Midterm Examination: Economics 210A October 2011

Similar documents
1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008

Answers to Econ 210A Midterm, October A. The function f is homogeneous of degree 1/2. To see this, note that for all t > 0 and all (x 1, x 2 )

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Applications I: consumer theory

Solutions to selected exercises from Jehle and Reny (2001): Advanced Microeconomic Theory

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

GS/ECON 5010 section B Answers to Assignment 1 September Q1. Are the preferences described below transitive? Strictly monotonic? Convex?

CONSUMER DEMAND. Consumer Demand

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Microeconomics II Lecture 4. Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply)

PhD Qualifier Examination

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

Notes on Consumer Theory

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Static Problem Set 2 Solutions

1 Convexity, concavity and quasi-concavity. (SB )

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Iowa State University. Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer Homework #5. Solutions

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Econ 5150: Applied Econometrics Empirical Demand Analysis. Sung Y. Park CUHK

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

Additional questions for Chapter 1 - solutions: 1. See Varian, p.20. Notice that Varian set a1=a2. 2. See Varian, p.20.

Mathematical Foundations -1- Constrained Optimization. Constrained Optimization. An intuitive approach 2. First Order Conditions (FOC) 7

a = (a 1; :::a i )

Convex Sets and Functions (part III)

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Math for Economics 1 New York University FINAL EXAM, Fall 2013 VERSION A

x 1 1 and p 1 1 Two points if you just talk about monotonicity (u (c) > 0).

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2002

Chapter 1 Consumer Theory Part II

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Utility Maximization Problem

Differentiation. 1. What is a Derivative? CHAPTER 5

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Week 9: Topics in Consumer Theory (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 2)

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Functions. Paul Schrimpf. October 9, UBC Economics 526. Functions. Paul Schrimpf. Definition and examples. Special types of functions

Solutions to Math 41 First Exam October 15, 2013

A function(al) f is convex if dom f is a convex set, and. f(θx + (1 θ)y) < θf(x) + (1 θ)f(y) f(x) = x 3

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Math 5588 Final Exam Solutions

Demand Theory. Lecture IX and X Utility Maximization (Varian Ch. 7) Federico Trionfetti

Stat 8931 (Exponential Families) Lecture Notes The Eggplant that Ate Chicago (the Notes that Got out of Hand) Charles J. Geyer November 2, 2016

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo

Optimization. Charles J. Geyer School of Statistics University of Minnesota. Stat 8054 Lecture Notes

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2005

Linear and non-linear programming

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

164 Final Solutions 1

Rules of Differentiation

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, February 21st, 2018

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 29 September 2004.

Partial Solutions to Homework 2

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Utility Maximization Problem. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 2

Competitive Consumer Demand 1

Generalized Convexity in Economics

Convexity in R n. The following lemma will be needed in a while. Lemma 1 Let x E, u R n. If τ I(x, u), τ 0, define. f(x + τu) f(x). τ.

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2: Demand Theory

Consumer Theory. Ichiro Obara. October 8, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Consumer Theory October 8, / 51

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Homework #2

PS4-Solution. Mehrdad Esfahani. Fall Arizona State University. Question 1 Question 2 Question 3 Question 4 Question 5

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Probability inequalities 11

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

First Midterm Exam. You are responsible for upholding the University of Maryland Honor Code while taking this exam.

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Theory of Value Fall 2017

ECE580 Fall 2015 Solution to Midterm Exam 1 October 23, Please leave fractions as fractions, but simplify them, etc.

Lecture Notes: Math Refresher 1

1.3 The Indirect Utility Function

Advanced Microeconomics

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Chapter 1 - Preference and choice

Transcription:

Midterm Examination: Economics 210A October 2011 The exam has 6 questions. Answer as many as you can. Good luck. 1) A) Must every quasi-concave function must be concave? If so, prove it. If not, provide a counterexample. (In all answers where you provide a counterexample, you must show that your example is really a counterexample.) Answer: Not every quasi-concave function is concave. Here is a counterexample. Define the function F with domain R + (the positive real numbers.) such that F (x) = x 2. We show two things: 1) This function is quasi-concave. 1 To see this, note that F is a strictly increasing function on R +. Therefore if F (y) F (x), it must be that y x and hence for any t [0, 1], ty + (1 t)x x. Since F is an increasing function, it follows that F (ty + (1 t)x) F (x). Therefore F is quasi-concave. 2) The function F is not concave. To see this, note that F (2) = 4 and F (0) = 0, but F ( 1 2 2 + 1 2 0) = F (1) = 1 1 2 F (2) + 1 F (0) = 2. 2 This cannot be the case if F is a concave function. B) Must every concave function be quasi-concave? If so, prove it. If not, provide a counterexample. Answer: Every concave function is quasi-concave. Proof. If f is concave, its domain is a convex set A. For all x and y in A, and t between 0 and 1, if f(tx + (1 t)y) tf(x) + (1 t)f(y). (1) From the Expression 1 it follows that f(tx + (1 t)y) f(y) + t (f(x) f(y)). (2) If f(x) f(y), then it follows from Expression 2 that which means that f is quasi-concave. f(tx + (1 t)y) f(y). (3) 1 By the way, F (x) = x 2 defined on the entire real line would not be quasi-concave. Can you show this? 1

