z known to the agent at the time of decision making. Suppose that ɛ is mean independent of Z. Then the action that the agent takes (denoted A) should in expectation better than other actions: E[f(A, X, θ 0 ) f(a, X, θ 0 ) Z] 0 for any a in the action space A. Suppose that the econometrician observes X then she can use the following moment inequality model to infer about θ 0 : E[f(A, X, θ 0 ) f(a, X, θ 0 ) Z = z] 0 a A, z Z, (13) where Z is the support of Z. If Z has finite point, then this model is a moment inequality that we discuss in this lecture. Otherwise, it is a conditional moment inequality model. The key to formulate moment inequality this way is that there are variables that the econometricians observe but the agents did not at the time of the decision making. One such variable, for example, is the price of a product in a Cournot model, which is determined by the quantities chosen by the Cournot players and the demand and the demand is not completely known to the players when they chose the quantities to supply. Because the moment inequality is not necessarily point identified, there usually is no consistent estimator for θ 0. We have also learned that consistent estimation of the identified set Θ 0 = {θ Θ : E F m(w, θ) 0} is difficult and solutions available are controversial. However, we can still construct confidence sets for θ 0 that has the same interpretation as confidence sets in standard point identified models. We construct a confidence set CS n by inverting the test for the null hypothesis: H 00 : θ 0 = θ, Xiaoxia Shi Page: 4

i.e., a confidence set is the collection of θ Θ such that a test for this H 00 fail to reject. The only testable implication of H 00 is H 0 : E F m(w, θ) 0. (14) Thus, testing H 00 amounts to testing H 0. But testing the latter is a special case of the inequality testing we discribed above with h F = E F m(w, θ). Therefore, a QLR/PA or QLR/GMS test can be constructed and when inverted they leads to the QLR/PA and QLR/GMS confidence sets. To be specific, the QLR test statistic is T n (θ) = n min t 0 ( m n(θ) t) Σ 1 n (θ)( m n (θ) t), (15) where m(θ) is the sample average of m(w, θ) and Σ n (θ) the sample variance. The PA critical value and the GMS critical value can be defined similarly to those on page 2 as well. We denote a generic critical value by c n (θ, 1 α). The confidence set of level 1 α is: CS n (1 α) = {θ Θ : T n (θ) c n (θ, 1 α)} (16) Remember that in the inequality testing context, we would like the asymptotic size of the test to be controled. Here that means, for any θ Θ 0, lim sup Pr F (T n (θ) > c n (θ, 1 α)) α. (17) n F F 0 The asymptotic requirement for the confidence set is slightly stronger: i.e. lim n lim inf Pr F (θ CS n (1 α)) 1 α, (18) F F 0,θ Θ 0(F ) sup n F F 0,θ Θ 0(F ) Pr F (T n (θ) > c n (θ, 1 α)) α. (19) This means, to prove the asymptotic validity of the confidence set, one needs a modified version of Assumption 8.1, where the modification is simply replacing F F 0 by F F 0, θ Θ 0 (F ) and Σ F by Σ F (θ) and in part(c), also requiring θ n to converge as a sequence. However, this modified Assumption 8.1 typically holds under the same primitive conditions as those required for Assumption 8.1. Xiaoxia Shi Page: 5