Analysis of the ruin probability using Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian theorems

Similar documents
University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

Finite-time Ruin Probability of Renewal Model with Risky Investment and Subexponential Claims

A Note On The Erlang(λ, n) Risk Process

Ruin probabilities in multivariate risk models with periodic common shock

Ruin probabilities of the Parisian type for small claims

NUMBER THEORY, BALLS IN BOXES, AND THE ASYMPTOTIC UNIQUENESS OF MAXIMAL DISCRETE ORDER STATISTICS

Extremes and ruin of Gaussian processes

Reinsurance and ruin problem: asymptotics in the case of heavy-tailed claims

Practical approaches to the estimation of the ruin probability in a risk model with additional funds

Ruin Probability for Non-standard Poisson Risk Model with Stochastic Returns

A polynomial expansion to approximate ruin probabilities

Lecture Notes on Risk Theory

Reduced-load equivalence for queues with Gaussian input

Asymptotics of random sums of heavy-tailed negatively dependent random variables with applications

Asymptotics of the Finite-time Ruin Probability for the Sparre Andersen Risk. Model Perturbed by an Inflated Stationary Chi-process

Rare event simulation for the ruin problem with investments via importance sampling and duality

AN ABSTRACT OF THE DISSERTATION OF. Sooie-Hoe Loke for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Mathematics presented on

Minimization of ruin probabilities by investment under transaction costs

Asymptotic Ruin Probabilities for a Bivariate Lévy-driven Risk Model with Heavy-tailed Claims and Risky Investments

TAUBERIAN THEOREM FOR HARMONIC MEAN OF STIELTJES TRANSFORMS AND ITS APPLICATIONS TO LINEAR DIFFUSIONS

Characterization through Hazard Rate of heavy tailed distributions and some Convolution Closure Properties

Stability of the Defect Renewal Volterra Integral Equations

Upper Bounds for the Ruin Probability in a Risk Model With Interest WhosePremiumsDependonthe Backward Recurrence Time Process

A Ruin Model with Compound Poisson Income and Dependence Between Claim Sizes and Claim Intervals

Characterizations on Heavy-tailed Distributions by Means of Hazard Rate

Prime numbers and Gaussian random walks

Ruin Probabilities of a Discrete-time Multi-risk Model

Distribution of the first ladder height of a stationary risk process perturbed by α-stable Lévy motion

Ruin Theory. A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science at George Mason University

Asymptotic Tail Probabilities of Sums of Dependent Subexponential Random Variables

Asymptotic Analysis of Exceedance Probability with Stationary Stable Steps Generated by Dissipative Flows

A Dynamic Contagion Process with Applications to Finance & Insurance

ON THE MOMENTS OF ITERATED TAIL

Randomly Weighted Sums of Conditionnally Dependent Random Variables

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

Introduction to Rare Event Simulation

Precise Large Deviations for Sums of Negatively Dependent Random Variables with Common Long-Tailed Distributions

Ruin, Operational Risk and How Fast Stochastic Processes Mix

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 5 Ruin Theory

f X (x) = λe λx, , x 0, k 0, λ > 0 Γ (k) f X (u)f X (z u)du

Multivariate Risk Processes with Interacting Intensities

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

Moment Properties of Distributions Used in Stochastic Financial Models

Comparing downside risk measures for heavy tailed distributions

Ruin probability and optimal dividend policy for models with investment

The Subexponential Product Convolution of Two Weibull-type Distributions

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 19 Aug 2017

Optimal stopping of a risk process when claims are covered immediately

The finite-time Gerber-Shiu penalty function for two classes of risk processes

Ruin probabilities in a finite-horizon risk model with investment and reinsurance

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas

NAN WANG and KOSTAS POLITIS

Introduction to Random Diffusions

NOTES AND PROBLEMS IMPULSE RESPONSES OF FRACTIONALLY INTEGRATED PROCESSES WITH LONG MEMORY

Regular Variation and Extreme Events for Stochastic Processes

On Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities in a Risk Model Under Quota Share Reinsurance

