Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Similar documents
ARDL Cointegration Tests for Beginner

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

OUTWARD FDI, DOMESTIC INVESTMENT AND INFORMAL INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA WAQAR AMEER & MOHAMMED SAUD M ALOTAISH

Stationarity and cointegration tests: Comparison of Engle - Granger and Johansen methodologies

Government expense, Consumer Price Index and Economic Growth in Cameroon

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

A New Nonlinear Unit Root Test with Fourier Function

THE LONG-RUN DETERMINANTS OF MONEY DEMAND IN SLOVAKIA MARTIN LUKÁČIK - ADRIANA LUKÁČIKOVÁ - KAROL SZOMOLÁNYI

Introduction to Modern Time Series Analysis

Quarterly Journal of Economics and Modelling Shahid Beheshti University SVAR * SVAR * **

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

EC821: Time Series Econometrics, Spring 2003 Notes Section 9 Panel Unit Root Tests Avariety of procedures for the analysis of unit roots in a panel

Strict and Flexible Inflation Forecast Targets: An Empirical Investigation

Introduction to Macroeconomics

TRINITY COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER 15-08

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data

12 TH RESEARCH MEETING OF NIPFP-DEA RESEARCH PROGRAMME

Explaining Inflation During the Great Contraction

The Dynamic Relationships between Oil Prices and the Japanese Economy: A Frequency Domain Analysis. Wei Yanfeng

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

Inflation Targeting as a Tool To Control Unemployment

Are US Output Expectations Unbiased? A Cointegrated VAR Analysis in Real Time

How Can We Extract a Fundamental Trend from an Economic Time-Series?

S TICKY I NFORMATION Fabio Verona Bank of Finland, Monetary Policy and Research Department, Research Unit

Real exchange rate behavior in 4 CEE countries using different unit root tests under PPP paradigm

The Seasonal KPSS Test When Neglecting Seasonal Dummies: A Monte Carlo analysis. Ghassen El Montasser, Talel Boufateh, Fakhri Issaoui

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

9) Time series econometrics

Efficient Within Country Estimation of the Theories of Nominal Rigidity - Draft

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Contracting Models of the Phillips Curve: Empirical Estimates for Middle-Income Countries

Unit Roots and Structural Breaks in Panels: Does the Model Specification Matter?

On inflation expectations in the NKPC model

Cointegration tests of purchasing power parity

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Title. Description. Remarks and examples. stata.com. stata.com. Introduction to DSGE models. intro 1 Introduction to DSGEs and dsge

Has the crisis changed the monetary transmission mechanism in Albania? An application of kernel density estimation technique.

A Horse-Race Contest of Selected Economic Indicators & Their Potential Prediction Abilities on GDP

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SWEDEN: A LEVERAGED BOOTSTRAP APPROACH, ( ) HATEMI-J, Abdulnasser * IRANDOUST, Manuchehr

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

The Causal Relation between Savings and Economic Growth: Some Evidence. from MENA Countries. Bassam AbuAl-Foul

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch

A Panel Test of Purchasing Power Parity. under the Null of Stationarity.

An empirical analysis of the Phillips Curve : a time series exploration of Hong Kong

Frederick Wallace Universidad de Quintana Roo. Abstract

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

11/18/2008. So run regression in first differences to examine association. 18 November November November 2008

CHAPTER 21: TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS: SOME BASIC CONCEPTS

Fundamental Disagreement

Econometrics and Structural

Financial Econometrics

Cointegration tests of purchasing power parity

Ladu and Meleddu, International Journal of Applied Economics, 13(1), March 2016, 15-31

Author: Yesuf M. Awel 1c. Affiliation: 1 PhD, Economist-Consultant; P.O Box , Addis Ababa, Ethiopia. c.

Introduction to Econometrics

Inflation Dynamics in the Euro Area Jensen, Henrik

Time Series Econometrics For the 21st Century

FinQuiz Notes

Forecast Performance, Disagreement, and Heterogeneous Signal-to-Noise Ratios

Convergence of prices and rates of in ation

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Trends and Unit Roots in Greek Real Money Supply, Real GDP and Nominal Interest Rate

What can survey forecasts tell us about information rigidities?

Wesleyan Economic Working Papers

BCT Lecture 3. Lukas Vacha.

