Small Open Economy. Lawrence Christiano. Department of Economics, Northwestern University

Similar documents
Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Final Exam. You may not use calculators, notes, or aids of any kind.

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Learning and Global Dynamics

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

Dynare Class on Heathcote-Perri JME 2002

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

The Real Business Cycle Model

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Money in the utility model

Monetary Policy and the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Puzzle. David K. Backus, Chris Telmer and Stanley E. Zin

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

SLOVAK REPUBLIC. Time Series Data on International Reserves/Foreign Currency Liquidity

Lars Svensson 10/2/05. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

The New Keynesian Model

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Problem 1 (30 points)

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

slides chapter 3 an open economy with capital

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Small Open Economy. Macroeconomic Theory, Lecture 9. Adam Gulan. February Bank of Finland

The Dornbusch overshooting model

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

A suggested solution to the problem set at the re-exam in Advanced Macroeconomics. February 15, 2016

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

1. Money in the utility function (start)

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

A t = B A F (φ A t K t, N A t X t ) S t = B S F (φ S t K t, N S t X t ) M t + δk + K = B M F (φ M t K t, N M t X t )

Sticky Leverage. João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke. September 28, 2013

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Assessing Structural VAR s

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

14.05 Lecture Notes Crises and Multiple Equilibria

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations

Based on the specification in Mansoorian and Mohsin(2006), the model in this

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Transcription:

Small Open Economy Lawrence Christiano Department of Economics, Northwestern University

Outline Simple Closed Economy Model Extend Model to Open Economy Equilibrium conditions Indicate complications to bring the model to the data. Similar in spirit to Ramses I model Adolfson-Laséen-Lindé-Villan at Swedish Riksbank Brief Discussion of Introducing Financial Frictions Christiano-Trabandt-Walentin (CTW) Model, Ramses II model. Based on Christiano-Motto-Rostagno ( Risk Shocks ) Mihai Copaciu of Romanian Central Bank. Application: will US lift off act like a locomotive to rest of world economy, or will it be a problem (especially for EME s)?

Simple Closed Economy Model Results from closed economy model Household preferences: ( E 0 β t { t=0 u (C t ) exp (τ t ) N1+ϕ t 1 + ϕ ), u (C t ) log C t Aggregate resources and household intertemporal optimization: Y t = pt R t A t N t, u c,t = βe t u c,t+1 π t+1 Law of motion of price distortion: ( pt 1 θ (π t ) = (1 ε 1 θ) 1 θ ) ε ε 1 + θπε t pt 1 1 (1)

Simple Closed Economy Model Equilibrium conditions associated with price setting: Y t C t + E t π ε 1 t+1 βθf t+1 = F t (2) [ 1 θπ ε 1 t F t 1 θ ] 1 1 ε = K t (3) ε (1 ν) ε 1 = W t Pt by household optimization {}}{ exp (τ t ) N ϕ t 1 Y t u c,t A t C t +E t βθπt+1k ε t+1 = K t (4) note: in simple closed economy model, Y t = C t, but this is not so in open economy. For a derivation in the simple closed economy, see, e.g., http://faculty.wcas.northwestern.edu/~lchrist/d16/d1614/ Labor_market_handout.pdf

Extensions to Small Open Economy Outline: the equilibrium conditions of the open economy model system jumps from 6 equations in basic model to 16 equations in 16 variables!

Extensions to Small Open Economy: 16 variables rate of depreciation, exports, real foreign assets, terms of trade, real exchange rate {}}{ s t, x t, a f t, p x t, q t price of domestic consumption (now, c is a composite of domestically produced goods & imports) {}}{ p c t price of imports {}}{ p m t consumption price inflation {}}{ π c t reduced form object to (i) achieve technical objective, (ii) adjust UIP implication {}}{ Φ t closed economy variables {}}{ R t, π t, N t, c t, K t, F t, p t

Extensions to Small Open Economy- Outline After describing 16 equilibrium conditions: compute the steady state the uncovered interest parity puzzle, and the role of Φ t in addressing the puzzle. summary of the endogenous and exogenous variables of the model, as well as the equations. several computational experiments to illustrate the properties of the model.

