Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Similar documents
Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Problem 1 (30 points)

Solutions to Problem Set 4 Macro II (14.452)

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Macroeconomics Theory II

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

The Smets-Wouters Model

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

The New Keynesian Model

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Monetary Economics Notes

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

1 The Basic RBC Model

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

1 The social planner problem

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Expanding Variety Models

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy Design in the Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. October 2015

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Macroeconomics Theory II

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Y t = log (employment t )

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Nonlinearity. Exploring this idea and what to do about it requires solving a non linear model.

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Macroeconomics Theory II

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Macroeconomics Theory II

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Vector Autoregressions as a Guide to Constructing Dynamic General Equilibrium Models

Transcription:

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano Gerzensee, August 27

Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive the Equilibrium Conditions. Look at some data through the eyes of the model: Money demand. Cross-sectoral resource allocation cost of inflation. Some policy implications of the model will be examined. Many policy implications will be discovered in later computer exercises.

Outline The model: Individual agents: their objectives, what they take as given, what they choose. Households, final good firms, intermediate good firms, gov t. Economy-wide restrictions: Market clearing conditions. Relationship between aggregate output and aggregate factors of production, aggregate price level and individual prices. Model equilibrium conditions: Small number of equations and a small number of variables, which summarize everything about the model (optimization, market clearing, gov t policy, etc.). Properties of Equilibrium: Classical Dichotomy when prices flexible (monetary policy irrelevant for real variables). Monetary policy essential to determination of all variables when prices sticky.

Households Households problem. Concept of Consumption Smoothing.

Households There are many identical households. The problem of the typical ( representative ) household: max E Â t= b t log C t exp (t t ) N+j t + j + glog Mt+ P t!, s.t. P t C t + B t+ + M t+ apple W t N t + R t B t + M t +Profits net of government transfers and taxes t. Here, B t and M t are the beginning-of-period t stock of bonds and money held by the household. Law of motion of the shock to preferences: t = lt t + # t t the preference shock is in the model for pedagogic purposes only, it is not an interest shock from an empirical point of view.

Household First Order Conditions The household first order conditions: where = be t C t C t+ e t C t N j t = W t. P t m t = Rt R t m t M t+ P t. R t p t+ (5) gc t (7), All equations are derived by expressing the household problem in Lagrangian form, substituting out the multiplier on budget constraint and rearranging. The last first order condition is real money demand, increasing in C t and decreasing in R t.

Figure: Money Demand, Relative to Two Measures of Velocity 8 6 4 2 96 97 98 99 2 2 6 4 2 96 97 98 99 2 2 3.5 2.2 3 2.5 2.5 2 4 6 8 2.8.6 2 4 6 Notes: (i) velocity is GDP/M, (ii) With the MZM measure of money, the money demand equation does well qualitatively, but not qualitatively because the theory implies the scatters in the 2, and 2,2 graphs should be on the 45.

Consumption Smoothing Later, we ll see that consumption smoothing is an important principle for understanding the role of monetary policy in the New Keynesian model. Consumption smoothing is a characteristic of households consumption decision when they expect a change in income and the interest rate is not expected to change. Peoples current period consumption increases by the amount that can, according to their budget constraint, be maintained indefinitely. So, a change in current income that is temporary triggers a small change in current consumption. a change in current income that is permanent triggers a much bigger increase in current consumption. if current income does not change, but future income does, then current consumption increases.

Consumption Smoothing: Example Problem: max c,c 2 log (c ) + blog (c 2 ) subject to : c + B apple y + rb c 2 apple rb + y 2. where y and y 2 are (given) income and, after imposing equality (optimality) and substituting out for B, c + c 2 r = y + y 2 r + rb, = br, c c 2 second equation is fonc for B. Suppose br = (this happens in steady state, see later): c = y + y 2 r + r + r + B r

Consumption Smoothing: Example, cnt d Solution to the problem: c = y + y 2 r + r + r + B. r Consider three polar cases: temporary change in income: Dy > and Dy 2 = =) Dc = Dc 2 = Dy + r permanent change in income: Dy = Dy 2 > =) Dc = Dc 2 = Dy future change in income: Dy = and Dy 2 > =) Dc = Dc 2 = Dy 2 r + r Common feature of each example: When income rises, then - assuming r does not change - c increases by an amount that can be maintained into the second period: consumption smoothing.