OPTIMAL DIVIDEND AND REINSURANCE UNDER THRESHOLD STRATEGY

Stochastic Areas and Applications in Risk Theory

ON ADDITIVE TIME-CHANGES OF FELLER PROCESSES. 1. Introduction

Chapter 2. Poisson Processes. Prof. Shun-Ren Yang Department of Computer Science, National Tsing Hua University, Taiwan

Tyler Hofmeister. University of Calgary Mathematical and Computational Finance Laboratory

Conditional Tail Expectations for Multivariate Phase Type Distributions

SOME INDICES FOR HEAVY-TAILED DISTRIBUTIONS

Modelling the risk process

Worst-Case-Optimal Dynamic Reinsurance for Large Claims

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 30 Sep 2009

Necessary and sucient condition for the boundedness of the Gerber-Shiu function in dependent Sparre Andersen model

Hawkes Processes and their Applications in Finance and Insurance

CIMPA SCHOOL, 2007 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.rm] 27 Jun 2017

The Ruin Probability of a Discrete Time Risk Model under Constant Interest Rate with Heavy Tails

fi K Z 0 23A:4(2002), ρ [ fif;μ=*%r9tμ?ffi!5 hed* c j* mgi* lkf** J W.O(^ jaz:ud=`ψ`j ψ(x), p: x *fl:lffi' =Λ " k E» N /,Xß=χο6Πh)C7 x!1~πψ(x)

Modèles de dépendance entre temps inter-sinistres et montants de sinistre en théorie de la ruine

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

1 Basic concepts from probability theory

Exponential functionals of Lévy processes

The optimality of a dividend barrier strategy for Lévy insurance risk processes, with a focus on the univariate Erlang mixture

Probabilistic analysis of the asymmetric digital search trees

Simulation methods in ruin models with non-linear dividend barriers

2 markets. Money is gained or lost in high volatile markets (in this brief discussion, we do not distinguish between implied or historical volatility)

Analysis methods of heavy-tailed data

1 Functions and Graphs

Lévy-VaR and the Protection of Banks and Insurance Companies. A joint work by. Olivier Le Courtois, Professor of Finance and Insurance.

Heavy Tailed Time Series with Extremal Independence

On Kesten s counterexample to the Cramér-Wold device for regular variation

The Exponential Estimate of the Ultimate Ruin Probability for the Non-Homogeneous Renewal Risk Model

The equivalence of two tax processes

Asymptotic Irrelevance of Initial Conditions for Skorohod Reflection Mapping on the Nonnegative Orthant

(2m)-TH MEAN BEHAVIOR OF SOLUTIONS OF STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS UNDER PARAMETRIC PERTURBATIONS

Non-Life Insurance: Mathematics and Statistics

Excursions of Risk Processes with Inverse Gaussian Processes and their Applications in Insurance

A RUIN FUNCTION APPROXIMATION JOHN A. BEEKMAN*

On the probability of reaching a barrier in an Erlang(2) risk process

F n = F n 1 + F n 2. F(z) = n= z z 2. (A.3)

Measuring the effects of reinsurance by the adjustment coefficient in the Sparre Anderson model

On a discrete time risk model with delayed claims and a constant dividend barrier

A LOGARITHMIC EFFICIENT ESTIMATOR OF THE PROBABILITY OF RUIN WITH RECUPERATION FOR SPECTRALLY NEGATIVE LEVY RISK PROCESSES.

Operational Risk and Pareto Lévy Copulas

Some Approximations on the Probability of Ruin and the Inverse Ruin Function

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks

Transcription:

Analysis of the ruin probability using Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian theorems Corina Constantinescu and Enrique Thomann Abstract The classical result of Cramer-Lundberg states that if the rate of premium, c, exceeds the average of the claims paid per unit time, λµ, then the probability of ruin of an insurance company decays exponentially fast as the initial capital u. In this note, the asymptotic behavior of the probability of ruin is derived by means of infinitesimal generators and Laplace transforms. Using these same tools, it is shown that the probability of ruin has an algebraic decay rate if the insurance company invests its capital in a risky asset with a price which follows a geometric Brownian motion. The latter result is shown to be valid not only for exponentially distributed claim amounts, as in Frolova et al. (22), but, more generally, for any claim amount distribution that has a moment generating function defined in a neighborhood of the origin. 1 Introduction The collective risk model, introduced by Cramer and Lundberg in 193, remains the subject of analysis by actuaries and mathematicians. In particular, different methods of analysis continue to be used in obtaining bounds or asymptotics of the ruin probability, under specific conditions on the claim size distribution (Cramer, 193; Gerber, 1973; Ross, 1996). For example, in the classical risk model under the Cramer-Lundberg condition, the ruin probability presents an exponential decay as the initial capital u (Cramer, 193). If the Cramer-Lundberg condition is weakened, the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probability changes dramatically. For instance, in the Oregon State University, Department of Mathematics, e-mail:corina@math.orst.edu Oregon State University, Department of Mathematics, e-mail:thomann@math.orst.edu 1

case of sub-exponentially distributed claim sizes, the ruin is asymptotically determined by a large claim (Embrechts et al., 1997). Some recent studies impose a perturbation on the classical model. These perturbations model uncertainties in the rate at which premiums are being collected, or the rate of returns on the investment strategies by the insurance company. The perturbations may influence the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probability. For example, if the perturbation is a Brownian motion, the ruin probability still presents an exponential decay (Schmidli, 1995). On the other hand, if the risk model is altered by a geometric Brownian motion, then the asymptotic decay rate of the ruin probability is at best algebraic. This latter perturbation models the risk when the company invests its capital into a risky asset with returns following an exponential of a Brownian motion (Frolova et al., 22). In this paper, the asymptotics of the ruin probability are derived by analyzing the properties of the Laplace transform of the ruin probability. Using this technique, the exponential decay of the classical Cramer Lundberg model has a simple derivation. The same method is used in extending the cited results of Frolova et al. (22) to more general claim size distributions than those considered in the original work. Specifically, while the result in Frolova et al. (22) holds for claim sizes with an exponential distribution, the result presented in this paper applies to claim sizes that have a moment generating function defined in a neighborhood of the origin. Furthermore, since this approach relies on the Karamata Tauberian theorems, it appears to be easier to use under different assumptions on claim inter-arrival times and investment strategies. We proceed in the following manner. In the next section, we consider the classical ruin problem and obtain the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probability. The integro-differential equation satisfied by the ruin probability is solved using elementary properties of the Laplace transform. In Section 3 we investigate the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probability under uncertain investments. The analysis starts once again using the infinitesimal generator of the risk process and the Laplace transform. However, given the more intricate form of the equation, we rely on the Karamata Tauberian theorem to obtain the asymptotic behavior. Some conclusions and research objectives are presented in Section 4. Finally, we include an Appendix with a summary of some technical tools used in this paper. 2

2 The classical Cramer Lundberg model The classical risk model N(t) X t = u + ct ξ k, is a compound Poisson process. X t describes the evolution of the capital of an insurance company, that charges premiums at a constant rate c. The number of claims up to time t is a Poisson process N(t), with a Poisson rate λ. The size or amount of the k-th claim is a random variable ξ k. The claim sizes ξ 1, ξ 2,.. are independent, identically distributed random variables, having the distribution function F, with positive mean µ and finite variance. The claims up to time t occur at random times t 1, t 2,..t N(t). Y 1 = t 1, Y k = t k t k 1, for k = 2, 3.., are independent exponentially distributed random variables with finite mean λ. (ξ k ) k and (Y k ) k are independent. The ruin probability in finite time is defined as Ψ(u, T ) = P(X t <, for some t T ), where < T < and u. The ruin probability k=1 Ψ(u) = Ψ(u, ), refers to the ruin probability with infinite horizon. The purpose of this paper is to study the asymptotic decay of the ruin probability as the initial capital u tends to infinity. The notation for the Laplace transform of the ruin probability is ˆΨ(s) = LΨ(u)(s) and for the Laplace transform of the density of the claim sizes is F(s) = L(f(ξ))(s). M ξ ( s) denotes the moment generating function of the distribution of the claim amounts ξ, and obviously, F(s) = M ξ ( s). Theorem 1. Consider the Cramer-Lundberg model N(t) X t = u + ct ξ k, under the net profit condition λµ < c. Assume that R > is the smallest positive number such that R is a solution of the Lundberg equation k=1 cs λ(1 F(s)) =. Denote ˆΨ(s)(s + R) Ψ() := Ĥ(s). If Ĥ is the Laplace transform of a function H, then the limit lim u Ψ(u)e Ru exists and moreover, lim u Ψ(u)eRu = λµ c + λf ( R) = λµ c c λm ξ (R). 3