Modifications to Simple Model to Create Open Economy Unchanged: household preferences production of (domestic) homogeneous good, Y t (= A t pt N t) three Calvo price friction equations Changes: household budget constraint includes opportunity to acquire foreign assets/liabilities. intertemporal Euler equation changed as a reduced form accommodation of evidence on uncovered interest parity. Y t = C t no longer true. introduce exports, imports, balance of payments. exchange rate, S t = domestic currency price of one unit of foreign currency domestic money S t = foreign money

Monetary Policy: two approaches Taylor rule ( ) Rt log R = ρ R log +r y log ( Rt 1 R ( yt+1 y ) + (1 ρ R ) E t [r π log ) ] + ε R,t ( π c ) t+1 π c (5) where (could also add exchange rate, real exchange rate and other things): π c ~target consumer price inflation ε R,t ~iid, mean zero monetary policy shock y t ~Y t /A t R t ~ risk free nominal rate of interest ε R,t ~mean zero monetary policy shock.

Monetary Policy: two approaches Second approach (Norges Bank, Riksbank) Solve a type of Ramsey problem in which preferences correspond to preferences of monetary policy committee: ( E t β j { 100 [π c t π c t 1 πc t 2 πc t 3 (πc ) 4]) 2 j=0 ( )) 2 yt + λ y (100 log y +λ R (400 [R t R t 1 ]) 2 + λ s (S t S) 2 } straightforward to implement in Dynare. We will stress first approach.

Household Budget Constraint Uses of funds less than or equal to sources of funds S t A f t+1 + P t C t + B t+1 B t R t 1 + S t [Φ t 1 R f t 1 Domestic bonds Foreign assets ] A f t + W t N t + transfers and profits t B t ~beginning of period t stock of loans R t ~rate of return on bonds A f t ~beginning-of-period t net stock of foreign assets (liabilities, if negative) held by domestic residents. Φ t Rt f ~rate of return on A f t Φ t ~premium on foreign asset returns

Household Intertemporal First Order Conditions: Foreign Assets Optimality of foreign asset choice (verify this by solving Lagrangian representation of household problem) utility cost of 1 unit of foreign currency=s t units of domestic currency, S t /P c t {}}{ u c,t S t P c t units of C t conversion into utility units {}}{ = βe t u c,t+1 quantity of domestic cons. goods purchased from the payoff of 1 unit of foreign currency {}}{ foreign currency payoff next period from one unit of foreign currency today {}}{ S t+1 Rt f Φ t Pt+1 c

Household Intertemporal First Order Conditions: Foreign Assets First order condition: Scaling: S t P c t C t = βe t S t+1 R f t Φ t P c t+1 C t+1 1 c t = βe t s t+1 R f t Φ t π c t+1 c t+1 exp ( a t+1 ), s t S t S t 1, c t = C t A t. (6) Technology: a t log (A t ), a t = a t a t 1.

Household Intertemporal First Order Conditions: Domestic Assets First order condition: Scaling: 1 R t Pt c = βe t C t Pt+1 c C t+1 1 R t = βe t c t π c t+1 c t+1 exp ( a t+1 ). (7)

Final Domestic Consumption Goods Produced by representative, competitive firm using: where C t = [ (1 ω c ) 1 η c ( C d t ) η c 1 η c + ω 1 ηc c ] ηc (Ct m ) η c 1 η c 1 η c Ct d ~ domestic homogeneous output good, price P t Ct m ~ imported good, price Pt m ( St Pt f ) C t ~ final consumption good, Pt c η c ~ elasticity of substitution, domestic and foreign goods.

