Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Similar documents
Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

The New Keynesian Model

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Smets-Wouters Model

Problem 1 (30 points)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Advanced Macroeconomics

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Y t = log (employment t )

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Economic transition following an emission tax in a RBC model with endogenous growth. EC-IILS JOINT DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES No. 17

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Expanding Variety Models

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Relative Deep Habits

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Advanced Macroeconomics

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

Nonlinearity. Exploring this idea and what to do about it requires solving a non linear model.

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Macroeconomics Theory II

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

1 The Basic RBC Model

Transcription:

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital Lawrence J. Christiano January 5, 2018

Objective Review the foundations of the basic New Keynesian model without capital. Clarify the role of money supply/demand. Derive the Equilibrium Conditions. Small number of equations and a small number of variables, which summarize everything about the model (optimization, market clearing, gov t policy, etc.). Look at some data through the eyes of the model: Money demand. Cross-sectoral resource allocation cost of inflation. Some policy implications of the model will be examined. Many policy implications will be discovered in later computer exercises.

Outline The model: Individual agents: their objectives, what they take as given, what they choose. Households, final good firms, intermediate good firms, gov t. Economy-wide restrictions: Market clearing conditions. Relationship between aggregate output and aggregate factors of production, aggregate price level and individual prices. Properties of Equilibrium: Classical Dichotomy - when prices flexible monetary policy irrelevant for real variables. Monetary policy essential to determination of all variables when prices sticky.

Households Households problem. Concept of Consumption Smoothing.

Households There are many identical households. The problem of the typical ( representative ) household: ( max E 0 β t log C t N1+ϕ t t=0 1 + ϕ + γz tlog ( Mt+1 P t ) ), s.t. P t C t + B t+1 + M t+1 W t N t + R t 1 B t + M t +Profits net of government transfers and taxes t. Here, B t and M t are the beginning-of-period t stock of bonds and money held by the household.

Household First Order Conditions The household first order conditions: where C t N ϕ t 1 1 = βe t C t C t+1 = W t. P t m t = ( Rt R t 1 m t M t+1 P t. R t π t+1 (5) ) γc t (7), All equations are derived by expressing the household problem in Lagrangian form, substituting out the multiplier on budget constraint and rearranging. The last first order condition is real money demand, increasing in C t and decreasing in R t 1.

Figure: Money Demand, Relative to Two Measures of Velocity 8 6 4 2 6 5 4 3 2 1 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 3.5 2.2 3 2.5 2 1.5 2 4 6 8 2 1.8 1.6 1 2 3 4 5 6 Notes: (i) velocity is GDP/M, (ii) With the MZM measure of money, the money demand equation does well qualitatively, but not qualitatively because the theory implies the scatters in the 2,1 and 2,2 graphs should be on the 45 0.

Consumption Smoothing: Example Problem: max c1,c 2 log (c 1 ) + βlog (c 2 ) subject to : c 1 + B 1 y 1 + rb 0 c 2 rb 1 + y 2. where y 1 and y 2 are (given) income and, after imposing equality (optimality) and substituting out for B 1, c 1 + c 2 r = y 1 + y 2 r + rb 0, 1 = βr 1, c 1 c 2 second equation is fonc for B 1. Suppose βr = 1 (this happens in steady state, see later): c 1 = y 1 + y 2 r 1 + 1 r + r 1 + 1 B 0 r

Consumption Smoothing: Example, cnt d Solution to the problem: c 1 = y 1 + y 2 r 1 + 1 r + r 1 + 1 B 0. r Consider three polar cases: temporary change in income: y 1 > 0 and y 2 = 0 = c 1 = c 2 = y 1 1+ 1 r permanent change in income: y 1 = y 2 > 0 = c 1 = c 2 = y 1 future change in income: y 1 = 0 and y 2 > 0 = c 1 = c 2 = y 2 r 1+ 1 r Common feature of each example: When income rises, then - assuming r does not change - c 1 increases by an amount that can be maintained into the second period: consumption smoothing.

Goods Production We turn now to the technology of production, and the problems of the firms. The technology requires allocating resources across sectors. We describe the efficient cross-sectoral allocation of resources. With price setting frictions, the market may not achieve efficiency.

Final Goods Production A homogeneous final good is produced using the following (Dixit-Stiglitz) production function: Y t = [ˆ 1 0 ] ε Y ε 1 ε 1 ε i,t di. Each intermediate good,y i,t, is produced by a monopolist using the following production function: Y i,t = e a t N i,t, a t exogenous shock to technology. Before discussing the firms that operate these production functions, we briefly investigate the socially efficient allocation of resources across i.

