Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Similar documents
Introduction to General Equilibrium

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

First Welfare Theorem

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

Second Welfare Theorem

ANSWERS TO ODD NUMBERED EXERCISES IN CHAPTER 3

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Advanced Microeconomics

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

2.9. V = u(x,y) + a(x-f(l x,t x )) + b(y-g(l y,t y )) + c(l o -L x -L y ) + d(t o -T x -T y ) (1) (a) Suggested Answer: V u a 0 (2) u x = -a b 0 (3)

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Adding Production to the Theory

Competitive Equilibrium

Notes on General Equilibrium

(ii) An input requirement set for this technology is clearly not convex as it

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Equilibrium and Pareto Efficiency in an exchange economy

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Lecture #3. General equilibrium

Public Goods and Private Goods

1 Second Welfare Theorem

1 General Equilibrium

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Econ Slides from Lecture 10

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

Sometimes the domains X and Z will be the same, so this might be written:

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Pareto Efficiency (also called Pareto Optimality)

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Lecture 3 - Axioms of Consumer Preference and the Theory of Choice

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

The Existence of Equilibrium in. Infinite-Dimensional Spaces: Some Examples. John H. Boyd III

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

Discussion Papers in Economics

Simon Fraser University, Department of Economics, Econ 201, Prof. Karaivanov FINAL EXAM Answer key

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

3. THE EXCHANGE ECONOMY

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Preferences and Utility

0 Aims of this course

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 12-4/22/10. Core is the most commonly used. The core is the set of all allocations such that no coalition (set of

Consider this problem. A person s utility function depends on consumption and leisure. Of his market time (the complement to leisure), h t

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Axiomatic bargaining. theory

Economics 101. Lecture 2 - The Walrasian Model and Consumer Choice

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Horizontal and Vertical Asymptotes from section 2.6

PhD Qualifier Examination

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Midterm Suggested Solutions 2/8/ (a) The equation of the indifference curve is given by,

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Walrasian Equilibrium in an exchange economy

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

Can everyone benefit from innovation?

1.2 Graphs and Lines. Cartesian Coordinate System

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

Market Failure: Externalities

1 Numbers, Sets, Algebraic Expressions

CS 598RM: Algorithmic Game Theory, Spring Practice Exam Solutions

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Transcription:

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu 1a The following is a Edgeworth box characterization of the Pareto optimal, and the individually rational Pareto optimal, along with some relevant curves. Key curves of 1 budget frontier for prices p = q,q Figure 1: 1a-d Pareto optimal individually rational Pareto optimal equilibrium allocation x 1 = 2,2 and x 2 = 2,2 b If either agent has a boundary allocation then his utility is 0, in which case, the pareto optimal allocation is to give everything to the other agent. There are two such pareto optimal exact and they correspond to the lower left and upper right corners of the Edgeworth box. Since the common utility function is strictly increasing in both variables in the interior, then any pareto optimal allocation involving interior must also be exact. The marginal rate of substitution of the function U = x 1i x 2i is x 2i x 1i. So for any exact allocation w 1 =, x 21, w 2 = 4, 4 x 21 to be Pareto optimal it must be the case that their marginal rates of substitution MRS at this allocation equal: x 21 = 4 x 21 4 The only solutions are when = x 21. Thus the Pareto optimal are { {x1 = s, s, x 2 = 4 s, 4 s} s [0, 4] } The individual rationality condition requires that s 2 3 = U 1 ω 1 and 4 s 2 3 = U 2 ω 2. So the set of individually rational Pareto optimal are { {x1 = s, s, x 2 = 4 s, 4 s} s [ 3, 4 3] } 1

c Define q = p 1 = so that p = q, q. Agent 1 s wealth is 4q and his demand D 1 p is argmax x 21 s.t. + x 21 q 4q,x 21 The constrained maximization problem has a unique solution 2, 2. By symmetry, D 2 p = 2, 2. So {q, q, x 1 = 2, 2, x 2 = 2, 2} is an equilibrium. d Given prices p = p 1,, agent 1 s wealth is p 1 + 3 and his demand D 1 p is argmax x 21 s.t. p 1 + x 21 p 1 + 3,x 21 [ ] p1 argmax 1 + 3 Taking the derivative and solving, we get p1 + 3 D 1 p =, p 1 + 3 and similarly The excess demand function is Ep = D 2 p = 3p1 +, 3p 1 + 4p 4, 4p 4 Setting this equal to 0, we get p 1 =, in which case we have the equilibrium of part c. Thus there are no other equilibria. e Given prices p = p 1,, first assume p 1, 0. Agent 1 s wealth is p 1 + 3 and his demand D 1 p is argmax min{, x 21 } s.t. p 1 + x 21 p 1 + 3,x 21 Since more of one good than the other provides no extra utility but does cost something, a necessary condition for utility maximizing behavior is that = x 21, so the constrained maximization problem can be simplified to so and similarly argmax s.t. p 1 + 3 D 1 p = D 2 p = p1 + 3, p 1 + 3 3p1 +, 3p 1 + 2

