EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Similar documents
EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

Technology 1. that describes the (net) output of the L goods of the production process of the firm. By convention,

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Additional questions for Chapter 1 - solutions: 1. See Varian, p.20. Notice that Varian set a1=a2. 2. See Varian, p.20.

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Advanced Microeconomics

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Notes on Consumer Theory

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

Second Welfare Theorem

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

a = (a 1; :::a i )

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

The Multi-Output Firm

PROFIT FUNCTIONS. 1. REPRESENTATION OF TECHNOLOGY 1.1. Technology Sets. The technology set for a given production process is defined as

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

The Envelope Theorem

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

General Equilibrium with Production

Microeconomics I. September, c Leopold Sögner

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

The Firm: Optimisation

Utility Maximization Problem

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Week 4: Calculus and Optimization (Jehle and Reny, Chapter A2)

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo

Mathematical Foundations II

Chapter 4: Production Theory

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Microeconomic Theory. Microeconomic Theory. Everyday Economics. The Course:

1 General Equilibrium

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Mathematical Preliminaries for Microeconomics: Exercises

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

ECON5110: Microeconomics

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

The Kuhn-Tucker and Envelope Theorems

THE FIRM: OPTIMISATION

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Exercises - SOLUTIONS UEC Advanced Microeconomics, Fall 2018 Instructor: Dusan Drabik, de Leeuwenborch 2105

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Economics 101A (Lecture 3) Stefano DellaVigna

Development Economics (PhD) Intertemporal Utility Maximiza

Solutions. F x = 2x 3λ = 0 F y = 2y 5λ = 0. λ = 2x 3 = 2y 5 = x = 3y 5. 2y 1/3 z 1/6 x 1/2 = 5x1/2 z 1/6. 3y 2/3 = 10x1/2 y 1/3

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Derivative Properties of Directional Technology Distance Functions

Solutions. ams 11b Study Guide 9 econ 11b

First Welfare Theorem

Applications I: consumer theory

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Positive Theory of Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Stability

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Solutions to selected exercises from Jehle and Reny (2001): Advanced Microeconomic Theory

CHAPTER 3: OPTIMIZATION

Mathematical Foundations -1- Convexity and quasi-convexity. Convex set Convex function Concave function Quasi-concave function Supporting hyperplane

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Course Handouts ECON 4161/8001 MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Professor: Alan G. Isaac These notes are very rough. Suggestions welcome. Samuelson (1938, p.71) introduced revealed preference theory hoping

Optimization Theory. Lectures 4-6

Demand Theory. Lecture IX and X Utility Maximization (Varian Ch. 7) Federico Trionfetti

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Transcription:

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 6 October, 2017

Properties of the Profit Function Recall the following property of the profit function π(p, w) = max x p f (x) w x = p f (x(p, w)) w x(p, w) Hotelling s Lemma: π p = y(p, w) 0 and π w i = x i (p, w) 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 2 / 49

Hessian of the Profit Function Consider now the Hessian matrix of the profit function π(p, w): 2 π 2 π p 2 p w 1 2 π p w h H = 2 π w 1 p. 2 π w h p 2 π w 2 1 2 π w 1 w h..... 2 π w h w 1 2 π wh 2 By Hotelling s Lemma the matrix H is: y y p w 1 H = y w h x 1 p x 1 w 1 x 1 w h...... x h p x h w 1 x h w h Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 3 / 49

Properties of the Hessian of the Profit Function Result Let F : A R where A R n is a convex open set. Let F ( ) be twice differentiable. Then the function F ( ) is convex if and only if the Hessian matrix of F ( ) is positive semi-definite on A. Recall that the profit function π(p, w) is convex in (p, w). This together with Young theorem implies that H is symmetric and has a non negative main diagonal. Assume now that π(p, w) is defined on an open and convex set S of prices (p, w) then convexity of π(p, w) is equivalent to the Hessian Matrix H being positive semi-definite. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 4 / 49

Profit Maximization Profit maximization can be achieved in two sequential steps: 1. Given y, find the choice of inputs that allows the producer to obtain y at the minimum cost; this generates conditional factor demands and the cost function; 2. Given the cost function, find the profit maximizing output level. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 5 / 49

Comments Notice: step 1 is common to firms that behave competitively in the input market but not necessarily in the output market. Only in step 2 we impose the competitive assumption on the output market. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 6 / 49