Goods Production We turn now to the technology of production, and the problems of the firms. The technology requires allocating resources across sectors. We describe the e cient cross-sectoral allocation of resources. With price setting frictions, the market may not achieve e ciency.

Final Goods Production A homogeneous final good is produced using the following (Dixit-Stiglitz) production function: Y t = "ˆ # # Y # # # i,t di. Each intermediate good,y i,t, is produced by a monopolist using the following production function: Y i,t = e a t N i,t, a t exogenous shock to technology. Before discussing the firms that operate these production functions, we briefly investigate the socially e cient allocation of resources across i.

E cient Sectoral Allocation of Resources With Dixit-Stiglitz final good production function, there is a socially optimal allocation of resources to all the intermediate activities, Y i,t. It is optimal to run them all at the same rate, i.e., Y i,t = Y j,t for all i, j 2 [, ]. For given N t, allocative e ciency: N i,t = N j,t = N t, for all i, j 2 [, ]. In this case, final output is given by "ˆ # # Y t = (e a t N i,t ) # # # di = e a t N t. One way to understand allocated e ciency result is to suppose that labor is not allocated equally to all activities. Explore one simple deviation from N i,t = N j,t for all i, j 2 [, ].

Suppose Labor Not Allocated Equally Example: N it 2 N t i, 2 2 N t i,,. 2 Note that this is a particular distribution of labor across activities: Nit di 2 2 N t 2 2 N t N t

Labor Not Allocated Equally, cnt d Y t Yi,t di 2 Y i,t e at 2 di 2 N i,t Yi,t di 2 di Ni,t di e at 2 2 N t di 2 Nt 2 e at 2 N t 2 di 2 2 e at N t e at N t f 2 2 2 2 di di

..2.3.4.5.6.7.8.9 f 2 2 2 2 Efficient Resource Allocation Means Equal Labor Across All Sectors.98.96.94 f.92.9 6.88

Final Good Producers Competitive firms: maximize profits ˆ P t Y t P i,t Y i,t dj, subject to P t, P i,t given, all i 2 [, ], and the technology: Foncs: Y t = "ˆ # Pt Y i,t = Y t! P i,t # # Y # # # i,t dj. cross price restrictions ˆ! # ( #) P i,t di z } { P t =

Intermediate Good Producers The i th intermediate good is produced by a monopolist. Demand curve for i th monopolist: # Pt Y i,t = Y t. P i,t Production function: Y i,t = e a t N i,t, a t exogenousshocktotechnology. Calvo Price-Setting Friction: P i,t = P t with probability q P i,t with probability q.

Marginal Cost of Production An important input into the monopolist s problem is its marginal cost: s t = dcost doutput = dcost dworker doutput dworker = ( n) W t P t e a t = ( n) et tc t N j t e a t after substituting out for the real wage from the household intratemporal Euler equation. The tax rate, n, represents a subsidy to hiring labor, financed by a lump-sum government tax on households. Firm s job is to set prices whenever it has the opportunity to do so. It must always satisfy whatever demand materializes at its posted price.

Present Discounted Value of Intermediate Good Revenues i th intermediate good firm s objective: E i t  j= period t+j profits sent to household z 2 } 3{ revenues total cost z } { z } { b j u t+j 4P i,t+j Y i,t+j P t+j s t+j Y i,t+j 5 u t+j -Lagrangemultiplieronhouseholdbudgetconstraint Here, E i t denotes the firm s expectation over future variables, including the future probability that the firm gets to reset its price.

