MATH 19520/51 Class 4

Similar documents
MATH 19520/51 Class 5

Tangent Plane. Nobuyuki TOSE. October 02, Nobuyuki TOSE. Tangent Plane

Partial derivatives BUSINESS MATHEMATICS

The Mean Value Theorem. Oct

1 Functions and Graphs

1. Which one of the following points is a singular point of. f(x) = (x 1) 2/3? f(x) = 3x 3 4x 2 5x + 6? (C)

Modelling Production

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

Microeconomic Analysis

ECON 186 Class Notes: Derivatives and Differentials

Intermediate Algebra. 7.6 Quadratic Inequalities. Name. Problem Set 7.6 Solutions to Every Odd-Numbered Problem. Date

The First Derivative and Second Derivative Test

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

The Change-of-Variables Formula for Double Integrals

Limits at. x means that x gets larger and larger without a bound. Oktay Olmez and Serhan Varma Calculus Lecture 2 1 / 1

Math 1: Calculus with Algebra Midterm 2 Thursday, October 29. Circle your section number: 1 Freund 2 DeFord

The First Derivative and Second Derivative Test

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 2

Limits and Continuity

A function is actually a simple concept; if it were not, history would have replaced it with a simpler one by now! Here is the definition:

Chapter 2: Unconstrained Extrema

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

Calculus I Exam 1 Review Fall 2016

Definitions: A binary relation R on a set X is (a) reflexive if x X : xrx; (f) asymmetric if x, x X : [x Rx xr c x ]

G.5 Concept of Function, Domain, and Range

MATH 13100/58 Class 6

Calculus Review Session. Rob Fetter Duke University Nicholas School of the Environment August 13, 2015

Continuity. To handle complicated functions, particularly those for which we have a reasonable formula or formulas, we need a more precise definition.

7.1 Functions of Two or More Variables

Math Exam III - Spring

MCE/EEC 647/747: Robot Dynamics and Control. Lecture 8: Basic Lyapunov Stability Theory

MATH 19520/51 Class 2

The University of British Columbia Final Examination - December 11, 2013 Mathematics 104/184 Time: 2.5 hours. LAST Name.

7) Important properties of functions: homogeneity, homotheticity, convexity and quasi-convexity

THE REAL NUMBERS Chapter #4

Solutions: Problem Set 4 Math 201B, Winter 2007

8.7 Taylor s Inequality Math 2300 Section 005 Calculus II. f(x) = ln(1 + x) f(0) = 0

Taylor and Maclaurin Series. Approximating functions using Polynomials.

Functions. A function is a rule that gives exactly one output number to each input number.

Mathematics for Economics ECON MA/MSSc in Economics-2017/2018. Dr. W. M. Semasinghe Senior Lecturer Department of Economics

Taylor and Maclaurin Series. Approximating functions using Polynomials.

McGill University Math 354: Honors Analysis 3

Topic # /31 Feedback Control Systems. Analysis of Nonlinear Systems Lyapunov Stability Analysis

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Limits, Continuity, and the Derivative

Limits at. x means that x gets larger and larger without a bound. Oktay Ölmez, Murat Şahin and Serhan Varma Calculus Lecture 2 1 / 9

THE USE OF A CALCULATOR, CELL PHONE, OR ANY OTHER ELECTRONIC DEVICE IS NOT PERMITTED IN THIS EXAMINATION.

Maths for Economists Tutorial 0: Revision of Basic Concepts

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Advanced Calculus Math 127B, Winter 2005 Solutions: Final. nx2 1 + n 2 x, g n(x) = n2 x

a k 0, then k + 1 = 2 lim 1 + 1

Review: Power series define functions. Functions define power series. Taylor series of a function. Taylor polynomials of a function.

Continuity. MATH 161 Calculus I. J. Robert Buchanan. Fall Department of Mathematics

14.3 Partial Derivatives

REVIEW OF MATHEMATICAL CONCEPTS

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

Math 241 Final Exam, Spring 2013

CHAPTER 1: Functions

Econ 325: Introduction to Empirical Economics

MATH CALCULUS I 1.5: Continuity

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

MATH 32A: MIDTERM 2 REVIEW. sin 2 u du z(t) = sin 2 t + cos 2 2

REVIEW OF MATHEMATICAL CONCEPTS

Econ 58 Gary Smith Spring Final Exam Answers

Calculus (Math 1A) Lecture 5

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Problem Set #5

4) Univariate and multivariate functions

(x x 0 ) 2 + (y y 0 ) 2 = ε 2, (2.11)

1.10 Continuity Brian E. Veitch

MATH 19520/51 Class 11

Math 261 Exam 3 - Practice Problems. 1. The graph of f is given below. Answer the following questions. (a) Find the intervals where f is increasing:

Concentric Circles Puzzle

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

g(t) = f(x 1 (t),..., x n (t)).