Key equilibrium curves of 1 budget frontiers Figure 2: 1e and the excess demand function is 4p Ep = 4, 4p 4 = 0 So we ve found some equilibria. Now assume the price is p 1, 0. Then agent 1 s budget frontier is the vertical line through ω 1 and therefore his demand correspondence is D 1 p = { 1, x 21 x 21 1 } and D 2 p = { 3, x 22 x 22 3 } Since the social is 4, 4, one can see the only way for the excess demand to be 0 is if x 21 = 1 and x 22 = 3. We can do a similar analysis for the case when prices are 0,. Collecting all the results together, we can express the set of equilibria as follows { {p1,, x 1 = p 1 + 3, p 1 + 3, x2 = 3, 3 } p = p1, R 2 + } f Most of the calculations translate easily over from d. First assume p 1, 0. Then p1 + 3 D 1 p =, p 1 + 3 4p1 + D 2 p =, 4p 1 + and the excess demand function is 5p Ep = 5, 5p 4 = 3 p2, p 1 0

curves of 1 These two curves don' t intersect, demonstrating that the price vector p = p 1, where p 1 > 0 does not support an equilibrium. Figure 3: 1f A p = p 1, budget frontier where p 1 > 0 equilibrium The p = 0, budget frontier So any equilibrium must have one of the prices as zero. So first suppose that the scarcer good is free i.e. = 0. Then D 1 p = { 1, x 21 x 21 1 } and D 2 p = { 4, x 22 x 22 4 } Notice there is no way x 21 + x 22 4, so markets can t clear for good 2 and this price supports no equilibrium. The last type of price is when the more common good is free i.e. p 1 = 0. In which case D 1 p = {, 3 3 } and D 2 p = { x 12, 1 x 12 1 } It is certainly possible for + x 12 5 and so the set of equilibria is { {0, p2, x 1 = 3 + r, 3, x 2 = 2 r, 1 } r [0, 1]} Thus, up to normalization there is now a unique equilibrium price p = 0, 1. 2a Using an argument similar to that found in exercise 1, we can show all Pareto optimal are exact. Agent 2 achieves her maximal utility, 4, with her ω 2. So a necessary condition for an exact allocation x 1 =, x 21, x 2 = 5, 5 x 21 to be Pareto optimal 4

and individually rational is that U 2 x 2 = 4. This is equivalent to 5 5 x 21 4. So such an allocation solves: argmax,x 21 x 21 s.t. 5 5 x 21 4 argmax 5 4 5 There is a unique solution = 3, making the exact allocation x = { x 1 = 3, 3, x 2 = 2, 2 } the unique allocation that is Pareto optimal and individually rational for both agents. These two don' t match. budget frontiers curves of 1 boundary of the region of 2 Pareto optimal allocation equilibrium The range of budget frontiers that correspond to equilibrium prices. Figure 4: 2a, b b Given prices p = p 1,, doing the same work as in exercise 1d we know that p D 1 p =, p In equilibrium, after agent 1 has taken what he can afford, the rest of the social must belong to the demand correspondence of agent 2: 9p1 4 5, 5 D 1 p =, 6p 2 p 1 D 2 p = { x 12, x 22 x 12 x 22 4 } 5

Let r = p 1 then since 9p 1 4 2p 1 6 p 1 2 = so the problem reduces to finding all r such that 9r 46 r 4r 9r 46 r 16r 9r 46 r 16r 0 3r 2 + 14r 8 0 3r 2 r + 4 0 r [ 2 3, 4] So the set of equilibria is { {p1,, x 1 = p, p, x 2 = 9p 1 4, 6 p 1 } r = p 1 [ 2 } 2p 1 2p 1 3, 4] There are a number of ways to show that none of the of this set is the Pareto optimal allocation x. Perhaps the most geometric way to show this is to note that all the budget frontiers of the equilibrium prices are steeper than the budget frontier that goes through x. Thus from agent 1 s perspective, x 1 is always out of reach too expensive given the equilibrium prices. Indeed the latter budget frontier has slope 1, whereas the budget frontiers corresponding to 3 the equilibrium prices range from 2 down to 4 remember given prices p 3 1, the budget frontier s slope is p 1. See picture. 3a In order to find the offer curves, we need to find each agent s demand. So fix a price p = p 1,. OC 2 budget frontiers Figure 5: 3a, b and also OC 1 The offer curve for agent 1 is just a single - his. This follows from a combination of two facts: one, he only cares about the first good, and two, all he has is the first 6

good. Thus no matter the prices, he can t afford to get more of the first good - since it s all he has to begin with! Agent 2 s wealth is 2 and her demand D 2 p is argmax x 22 + log x 12 s.t. x 12,x 22 p 1 x 12 + x 22 = 2 2 p 1 x 12 argmax + log x 12 x 12 x 12 = p 1 x 22 = 1 So D 2 p = p 1, 1 and OC 2 is the horizontal line with height 1 in agent 2 s consumption set R 2 ++. b Recall that the two offer curves must intersect in the Edgeworth box for there to be an equilibrium. Since OC 1 OC 2 = Ø there is no equilibrium. 4a Checking for Pareto optimality is straightforward - since the allocation is in the interior, and utilities are smooth, it suffices to check that the MRS equal. In the first exercise we calculated that the MRS at the allocation x 1i, x 2i is x 2i x 1i. Thus the MRS of each agent under the allocation is 1 and so we have Pareto optimality. b The agents 1 and 2 can get together and split their goods down the middle so that each agent receives the allocation 3.5, 3.5 which is strictly preferred to x 1 and x 2. In other words, these two agents would be mutually strictly better off splitting from the proposed allocation, and trading amongst themselves, leaving out agent 3. 7