EQUITY MARKET STABILITY

Similar documents
Hybrid Atlas Model. of financial equity market. Tomoyuki Ichiba 1 Ioannis Karatzas 2,3 Adrian Banner 3 Vassilios Papathanakos 3 Robert Fernholz 3

Stable Diffusions Interacting through Their Ranks, as Models of Large Equity Markets

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

LOCAL TIMES OF RANKED CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES

A Second-Order Model of the Stock Market

IOANNIS KARATZAS Mathematics and Statistics Departments Columbia University

Competing Brownian Particles

EXPLOSIONS AND ARBITRAGE IOANNIS KARATZAS. Joint work with Daniel FERNHOLZ and Johannes RUF. Talk at the University of Michigan

TRANSPORT INEQUALITIES FOR STOCHASTIC

Convex polytopes, interacting particles, spin glasses, and finance

Numerical Methods with Lévy Processes

Geometry of functionally generated portfolios

On a class of stochastic differential equations in a financial network model

Walsh Diffusions. Andrey Sarantsev. March 27, University of California, Santa Barbara. Andrey Sarantsev University of Washington, Seattle 1 / 1

The multidimensional Ito Integral and the multidimensional Ito Formula. Eric Mu ller June 1, 2015 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

Branching Processes II: Convergence of critical branching to Feller s CSB

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.mf] 26 Sep 2018

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage

Tools of stochastic calculus

Affine Processes. Econometric specifications. Eduardo Rossi. University of Pavia. March 17, 2009

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

Stochastic Calculus February 11, / 33

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

RESEARCH STATEMENT ANDREY SARANTSEV

Translation Invariant Experiments with Independent Increments

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Supermodular ordering of Poisson arrays

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

On countably skewed Brownian motion

Exact Simulation of Multivariate Itô Diffusions

Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes

Some Tools From Stochastic Analysis

Ernesto Mordecki 1. Lecture III. PASI - Guanajuato - June 2010

Stochastic Portfolio Theory: An Overview

DIVERSITY AND RELATIVE ARBITRAGE IN EQUITY MARKETS

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

An Analytic Method for Solving Uncertain Differential Equations

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

An Uncertain Control Model with Application to. Production-Inventory System

Trading strategies generated by Lyapunov functions

{σ x >t}p x. (σ x >t)=e at.

Small-time asymptotics of stopped Lévy bridges and simulation schemes with controlled bias

On the martingales obtained by an extension due to Saisho, Tanemura and Yor of Pitman s theorem

Asymptotic properties of maximum likelihood estimator for the growth rate for a jump-type CIR process

Poisson random measure: motivation

Bessel-like SPDEs. Lorenzo Zambotti, Sorbonne Université (joint work with Henri Elad-Altman) 15th May 2018, Luminy

Model-free portfolio theory and its functional master formula

Optimal exit strategies for investment projects. 7th AMaMeF and Swissquote Conference

Economics 672 Fall 2017 Tauchen. Jump Regression

STA 256: Statistics and Probability I

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

1 Brownian Local Time

VOLATILITY AND ARBITRAGE

Stat410 Probability and Statistics II (F16)

Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus

2012 NCTS Workshop on Dynamical Systems

Conditional Distributions

Mean-field dual of cooperative reproduction

Generalized Gaussian Bridges

FE 5204 Stochastic Differential Equations

Multi-Factor Lévy Models I: Symmetric alpha-stable (SαS) Lévy Processes

Simulation methods for stochastic models in chemistry

Local vs. Nonlocal Diffusions A Tale of Two Laplacians

Exercises. T 2T. e ita φ(t)dt.

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

Representing Gaussian Processes with Martingales

A class of globally solvable systems of BSDE and applications

Polynomial Preserving Jump-Diffusions on the Unit Interval

Stability and Sensitivity of the Capacity in Continuous Channels. Malcolm Egan

Filtrations, Markov Processes and Martingales. Lectures on Lévy Processes and Stochastic Calculus, Braunschweig, Lecture 3: The Lévy-Itô Decomposition

Jump-type Levy Processes

Optimal investment with high-watermark fee in a multi-dimensional jump diffusion model

The Uses of Differential Geometry in Finance

Properties of an infinite dimensional EDS system : the Muller s ratchet

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Economics 883 Spring 2016 Tauchen. Jump Regression

Exact Simulation of Diffusions and Jump Diffusions

Large deviations and averaging for systems of slow fast stochastic reaction diffusion equations.