MAT137 Calculus! Lecture 5

Calculus Review Session. Brian Prest Duke University Nicholas School of the Environment August 18, 2017

Functions of One Variable

Consequences of Continuity

EC611--Managerial Economics

Cauchy Integral Formula Consequences

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

f(x 0 + h) f(x 0 ) h slope of secant line = m sec

Business Mathematics. Lecture Note #13 Chapter 7-(1)

MATH 18.01, FALL PROBLEM SET # 6 SOLUTIONS

Answer Key. Calculus I Math 141 Fall 2003 Professor Ben Richert. Exam 2

Math Exam 03 Review

Math 1314 Lesson 23 Partial Derivatives

MA 223 PRACTICE QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL 3/97 A. B. C. D. E.

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

M311 Functions of Several Variables. CHAPTER 1. Continuity CHAPTER 2. The Bolzano Weierstrass Theorem and Compact Sets CHAPTER 3.

SHORT ANSWER. Write the word or phrase that best completes each statement or answers the question.

EconS Cost Structures

Solutions to Math 1b Midterm II

Basic Probability. Introduction

2. Which of the following is the ECONOMISTS inverse of the function y = 9/x 2 (i.e. find x as a function of y, x = f(y))

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Spring 2015 Sample Final Exam

Transcription:

MATH 19520/51 Class 4 Minh-Tam Trinh University of Chicago 2017-10-02

1 Functions and independent ( nonbasic ) vs. dependent ( basic ) variables. 2 Cobb Douglas production function and its interpretation. 3 Graphing multivariable functions. 4 Level curves ( indifference curves ). 5 Limits in several variables. 6 Continuity in several variables.

Functions and Variables For Stewart, a function of n variables is a formula that expresses a quantity in terms of n other numbers: for example, (1) V (r, h) = 1 3 πr2 h or income = revenue expense

Functions and Variables For Stewart, a function of n variables is a formula that expresses a quantity in terms of n other numbers: for example, (1) V (r, h) = 1 3 πr2 h or income = revenue expense Above, V and income are called the dependent or basic or bound variables. r, h, revenue, expense are called the independent or nonbasic or unbound variables. 1/3 and π are constants.

If f is a function of n variables, then the domain of f is the set of points (x 1,..., x n ) R n where f (x 1,..., x n ) is well-defined.

If f is a function of n variables, then the domain of f is the set of points (x 1,..., x n ) R n where f (x 1,..., x n ) is well-defined. For Stewart, the range of f is the set of values that f produces as output. If the domain is D, then the range is (2) {f (x 1,..., x n ) R : (x 1,..., x n ) D}. Other people call this the image of f.

Example (Cobb Douglas Production Function) A useful function in economics: (3) P(L, K) = bl α K 1 α.

Example (Cobb Douglas Production Function) A useful function in economics: (3) P(L, K) = bl α K 1 α. Above, 1 The dependent variable P stands for the total production ($) of an economic system.

Example (Cobb Douglas Production Function) A useful function in economics: (3) P(L, K) = bl α K 1 α. Above, 1 The dependent variable P stands for the total production ($) of an economic system. 2 The independent variables L and K stand for total labor (person-hours) and invested capital ($), respectively.

Example (Cobb Douglas Production Function) A useful function in economics: (3) P(L, K) = bl α K 1 α. Above, 1 The dependent variable P stands for the total production ($) of an economic system. 2 The independent variables L and K stand for total labor (person-hours) and invested capital ($), respectively. 3 b and α are constants depending on empirical data.

Example (Cobb Douglas Production Function) A useful function in economics: (3) P(L, K) = bl α K 1 α. Above, 1 The dependent variable P stands for the total production ($) of an economic system. 2 The independent variables L and K stand for total labor (person-hours) and invested capital ($), respectively. 3 b and α are constants depending on empirical data. The domain of P(L, K) is {(L, K) R 2 : L, K 0} because labor and capital are nonnegative quantities.

Graphs of Multivariable Functions Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = 1 xy.

Graphs of Multivariable Functions Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = 1 xy. The formula is well-defined as long as xy 0, meaning we have both x 0 and y 0. So the domain is (4) {(x, y) R 2 : x 0 and y 0}.

Graphs of Multivariable Functions Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = 1 xy. The formula is well-defined as long as xy 0, meaning we have both x 0 and y 0. So the domain is (4) {(x, y) R 2 : x 0 and y 0}. This is the (x, y)-plane with the x- and y-axes removed.

Graphs of Multivariable Functions Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = 1 xy. The formula is well-defined as long as xy 0, meaning we have both x 0 and y 0. So the domain is (4) {(x, y) R 2 : x 0 and y 0}. This is the (x, y)-plane with the x- and y-axes removed. We never have f (x, y) = 0, but if a 0, then f (1/a, 1) = a. So the range is R \ {0}, the set of nonzero real numbers.

Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2.

Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2. The formula is well-defined for all (x, y), so the domain of f is all of R 2.

Example Find the domain and range of f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2. The formula is well-defined for all (x, y), so the domain of f is all of R 2. If t = 1 + x 2 + y 2, then t can take any value in the interval [1, ) and only those values. So log 1 + x 2 + y 2 can take any value in the interval [0, ) and only those values. So the range of f is [0, ).

The graph of f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2 has radial symmetry: https://academo.org/demos/3d-surface-plotter/

Level/Indifference Sets Example Where is f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2 equal to 1?

Level/Indifference Sets Example Where is f (x, y) = log 1 + x 2 + y 2 equal to 1? This happens when 1 + x 2 + y 2 = e. The set of points where f (x, y) = 1 is (5) {(x, y) R 2 : x 2 + y 2 = e 2 1}, the circle of radius e 2 1 centered at the origin.

The level curves where log 1 + x 2 + y 2 = 1, 2,..., 6: https://www.desmos.com/calculator

In general, if f is a function of n variables, then the level set or indifference set of f corresponding to a value a in its range is: (6) f 1 (a) = {(x 1,..., x n ) R n : f (x 1,..., x n ) = a}. Level sets are subsets of the domain of f. Intuitively, a function is indifferent to movement within a level set.

20 15 10 Em 5 2 0 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 x 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 2 1 0 ẋ 1 Em(x, ẋ) 20 10 0 http://pgfplots.net/tikz/examples/contour-surface/

1 If f is a function of two variables, then level sets usually look like curves. (E.g., the previous slide.)

1 If f is a function of two variables, then level sets usually look like curves. (E.g., the previous slide.) 2 If f is a function of three variables, then level sets usually look like surfaces.

1 If f is a function of two variables, then level sets usually look like curves. (E.g., the previous slide.) 2 If f is a function of three variables, then level sets usually look like surfaces. This is why we talk about level curves and level surfaces.

Limits Let f be a function of n variables. Suppose D R n is the domain of f and a = (a 1,..., a n ) is a point in or on the boundary of D.

Limits Let f be a function of n variables. Suppose D R n is the domain of f and a = (a 1,..., a n ) is a point in or on the boundary of D. The limit of f at a is a value L such that, for any margin-of-error ɛ > 0, we can find a radius δ > 0 small enough that (7) f ( x) is within distance ɛ of L whenever x a is within distance δ of a. In this case, we write L = lim x a f ( x).

Example Let f (x, y) = sin(x2 + y 2 ) x 2 + y 2.

Example Let f (x, y) = sin(x2 + y 2 ) x 2 + y 2. The function f is well-defined everywhere except (x, y) = (0, 0). It turns out (8) lim f (x, y) = 1. (x,y) (0,0)

Example Let f (x, y) = sin(x2 + y 2 ) x 2 + y 2. The function f is well-defined everywhere except (x, y) = (0, 0). It turns out (8) lim f (x, y) = 1. (x,y) (0,0) Using Taylor series, one can show that (9) 1 ɛ < f (x, y) < 1 + ɛ whenever (x, y) (0, 0) is within distance δ = 4 ɛ of (0, 0).

Warning! Just like in the single-variable case, limits need not exist.

Warning! Just like in the single-variable case, limits need not exist. Example (Stewart, 14.2, Example 2) xy Does the limit of f (x, y) = x 2 exist at (0, 0)? + y2

Warning! Just like in the single-variable case, limits need not exist. Example (Stewart, 14.2, Example 2) xy Does the limit of f (x, y) = x 2 exist at (0, 0)? + y2 Approach along the x-axis: f (t, 0) 0 as t 0. Approach along the y-axis: f (0, t) 0 as t 0. Approach along the line where x and y are equal: f (t, t) 1 2 as t 0. So lim (x,y) (0,0) f (x, y) does not exist.

Continuity We say that f is continuous at a if and only if the following hold: 1 f ( a) exists. 2 lim x a f ( x) exists. 3 f ( a) = lim x a f ( x).

Continuity We say that f is continuous at a if and only if the following hold: 1 f ( a) exists. 2 lim x a f ( x) exists. 3 f ( a) = lim x a f ( x). In words, a belongs to the domain of f, and the value of f does not jump as we approach a from any direction.

Example What value(s) of a make (10) f (x, y) = { e xy (x, y) (0, 0) a (x, y) = (0, 0) continuous?

Example What value(s) of a make (10) f (x, y) = { e xy (x, y) (0, 0) a (x, y) = (0, 0) continuous? We see that lim (x,y) (0,0) f (x, y) = 1. Therefore, f is continuous if a = 1, and discontinuous otherwise.