Firms that Can Change Price at t Let ep t denote the price set by the q firms who optimize at time t. Expected value of future profits sum of two parts: future states in which price is still ep t,soep t matters. future states in which the price is not ep t,soep t is irrelevant. That is, b j u t+j Pi,t+j Y i,t+j P t+j s t+j Y i,t+j E i t  j= Z t z } { = E t  (bq) j u t+j P t Y i,t+j P t+j s t+j Y i,t+j +Xt, j= where Z t is the present value of future profits over all future states in which the firm s price is P t. X t is the present value over all other states, so dx t /dep t =.

When q =, get standard result - price is fixed markup over marginal cost. Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Substitute out demand curve: E t  (bq) j u t+j P t Y i,t+j j= = E t  j= (bq) j u t+j Y t+j P # t+j P t+j s t+j Y i,t+j h i P t # P t+j s t+j P t #. Di erentiate with respect to P t : h i E t  (bq) j u t+j Y t+j P t+j # # ( #) P t + #Pt+j s t+j P t # =, j= or, E t  j= (bq) j u t+j Y t+j P #+ t+j apple P t P t+j # # s t+j =.

Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Substitute out the multiplier: E t  (bq) j j= = u t+j z } { u C t+j Y P t+j P #+ t+j t+j apple P t P t+j # # s t+j =. Using assumed log-form of utility, E t  (bq) j Y t+j j= apple # p t X t,j # s t+j =, # X t,j C t+j p t P t, p t P t, X t,j = p t+j p t+j p t+, j P t P t, j =. recursive property : X t,j = X t+,j p t+, j >,

Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Want p t in: E t  (bq) j Y apple t+j # # X C t,j p t X t,j j= t+j # s t+j = Solving for p t, we conclude that prices are set as follows: p t = E t  j= (bq)j Y t+j C t+j X t,j # # # s t+j E t  j= Y t+j C t+j (bq) j X t,j # = K t F t. Need convenient expressions for K t, F t.

Simplifying Numerator K t = E t  (bq) j Y t+j # # X C t,j j= t+j # s t+j = # Y t s t # C t + bqe t  j= Y t+j C t+j (bq) j B @ =X t,j, recursive property z } { p t+ X t+,j C A # # # s t+j = # Y t s t + Z t, # C t where Z t = bqe t  (bq) j j= Y t+j # # X C t+j p t+,j t+ # s t+j

Simplifying Numerator, cnt d K t = E t  (bq) j Y t+j # # X C t,j j= t+j # s t+j = # # s t + Z t Z t = bqe t  (bq) j j= Y t+j # # X C t+j p t+,j t+ # s t+j #  = bqe t (bq) j Y t+j+ X # p t+ C j= t+j+ = bq t+,j # # s t++j =E t by LIME z } { #  E t E t+ (bq) j Y t+j+ X # p t+ C j= t+j+ = bqe t p t+ exactly K t+! # t+,j # # s t++j z } { E t+  (bq) j Y t+j+ X # # C t+,j t+j+ # s t++j j=

Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Recall, p t = E t  j= (bq)j Y t+j C t+j X t,j # # # s t+j E t  j= (bq)j Y t+j C t+j X t,j # = K t F t We have shown that the numerator has the following simple representation: K t = E t  (bq) j Y t+j # # X C t,j j= t+j # s t+j = # ( n) e t ty t N j t # e a t + bqe t p t+ after using s t = ( n) e t tc t N j t /ea t. Similarly, F t = Y t # + bqe t F t+ (2) C t p t+ # K t+ (),

Interpretation of Price Formula Note (l t denotes marginal cost in currency units): P t+j = P t X t,j, s t+j = l t+j P t+j = l t+j P t X t,j, p t = P t P t. Multiply both sides of the expression for p t by P t : where P t = E t  j= (bq) j Y t+j # # C t+j X t,j # l t+j E t  l= (bq)l Y = # t+l C t+l (X t,l ) # # w t,j = (bq) j Y t+j C t+j X t,j # E t  l= (bq)l Y t+l C t+l (X t,l ) #,  E t w t,j l t+j j=  E t w t,j =. j= Evidently, price is set as a markup over a weighted average of future marginal cost, where the weights are shifted into the future depending on how big q is.

