In the figure below, the point d indicates the location of the consumer that is under competition. Transportation costs are given by td.

Similar documents
Price competition with capacity constraints. Consumers are rationed at the low-price firm. But who are the rationed ones?

3.2. Cournot Model Cournot Model

Economics 101. Lecture 4 - Equilibrium and Efficiency

How Strong Are Weak Patents? Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro. Supplementary Material Licensing Probabilistic Patents to Cournot Oligopolists *

Hila Etzion. Min-Seok Pang

PROBLEM SET 7 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

CS286r Assign One. Answer Key

Online Appendix. t=1 (p t w)q t. Then the first order condition shows that

,, MRTS is the marginal rate of technical substitution

University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2009 Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION FOR THE Ph.D.

Kernel Methods and SVMs Extension

1. relation between exp. function and IUF

Cournot Equilibrium with N firms

A NOTE ON CES FUNCTIONS Drago Bergholt, BI Norwegian Business School 2011

Physics 240: Worksheet 30 Name:

On the correction of the h-index for career length

THE CHINESE REMAINDER THEOREM. We should thank the Chinese for their wonderful remainder theorem. Glenn Stevens

Assortment Optimization under MNL

Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly consisting of a single public firm and foreign competitors. Abstract

Dummy variables in multiple variable regression model

f(x,y) = (4(x 2 4)x,2y) = 0 H(x,y) =

Let p z be the price of z and p 1 and p 2 be the prices of the goods making up y. In general there is no problem in grouping goods.

Structure and Drive Paul A. Jensen Copyright July 20, 2003

Section 8.3 Polar Form of Complex Numbers

Welfare Analysis of Cournot and Bertrand Competition With(out) Investment in R & D

APPENDIX 2 FITTING A STRAIGHT LINE TO OBSERVATIONS

Errors for Linear Systems

Limited Dependent Variables

Pricing and Resource Allocation Game Theoretic Models

find (x): given element x, return the canonical element of the set containing x;

Definition. Measures of Dispersion. Measures of Dispersion. Definition. The Range. Measures of Dispersion 3/24/2014

Department of Statistics University of Toronto STA305H1S / 1004 HS Design and Analysis of Experiments Term Test - Winter Solution

Module 9. Lecture 6. Duality in Assignment Problems

k t+1 + c t A t k t, t=0

Welfare Properties of General Equilibrium. What can be said about optimality properties of resource allocation implied by general equilibrium?

( ) 1/ 2. ( P SO2 )( P O2 ) 1/ 2.

Chapter 2 - The Simple Linear Regression Model S =0. e i is a random error. S β2 β. This is a minimization problem. Solution is a calculus exercise.

Lectures - Week 4 Matrix norms, Conditioning, Vector Spaces, Linear Independence, Spanning sets and Basis, Null space and Range of a Matrix

Math1110 (Spring 2009) Prelim 3 - Solutions

Lecture Notes, January 11, 2010

Equilibrium with Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Introduction to Vapor/Liquid Equilibrium, part 2. Raoult s Law:

Quantity Precommitment and Cournot and Bertrand Models with Complementary Goods

princeton univ. F 17 cos 521: Advanced Algorithm Design Lecture 7: LP Duality Lecturer: Matt Weinberg

Physics 5153 Classical Mechanics. Principle of Virtual Work-1

e - c o m p a n i o n

Economics 130. Lecture 4 Simple Linear Regression Continued

Unit 5: Quadratic Equations & Functions

Supporting Information for: Two Monetary Models with Alternating Markets

Solution Thermodynamics

G = G 1 + G 2 + G 3 G 2 +G 3 G1 G2 G3. Network (a) Network (b) Network (c) Network (d)

Physics 4B. A positive value is obtained, so the current is counterclockwise around the circuit.