Efficient Sectoral Allocation of Resources With Dixit-Stiglitz final good production function, there is a socially optimal allocation of resources to all the intermediate activities, Y i,t. It is optimal to run them all at the same rate, i.e., Y i,t = Y j,t for all i, j [0, 1]. For given N t, allocative efficiency: N i,t = N j,t = N t, for all i, j [0, 1]. In this case, final output is given by Y t = [ˆ 1 0 (e a t N i,t ) ε 1 ε di ] ε ε 1 = e a t N t. One way to understand allocated efficiency result is to suppose that labor is not allocated equally to all activities. Explore one simple deviation from N i,t = N j,t for all i, j [0, 1].

Suppose Labor Not Allocated Equally Example: N it 2 N t i 0, 1 2 1 2 1 N t i,1,0 1. 2 Note that this is a particular distribution of labor across activities: 0 1 Nit di 1 2 2 N t 1 2 2 1 N t N t

Labor Not Allocated Equally, cnt d Y t 1 1 Yi,t di 0 1 0 1 2 1 Y i,t e at 0 1 2 di 1 2 1 N i,t 1 1 Yi,t di 1 2 di 1 1 Ni,t 1 di 1 1 e at 2 2 N t 1 1 di 0 1 2 1 Nt 1 2 1 e at 2 N t 2 1 1 1 di 0 1 2 1 2 e at N t e at N t f 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 1 di 1 di 1 1

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 f 1 2 2 1 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 Efficient Resource Allocation Means Equal Labor Across All Sectors 10 0.98 0.96 0.94 f 0.92 0.9 6 0.88

Final Good Producers Competitive firms: maximize profits P t Y t ˆ 1 0 P i,t Y i,t dj, subject to P t, P i,t given, all i [0, 1], and the technology: Foncs: Y t = [ˆ 1 0 ] ε Y ε 1 ε 1 ε i,t dj. cross price restrictions {}}{ ( ) ε (ˆ ) 1 1 Pt Y i,t = Y t P t = P (1 ε) 1 ε P i,t di i,t 0

Intermediate Good Producers The i th intermediate good is produced by a monopolist. Demand curve for i th monopolist: ( ) ε Pt Y i,t = Y t. P i,t Production function: Y i,t = e a t N i,t, a t exogenous shock to technology. Calvo Price-Setting Friction: { P i,t = P t with probability 1 θ with probability θ P i,t 1.

Marginal Cost of Production An important input into the monopolist s problem is its marginal cost: s t = dcost doutput = dcost dworker doutput dworker = (1 ν) W t P t e a t = (1 ν) C tn ϕ t e a t after substituting out for the real wage from the household intratemporal Euler equation. The tax rate, ν, represents a subsidy to hiring labor, financed by a lump-sum government tax on households. Firm s job is to set prices whenever it has the opportunity to do so. It must always satisfy whatever demand materializes at its posted price.

Present Discounted Value of Intermediate Good Revenues i th intermediate good firm s objective: E i t j=0 period t+j profits sent to household { }} { revenues total cost {}}{{}}{ β j υ t+j P i,t+j Y i,t+j P t+j s t+j Y i,t+j υ t+j - Lagrange multiplier on household budget constraint Here, E i t denotes the firm s expectation over future variables, including the future probability that the firm gets to reset its price.

Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Let p t = P t P t. The firm s profit-maximizing choice of P t satisfies: p t = E t j=0 (βθ)j Y t+j C t+j ( Xt,j ) ε E t j=0 ε ε 1 s t+j Y t+j C t+j (βθ) j ( ) 1 ε, X t,j the present discounted value of the markup, ε/ (ε 1) over real marginal cost.

Decision By Firm that Can Change Its Price Recall, p t = E t j=0 (βθ)j Y t+j C t+j ( Xt,j ) ε ε ε 1 s t+j E t j=0 (βθ)j Y t+j C t+j ( Xt,j ) 1 ε = K t F t The numerator has the following simple representation: K t = E t (βθ) j Y t+j ( ) ε ε Xt,j C j=0 t+j ε 1 s t+j = ε (1 ν) Y t N ϕ t ε 1 e a t + βθe t ( 1 π t+1 after using s t = (1 ν) e τ tc t N ϕ t /ea t. Similarly, F t = Y ( ) t 1 1 ε + βθe t F t+1 (2) C t π t+1 ) ε K t+1 (1),

Moving On to Aggregate Restrictions Link between aggregate price level, P t, and P i,t, i [0, 1]. Potentially complicated because there are MANY prices, P i,t, i [0, 1]. Link between aggregate output, Y t, and N t. Potentially complicated because of earlier example with f (α). Analog of f (α) will be a function of degree to which P i,t = P j,t. Market clearing conditions. Money and bond market clearing. Labor and goods market clearing.