Cost Minimization We shall start from step 1: min x s.t. w x f (x) y The necessary first order conditions are: y = f (x ), w λ f (x ) and [w λ f (x )] x = 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 7 / 49

Cost Minimization (cont d) or for every input l = 1,..., h: with equality if x l > 0. w l λ f (x ) x l The first order conditions are also sufficient if f (x) is quasi-concave (the input requirement set is convex). Alternatively, a set of sufficient conditions for a local minimum are that f (x) is quasi-concave in a neighborhood of x. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 8 / 49

Cost Minimization (cont d) This can be checked (sufficient condition) by means of the bordered hessian matrix and its minors. In the case of only two inputs f (x 1, x 2 ) we have: with equality if x l > 0 w l λ f (x ) x l, l = 1, 2 and SOC: 0 f 1 (x ) f 2 (x ) f 1 (x ) f 11 (x ) f 12 (x ) f 2 (x ) f 21 (x ) f 22 (x ) > 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 9 / 49

Cost Minimization (cont d) In the case the two first order conditions are satisfied with equality (no corner solutions) we can rewrite the necessary conditions as: and MRTS = dx 2 dx 1 = f (x )/ x 1 f (x = w 1 )/ x 2 w 2 y = f (x ) Notice a close formal analogy with consumption theory (expenditure minimization). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 10 / 49

Conditional Factor Demands and Cost Function This leads to define: the solution to the cost minimization problem: z 1 (w, y) x = z(w, y) =. z h (w, y) the conditional (to y) factor demands (correspondences). the minimand function of the cost minimization problem: the cost function. c(w, y) = w z(w, y) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 11 / 49

Properties of the Cost Function 1. c(w, y) is non-decreasing in y. Proof: Suppose not. Then there exist y < y such that (denote x and x the corresponding solution to the cost minimization problem) w x w x > 0 If the latter inequality is strict we have an immediate contradiction of x solving the cost minimization problem. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 12 / 49

Properties of the Cost Function (cont d) If on the other hand w x = w x > 0 then by continuity and monotonicity of f ( ) there exists α (0, 1) close enough to 1 such that f (α x ) > y and w x > w αx which contradicts x solving the cost minimization problem. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 13 / 49

Properties of the Cost Function (cont d) 2. c(w, y) is non-decreasing with respect to w l for every l = 1,..., h. Proof: Consider w and w such that w l w l for every k l. but w k = w k Let x and x be the solutions to the cost minimization problem with w and w respectively. Then by definition of c(w, y) c(w, y) = w x w x w x = c(w, y). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 14 / 49

Properties of the Cost Function (cont d) 3. c(w, y) is homogeneous of degree 1 in w. Proof: The feasible set of the cost minimization problem f (x) y does not change when w is multiplied by the factor t > 0. Hence t > 0, minimizing (t w) x on this set leads to the same answer as minimizing w x. Let x be the solution, then: c(t w, y) = (t w) x = t c(w, y). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 15 / 49

Properties of the Cost Function (cont d) 4. c(w, y) is a concave function in w. Proof: Let ŵ = t w + (1 t) w for t [0, 1]. Let ˆx be the solution to the cost minimization problem for ŵ. Then c(ŵ, y) = ŵ ˆx = t w ˆx + (1 t) w ˆx t c(w, y) + (1 t) c(w, y) by definition of c(w, y) and c(w, y) and f (ˆx) y. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 16 / 49

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands 5. Shephard s Lemma: If z(w, y) is single valued with respect to w then c(w, y) is differentiable with respect to w and c(w, y) w l = z l (w, y) Proof: By constrained Envelope Theorem and the definition of cost function c(w, y) = w z(w, y) = w z(w, y) λ(w, y) [f (z(w, y) y] Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 17 / 49

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont d) 6. z(w, y) is homogeneous of degree 0 in w. Proof: By Shepard s Lemma and the following result. Result If a function G(x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then ( G/ x l ) is homogeneous of degree (r 1) in x for every l = 1,..., L. Proof: Differentiate with respect to x l the identity that defines homogeneity of degree r: G(k x) k r G(x) k > 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 18 / 49

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont d) We obtain: k G(k x) x l = k r G(x) x l k > 0 or G(k x) x l (r 1) G(x) = k k > 0 x l This is the definition of homogeneity of degree (r 1) of the G(k x) function. x l Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 19 / 49