A. Bovier () Branching Brownian motion: extremal process and ergodic theorems

Nested Uncertain Differential Equations and Its Application to Multi-factor Term Structure Model

Notes, March 4, 2013, R. Dudley Maximum likelihood estimation: actual or supposed

Multilevel Monte Carlo for Lévy Driven SDEs

Vast Volatility Matrix Estimation for High Frequency Data

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. September 23, 2015

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

On Minimal Entropy Martingale Measures

Stochastic differential equation models in biology Susanne Ditlevsen

Lecture 4: Ito s Stochastic Calculus and SDE. Seung Yeal Ha Dept of Mathematical Sciences Seoul National University

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

SDE Coefficients. March 4, 2008

THE MALLIAVIN CALCULUS FOR SDE WITH JUMPS AND THE PARTIALLY HYPOELLIPTIC PROBLEM

Transcription:

EQUITY MARKET STABILITY Adrian Banner INTECH Investment Technologies LLC, Princeton (Joint work with E. Robert Fernholz, Ioannis Karatzas, Vassilios Papathanakos and Phillip Whitman.) Talk at WCMF6 conference, Santa Barbara September 27, 2014 For Information Purposes Only 1 / 26

Model for an equity market Equity market framework with capitalizations modeled by continuous semimartingales; e.g., Bachelier, Samuelson... dx i (t) X i (t) = α i(t) dt + N ξ iν (t) dw ν (t), i = 1,..., N, ν=1 where W ( ) = (W 1 ( ),, W n ( )) is B.M. in dimension N N. Mean Return rates α( ) = (α 1 ( ),..., α N ( )) Volatility rates ξ( ) = (ξ iν ( )) 1 i N,1 ν N Covariance rates σ( ) = ξ( )ξ ( ), (N N) matrix given by σ ij (t) := N ξ iν (t)ξ jν (t) = ν=1 1 X i (t)x j (t) d dt X i, X j (t). Both α( ) and σ( ) are assumed to be locally integrable. 2 / 26

Logarithmic representation Define log capitalizations Y ( ) by so that the equation becomes Y i ( ) := log X i ( ), dx i (t) X i (t) = α i(t) dt + dy i (t) = γ i (t) dt + N ξ iν (t) dw ν (t) ν=1 N ξ iν (t) dw ν (t), ν=1 where the growth rate of the i th asset is γ i (t) := α i (t) 1 2 σ ii(t). 3 / 26

Market weights Define the total market capitalization X (t) := X 1 (t) + + X N (t). Consider now the relative weights of the various assets, in terms of capitalization: µ i (t) := X i(t) X (t) = X i (t), i = 1,..., N. X 1 (t) + + X N (t) These are strictly positive numbers, add up to 1, and are determined on the basis of the capitalizations of the market s various assets at any given time. They are perfectly observable, at all times. 4 / 26

Ranked log capitalizations Descending order statistics: max Y i( ) =: Y (1) ( ) Y (N) ( ) := min Y i( ). 1 i N 1 i N Ties are resolved lexicographically, by resorting to the lowest index (name) i. Similar ordering for the capitalizations X (k) ( ) = exp(y (k) ( )) and for the ordered market weights µ (k) ( ) = X (k) ( ) X 1 (t) +... + X N (t), k = 1,, N. 5 / 26

Capital distribution, U.S. equity market 1973-2013 10% 1% 10 bps 1973 1983 1993 2003 2013 Market Weight 1 bp 0.1 bp 0.01 bp 0.001 bp 0.0001 bp 0.00001 bp 1 10 100 1,000 10,000 Stocks Ranked by Capitalization 6 / 26

Implications of market stability Many rules-based strategies ( smart beta ) are seen to outperform cap-weighted indexes over the long term. Equity market stability is critical to this outperformance. Example: a continuously rebalanced equal-weight portfolio E. (N.B. over $10B invested in equal-weight portfolios.) Its relative value process versus the market M is (Fernholz 2002): d log(v E (t)/v M (t)) = ds(t) + θ(t) dt where θ( ) is a.s. positive and S(t) := 1 N N log µ i (t). A stable capital distribution implies that S( ) is mean-reverting, hence the relative performance is positive over sufficiently long time periods. i=1 7 / 26

Collision local times The ordered processes Y (k) are themselves semimartingales (as we shall see), and for 1 k < l N, the gap ( ) ( ) G (k,l) X(k) ( ) µ(k)( ) ( ) := Y (k) ( ) Y (l) ( ) = log = log 0 X (l) ( ) µ (l) ( ) is a continuous, nonnegative semimartingale. We shall denote by Λ (k,l) ( ) := L G (k,l) ( ) its local time at the origin (collision local time of order l k + 1). For a nonnegative continuous semimartingale G( ), recall its local time process L G ( ) = 0 1 1 {G(t)=0} dg(t) = lim ε 0 2ε 0 1 {0 G(t)<ε} d G (t). 8 / 26