Final Domestic Consumption Goods Profit maximization by representative firm: max P c t C t P m t C m t P t C d t, subject to production function. First order conditions associated with maximization: C m t : P c t ( ) 1 = ω Ct ηc c Ct {}} m { dc t dct m = P m t, C d t : P c t ( ) 1 ηc = (1 ω c ) C t Ct {}}{ d dc t dct d = P t so that the demand functions are: C m t = ω c ( P c t P m t ) ηc Ct, C d t = (1 ω c ) ( ) P c ηc t Ct. P t

Price Function Substituting demand functions back into the production function: or C t = [(1 ω c ) 1 η c (C t ( P c t +ω p c t = 1 η c c ( ω c ( P c t P m t P t ) ηc (1 ωc )) η c 1 η c ) ηc Ct ) η c 1 η c ] η c η c 1, [ ] (1 ω c ) + ω c (pt m ) 1 η 1 1 η, c c (8) where p c t Pc t P t, p m t Pm t P t.

Real Exchange Rate and Consumption Price Inflation Real Exchange Rate: p m t = Pc t P c t = p c t P m t P t S t P f t P c t, real exchange rate {}}{ q t (9) Consumption good inflation and homogeneous good inflation: π c t Pc t P c t 1 = P tp c t P t 1 p c t 1 = π t [ (1 ω c ) + ω c (p m t ) 1 η c (1 ω c ) + ω c ( p m t 1 ) 1 ηc ] 1 1 η c (10)

Exports Foreign demand for domestic goods: ( P x X t = t P f t ) ηf Y f t = (p x t ) η f Y f t, terms of trade {}}{ p x t = Px t P f t Yt f ~ foreign output Pt f ~ foreign currency price of foreign good Pt x ~ foreign currency price of export good Scaling by A t x t = (p x t ) η f y f t (11)

Rate of Depreciation, Inflation... Competition: Price of export equals marginal cost: Scaling: Also, S t P x t = P t. 1 = S tpt x = Pc t S t Pt f Pt x P t P t Pt c Pt f = q t pt x pt c (12) q t π = f t s t q t 1 π c, s t S t, π f t t S t 1 Pf t P f t 1 (13)

Homogeneous Goods Market Clearing Clearing in domestic homogeneous goods market: output of domestic homogeneous good, Y t = uses of domestic homogeneous goods = goods used in production of final consumption, C t {}}{ exports government {}}{{}}{ Ct d + X t + G t = (1 ω c ) (p c t ) η c C t + X t + G t.

Aggregate Employment and Uses of Homogeneous Goods Substituting out in previous expression for Y t : A t p t N t = (1 ω c ) (p c t ) η c C t + X t + G t, or, p t N t = (1 ω c ) (p c t ) η c c t + x t + g t, (14) c t C t A t, x t X t A t, g t G t A t.

Balance of Payments equality of international flows relating to trade in goods and in financial assets: acquisition of new net foreign assets, in domestic currency units {}}{ S t A f t+1 + expenses on imports t = receipts from exports t + receipts from existing stock of net foreign assets {}}{ S t R f t 1Φ t 1 A f t

Balance of Payments, the Pieces Exports and imports: expenses on imports t = S t P f t ω c ( p c t receipts from exports t = S t P x t X t. p m t ) ηc C t Balance of payments: ) ηc Ct ( p S t A f t+1 + S t Pt f c ω t c pt m = S t Pt x X t + S t Rt 1Φ f t 1 A f t.

Balance of Payments, Scaling Scaling by P t A t : S t A f t+1 P t A t + S tp f t P t ω c ( p c t p m t ) ηc ct or, = S tp x t P t x t + S tr f t 1 Φ t 1A f t P t A t, a f t + p m t ω c ( p c t p m t ) ηc ct = pt c q t pt x x t + s trt 1 f Φ t 1at 1 f, (15) π t exp ( a t ) where a f t is scaled, homogeneous goods value of net foreign assets : a f t = S ta f t+1 P t A t.

Risk Term ) Φ t = Φ (at f, Rt f, R t, φ t = (16) ( ) ( exp ( φ a at f ā + φ s R t Rt f (R )) ) R f + φ t φ a > 0, small and not important for dynamics φ s > 0, important φ t ~mean zero, iid. Discussion of φ a. φ a > 0 implies (i) if at f > ā, then return on foreign assets low and f ; (ii) if at f < ā, then return on foreign assets high and at f implication: φ a > 0 is a force that drives at f ā in steady state, independent of initial conditions. logic is same as reason why steady state stock of capital in neoclassical growth model is unique, independent of initial conditions. in practice, put in a tiny value of φ a, so that its only effect is to pin down at f in steady state and it does not affect dynamics (see Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe).