Proof. Using classical renewal theory or computing the infinitesimal generator of the risk model AΨ(u) =, as in Paulsen and Gjessing (1997) (see Appendix), one can show that the ruin probability satisfies cψ (u) + λ u Ψ(u y)df (y) λψ(u)(1 F (u)) =, (1) with Ψ() = λµ c. The Laplace transform of this equation, has the solution s ˆΨ(s) Ψ() + λ c ˆΨ(s)F(s) λ c ˆΨ(s) + λ c (1 s F(s) s ) = ˆΨ(s) = cψ() λ (1 F(s)) s. cs λ(1 F(s)) Recall that the denominator in this expression, L(s) = cs λ(1 F(s)) gives the Lundberg equation L(s) =. Since the numerator doesn t vanish at R, R is a pole of ˆΨ(s). By hypothesis, ˆΨ(s) = 1 s + RĤ(s) + 1 s + R Ψ(). As the Laplace transform of a product of two functions is the Laplace transform of the convolution of the given functions, by the uniqueness of the Laplace transform it follows that Ψ(u) = u Since Ĥ( R) is defined, passing to limit one has lim u eru Ψ(u) = Since L( R) =, e (u t)r H(t)dt + e Ru Ψ(). (2) e ( R)t H(t)dt + Ψ() = Ĥ( R) + Ψ(). Ĥ(s) + Ψ() = ˆΨ(s)(s + R) = cψ() λ (1 F(s)) s L(S) L( R) s+r and (1 F( R)) = c ( R). Therefore, as s R, λ Ĥ( R) + Ψ() = cψ() λ c ( R) R λ L ( R) = cψ() λ c ( R) R λ. c + λf ( R) 4

The initial condition, Ψ() = λµ, together with F ( R) = M c ξ (R), imply λµ lim u e Ru Ψ(u) = Ĥ( R) + Ψ() = in agreement with Rolski et al. (1999). c c + λf ( R) = λµ c (3) c λm ξ (R), Remark 1. If the claim sizes are exponentially distributed, the conditions on the Laplace transform of the ruin probability are trivially satisfied, since Ĥ(s) =. In general, the existence of the function H depends upon the tail of the distribution of the claim sizes. 3 The Cramer Lundberg model with investments This section identifies the effects of a risky investment on the asymptotic behavior of the probability of ruin. If the insurance company invests the capital in an asset with a price that follows a geometric Brownian motion, with drift a and volatility σ, then the ruin probability has an algebraic decay rate or equals one, depending only on the parameters a and σ of the asset (Frolova et al., 22). In the cited paper the result is established only for exponentially distributed claim sizes, because the method of proof relies on special properties of the exponential functions. A generalization of the result for distributions of the claim sizes having moment generating functions defined on a neighborhood of the origin is possible. When the company capital is invested in a risky asset, the risk process is given by t t N(t) X t = u + a X s ds + σ X s dw s + ct ξ k, (4) where ξ k represents the size of the k-th claim, with the probability distribution function F on (, ), c is the fixed rate of premium and u is the initial capital. The capital X t is continuously invested in a risky asset, with relative price increments dx t = adt+σdw t, where a and σ are the drift and volatility of the returns of the asset. Theorem 2. Consider the model given by (4) and assume that σ >. Assume also that the distribution of the claims sizes F has a moment generating function defined on a neighborhood of the origin. Then: If the ruin probability decays at infinity, then 2a/σ 2 > 1. 5 k=