Reasonable conditions for stability A: No single stock crashes relative to the entire market (coherence): lim T 1 T log µ i(t ) = 0, a.s., i = 1,..., N. B: Convergence in distribution: ( µ(1) (T ),..., µ (N) (T ) ) (M 1,, M N ), as T. C: Strong laws of large numbers for local times: lim T 1 2T Λ(k,k+1) (T ) =: λ k > 0, a.s., k = 1,, N. 9 / 26

A result of Fernholz Suppose that the eigenvalues of σ( ) are bounded from above and below a.s., and that γ i (t) = γ(t) for all i = 1,..., n (common growth rate). Then lim T 1 T µ T (1) (t) dt = 1. 0 This is a degenerate form of stability in which a single stock occupies virtually the entire market capitalization. This is not consistent with empirical observations. We seek a simple model with stability but not concentration into a subset of the stocks. 10 / 26

First-order models With given real numbers γ, γ 1,..., γ N and σ 1 > 0,..., σ N > 0, and independent Brownian motions W 1 ( ),..., W N ( ), we consider the system of SDEs with rank-based interactions dy i (t) = ( γ + ) N γ k 1 {Yi (t)=y (k) (t)} dt k=1 + N σ k 1 {Yi (t)=y (k) (t)}dw i (t). k=1 Bass & Pardoux (1987) show that this system has a weak solution, unique in distribution (well-posed martingale problem). 11 / 26

Pathwise uniqueness Ichiba, Karatzas & Shkolnikov (2013) show that there is pathwise uniqueness, thus also strength, for the above system up until the first time 3 particles collide simultaneously. For this never to happen, it is necessary and almost sufficient (IKS op. cit.) that the mapping {1,, N} k σ 2 k (0, ) be concave. Sarantsev has recently proved that concavity is indeed sufficient. However, the weaker property Λ (k,l) ( ) 0 for l k 2 is always satisfied. 12 / 26

In such a system, the ranked log-capitalizations are rather simple to describe: Y (k) (t) = Y (k) (0) + (γ + γ k )t + σ k B k (t) + 1 ( ) Λ (k,k+1) (t) Λ (k 1,k) (t). 2 In other words, they behave as independent Brownian motions B k ( ) := N i=1 0 1 {Yi (t)=y (k) (t)}dw i (t) (by the P. Lévy theorem) with drift, bouncing off each other with the help of the two-by-two collision local times. Alternative Picture: Brownian motion with drift, reflecting off the walls of the Weyl chamber W = {(y 1,..., y N ) R N : y 1 y 2 y N }. 13 / 26

Stochastic stability This system is stable if γ 1 < 0,..., γ 1 + + γ N 1 < 0, γ 1 + + γ N = 0. Most basic example ( Atlas Configuration): γ = g > 0, γ 1 = = γ N 1 = g, γ N = (N 1)g. Under this condition, we have the SLLN for local times lim T 1 2T Λ(k,k+1) (T ) = λ k := (γ 1 + + γ k ) > 0, a.s. for k = 1,..., N 1. 14 / 26

Under this stability condition, the vector process of gaps ( ) G (k,k+1) µ(k) ( ) ( ) = Y (k) ( ) Y (k+1) ( ) = log, k = 1,..., N 1 µ (k+1) ( ) converges in distribution to a random vector (G 1,..., G N 1 ) with exponential marginals P (G k > u) = e ur k, u > 0 where r k := 4λ k σ 2 k + σ2 k+1 = 1 E(G k ). The components G 1,..., G N 1 of this vector are independent, if the variances are either all the same or grow linearly by rank: σ 2 2 σ 2 1 = = σ 2 N σ2 N 1 0. 15 / 26

Rank-based variances, U.S., 1964 2012 (smoothed) Variance 0.08 0.10 0.12 0.14 0.16 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Rank 16 / 26

Estimated γ k, U.S. Equity market, 1964-2012. g k -0.15-0.10-0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Rank 17 / 26

Size-based approaches The study of rank-based models such as first-order models leads to local times. Can they be avoided? Consider a simplistic size-based model is of the form dy i (t) = G(Y i (t)) dt + S(Y i (t)) dw i (t) for suitable G, S. This is not realistic, since there may be no stability in (Y 1 ( ),..., Y N ( )). Refine by choosing G and S so that (Y 1 ( ),..., Y N ( )) has an invariant distribution, then set X i (t) = M(t) exp Y i (t) for some market growth factor M(t), independent of Y i (t). Alternatively, use the weight-based variant dy i (t) = G(µ i (t)) dt + S(µ i (t)) dw i (t). 18 / 26