Risk Term Discussion of φ t : Captures, informally, the possibility that there is a shock to the required return on domestic assets. Discussion of φ s : When φ t > 0, capital outflow shock, people stop liking domestic assets When φ t < 0, safe haven shock, people love domestic assets (e.g., Swiss Franc in recent years). φ s reduced form fix for the model. With φ s = 0, model implies Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP), which does not hold in the data. to better explain this, it is convenient to first solve for the model s steady state.

Steady State household intertemporal effi ciency conditions: sr 1 = f β π c exp ( a) (6) R 1 = β π c exp ( a) (7) assumption about foreign households: π f t Pf t P f t 1 (exogenous) R f 1 = β π f exp ( a)

Steady State Taylor rule implies: π c = π c, (5). Additional steady state equations: π P t P t 1 = π c (inflation target) (10) p = s = πc π f, R = R f = R/s 1 θπ ε 1 θ ( 1 θ(π) ε 1 1 θ π exp ( a) β ) ε, (no distortion if π c = 1) (1) ε 1 (13) (7) ((6),(7))

Steady State, Potentially Iterative Part Rest of the algorithm solves a single non-linear equation in a single unknown, ϕ. Set ϕ = p c q p m = ϕ (9) and p x = 1 ϕ (12) p c = [ ] (1 ω c ) + ω c (p m ) 1 η 1 1 η c c (8) q = ϕ p c

Steady State, Potentially Iterative Part... Let g = η g y, ā = η a y. Then, ( ) p 0 = p m c ηc ( ω c c p c p m qp x sr x f ) π exp ( a) 1 η a p N (15) ) 0 = (1 ω c ) (p c ) η c c + x (1 η g Np (14) p F = N c (1 π ε 1 βθ) (2) [ ] 1 1 θπ ε 1 1 ε K = F (3) 1 θ ε 0 = ε 1 (1 ν) N1+ϕ p + (βθπ ε 1) K (4), These five equations involve the five unknowns: c, N, F, K, x. Solve these. Adjust ϕ until (11) is satisfied. In practice, we simply set ϕ = 1 and used (11) to solve for y f.

Uncovered Interest Parity Algebra subtract equations (6) and (7): [ R t s t+1 R f ] t Φ t E t c t+1 π c t+1 exp ( a = 0. t+1) totally different object in square brackets and evaluate in steady state: where R t s d t+1 Rt f Φ t c t+1 π c t+1 exp ( a t+1) dr t = cπ c exp ( a) 1 ] [sr f cπ c dφ t + sdrt f + R f ds exp ( a) t+1 R sr f [cπ c exp ( a)] 2 d [ c t+1 π c t+1 exp ( a t+1) ] = 1 { [ ]} ˆR t ˆΦ t + ˆR t f + ŝ t+1 βc ˆx t (x t x) /x = dx t /x.

Uncovered Interest Parity, Linearized Representation Then, is, to a first approximation, or, [ R t s t+1 R f ] t Φ t E t c t+1 π c t+1 exp ( a = 0, t+1) [ 1 { [ ]} ] E t ˆR t ˆΦ t + ˆR t f + ŝ t+1 = 0 βc ˆR t = E t ŝ t+1 + ˆR f t + ˆΦ t. Conclude, using dx t x log (x t /x), log Φ = 0 : log R t log R = E t [log s t+1 log (s)] + log R f t log R f + log Φ t or, using log R f = log R log s, definition of s t+1, r t log R t, rt f log Rt f E t log S t+1 log S t = r t r f t + log Φ t