If 1 < 2a/σ 2 < 2, then for some K >, lim 1 u Ψ(u)u2a/σ2 = K. Proof. Let ρ = 2a/σ 2. Consider the function { if u < U(u) = Ψ(x)dx if u. u Let Ũ(s) be the Laplace Stieltjes transform of U(u). Note that the Laplace transform of the ruin probability Ψ(u), ˆΨ(s), equals the Laplace Stieltjes transform of the function U(u), Ũ(s), ˆΨ(s) = L(Ψ(u))(s) = e su Ψ(u)du = e su du(u) = Ũ(s). The key point of the proof is to show that Ũ(s) behaves asymptotically at zero as ks ρ 2. Then, using the Karamata Tauberian Theorem and the Monotone Density Theorem (Bingham et al., 1987), the result follows. The analysis of the asymptotic behavior of ˆΨ(s) follows the same path as in the classical case study. Recall that Theorem 2.1. (Paulsen and Gjessing, 1997) states that the ruin probability is the solution of the equation AΨ(u) = together with the boundary conditions (see Appendix). The infinitesimal generator of the ruin probability Ψ(u) is given by AΨ(u) = σ2 2 u2 Ψ (u) + (au + c)ψ (u) + λ (Ψ(u y) Ψ(u)) df (y). Since Ψ(u y) = 1 for any u < y, and df (y) = 1, the equation is equivalent to σ 2 2 u2 Ψ (u) + (au + c)ψ (u) + λ u The Laplace transform of this equation is σ 2 2 Ψ(u y) df (y) λψ(u) =. d 2 (s 2 ˆΨ(s)) d(s ˆΨ(s)) a +cs ds 2 ds ˆΨ(s) λ ˆΨ(s)+λ ˆΨ(s)F(s)+ λ (1 F(s)) = cψ(), s and after differentiation becomes σ 2 s 2 2 ˆΨ (s)+(2sσ 2 as) ˆΨ (s)+(cs λ+λf(s)+σ 2 a) ˆΨ(s) = cψ() λ s (1 F(s)). 6

Thus, the equation to be analyzed has the form s 2 y + p(s)sy + q(s)y = g(s), (5) with p, q and g holomorphic functions of the form p(s) = p = 2(2σ2 a) σ 2 q(s) = q + q 1 (s) = 2(σ2 a) σ 2 g(s) = g + g 1 (s) = + q 1 (s) 2(cΨ() λµ) + g 1 (s). Due to the fact that s = is a regular singular point of the homogeneous equation s 2 y + p(s)sy + q(s)y =, the solution has the form ŷ(s) = s ρ k= c k s k = σ 2 c k s ρ+k, (6) where the coefficients satisfy the recurrence system of equations c = 1 and with k= c k f(ρ + k) + c k 1 f 1 (ρ + k 1) + + c f k (ρ) =, f(ρ) = ρ(ρ 1) + p ρ + q, as in Fedoryuk (1991). The first of these equations c f(ρ) = is equivalent to ρ 2 + 3σ2 2a ρ + 2σ2 2a =. σ 2 σ 2 If 2σ 2 a, the solutions of the homogeneous equation are of the form ŷ 1 (s) = s 1 γ 1 (s) ŷ 2 (s) = s 2+ρ γ 2 (s), where γ 1 () = γ 2 () = 1. Using variation of parameters, one can show that the solutions of the non-homogeneous equation (5) have the form ŷ = c 1 s 1 γ 1 (s) + c 2 s 2+ρ γ 2 (s) + c 3 γ 3 (s), under the condition ρ < 2, with c 1, c 2, c 3 real constants, γ 1, γ 2 and γ 3 holomorphic functions and γ 1 () = γ 2 () = γ 3 () = 1. The asymptotic behavior 7