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

On Consistency of Tests for Stationarity in Autoregressive and Moving Average Models of Different Orders

Is the US Demand for Money Unstable? B. Bhaskara Rao University of Western Sydney, Sydney (Australia)

Human Development and Trade Openness: A Case Study on Developing Countries

ECON/FIN 250: Forecasting in Finance and Economics: Section 3.2 Filtering Time Series

Extended IS-LM model - construction and analysis of behavior

LATVIAN GDP: TIME SERIES FORECASTING USING VECTOR AUTO REGRESSION

Autoregressive models with distributed lags (ADL)

LECTURE 9: GENTLE INTRODUCTION TO

growth in a time of debt evidence from the uk

Nonstationary Time Series:

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Panel Cointegration and the Monetary Exchange Rate Model

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Population Growth and Economic Development: Test for Causality

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.9-1 (2009)

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Stationarity Revisited, With a Twist. David G. Tucek Value Economics, LLC

WORKING PAPER NO DO GDP FORECASTS RESPOND EFFICIENTLY TO CHANGES IN INTEREST RATES?

Purchasing Power Parity and the European Single Currency: Some New Evidence

Volume 30, Issue 1. EUAs and CERs: Vector Autoregression, Impulse Response Function and Cointegration Analysis

Are 'unbiased' forecasts really unbiased? Another look at the Fed forecasts 1

Volume 31, Issue 1. Mean-reverting behavior of consumption-income ratio in OECD countries: evidence from SURADF panel unit root tests

A NEW APPROACH FOR EVALUATING ECONOMIC FORECASTS

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method Antonio Paradiso and B. Bhaskara Rao and Marco Ventura 12. February 2011 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/28867/ MPRA Paper No. 28867, posted 16. February 2011 21:14 UTC

1990 words Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method Antonio Paradiso anto_paradiso@hotmail.com Department of Economics University of Rome La Sapienza, Rome (Italy) B. Bhaskara Rao raob123@bigpond.com School of Economics and Finance University of Western Sydney, Sydney (Australia) Marco Ventura mventura@istat.it ISTAT, Italian National Institute of Statistics, Rome (Italy) Abstract This paper tests for the time series properties of the variables in the sticky information Phillips curve and estimates it for the US with the general to specific method (GETS). Our results show that the estimates of the stickiness parameter range from 0.25 to 0.42. Keywords: Sticky information Phillips curve, General to specific method, Stickiness parameter. JEL: E3

1. Introduction Recent empirical papers on the Phillips curves have ignored the time series properties of the variables and used classical estimation methods. However, tests show that all or at least one variable (usually the rate of inflation) are nonstationary. Therefore, classical estimation methods give spurious results and their inferences are unreliable. It is necessary, therefore, to estimate the Phillips curve and its variants viz., the new Keynesian and sticky information Phillips curves with appropriate estimation methods where all or some variables are nonstationary. This paper estimate the sticky information Phillips curve (SIPC) for the USA for 1978Q1 to 2010Q4 with the general to specific method (GETS). Section 2 discusses specification and estimation issues. Empirical results are in Section 3 and Section 4 concludes. 2. Specification and Estimation With a calibrated model Mankiw and Reis (2003) showed that SIPC explains stylised facts of inflation better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC). Subsequently, Carroll (2003), Khan and Zhu (2006) used classical methods to estimate SIPC for the USA. Pickering (2004) has also estimated SIPCs with the classical methods for some OECD countries. However, unit root tests show that the rate of inflation contains a unit root, but the stationarity properties of the proxies for the driving force of inflation (e.g., share of wages and output gap etc.,) depend on how they are measured. However, since both the level and changes of these driving force appear in the SIPC, both I(1) and I(0) variables will be present and it should be estimated with an appropriate method. Two such popular methods are the bounds test of Pesaran and Shin (1999) and the general to specific approach (GETS) of the London School of Economics (LSE), of which David Hendry is the most ardent exponent. 1 For reasons explained later we use GETS to estimate the US SIPC. We follow Pickering and Khan and Zhu and specify SIPC as: 1 1 j t y t Et 1 j t yt j0 (1) 1 For some recent applications of GETS see Rao (2007).