2) Let F and G be real-valued concave functions with the same domain, A. Define the function H so that for all x A, H(x) = F (x) + G(x). Is H a concave function? If so, prove it. If not, provide a counterexample. Answer: Since F and G are concave functions with domain A, it must be that if x A and y A, then for all t between 0 and 1, and F (tx + (1 t)y) tf (x) + (1 t)f (y) G(tx + (1 t)y) tg(x) + (1 t)g(y) Given these two inequalities, we see that H (tx + (1 t)y) = F (tx + (1 t)y) + G(tx + (1 t)y) tf (x) + (1 t)f (y) + tg(x) + (1 t)g(y) = t (F (x) + G(x)) + (1 t) (F (y) + G(y)) = th(x) + (1 t)h(y) By definition, the left side of Expression 4 equals H(tx + (1 t)y). The right side of Expression 4 equals tf (x) + tg(x) + (1 t)f (y) + (1 t)g(y) = th(x) + (1 t)hy ). Therefore H(tx + (1 t)y th(x) + (1 t)h(y) for all t between 0 and 1, which means that H is a concave function. 3 Let F and G be real-valued concave functions with the same domain, A. Define the function H so that for all x A, H(x) = F (x)g(x). A) Is H a concave function? If so, prove it. If not, provide a counterexample. Answer: H is not necessarily concave. For example, let A be the real line and let F (x) = x and G(x) = x. Both F and G are concave functions. But H(x) = x 2. If a function of a single real variable is concave, its second derivative is negative or zero everywhere. But H (x) = 2 > 0, so H is not a concave function. B) Is H a quasi-concave function? If so, prove it. if not, provide a counterexample. Answer: H is not in general quasi-concave, but it will be if F (x) > 0 and G(x) > 0 for all x A. If this is the case, then ln H(x) = ln F (x) + ln G(x). Now ln F (x) and ln G(x) are concave 2

functions (because a concave function of a concave function is concave). Therefore ln H(x) which is the sum of two concave functions is concave. It follows that H(x) is a monotone transformation of a concave function and hence is quasi-concave. On the other hand, if one of these functions is negative valued, ln H is not well-defined, so this argument doesn t work and in fact H(x) doesn t have to be quasi-concave when F and G are concave. For example, suppose that A is the set of all real numbers and F (x) = 1 for all x, while and G(x) = x 2. Both of these functions are concave, since their second derivatives are non-positive for all x. Then H(x) = G(x) = x 2. This function is not quasi-concave. To see this, note that H(1) = H( 1) = 1, but H ( 1 1 + 1 2 2 ( 1)) = H(0) = 0 < H(1). 4) A consumer has preferences represented by the utility function U(x 1, x 2 ) = x 1 + x 2 + 2x 1/2 2. Good 1 is the numeraire and has price 1. The price of good 2 is p 2 and the consumer s income is m. A) Find this consumer s Marshallian demands for goods 1 and 2 as a function of p 2 and m. Be careful to account for corner solutions if there are any. Answer:The marginal rate of substitution between good 2 and good 1 is 1 + x 1/2 2 > 1. At an interior solution, it must be that p 2 = 1 + x 1/2 2. This is possible only if p 2 > 1. If the consumer chooses positive amounts of both goods, the Marshallian demands are 1 x 2 (1, p 2, m) =. p 2 1 and 1 x 1 (1, p 2, m) = m p 2. p 2 1 There is positive consumption of good 1 if and only if p 2 > 1 and ( ) m > p 1 2. 2 p 2 1 If consumption of good 1 is zero, then x2 (1, p 2, m) = m/p 2 and x 1 (1, p 2, m) = 0. Consumption of good 2 is always positive, since the marginal rate of substitution approaches infinity as x 2 approaches zero. B) Use your solution to Part A and the relevant homogeneity property of Marshallian demand to find this consumer s demands for goods 1 and 2 for arbitrary 3

non-negative prices p 1, p 2, and income m. (Simplify your expressions for answers as much as possible.) Answer: Since demand is homogeneous of degree zero in prices and income, it must be that x i (p 1, p 2, m) = x i (1, p 2 p 1, m p 1 ) Therefore it follows from the answers to Part A that at an interior solution, x 2 (p 1, p 2, m) = 1 2 p 2 = p 1 1 x 1 (p 1, p 2, m) = m p 2 1 2 p p 1 p 2 = m p 1p 2 1 p 1 1 p 1 C) Find this consumer s Hicksian demand functions h 1 (p 1, p 2, u) and h 2 (p 1, p 2, u). Be careful to account for corner solutions if there are any. and Answer: At an interior solution, h 2 (p 1, p 2, u) = ( h 1 (p 1, p 2, u) = u h 2 (p 1, p 2, u) 2h 2 (p 1, p 2, m) 1/2 ( ) = u 2 ) 2 = u ( + 1 1 = u + 1 ( ) 2 ) 2 if From 4 we see that there will be an interior solution if and only u + 1 >. 4