Interpretation of Price Formula, cnt d Price formula: where w t,j = P t = # #  E t w t,j l t+j j= (bq) j Y t+j C t+j X t,j # E t  l= (bq)l Y t+l C t+l (X t,l ) #,  E t w t,j =. j= Suppose prices are fully flexible, q = : w t, =, w t,j =, j >. That means, P t = # # l t, so that all prices are the same. Hence, Y i,t = Y j,t, so get allocative e ciency.

Moving On to Aggregate Restrictions Link between aggregate price level, P t, and P i,t, i 2 [, ]. Potentially complicated because there are MANY prices, P i,t, i 2 [, ]. Link between aggregate output, Y t, and N t. Potentially complicated because of earlier example with f (a). Analog of f (a) will be a function of degree to which P i,t 6= P j,t. Market clearing conditions. Money and bond market clearing. Labor and goods market clearing.

Aggregate Price Index Trick: rewrite the aggregate price index. let p 2 (, ) the set of logically possible prices for intermediate good producers. let g t (p) denote the measure (e.g., number ) of producers that have price, p, in t let g t,t (p), denote the measure of producers that had price, p, in t and could not re-optimize in t Then, P t = ˆ P ( #) i,t di! # ˆ = g t (p) p ( #) # dp. Note: P t = ˆ ( q) P t # + g t,t (p) p ( #) # dp.

Aggregate Price Index Calvo randomization assumption: measure of firms that had price, p, in t z } { g t,t (p) and could not change = q measure of firms that had price p in t z } { g t (p)

Aggregate Price Index Using g t,t (p) = qg t (p) : P t = ˆ ( q) P t # + g t,t (p) p ( #) # dp =P # t ˆ z } { P t = B @ ( q) P t # + q g t (p) p ( #) dp C A # P t = ( q) P t # + qp t # # Wow, simple!: Only two variables: P t and P t.

Aggregate Price Index Using g t,t (p) = qg t (p) : P t = = Divide by P t : ˆ ( q) P t # + ( q) P # t + qp # t = ( q) p # t g t,t (p) p ( #) dp # # + q p t #! # Rearrange: p t = apple q( p t ) # q #

Aggregate Output vs Aggregate Labor and Tech (Tack Yun, JME996) Define Y t : Y t ˆ Y i,t di = demand curve z} { = Y t ˆ = Y t P # t (P t ) # Pi,t P t ˆ e a t N i,t di = e a t N t! # di = Y t P # t ˆ where, using Calvo result : "ˆ # # h Pt P # i,t di = ( q) P t # + q Pt Then Y t = p t Y t, p t = P t P #. (P i,t ) # di i # #

Gross Output vs Agg Materials and Labor Relationship between aggregate inputs and outputs: Y t = p t Y t or, Y t = p t e a t N t. Note that p t is a function of the ratio of two averages (with di erent weights) of P i,t, i 2 (, ) So, when P i,t = P j,t for all i, j 2 (, ), then p t =. But, what is p t when P i,t 6= P j,t for some (measure of) i, j 2 (, )?

Tack Yun Distortion Consider the object, pt P # = t, P t where P t = ˆ! # P # i,t di, P t = ˆ P ( #) i,t di! # In following slide, use Jensen s inequality to show: p t apple.

Tack Yun Distortion Let f (x) = x 4, aconvexfunction.then, convexity: ax 4 + ( a) x4 2 > (ax + ( a) x 2 ) 4 for x 6= x 2,< a <. Applying this idea: convexity: ˆ () P ( #) i,t ˆ # # di ˆ P! ˆ P # i,t di P ( #) i,t di ( #) i,t! # # di! # # () P t z } { ˆ P # i,t di! # apple P t z } { ˆ P ( #) i,t di! #

Law of Motion of Tack Yun Distortion We have Dividing by P t : P t = pt P # t = P t " h ( q) P # t + q P t ( q) p # t + q p# t p t # i # # = @( q) " q ( p t ) # q # # # + q p# t p t A (4) using the restriction between p t and aggregate inflation developed earlier.