where rate of inflation, y GAP and E expected value. The rationale underlying equation (1) is explained in Mankiw and Reis (2003) and Carroll (2003). Basically it is assumed that firms take time to assimilate information to form expectations. While proportion firms are efficient and use the current information to form expectations, the rest of (1 ) proportion need different lengths of time to use the available information. We assume rational expectations and, as in Pickering (2004), the forecast in period t j improves the forecast in period t j 1 according to some random innovation. This implies E t jt Et j1 t t 1, where t 1 represents the forecast error due to new information in period t 1 which was unavailable in the previous period. With rational expectations, SIPC in (1) reduces to: y E E y u 1 t t t1 t t1 t t (2) Unit root tests in the following section show that while inflation contains a unit root, results on y and y, measured here with the output GAP, are ambiguous. 3. Empirical Results We measure inflation with both CPI and GDP deflator and y with GAP i.e., deviation of GDP from its linear-quadratic trend and also with its HP filtered value. Unit root test results for these variables are in the appendix and show that the SIPC in (2) contains both I(1) and I(0) variables. For estimating relationships with a mixed order of variables, Pesaran and Shin s (1999) bounds test is popular in the applied work. However, it has some limitations. The computed test statistics for cointegration may fall into a substantial inconclusive range and the critical values are given for samples of 500 and above. Therefore, their finite sample properties are not known. An alternative is the general to specific method (GETS). In GETS dynamics is an empirical issue because economic theory is mainly concerned with establishing equilibrium relationships between the levels of the variables and silent on dynamics. Therefore, dynamics is estimated in a way consistent with the underlying data generation process (DGP). The theory behind the relationship is used to specify the long run equilibrium part of the specification in the levels of the variables and lagged changes in the variables are used to capture the short run dynamics. If the underlying theories are valid for the specification of the long run relationships, the combination of

the level variables in the long run part should be I(0). Therefore, GETS specifications with level variables and their changes are I(0) because changes of variables are generally I(0) and GETS specifications can be estimated with the classical methods. Equation (2) can be rewritten as a GETS equation and the term Et1yt enters into the short run in the following way: y E E y E (3) t t1 t1 t1 t t1 t 1 t1 2 t2 t1 where = loading parameter, /1, and is expected to be 1. We firstly estimate equation (3) with all the changes in the other variables to capture the underlying DGP. If some changes are not statistically significant we drop them to obtain a final parsimonious dynamic equation. For forecasts of the variables we follow Carroll (2003) and use the survey data of Professional Forecaster of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Two impulse dummy variables DUM06Q4 and DUM08Q4 are added to capture the effects of a steep decline in energy prices and the financial crisis; see data appendix. To conserve space Table 1 and 2 show only the results with GAP, computed with HP filtered values of GDP. Other results are available upon request. Table 1 shows results for SIPC with CPI-Inflation. Estimates with three lagged changes in the variables are in column (1). Since the change in the lagged inflation rate ( t 1) is insignificant it is dropped and the reestimate is in column (2). All the summary statistics show that these are satisfactory, except for some autocorrelation at higher lags, and the Wald test that 1is not rejected. Estimates with the constraint that 1 are in column (3) and are similar to those in (2) except for the intercept and a small decrease in the estimate of the stickiness parameter, from 0.402 to 0.325. These results imply that the acceleration hypothesis is valid and about 32% to 40% of firms use current information on the expected rate of inflation in pricing decisions.

Table 1: GETS estimates of CPI inflation (1978Q1 2010Q4) y E E y E t t1 t1 t1 t t1 t 1 t1 2 t2 t1 Intercept 0.445 (0.321) -0.702 (0.186)*** 0.509 (0.179)*** 0.904 (0.120)*** 0.887 (0.400)** 0.172 1 (0.125) -0.570 2 (0.167)*** DUM06Q4-5.761 (1.766)*** DUM08Q4-13.405 2 R LM Serial corr. Test LM(2) LM(4) (Prob. Value) Wald Test H 0 : 1 (Prob. Value) (1.832)*** 0.576 (0.308)* -0.513 (0.126)*** 0.640 (0.237)*** 0.791 (0.156)*** 0.948 (0.399)** 0.169 (0.156) -0.553 (0.124)*** 0.528 (0.201)*** 1 1.095 (0.390)*** - - -0.409 (0.119)*** -5.801 (1.772)*** -13.534 (1.836)*** -0.453 (0.116)*** -5.745 (1.781)*** -13.393 (1.844)*** 0.729 0.728 0.725 0.674 0.049 0.427 0.042 0.275 0.035 0.426 0.182-0.365 0.403 0.325