at zero of the solution of equation (5) describes the asymptotic behavior at zero of ˆΨ(s), consequently of Ũ(s). The leading term of this linear combination dictates the asymptotic behavior of the solution as s. Two cases can be distinguished. If the leading term of the linear combination is s 1 then by Karamata Tauberian and Monotone Density theorem Ψ(u) αγ(1/u) Γ(2) as u. Hence lim Ψ(u) = u α Γ(2), where α is a real constant. In other words, the ruin probability has a constant asymptotic behavior, as u. Obviously, in this case, the function does not satisfy the boundary conditions from Paulsen and Gjessing (1997) theorem, so it is not a solution that can be related to the ruin probability. In the second case, if s 2+ρ is the leading term, then Ũ(s) αs 2+ρ γ(s) as s. The Karamata-Tauberian Theorem implies U(u) αu2 ρ γ(1/u), as u. Γ(3 ρ) Ψ(u) is monotone, α R and ρ R, hence the Monotone Density Theorem implies Ψ(u) α(2 ρ)u2 ρ 1 γ(1/u), as u. Γ(3 ρ) Since Ψ(u) must decay, ρ needs to satisfy the condition 2 ρ 1 <. The conclusion is that or where K = α(2 ρ) Γ(3 ρ). Ψ(u) = Ku 1 ρ γ(1/u), as u, for 1 < ρ < 2 lim u Ψ(u)uρ 1 = K, as u, for 1 < ρ < 2 Remark 2. It is conjectured that if ρ 1, then Ψ(u) = 1 for all u. 8

4 Conclusion This paper illustrates how Laplace transforms and Karamata Tauberian arguments can be used effectively in the analysis of the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probabilities. For example, the classical Cramer Lundberg result can be obtained using elementary properties of the Laplace transform. When uncertain returns on investments are modeled by a geometric Brownian Motion, the asymptotic behavior of the ruin probability can be derived using this methodology. Given the analytic nature of these tools, the results obtained in this paper can be generalized to include different claim inter-arrival times or investment strategies. The results presented in this paper are part of the PhD thesis of Corina Constantinescu at Oregon State University. 5 Appendix This is a short summary of some of the technical results used in the paper. Theorem 3 (Paulsen and Gjessing (1997)). If Ψ(u) is a bounded and twice continuous differentiable function defined for u that solves AΨ(u) = on u > together with the boundary conditions: then the solution is Ψ(u) = 1, for u < lim Ψ(u) = u Ψ(u) = P(T u < ). Definition 1. Let l be a positive measurable function, defined in some neighborhood [M, ) of infinity, and satisfying l(λx)/l(x) 1, as x, λ >, then l is said to be slowly varying in Karamata s sense (Bingham et al., 1987). Theorem 4 (Karamata Tauberian Theorem). Let U be a non-decreasing right-continuous function on R with U(x) = for all x <. If l varies slowly and c, ρ the following are equivalent: U(x) cx ρ l(x)/γ(1 + ρ), (x ), where Ũ(s) cs ρ l(1/s), (s + ), Ũ denotes the Laplace-Stieltjes transform (Bingham et al., 1987). 9

Definition 2. A function f is ultimately monotone if there exists y such that for any x > y, f(x) is monotone. Theorem 5 (Monotone Density Theorem). Let U(x) = x u(y)dy. If U(x) cx ρ l(x), x, where c R, l R, and if u is ultimately monotone, then (Bingham et al., 1987). References u(x) cρx ρ 1 l(x), x, N.H. Bingham, C.M. Goldie, and J.L. Teugels. Regular variation. Encyclopedia of Mathematics and its Applications, Cambridge University Press, 1987. H. Cramer. On the mathematical theory of risk. Skandia Jubilee Volume, Stockholm, 193. P. Embrechts, C. Kluppelberg, and T. Mikosch. Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance. Springer, Berlin, 1997. M. Fedoryuk. Asymptotic Analysis. Springer-Verlag, 1991. A. Frolova, Y. Kabanov, and S. Pergamenshchikov. In the insurance business risky investments are dangerous. Finance and stochastics, 6:227 235, 22. H.. Gerber. Martingales in risk theory. Mitteilungen der Vereinigung schweizerischer Versicherungsmathematiker, 73:25 216, 1973. J. Paulsen and H. Gjessing. Ruin theory with stochastic return on investments. Advanced Applied Probability, 29:965 985, 1997. T. Rolski, H. Schmidli, V. Schmidt, and J. Teugels. Stochastic Processes for Insurance and Finance. Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics, New York, 1999. S. Ross. Stochastic Processes. Wiley, New York, 1996. H. Schmidli. Cramer-lundberg approximations for ruin probabilities of risk processes perturbed by diffusion. Insurance: Mathematics and Econos, 16: 135 149, 1995. 1