Important Calvo result: Divide by P t : Aggregate Price Index 1 = P t = = ( [ Rearrange: p t = (ˆ 1 0 P (1 ε) i,t di ( (1 θ) P 1 ε t (1 θ) p 1 ε t ] 1 1 θ( π t ) ε 1 1 ε 1 θ ) 1 1 ε ) + θp 1 ε 1 1 ε t 1 ( 1 + θ π t ) 1 ε ) 1 1 ε

Aggregate Output vs Aggregate Labor and Tech (Tack Yun, JME1996) Define Y t : Y t ˆ 1 0 Y i,t di demand curve {}}{ = Y t ˆ 1 = Y t P ε t (P t ) ε 0 ( = ( Pi,t P t ˆ 1 0 e a t N i,t di = e a t N t ) ) ε di = Y t P ε t where, using Calvo result : [ˆ ] 1 1 ε [ Pt P ε i,t di = (1 θ) P t ε Then 0 Y t = p t Y t, p t = ( P t P ˆ 1 0 (P i,t ) ε di + θ ( Pt 1 ) ] 1 ε ε ) ε.

Gross Output vs Aggregate Labor Relationship between aggregate inputs and outputs: Y t = p t Y t or, Y t = p t e a t N t. Note that p t is a function of the ratio of two averages (with different weights) of P i,t, i (0, 1) So, when P i,t = P j,t for all i, j (0, 1), then p t = 1. But, what is p t when P i,t = P j,t for some (measure of) i, j (0, 1)?

Tack Yun Distortion Consider the object, where P t = (ˆ 1 0 P ε i,t di ( pt P ) ε = t, P t ) 1 ε, P t = (ˆ 1 0 P (1 ε) i,t di ) 1 1 ε Follows easily from (intuition) and Jensen s inequality: p t 1.

Law of Motion of Tack Yun Distortion We have Dividing by P t : P t = ( pt P ) ε t = P t [ [ (1 θ) P t ε + θ ( Pt 1 ) ] 1 ε ε (1 θ) p ε t + θ πε t p t 1 ] 1 = (1 θ) [ 1 θ ( π t ) ε 1 1 θ ] ε 1 ε + θ πε t p t 1 1 (4) using the restriction between p t and aggregate inflation developed earlier.

Evaluating the Distortions Tack Yun distortion: pt = (1 θ) ( 1 θ π (ε 1) ) ε ε 1 t + θ πε t 1 θ p t 1 1. Potentially, NK model provides an endogenous theory of TFP. Standard practice in NK literature is to set pt = 1 for all t. First order expansion of pt around π t = pt = 1 is: p t = p + 0 π t + θ (p t 1 p ), with p = 1, so p t 1 and is invariant to shocks.

Empirical Assessment of Tack Yun Distortion Do back of the envelope calculations in a steady state when inflation is constant and p is constant. Can also use pt = (1 θ) ( 1 θ π (ε 1) ) ε ε 1 t + θ πε t 1 θ p t 1 to compute times series estimate of p t. But, results very similar to what you find with steady state calculations. 1.

Cost of Three Alternative Permanent Levels of Inflation p = 1 θ πε 1 θ ( 1 θ ) ε ε 1 1 θ π (ε 1) Table: Percent of GDP Lost Due to Inflation, 100(1 p t ) ε steady state inflation markup, ε 1 1.20 1.15 1.10 1970s: 8% 2.41 3.92 10.85 proposal for dealing with ZLB: 4% 0.46 0.64 1.13 recent average: 2% 0.10 0.13 0.21

Tack Yun Distortion The magnitude of the distortion is typically small. Explains why standard literature abstracts from the distortion by linearizing about zero inflation. To first order approximation, p = 1 at zero inflation (see later). Could have p = 1 to first order around positive inflation if price indexation is assumed, as in CEE. But, prices don t appear to be indexed. Caution: distortion may be small because of simplicity of the model. Distortions at least two times bigger when production occurs in networks of firms. See this and this. Distortions may be bigger when there are intermediate good firm-specific idiosyncratic shocks to demand and supply of intermediate good firms.