Table 2 shows results when inflation is measured with GDP deflator and these are also impressive. Unlike Table 1 there is no trace of autocorrelation. Furthermore, the coefficients of the changes in the lagged inflation and its expected value are insignificant and are dropped from the estimates in column (2). This made very little change. Table 2: GETS estimates of GDP deflator inflation (1978Q1 2010Q4) y E E y E t t1 t1 t1 t t1 t 1 t1 2 t2 t1 Intercept 0.111 (0.155) -0.477 (0.119)*** 0.323 (0.138)** 0.860 (0.085)*** 0.442 (0.210)** -0.148 1 (0.091) -0.218 2 (0.151) DUM08Q4-4.199 2 R LM Serial corr. Test LM(2) LM(4) (Prob. Value) Wald Test H 0 : 1 (Prob. Value) (0.969)*** 0.128 (0.155) -0.602 (0.087)*** 0.212 (0.096)** 0.878 (0.065)*** 0.425 (0.208)** -0.124 (0.083) -0.592 (0.087)*** 0.175 (0.095)* 1 0.519 (0.205)** - - - - -4.135 (0.977)*** -3.978 (0.984)*** 0.847 0.842 0.839 0.108 0.051 0.947 0.116 0.971 0.115 0.104 0.064-0.422 0.333 0.252

However, the Wald test that 1 holds at a slightly lower level of significance. Estimates with the constraint that 1 are in column (3) and imply that 0.252. This is almost the same as its assumed value in Mankiw and Reis (2003) and close to its estimate of 0.27 in Carroll (2003). However, estimates of this parameter are more sensitive compared to those in Table 1. These estimates also imply that the acceleration hypothesis is valid and the long run US Phillips curve is vertical although 42% to 25% of firms use current information on the expected rate of inflation efficiently. 4. Conclusions This paper estimated the SIPC for the USA with an appropriate valid method when both I(1) and I(0) variables are present in a relationship. Inferences based on our estimates are more reliable than other estimates with the classical methods. Our estimates imply that the US Phillips curve is vertical in the long run and between 40% and 25% of firms use information on the expected values efficiently.

Data Appendix Definitions and Data Source: 1978Q1 2010Q4 Variable Definition Source E t 1 E t 1 y t d t Percent change from previous quarter at annual rates of Consumer Price Index (seasonally adjusted) or the GDP deflator (seasonally adjusted) and denoted below and in Table 1A as d. Forecasts for the CPI Inflation, percent change from previous quarter at annual rates (Seasonally adjusted). The series begins in 1981Q3. For period 1978Q1 1981Q2 we use forecasts data of GDP Price Deflator Inflation (the two series in 1980s are very similar). Forecasts for the GDP deflator Inflation, percent change from previous quarter at annual rates of CPI (Seasonally adjusted). Real output gap using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 1600 ( HP y ). Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED). Survey of Professional Forecaster, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (SPF). SPF FRED Real output gap using linear and quadratic trend ( TR y ). E y Forecasts for the real GDP (Seasonally adjusted). SPF t 1 t DUM06Q4 DUM08Q4 This dummy is one in this quarter and zero in other periods. It captures the drop (-32% from previous quarter at annual rates) in energy prices caused by a drop in oil prices (-47% from previous quarter at annual rates). This is a similar dummy to capture the peak effects of the financial crisis (Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, etc.). - -

Unit Root Tests Table A1 Unit Root Tests: 1978Q1 2010Q4 Variable ADF KPSS t -2.382 0.743*** t -13.777*** 0.170 d -1.675 0.797*** t d t -10.505*** 0.102 HP y -3.941** 0.042 t HP y t -8.827*** 0.032 TR y -1.662 0.107 t TR y t -7.875*** 0.086 Notes: *** Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%. generated by HP filter; HP y = GAP TR y = GAP generated by linear and quadratic trend. Lags in ADF are selected with Schwartz Information Criterion and in KPSS with the Newey-West Bandwith Bartlett kernel. The null in the unit root tests are: I(1) and I(0) for ADF and KPSS, respectively. Tests for output gap include an intercept and a deterministic trend, whereas for inflation only an intercept.

References Carroll, C. D. (2003) Macroeconomic expectations of households and professional forecasters, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 269-298. Khan, H. and Zhu, Z. (2006) Estimates of the sticky-information Phillips Curve for the United States, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 38, 195-207. Mankiw, N. G. and Reis, R. (2003) Sticky information: A model of monetary nonneutrality and structural slumps. In Knowledge, Information and Expectations in Modern Macroeconomics: In Honour of Edmund S. Phelps, edited by P. Aghion, R. Friedman, J. Stiglitz, and M. Woodford, Princeton University Press. Pickering, A. (2004) Sticky information and the Phillips Curve A tale of two forecasts, Manuscript, University of Bristol. Pesaran, H. M., and Shin, Y. (1999) Autoregressive distributed lag modelling approach to cointegration analysis, Chapter 11, in: Storm, S. (ed.), Econometrics and Economic Theory in the 20 th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium, Cambridge University Press. Rao, B. B. (2007) Estimating short and long-run relationships: a guide for the applied economist, Applied Economics, 39, 1613-1625.