CinChE Problem-Solving Strategy Chapter 4 Development of a Mathematical Model. formulation. procedure

Problem Set 9 Solutions

Supporting Materials for: Two Monetary Models with Alternating Markets

Stanford University CS359G: Graph Partitioning and Expanders Handout 4 Luca Trevisan January 13, 2011

Chapter 3 Describing Data Using Numerical Measures

Managing Capacity Through Reward Programs. on-line companion page. Byung-Do Kim Seoul National University College of Business Administration

Difference Equations

x yi In chapter 14, we want to perform inference (i.e. calculate confidence intervals and perform tests of significance) in this setting.

One-sided finite-difference approximations suitable for use with Richardson extrapolation

Problem Set 4: Sketch of Solutions

MA 323 Geometric Modelling Course Notes: Day 13 Bezier Curves & Bernstein Polynomials

Price Discrimination of Digital Content

AS-Level Maths: Statistics 1 for Edexcel

BIO Lab 2: TWO-LEVEL NORMAL MODELS with school children popularity data

LAB # 4 - Torque. d (1)

1 The Sidrauski model

Environmental taxation: Privatization with Different Public Firm s Objective Functions

Week3, Chapter 4. Position and Displacement. Motion in Two Dimensions. Instantaneous Velocity. Average Velocity

MATH Sensitivity of Eigenvalue Problems

ACTM State Calculus Competition Saturday April 30, 2011

The Number of Ways to Write n as a Sum of ` Regular Figurate Numbers

Mixed Taxation and Production Efficiency

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 10: Education Policies and Simpler Theory of Capital Taxation

Case A. P k = Ni ( 2L i k 1 ) + (# big cells) 10d 2 P k.

e i is a random error

Upstream competition. Stéphane Caprice Toulouse School of Economics

The Fundamental Theorem of Algebra. Objective To use the Fundamental Theorem of Algebra to solve polynomial equations with complex solutions

The oligopolistic markets

Gravitational Acceleration: A case of constant acceleration (approx. 2 hr.) (6/7/11)

(1) The saturation vapor pressure as a function of temperature, often given by the Antoine equation:

Resource Allocation and Decision Analysis (ECON 8010) Spring 2014 Foundations of Regression Analysis

Monopolistic competition with a mail order business

since [1-( 0+ 1x1i+ 2x2 i)] [ 0+ 1x1i+ assumed to be a reasonable approximation

Midterm Examination. Regression and Forecasting Models

Economics 8105 Macroeconomic Theory Recitation 1

Econ674 Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment

Notes on Kehoe Perri, Econometrica 2002

HMMT February 2016 February 20, 2016

ANSWERS. Problem 1. and the moment generating function (mgf) by. defined for any real t. Use this to show that E( U) var( U)

PHYS 705: Classical Mechanics. Calculus of Variations II

Ryan (2009)- regulating a concentrated industry (cement) Firms play Cournot in the stage. Make lumpy investment decisions

January Examinations 2015

Affine transformations and convexity

( ) 2 ( ) ( ) Problem Set 4 Suggested Solutions. Problem 1

Investment Secrecy and Competitive R&D

THE ROYAL STATISTICAL SOCIETY 2006 EXAMINATIONS SOLUTIONS HIGHER CERTIFICATE

Physics 114 Exam 2 Fall 2014 Solutions. Name:

Copyright (C) 2008 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of the Creative

Transcription:

UC Berkeley Economcs 11 Sprng 006 Prof. Joseph Farrell / GSI: Jenny Shanefelter Problem Set # - Suggested Solutons. 1.. In ths problem, we are extendng the usual Hotellng lne so that now t runs from [-a, 1+a]. Frms are located at 0 and 1. Unless there s a large prce dfference, consumers n the tals buy from the closest frm. We wll consder only the case n whch the consumers n the tals buy from the closer frm, so the frms compete only for the consumers n the (0,1) range. Note that for large enough cost dfference, however, there s a dscontnuty of demand the frm wth the lower cost (prce plus transportaton costs) wll take the whole market. In the fgure below, the pont d ndcates the locaton of the consumer that s under competton. Transportaton costs are gven by td. ---------- ------------------ -------------------- ---------- -a 0 d 1 1+a We can wrte out the total cost to the consumer n the mddle range: If a consumer n the mddle purchases from Frm 1, pays: p 0 +td If a consumer n the mddle purchases from Frm, pays: p 1 +t(1-d) Consumers n [-a,0] wll buy from Frm 0 unless there s a very large prce dfference,.e., that p 0 plus transportaton costs s greater than p 1 plus (hgher) transportaton costs. Consumers n [1,1+a] wll smlarly buy from Frm 1. To fnd the consumer who s ndfferent between the two frms: p 0 +td=p 1 +t(1-d) Solvng for d: d=(1/) + (p 1 p 0 /t) Now thnk about maxmzng profts of Frm 0. π= (p 0 -c)*a + (p 0 -c)*[(1/)+( p 1 p 0 )/t] π= a p 0 ca + (p 0 -c)/ + (p 0 p 1 /t) (p 0^/t) - (c p 1 /t) + (c p 0 /t) dπ/d p 0 = a + ½ + p 1 /t p 0 /t + c/t = 0 ta + t + p 1 p 0 + c =0 p 0 = ta + t + p 1 +c By symmetry, p 1 = ta + t + p 0 + c and, p 0 = p 1 =p

Substtutng and addng together, 4p = 4ta + t + p + c p = ta + t + c Note that the prce s now hgher by the amount ta the transportaton cost to cover the extra dstance of a on ether end. Prce s ncreasng n both a and t a greater number of captve consumers and hgher transportaton costs (or equvalently, more dfferentaton), mply a hgher prce. As n class, another way to solve once we have d=(1/) + (p 1 p 0 )/(t) s to use resdual demand elastcty and the Lerner equaton. Snce the slope of demand (for the frm at 0, say) s -1/(t), and n symmetrc equlbrum the quantty for each frm s now a + (1/), the elastcty of resdual demand s p/[t(a+1)]. So the Lerner equaton tells us that (p c)/p = t(a+1)/p, or p = c + (a+1)t. Note that the case a=0 confrms the calculatons we dd n class.. Snce consumers pay more under ths framework, and relatve to the case dscussed n class, the addtonal prce at exceeds the addtonal transportaton cost, whch s at most at, t follows that consumers have greater ncentve to credbly gnore dfferentaton. A central purchasng agency would thus be more attractve n ths set-up.. a. Ths s a surprsngly hgh elastcty, especally for a durable good lke cars. In 1955, 45% change n output only led to a 6% change n prce. (Arc) Elastcty = 45/6 = 7.5. b. Output ncreased a lot (45%), whle prces fell only a lttle bt (6%). So, f profts fell whle output ncreased and prces fell a small amount, ths mples that frms were prcng close to margnal cost. If not, you would expect a large change n output accompaned by a small change n prce to ncrease profts. Specfcally, f p s the normal prce and Q the normal quantty, we have: (0.94p c)*(1.45q) < (p c)q. Dvdng both sdes by Q and dong some arthmetc yelds 1.363p 1.45c < p c, or 0.45c > 0.363p, or c > 0.8p. c. If MC, AC < p and prce s close to margnal cost, then there are not sgnfcant economes of scale n the ndustry. Scale economes are ncreasng n the rato of AC/MC. d. The key dfference s that cars are a durable good. You would expect that a durable good would be more senstve to prce changes n nearby years. Ignorng 1955, the trend of automoble output gven n Car Wars s surprsngly steady. It looks a bt more lke what you would expect for a non-durable good, such as arlne travel. You would expect that f prces were low (and output was hgh) n one year that the output n the followng year would be abnormally low (snce everyone thnkng about buyng a car n 1956 was lured nto buyng a car n 1955 nstead). For arlne travel, you mght expect that a temporary decrease n prce would (mostly) expand rather than shft demand for that year. 3. p = A Q, N frms n the market frm-specfc unt costs, c c = (1/N)Σc