Government Government budget constraint: expenditures = receipts purchases of final goods subsidy payments gov t bonds (lending, if positive) {}}{{}}{{}}{ P t G t + νw t N t + = + money injection, if positive {}}{ M t µ t + where µ t denotes money growth rate. B g t+1 transfer payments to households {}}{ T trans t tax revenues {}}{ Tt tax +R t 1 B g t Government s choice of µ t determines evolution of money supply: M t+1 = (1 + µ t ) M t, µ t money growth rate.

Government The law of motion for money places restrictions on m t : for t = 0, 1,.... m t M t+1 = M t+1 M t P t 1 P t M t P t 1 P t ( ) 1 + µt m t = m t 1 (8), π t

Market Clearing We now summarize the market clearing conditions of the model. Money, labor, bond and goods markets.

Money Market Clearing We temporarily use the bold notation, M t, to denote the per capita supply of money at the start of time t, for t = 0, 1, 2,.... The supply of money is determined by the actions, µ t, of the government: M t+1 = M t + µ t M t, for t=0,1,2,... Households being identical means that in period t = 0, M 0 = M 0, where M 0 denotes beginning of time t = 0 money stock of the representative household. Money market clearing in each period, t = 0, 1,..., requires M t+1 = M t+1, where M t+1 denotes the representative household s time t choice of money. From here on, we do not distinguish between M t and M t.

Other Market Clearing Conditions Bond market clearing: Labor market clearing: Goods market clearing: B t+1 + B g t+1 = 0, t = 0, 1, 2,... supply of labor {}}{ N t = demand for labor {}}{ ˆ1 0 N i,t di demand for final goods supply of final goods {}}{{}}{ C t + G t = Y t, and, using relation between Y t and N t : C t + G t = p t e a t N t (6)

Next Collect the equilibrium conditions associated with private sector behavior. Comparison of NK model with RBC model (i.e., θ = 0) Classical Dichotomy: In flexible price version of model real variables determined independent of monetary policy. Fiscal policy still matters, because equilibrium depends on how government deals with the monopoly power, i.e., selects value for subsidy, ν. In NK model, markets don t necessarily work well and good monetary policy essential. To close model with θ > 0 must take a stand on monetary policy.

Equilibrium Conditions 8 equations in 8 unknowns: m t, C t, p t, F t, K t, N t, R t, π t, and 3 policy variables: ν, µ t, G t. K t = ε (1 ν) Y t N ϕ t + βθe t π t+1 ε ε 1 A K t+1 (1) t F t = Y t + βθe t π C t+1 ε 1 F t+1 (2), t pt = (1 θ) 1 1 = βe t C t m t = C t+1 ( R t K t F t = [ 1 θ π (ε 1) ) ε ε 1 t + θ πε t 1 θ 1 θ π (ε 1) t 1 θ p t 1 1 (4) (5), C t + G t = pt e a t N t (6) π t+1 ( ) 1 + µt m t 1 (8) γc t (1 1 Rt ) (7), m t = π t ] 1 1 ε (3)

Classical Dichotomy Under Flexible Prices Classical Dichotomy: when prices flexible, θ = 0, then real variables determined regardless of the rule for µ t (i.e., monetary policy). Equations (2),(3) imply: F t = K t = Y t C t, which, combined with (1) implies ε (1 ν) ε 1 Marginal Cost of work {}}{ CN ϕ t = Expression (6) with p t = 1 (since θ = 0) is C t + G t = e a t N t. marginal benefit of work {}}{ e a t Thus, we have two equations in two unknowns, N t and C t.

Classical Dichotomy: No Uncertainty Real interest rate, R t R t/ π t+1, is determined: R t = 1 C t β 1 C t+1. So, with θ = 0, the following are determined: R t, C t, N t, t = 0, 1, 2,... What about the nominal variables? Suppose the monetary authority wants a given sequence of inflation rates, π t, t = 0, 1,.... Then, R t = π t+1 R t, t = 0, 1, 2,... What money growth sequence is required? From (7), obtain m t, t = 0, 1, 2,.... Also, m 1 is given by initial M 0 and P 1. From (8) 1 + µ t = m t m t 1 π t, t = 0, 1, 2,...