Uncovered Interest Parity Under UIP, ˆΦ t = 0 : r t > r f t must be an anticipated depreciation (instantaneous appreciation) of the currency for people to be happy holding the existing stock of net foreign assets Consider regression relation: log S t+1 log S t = β 0 + β 1 (r t r f t ) + u t. Under UIP (and, rational expectations), ˆβ 0 = 0, ˆβ 1 = 1. When ˆΦ t = 0: ˆβ 1 = cov ( log S t+1 log S t, r t rt f ) var ( ) r t rt f = 1 φ s,

UIP Puzzle In data, ˆβ 1.75, so UIP rejected (that s the UIP puzzle) Note: because φ s = 1.75 ˆβ 1 = 0.75. ˆβ 1 = cov ( log S t+1 log S t, r t rt f ) var ( ) r t rt f = 1 φ s, Another way to see UIP puzzle is from VAR impulse responses by Eichenbaum and Evans (QJE, 1992) Data: r t after monetary policy shock log S t+j falls slowly for j = 1, 2, 3,.... UIP theory: r t after monetary policy shock log S t+1 log S t.

Intuition Behind UIP Puzzle UIP puzzle: r t and expected appreciation of the currency represents a double-boost to the return on domestic assets. On the face of it, it appears that there is an irresistible profit opportunity. Why doesn t the double-boost to domestic returns launch an avalanche of pressure to buy the domestic currency? In standard models, this pressure produces a greater instantaneous appreciation in the exchange rate, until the familiar UIP overshooting result emerges - the pressure to buy the currency leads to such a large appreciation, that expectations of depreciation emerge. In this way, UIP leads to the counterfactual prediction that a higher r t will be followed (after an instantaneous appreciation) by a period of time during which the currency depreciates.

Intuition Behind Resolution of Puzzle Model s resolution of the UIP puzzle: when r t the return required for people to hold domestic bonds rises. This is why the double-boost to domestic returns does not create an appetite to buy large amounts of domestic assets. Possibly this is a reduced form way to capture the notion that increases in r t make the domestic economy more risky. (However, the precise mechanism by which the domestic required return rises - earnings on foreign assets go up - may be diffi cult to interpret. An alternative specification was explored, with risk-premia affecting domestic bonds, but this resulted in indeterminacy problems.)

Dynamics 16 equations: price setting, (1),(2),(3),(4); monetary policy rule, (5); household intertemporal Euler equations (6),(7); relative price equations (8),(9),(10),(12),(13); aggregate resource condition, (14); balance of payments, (15); risk term, (16); demand for exports (11). 16 endogenous variables: p c t, p m t, q t, R t, π t, π c t, p x t, N t, p t, a f t, Φ t, s t, x t, c t, K t, F t. exogenous variables: R f t, y f t, φ t, g t, ε R,t, a t, τ t, π f t. for the purpose of numerical calculations, these were modeled as independent scalar AR(1) processes.

Extensions to Small Open Economy... the model was solved in the manner described above: - compute the steady state using the formulas described above - log-linearize the 16 equations about steady state - solve the log-linearized system - these calculations were made easy by implementing them in Dynare.

Parameter Values Numerical examples: Parameter values: π f = π c = 1.005 φ a = 0.03 β = 1.03 1/4 θ = 3/4 ϕ = 1 ε = 6 1 ν = ε 1 ε η c = 5 ω c = 0.4 η g = 0.3 η a = 0 η f = 1.5 ρ R = 0.9 r π = 1.5 r y = 0.15

Modifying UIP iid shock, 0.01, to ε R,t. φ s = 0 after instantaneous appreciation, positive ε R,t shock followed by depreciation. for higher φ s, shock followed by appreciation. long run appreciation is increasing function of persistence of ρ R.

Impact of Modifications to UIP We now consider a monetary policy shock, ε R,t = 0.01. According to (5), implies a four percentage point (at an annual rate) policy-induced jump in R t. The dynamic effects are displayed in the following figure, for φ s = 0, φ s = 1.75 Note: (i) appreciation smaller, though more drawn out, when φ s is big; (ii) smaller appreciation results in smaller drop in net exports, so less of a drop in demand, so less fall in output and inflation; (iii) smaller drop in net exports results in smaller drop in real foreign assets.