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont d) Notice that 6. The Lagrange multiplier of the cost minimization problem is the marginal cost of output: c(w, y) y = λ(w, y) Proof: By constrained Envelope Theorem applied to the cost function: c(w, y) = w z(w, y) λ(w, y) [f (z(w, y) y] Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 20 / 49

Law of Supply 7. Let the set W of input prices w be open and convex, if z(w, y) is differentiable in w then: H = 2 c w 2 1 2 c w 1 w h..... 2 c w h w 1 2 c wh 2 = z 1 z 1 w h w 1..... z h w 1 z h w h is a symmetric and negative semi-definite matrix. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 21 / 49

Law of Supply Proof: Symmetry follows from Shephard s lemma and Young Theorem: z l = ( ) c(w, y) = ( ) c(w, y) = z i w i w i w l w l w i w l While negative semi-definiteness follows from the concavity of c(w, y), the fact that W is open and convex and the following result. Result Let F : A R where A R n is a convex open set. Let F ( ) be twice differentiable. Then the function F ( ) is concave if and only if the Hessian matrix of F ( ) is negative semi-definite on A. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 22 / 49

Euler Theorem Result (Euler Theorem) If a function G(x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then: r G(x) = G(x) x Proof: Differentiating with respect to k the identity: G(k x) k r G(x) k > 0 we obtain: G(kx) x = rk (r 1) G(x) k > 0 for k = 1 we obtain: G(x) x = r G(x). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 23 / 49

Returns to Scale We now introduce a set of new properties closely related to the ones of the expenditure function in consumer theory. 8. If f (x) is homogeneous of degree one (i.e. exhibits constant returns to scale), then c(w, y) and z(w, y) are homogeneous of degree one in y. Proof: Let k > 0 and consider: c(w, k y) = min x s.t. w x f (x) k y (1) By definition of c(w, y) if x is the solution to the cost minimization problem we have y = f (x ). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 24 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) Hence by homogeneity of degree 1 of f (x) we obtain: k y = k f (x ) = f (k x ) which implies that k x is feasible in Problem (1). Therefore: k c(w, y) = k [w x ] = w (k x ) c(w, k y). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 25 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) Let now ˆx be the solution to Problem (1). Necessarily: f (ˆx) = k y or, by homogeneity of degree 1: f [(1/k) ˆx] = (1/k) f (ˆx) = y which implies that [(1/k) ˆx] is feasible in the problem that defines c(w, y). Therefore we get: c(w, k y) = w ˆx = k w [(1/k) ˆx] k c(w, y) which concludes the proof. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 26 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) 8. In other words, a technology that exhibits CRS has a cost function that is linear in y: c(w, y) = c(w)y. 9. A technology that exhibits CRS has equal and constant marginal ( c(w, y)/ y) and average cost functions ( c(w, y)/ y) = (c(w, y)/y). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 27 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) Proof: Homogeneity of degree 1 and Euler theorem imply c(w, y) c y (w)y = c(w, y) or c y (w) =. y c y (w) = c(w,y) y y c(w, y) = c y (w) y y Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 28 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) 10. If f (x) is convex (IRS technology), then the cost function c(w, y) is concave in y. 11. A technology that exhibits IRS has a decreasing marginal cost function ( c(w, y)/ y) and average cost function ( c(w, y)/ y) (c(w, y)/y) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 29 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) c(w,y) y c(w, y) c y (w, y) y y Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 30 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) 12. If f (x) is concave (DRS technology), then the cost function c(w, y) is convex in y. 13. A technology that exhibits DRS has an increasing marginal cost function ( c(w, y)/ y) and average cost function ( c(w, y)/ y) (c(w, y)/y) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 31 / 49

Returns to Scale (cont d) c y (w, y) c(w,y) y c(w, y) y y Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 32 / 49

Profit Maximization with Single Output Assume that the output market is competitive. The profit maximization problem is then: max y p y c(w, y) The necessary FOC are: p c(w, y ) y 0 with equality if y > 0. The sufficient SOC for a local maximum: 2 c(w, y ) y 2 > 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 33 / 49

Profit Maximization with Single Output (cont d) Clearly the SOC imply at least local DRS in a neighborhood of y. Notice that if y > 0 the optimal choice of the firm is: p = c(w, y ) y = MC(y ) In words, price equal to marginal cost. This condition defines the solution to the profit maximization problem: the supply function: y (w, p) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 34 / 49

Profit Maximization with Single Output (cont d) The two profit maximization problems we have considered so far produce the same outcome for equal (w, p). In fact: max y py c(w, y) where c(w, y) = min x s.t. w x f (x) y yields max x s.t. p y w x f (x) = y which is the very first problem we considered. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 35 / 49