If u + 1 <, then h 1 (p 1, p 2, u) = 0 and u = h 2 (p 1, p 2, u) + 2 h 2 (p 1, p 2, u). The right side of the second equation is a strictly increasing function of h 2, which means that for any specified (p 1, p 2, u), there is a unique solution for h 2 (p 1, p 2, u). However, this solution does not have a simple closed form expression. D) Find this consumer s expenditure function e(p 1, p 2, u). Answer: e(p 1, p 2, u) = p 1 h(p 1, p 2, u) + p 2 h 2 (p 1, p 2, y). We can write this out in detailed form using the results of Section C. For an interior solution, we have e(p 1, p 2, u) = p 1 u + 1 + p 2 = p 1 (u + 1) + p 2p 2 1 p 1 p 2 2 = p 1 (u + 1) p 1p 2 (4) E) Verify that Shephard s lemma applies in this case. Answer: We will show this for the case of interior solutions. According to Shephard s lemma, e(p 1, p 2, u) p i = h i (p 1, p 2, u). Differentiating the expression in Part D with respect to p 2, we have e(p 1, p 2, u) p 2 = ( )p 1 + p 1 p 2 = We found in part C that h 2 (p 1, p 2 ) = p 2 1. p 2 1.

Thus we see that Shephard s lemma applies for good 2. Differentiating the expression in Part D with respect to p 1, we have e(p 1, p 2, u) = u 1 + 1 ( )p 2 + p 1 p 2 p 1 p 2 = u + 1 ( ) We found in Part C that p 2 h 1 (p 1, p 2, u) = u + 1. ( ) This verifies that Shephard s lemma holds for good 2. ) A consumer has utility function u(x 1, x 2 ) = min{v 1 (x 1, x 2 ), v 2 (x 1, x 2 )} where v 1 and v 2 are both quasi-concave functions Is u quasi-concave? prove it. If not, provide a counterexample. If so, Answer: Credit to Irving Fernandez and Serena Canaan for the most elegant answers to this one. Note that the assumption that v i is concave means that for i = 1, 2, v i (tx + (1 t)y) min{v i (x), v i (y)}. Now u(tx + (1 t)y) = min{v 1 (tx + (1 t)y, v 2 (tx + (1 t)y)} min{min{v 1 (x), v 1 (y)}, min{min{v 2 (x), v 2 (y)} = min{min{v 1 (x), v 2 (x)}, min{min{v 1 (y), v 2 (y)} = min{u(x), u(y)} This implies that u is quasi-concave. The clever key step in this argument is the step from line 2 to line 3. Can you explain why one is justified in taking this step? 6) A sculpture is placed on top of a horizontal grid. The height of the sculpture above the point on the grid with coordinates (x 1, x 2 ) is x 2 1 3x 1 x 2 +x 2 2. An ant is crawling on the surface of the sculpture. 6

A) If the ant is initially at the point directly above the point (2, 1) on the grid, what is the directional derivative of the height of the ant if it is crawling on the surface of the sculpture in the direction ( 1 2, ) as measured on the grid? Answer: The gradient of the height of the sculpture at the point (2, 1) is (2x 1 3x 2, 3x 1 + 2x 2 ) = (1, 4). The directional derivative in the direction ( 1 2, ) is the inner product of this directional vector with the gradient. This is equal to 7. B) In what direction on the surface should the ant crawl if it wants to climb most steeply? (Hint: Directions should be described by a vector whose length is 1 unit.) Answer: If the ant wants to climb most steeply, it should climb in the direction of the gradient. That direction is ( ) 1, 4. C)In what direction should it crawl if it wants to descend most steeply? Answer: To descend most steeply, it should crawl in the opposite direction from the gradient. This is ( 1 4, ). D) If the ant is moving along the surface of the statue in the direction of steepest climb at the rate of one unit per second, at what rate is its height above the ground increasing? Answer: The answer is the inner product of the gradient with the vector representing the direction of steepest climb. The initial rate of ascent if the ant crawls in the direction of the gradient is the inner product of the gradient vector (1, 4) with the direction of steepest ascent which is ( ) 1, 4. This inner product is equal to 1 1 + ( 4) 4 =. 7