Capital Outflow Shock Consider now a domestic economy risk premium shock, a jump in the innovation to φ t equal to 0.01. With the reduced interest in domestic assets, (i) the currency depreciates, (ii) net exports rise, (iii) hours and output rise, (iv) the upward pressure on costs associated with higher output leads to a rise in prices.

Question Confronting Many Emerging Market Economies.. At some point, the Fed will implement its exit strategy and raise US interest rates (300-350 basis points?). In the past, when Fed raised rates sharply (e.g., 1982 Volcker disinflation, 1994 run-up in interest rates), hit the rest of world like a brick: Chilean crisis of 1982, Mexican default of August 1982. Mexican crisis of 1994. Will the US exit strategy inflict financial crises around the world, especially in emerging market economies? Summer 2013 taper episode makes people worry about this possibility. I ll call the above possibility the BIS scenario.

BIS Scenario Low US interest rates since 2008 have encouraged excessive accumulation of debt in the world. This has particularly affected emerging market economies in Asia andlatin America.

Currency Mismatch Problem May Be Understated.. (Hyun Shin, The Second Phase of Global Liquidity..., November, 2013) Many emerging market borrowers issue dollar-denominated debt through foreign subsidiaries (say in the UK). By the usual definition (based on the residence of the issuer), the bonds are a liability of the UK entity. But, it s the consolidated balance sheet that matters to the emerging market firm. So, the debt issued via a foreign subsidiary could make the emerging market firm vulnerable to currency mismatch problems.

Hyun Shin argues: Amount of dollar denominated debt from emerging market firms may be greatly understated. This is suggested by evidence that foreign currency debt by nationality can be much larger than foreign debt by the usual residency definition.

Shin conjectures that distinction between external debt according to nationality and residence helps to resolve the taper puzzle: convulsions in emerging markets during taper episode in summer 2013 seem inconsistent with apparently small net external debt position (measured in residence terms) of firms in emerging markets. Less surprising if external debt position is in fact much bigger.

BIS Scenario US raises interest rates. Emerging market exchange rates depreciate. Financial health of emerging market firms compromised. They cut back on investment activity....recessions start. Runs on emerging market banks known to be have made loans to now-questionable emerging market non-financial firms. And so on...

Locomotive Scenario Previous episodes of US interest rate hikes may be playing too big a role in the pessimistic outlook. The circumstances in which the US raises interest rates may make a difference. In present circumstances, Fed has (credibly, I think) committed to only raise rates until well after the US economy has returned to health. Under these circumstances, interest rate hikes occur when the US is firmly in the position of a locomotive, pulling the rest of the world economy forward in its wake.

Which Will it Be: BIS or Locomotive Scenario? Need a model to think about this question. Build in the BIS-type factors that raise concerns about the world economy. Accurately capture the degree of foreign currency indebtedness of financial and nonfinancial firms (i.e., avoid the biases that Hyun Shin is concerned about). Build in the nature of the constraints that cause firms to pull back when their net worth contracts with exchange rate depreciation. Build in the locomotive scenario: Carefully model forward guidance Fed commitment to keep interest rates low even after the US economy has begun to strengthen.

A Model Mihai Copaciu (Romanian Central Bank) Constructs small open economy models in which investment is sustained by purchases of entrepreneurs, who earn their revenues in domestic currency units. Entrepreneurs need financing, and the amount of financing they can get is partially a function of their accumulated net worth. Some of the financing is obtained from abroad. When the currency depreciates, entrepreneurs that borrowed abroad make capital losses and their net worth suffers. They are forced to cut back on expenditures, so that investment crashes, bringing down the economy. Same model also contains the usual features that imply an expansion in the US acts as a locomotive on the rest of the world.

DSGE Models Can Play a Useful Role in Discussions about Fed Exit Strategy New Keynesian Open Economy Models can Capture Two Competing Views. Potential for US take-off to: be a locomotive. cause a loss of net worth by foreign firms/financial institutions and force a cut-back in foreign investment ( BIS scenario ).