Q = Σq a. Frst, wthout loss of generalty, look at the proft functon for frm 1: π I = pq 1 c 1 q 1 π I = (A-Q) q 1 c 1 q 1 = A q 1 q 1 Σ q c 1 q 1 Maxmze wth respect to q 1. dπ I /d q 1 = A q 1 - Σ q + q 1 c 1 = 0 q 1 = A Q c 1 That s Frm 1 s quantty. Now add up q 1 + q + + q n Σ q = NA NQ - Σc Q = NA NQ - Σ c Q/N = A Q (1/N)Σc = A Q - c Q = N(A c ) Then plug ths back nto the prce equaton: p = A Q = A N(A c ) p = A + Nc Notce (not strctly part of answerng the queston, but worth notcng) that as N gets bg, ths says prce wll be near cost; for N=1 t gves well known monopoly prce formula. Notce also that near cost n that last sentence means near c. The extremely alert student wll already be askng how frms wth notceably above-average unt costs can survve see part (c) below! b. Average cost of producton = total cost/q Frm s total cost of producton = TC = c q Industry total cost of producton =TC = Σ TC Σ TC = Σc (A-Q-c ) = Σ(Ac Qc c ) TC = ΣAc ΣQc Σc ) Recall, var[c] = 1 N (c c ) Expandng, we fnd that

var[c] = 1 N c c c + Nc Rearrangng and substtutng c = N var[c] + Nc c = Nc : Substtute ths nto above total cost equaton: TC = A c Q c N var[c] + Nc Agan substtutng c = Nc and dvdng by Q, to express as average cost: TC ANc QNc N var[c]+ Nc ANc N var[c] + Nc = = Nc Q Q Q Recall that Q = N(A c ) (from part a.) and substtute: TC Q = (ANc N var[c] + Nc ) N(A c ) Nc Cancellng out, rearrangng and combnng: TC Q = Ac c var[c](n +1) ( N + 1)var[ c] = c A c A c By the way, we can also say the followng (not asked n the queston) about average producton cost n Cournot equlbrum wth nonlnear demand. Average cost of producton s ( q / Q ) c = sc where s s frm s market share. Rememberng that each frm s resdual demand elastcty n Cournot s the market demand elastcty dvded by ts share, we have ( p c )/ p= s / ε Multplyng through by p and by s and addng up for all frms gves us s ( p c ) = p s / ε. Snce the shares add up to 1, and rememberng the defnton of the Herfndahl ndex H, ths s

p sc = ph / ε so the average cost of producton s equal to p(1 H / ε ). Ths would gve an alternatve route to answer the queston here, though not necessarly a smpler one gven that both p and market demand elastcty are functons of all the c s. c. If frms shut down, t wll be the hgh cost frms that do so. So, the theoretcal average cost of producton s hgher than the actual average cost of producton, gven that frms can decde not to produce. Frm wll ext the market f frm AC (=c ) exceeds MR (=p). Ext f: p = A + Nc A c < c (c c )N + c > A ( N + 1) c > Nc + A, whch says that the frm s unt cost exceeds a weghted average of all (ncludng ts own) cost draws together wth the demand ntercept (note that the demand ntercept s the cost level above whch even a monopoly would ext). A mnute s thnkng about how averages work should tell you that ths means the same as sayng that the frm s unt cost exceeds a weghted average of other frms cost draws and the demand ntercept. d. Undfferentated Bertrand competton assgns all producton to the lowest cost frm, so the average cost of producton wll be lower than under Cournot (gven varyng c s). Bertrand prcng gves the second-lowest cost as prce. If the cost of the second-lowest frm s below the Cournot prce then the Bertrand prce wll be lower. It s temptng to say that f the second-lowest cost level s above the Cournot prce then the Bertrand prce would be hgher. But actually the only way that could happen (snce then only the lowest-cost frm would be producng n Cournot equlbrum) s f the monopoly prce, for the lowest-cost frm, s below the second-lowest cost: what we descrbed n class as a drastc cost dfference. And n that case, of course, the lowest-cost frm pcks ts monopoly prce and other frms stay out, both n Bertrand and n Cournot.