Short Run Short run cost minimization arises when one or more inputs may be fixed, x h = x h, while the remaining inputs may be varied at will. The short run variable cost function: Alternatively: h 1 c S (w, y, x h ) = w h x h + min w l x l x 1,...,x h 1 s.t. l=1 f (x 1,..., x h 1, x h ) y c S (w, y, x h ) = min x s.t. w x f (x) y x h = x h Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 36 / 49

Short Run (cont d) If z(w, y) denotes the long run conditional factor demands, that solve: c(w, y) = min w x x s.t. f (x) y Let x = ( x 1,..., x h ) be the input vector that achieves the minimum long run cost of producing ȳ with prices w: x = ( x 1,..., x h ) = z( w, ȳ) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 37 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run We can then characterize the relationship between short and long run total costs, or alternatively, short run and long run variable costs (more familiar). Notice that c(w, y) c S (w, y, z h (w, y)) (2) or c(w, y) y cs (w, y, z h (w, y)) y Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 38 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont d) moreover by Envelope Theorem c(w, y) y cs (w, y, z h (w, y)) y (3) We shall now focus on a neighborhood of ( w, ȳ) and set x h = z h ( w, ȳ). From (2) above by Envelope Theorem we get: c(w, y) y = cs (w, y, x h ) y Recall that Envelope Theorem implies that only the first order effect is zero. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 39 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont d) Since (3) is an identity in (w, y) we can differentiate both sides with respect to y: 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y 2 + 2 c S (w, y, x h ) z h (w, y) = 2 c(w, y) y x h y y 2 and with respect to w h : 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y w h + 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y x h z h (w, y) w h = 2 c(w, y) y w h Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 40 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont d) Now 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y w h = 0 since is independent of y. c S (w, y, x h ) w h = x h Hence by Shephard s Lemma: 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y x h = z h(w, y)/ y z h (w, y)/ w h Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 41 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont d) which implies by substitution: 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y 2 + ( z h(w, y)/ y) 2 = 2 c(w, y) z h (w, y)/ w h y 2 which delivers: 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y 2 2 c(w, y) y 2 since ( z h (w, y)/ y) 2 z h (w, y)/ w h 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 42 / 49

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont d) This allows us to conclude that the loss function: l(w, y) = c(w, y) c S (w, y, x h ) 0 reaches a local maximum at x. Proof: We have shown above that the FOC are satisfied: c S (w, y, x h ) y = c(w, y) y and we just proved that the SOC hold: 2 c(w, y) y 2 2 c S (w, y, x h ) y 2 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 43 / 49

Le Chatelier Principle In other words: c(w, y) c S (w, y, x h ) A similar approach proves that for every l {1,..., h}: Moving to profit maximization: 0 zs l w l z l w l and 0 x S l w l x l w l 0 y S p y p All these results are known as Le Chatelier Principle. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 44 / 49

Aggregation The question we address is when can we speak of an aggregate supply function in similar terms as the aggregate demand you have seen before? The question above is closely related to the question: under which conditions can we speak of a representative producer? Recall that the key problem when constructing an aggregate demand was the presence of income effects in consumer theory. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 45 / 49

Aggregate Supply The absence of a budget constraint implies that individual firms supply are not subject to income effects. Hence aggregation of production theory is simpler and requires less restrictive conditions. Consider J production technologies: (Z 1,..., Z J ) Let z j (p, w) = ( x j (p, w) y j (p, w) ) be firm j s production plan. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 46 / 49

Law of Supply We have seen that the matrix of cross and own price effects of production plan z j (p.w): Dz j (p, w) is symmetric and positive semi-definite. This is also known as law of supply. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 47 / 49

Aggregate Law of Supply Define now the following aggregate optimal production plan: z(p, w) = J j=1 z j (p, w) = ( j x j (p, w) j y j (p, w) ) Does an aggregate law of supply hold? Since both symmetry and positive semi-definiteness are preserved under sum then Dz(p, w) is also symmetric and positive semi-definite. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 48 / 49

Representative Producer Result In a purely competitive environment the maximum profit obtained by every firm maximizing profits separately is the same as the profit obtained if all J firms where they coordinate their choices in a joint profit maximization: J π(p, w) = π j (p, w) j=1 In other words, there exists a representative producer. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 49 / 49