Evaluating the Distortions Tack Yun distortion: 2 pt = 4( q) q p t q (# )! # # + q p# t p t 3 5. Potentially, NK model provides an endogenous theory of TFP. Standard practice in NK literature is to set pt = for all t. First order expansion of pt around p t = pt = is: p t = p + p t + q (p t p ), with p =, so p t! and is invariant to shocks.

Empirical Assessment of Tack Yun Distortion First, do back of the envelope calculations in a steady state when inflation is constant and p is constant. Then, use 2 pt = 4( q) q p t q (# )! # # + q p# t p t 3 5. to compute times series estimate of p t.

Three Inflation Rates: Average inflation in the 97s, 8 percent APR. Suggestion: raise inflation target to 4 percent so that nominal rate of interest is higher, and less likely to hit lower bound. http://www.voxeu.org/article/case-4-inflation Two percent inflation is the average in the recent (pre-28) low inflation environment.

Figure: US Quarterly Gross Inflation.4.3.2..99.98 quarterly gross CPI inflation mean, 972Q-983Q4 =.2 95 96 97 98 99 2 2

Cost of Three Alternative Permanent Levels of Inflation p = q p# q q q p (# ) # # Table: Percent of GDP Lost Due to Inflation, ( p t ) # steady state inflation markup, #.2.5. 8% 2.4 3.92.85 4%.46.64.3 2%..3.2

Costs of Inflation, Dynamic Formula Figure a: Percent loss of GDP due to Inflation, assumed markup is.2 5 US CPI inflation (APR) With networks No networks percent 5 5 95 96 97 98 99 2 2 Figure b: Percent loss of GDP due to Inflation, assumed markup is.5 2 5 percent 5 5 95 96 97 98 99 2 2 Notes: (i) the figure reports the percent loss of output, ( pt ),duetocross-sectoral resource misallocation; (ii) losses are for the model in these notes as well as for the version of the model with networks, the annualized percent inflation networks; theinflationrateis expressed in annual, percent terms.

Government Government budget constraint: expenditures = receipts purchases of final goods subsidy payments gov t bonds (lending, if positive) z} { z } { z} { P t G t + nw t N t + = + money injection, if positive z } { M t µ t + where µ t denotes money growth rate. Then, T tax t B g t+ transfer payments to households z } { T trans t tax revenues z} { Tt tax +R t B g t T trans t = nw t N t + B g t+ + P tg t M t µ t R t B g t Government s choice of µ t determines evolution of money supply: M t+ = ( + µ t ) M t, µ t money growth rate.

Government The law of motion for money places restrictions on m t : for t =,,.... m t M t+ = M t+ M t P t P t M t P t P t + µt! m t = m t (8), p t

Market Clearing We now summarize the market clearing conditions of the model. Money, labor, bond and goods markets.

Money Market Clearing We temporarily use the bold notation, M t, to denote the per capita supply of money at the start of time t, for t =,, 2,.... The supply of money is determined by the actions, µ t, of the government: M t+ = M t + µ t M t, for t=,,2,... Households being identical means that in period t =, M = M, where M denotes beginning of time t = money stock of the representative household. Money market clearing in each period, t =,,..., requires M t+ = M t+, where M t+ denotes the representative household s time t choice of money. From here on, we do not distinguish between M t and M t.