Classical Dichotomy versus New Keynesian Model When θ = 0, then the Classical Dichotomy occurs. In this case, monetary policy (i.e., the setting of µ t, t = 0, 1, 2,... ) cannot affect the real interest rate, consumption and employment. Monetary policy simply affects the split in the real interest rate between nominal and real rates: R t = R t π t+1. For a careful treatment when there is uncertainty, see. When θ > 0 (NK model) then real variables are not determined independent of monetary policy. In this case, monetary policy matters.

Monetary Policy in New Keynesian Model Suppose θ > 0, so that we re in the NK model and monetary policy matters. The standard assumption is that the monetary authority sets µ t to achieve an interest rate target, and that that target is a function of inflation: R t /R = (R t 1 /R) α exp [(1 α) φ π ( π t π) + φ x x t ] (7), where x t denotes the log deviation of actual output from target. This is a Taylor rule, and it satisfies the Taylor Principle when φ π > 1. Smoothing parameter: α. Bigger is α the more persistent are policy-induced changes in the interest rate.

Equilibrium Conditions of NK Model with Taylor Rule K t = ε (1 ν) Y t N ϕ t + βθe t π t+1 ε ε 1 A K t+1 (1) t F t = Y t + βθe t π C t+1 ε 1 F t+1 (2), t pt = (1 θ) ( K t F t = [ 1 θ π (ε 1) ) ε ε 1 t + θ πε t 1 θ 1 θ π (ε 1) t 1 θ p t 1 1 (4) ] 1 1 ε 1 1 R t = βe t (5), C t + G t = pt e a t N t (6) C t C t+1 π t+1 R t /R = (R t 1 /R) α exp [(1 α) φ π ( π t π) + φ x x t ] (7). (3) Conditions (7) and (8) have been replaced by (7).

Equilibrium Conditions of NK Model The model represents 7 equations in 7 unknowns: C, p t, F t, K t, N t, R t, π t After this system has been solved for the 7 variables, equations (7) and (8) can be used to solve for µ t and m t. This is rarely done, because researchers are uncertain of the exact form of money demand and because m t and µ t are in practice not of direct interest.

When θ = 0, then ε (1 ν) ε 1 Natural Equilibrium Marginal Cost of work {}}{ C t N ϕ t = marginal benefit of work {}}{ e a t so that we have a form of efficiency when ν is chosen to that ε (1 ν) / (ε 1) = 1. In addition, recall that we have allocative efficiency in the flexible price equilibrium. So, the flexible price equilibrium with the efficient setting of ν represents a natural benchmark for the New Keynesian model, the version of the model in which θ > 0. We call this the Natural Equilibrium. To simplify the analysis, from here on we set G t = 0.

Natural Equilibrium With G t = 0, equilibrium conditions for C t and N t : Marginal Cost of work {}}{ C t N ϕ t = aggregate production relation: C t = e a t N t. Substituting, e a t N 1+ϕ t = e a t N t = 1 C t = exp (a t ) R t = 1 C t βe t 1 C t+1 = 1 = C βe t t C t+1 marginal benefit of work {}}{ e a t 1 βe t exp ( a t+1 )

Natural Equilibrium, cnt d Natural rate of interest: R t = Two models for a t : 1 C t βe t 1 C t+1 = 1 βe t exp ( a t+1 ) DS : a t+1 = ρ a t + ε a t+1 TS : a t+1 = ρa t + ε a t+1

Natural Equilibrium, cnt d Suppose the ε t s are Normal. Then, E t exp ( a t+1 ) = exp ( E t a t+1 + 12 ) V, where V = σ 2 a Then, with r t log R t r t = log β + E t a t+1 1 2 V. Useful: consider how natural rate responds to ε a t shocks under DS and TS models for a t. To understand how rt responds, consider implications of consumption smoothing in absence of change in rt. Hint: in natural equilibrium, rt steers the economy so that natural equilibrium paths for C t and N t are realized.

Conclusion Described NK model and derived equilibrium conditions. The usual version of model represents monetary policy by a Taylor rule. When θ = 0, so that prices are flexible, then monetary policy is (essentially) neutral. Changes in money growth move prices and wages in such a way that real wages do not change and employment and output don t change. When prices are sticky, then a policy-induced reduction in the interest rate encourages more nominal spending. The increased spending raises W t more than P t because of the sticky prices, thereby inducing the increased labor supply that firms need to meet the extra demand. Firms are willing to produce more goods because: The model assumes they must meet all demand at posted prices. Firms make positive profits, so as long as the expansion is not too big they still make positive profits, even if not optimal.