Example: volatility-stabilized model With α 0, the weight-based model (Fernholz & Karatzas 2004) dy i (t) = α 2µ i (t) dt + 1 µi (t) dw i(t) is known as a volatility-stabilized model. The coordinates can be expressed as time-changed square Bessel processes of dimension 2(1 + α). Coherence holds for α > 0 but fails for α = 0. The invariant distribution of market weights is Dirichlet (Pal 2011). Many other properties are known (e.g. Goia 2009, Shkolnikov 2011). 19 / 26

Example: logarithmic potential Stabilization from the previous model follows from unbounded volatility (and growth rate, for α > 0). Consider instead the size-based model dy i (t) = ( g + σ2 2Y i (t) for g > 0, σ > 0, α 0. Coordinates are now independent. ) dt + σ exp( αy i (t)) dw i (t), With λ = 2g/σ 2, the stable density G( ) on (0, ) is { C exp ( 2αx λ G(x) = 2α e2αx + Ei(2αx) ), if α > 0 λ 2 xe λx, if α = 0. Very good agreement with observed data. 20 / 26

A jump model A potential barrier in the form of an unbounded growth rate may seem unrealistic (similar to Atlas stock). Consider instead a jump model: dy i (t) = γ dt + σ dw i (t) if Y i (t) > 0; when Y i (t) = 0, it is kicked back into (0, ) at random location η chosen (independently) according to the distribution F (x) = P(η x), 0 < x <. Interpretation: If the relative stock capitalization is too small, the stock exits the market (bankruptcy). It is immediately replaced by a new stock (IPO). This gives a constant number of stocks for convenience; a reinterpretation as a Poisson point process would allow a variable number of stocks. 21 / 26

Stability in the jump model As described in Gihman & Skorokhod (1972), the system has a stable distribution G( ) if ( x ) e 2γx e 2γy (1 F (y)) dy dx <. 0 Question: how can we ensure that F G? 0 Assume the kicks are absolutely continuous w.r.t. Lebesgue measure. Then 1 F (x) = for some pdf f ( ) on (0, ). x f (u) du 22 / 26

It develops that where f (x) = N f (x) 0 N f (u) du, x ( N f (x) := e 2γx e 2γy If f ( ) is C 2, it must then solve the ODE 0 y ) f (u) du dy. f (x) + 2γf (x) + f (0 + )f (x) = 0, x (0, ). A solution (not known to be unique!) is given by f (x) = ( γ σ 2 ) 2 xe γx/σ 2, leading to a Gamma distribution with parameter 2, bearing more than a passing resemblance to the analogous distribution for the logarithmic potential with constant variance (α = 0). 23 / 26

Summary Macroscopic models should be consistent with observations of stability and growth rates. All the models considered here have a stabilization mechanism at the bottom (Atlas stock, logarithmic potential, bankruptcy/ipo). Stabilization may also occur at the top, e.g. antitrust. Many open questions and generalizations, e.g.: Understand ranks and local time properties for non-rank-based models Study properties of canonical portfolios, e.g. equal-weight, universal, in these models Better linkage of common features between these models Thank you! 24 / 26

A few references A. Banner, E.R. Fernholz & I. Karatzas (2005) Atlas models of equity markets. Annals of Applied Probability 15, 2296-2330. A. Banner & R. Ghomrasni (2008) Local times of ranked continuous semimartingales. Stochastic Processes & Applications 118, 1244-1253. R. Bass & E. Pardoux (1987) Uniqueness for diffusions with piecewise constant coëfficients. Probability Theory & Related Fields 76, 557-572. S. Chatterjee & S. Pal (2010) A phase transition behavior for Brownian motions interacting through their ranks. Probability Theory & Related Fields 147, 123-159 25 / 26

E.R. Fernholz (2002) Stochastic Portfolio Theory. Springer-Verlag, New York. T. Ichiba, I. Karatzas & M. Shkolnikov (2013) Strong solutions of stochastic equations with rank-based coëfficients. Probability Theory & Related Fields 56, 229-248. S. Pal & M. Shkolnikov (2013) Concentration of measure for Brownian particle systems interacting through their ranks. Probability Theory & Related Fields, to appear. M. Shkolnikov (2012) Large systems of diffusions interacting through their ranks. Stochastic Processes & Their Applications 122, 1730-1747. 26 / 26