Other Market Clearing Conditions Bond market clearing: Labor market clearing: Goods market clearing: B t+ + B g t+ =, t =,, 2,... supply of labor z} { N t = demand for labor z } { ˆ N i,t di demand for final goods supply of final goods z } { z} { C t + G t = Y t, and, using relation between Y t and N t : C t + G t = p t e a t N t (6)

Walras Law We use the market clearing conditions in constructing the equilibrium conditions used to solve the model. We will not use the household budget constraint because (by Walras Law) it is redundant given market clearing, the government budget constraint and the definition of profits. It is useful to verify Walras Law, as a way to make sure that the model has been correctly specified and understood. Next, we derive Walras Law for the model.

Household budget constraint: or, Q t = Walras Law P t C t + B t+ + M t+ = W t N t + R t B t + M t + Q t lump-sum profits & gov t taxes Q t profits from ownership in monopolists ˆ z } { ˆ P i,t Y i,t ( n) W t N i,t di + Tt trans T tax t zero profits in final goods and labor market clearing z} { = P t Y t ( n) W t N t + T trans t T tax t Need to make use of government budget constraint.

Walras Law Lump sum receipts of households, Q t : Q t = P t Y t ( n) W t N t + T trans t Then, T tax t government budget z} { = P t Y t ( n) W t N t nw t N t B g t+ P t G t + M t µ t + R t B g t P t C t + B t+ + M t+ = W t N t + R t = W t N t + R t B t + M t B t + M t + Q t +P t Y t W t N t B g t+ P t G t + M t µ t + R t B g t Rearranging: P t (C t + G t ) + B t+ + B g t+ + M t+ = R t B t + B g t + M t ( + µ t ) + P t Y t, which is satisfied with bond, money and goods market clearing.

Next Collect the equilibrium conditions associated with private sector behavior. Comparison of NK model with RBC model (i.e., q = ) Classical Dichotomy: In flexible price version of model real variables determined independent of monetary policy. Fiscal policy still matters, because equilibrium depends on how government deals with the monopoly power, i.e., selects value for subsidy, n. In NK model, markets don t necessarily work well and good monetary policy essential. To close model with q > must take a stand on monetary policy.

Equilibrium Conditions 8equationsin8unknowns:m t, C t, p t, F t, K t, N t, R t, p t, and 3 policy variables: n, µ t, G t. K t = # ( n) e t ty t N j t + bqe t p t+ # # A K t+ () t F t = Y t + bqe t p C t+ # F t+ (2), t 2 pt = 4( q) = be t C t m t = C t+ q p t q R t (# ) K t F t =! # # + q p# t " q p t q 3 p t 5 (# ) (4) (5), C t + G t = pt e a t N t (6) p t+ + µt m t (8) gc t Rt (7), m t = p t # # (3)

Classical Dichotomy Under Flexible Prices Classical Dichotomy: when prices flexible, q =, then real variables determined regardless of the rule for µ t (i.e., monetary policy). Equations (2),(3) imply: F t = K t = Y t C t, which, combined with () implies # ( n) # Marginal Cost of work z } { e t t C t N j t = Expression (6) with p t = (since q = ) is C t + G t = e a t N t. marginal benefit of work z} { e a t Thus, we have two equations in two unknowns, N t and C t.

Classical Dichotomy: No Uncertainty Real interest rate, R t R t/ p t+, is determined: R t = C t b C t+. So, with q =, the following are determined: R t, C t, N t, t =,, 2,... What about the nominal variables? Suppose the monetary authority wants a given sequence of inflation rates, p t, t =,,.... Then, R t = p t+ Rt, t =,, 2,... What money growth sequence is required? From (7), obtain m t, t =,, 2,.... Also, m M and P. From (8) + µ t = m t m t p t, t =,, 2,... is given by initial

Classical Dichotomy versus New Keynesian Model When q =, then the Classical Dichotomy occurs. In this case, monetary policy (i.e., the setting of µ t, t =,, 2,... )cannota ect the real interest rate, consumption and employment. Monetary policy simply a ects the split in the real interest rate between nominal and real rates: R t = R t p t+. For a careful treatment when there is uncertainty, see. When q > (NK model) then real variables are not determined independent of monetary policy. In this case, monetary policy matters.

Monetary Policy in New Keynesian Model Suppose q >, so that we re in the NK model and monetary policy matters. The standard assumption is that the monetary authority sets µ t to achieve an interest rate target, and that that target is a function of inflation: R t /R = (R t /R) a exp [( a) f p ( p t p)+f x x t ] (7), where x t denotes the log deviation of actual output from target (more on this later). This is a Taylor rule, and it satisfies the Taylor Principle when f p >. Smoothing parameter: a. Bigger is a the more persistent are policy-induced changes in the interest rate.

Equilibrium Conditions of NK Model with Taylor Rule K t = # ( n) e t ty t N j t + bqe t p t+ # # A K t+ () t F t = Y t + bqe t p C t+ # F t+ (2), t 2 pt = 4( q) q p t q (# ) K t F t =! # # + q p# t " q p t q 3 p t 5 (# ) (4) # # R t = be t (5), C t + G t = pt e a t N t (6) C t C t+ p t+ R t /R = (R t /R) a exp [( a) f p ( p t p)+f x x t ] (7). (3) Conditions (7) and (8) have been replaced by (7).

Equilibrium Conditions of NK Model The model represents 7 equations in 7 unknowns: C, p t, F t, K t, N t, R t, p t After this system has been solved for the 7 variables, equations (7) and (8) can be used to solve for µ t and m t. This is rarely done, because researchers are uncertain of the exact form of money demand and because m t and µ t are in practice not of direct interest.

When q =, then # ( n) # Natural Equilibrium Marginal Cost of work z } { e t t C t N j t = marginal benefit of work z} { e a t so that we have a form of e # ( n) / (# ) =. ciency when n is chosen to that In addition, recall that we have allocative e flexible price equilibrium. ciency in the So, the flexible price equilibrium with the e cient setting of n represents a natural benchmark for the New Keynesian model, the version of the model in which q >. We call this the Natural Equilibrium. To simplify the analysis, from here on we set G t =.

Natural Equilibrium With G t =, equilibrium conditions for C t and N t : Marginal Cost of work z } { e t t C t N j t = aggregate production relation: C t = e a t N t. marginal benefit of work z} { e a t Substituting, e t e a t N +j t = e a tt t! N t = exp + j t C t = exp a t + j R t = C t be t C t+ = = C be t t C t+ be t exp Da t+ + Dt t+ +j

Natural Equilibrium, cnt d Natural rate of interest: R t = C t be t C t+ = be t exp Da t+ + Dt t+ +j Two models for a t : DS : Da t+ = rda t + # a t+ TS : a t+ = ra t + # a t+ Model for t : t t+ = lt t + # t t+

Natural Equilibrium, cnt d Suppose the # t s are Normal. Then, E t exp Da t+ + Dt t+ = exp + j where Then, with r t log R t V = s 2 a + s 2 t ( + j) 2 r t = log b + E t Da t+ E t Dt t+ + j Dt E t Da t+ + E t+ t + j + 2 V 2 V. Useful: consider how natural rate responds to # a t shocks under DS and TS models for a t and how it responds to # t t shocks. To understand how rt responds, consider implications of consumption smoothing in absence of change in rt. Hint: in natural equilibrium, rt steers the economy so that natural equilibrium paths for C t and N t are realized.

Conclusion Described NK model and derived equilibrium conditions. The usual version of model represents monetary policy by a Taylor rule. When q =, so that prices are flexible, then monetary policy is (essentially) neutral. Changes in money growth move prices and wages in such a way that real wages do not change and employment and output don t change. When prices are sticky, then a policy-induced reduction in the interest rate encourages more nominal spending. The increased spending raises W t more than P t because of the sticky prices, thereby inducing the increased labor supply that firms need to meet the extra demand. Firms are willing to produce more goods because: The model assumes they must meet all demand at posted prices. Firms make positive profits, so as long as the expansion is not too big they still make positive profits, even if not optimal.