Hans Zenger University of Munich. Abstract

Similar documents
EconS Vertical Integration

A Solution to the Problem of Externalities When Agents Are Well-Informed

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

EconS Sequential Competition

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

Solutions to problem set 11 (due Tuesday, April 29 1st, before class)

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Notes on the Mussa-Rosen duopoly model

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Modeling Technological Change

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Mixed oligopoly in a two-dimensional city y

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Research and Development

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Advanced Microeconomics Problem Set 1

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Answer Key: Problem Set 1

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Cumulative Harm, Products Liability, and Bilateral Care* Andrew F. Daughety and Jennifer F. Reinganum

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Part I: Exercise of Monopoly Power. Chapter 1: Monopoly. Two assumptions: A1. Quality of goods is known by consumers; A2. No price discrimination.

Congestion Externality and Autonomous Vehicles

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

9 A Class of Dynamic Games of Incomplete Information:

Educjatipnal. L a d ie s * COBNWALILI.S H IG H SCHOOL. I F O R G IR L S A n B k i n d e r g a r t e n.

Hotelling Meets Weber

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Advanced Microeconomics

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Low-Quality Leadership in a Vertically Differentiated Duopoly with Cournot Competition

Exclusive contracts and market dominance

WARWICK ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

Dynamic Merger Review

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

a = (a 1; :::a i )

Flexible vs Dedicate Technologies in a mixed duopoly

Economic Growth: Lectures 10 and 11, Endogenous Technological Change

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Basics of Game Theory

Price and Quantity Competition in Di erentiated Oligopoly Revisited

Taxation and supply-function equilibrium

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

A Unified Model of Spatial Price Discrimination

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #10 - Externalities

a s*:?:; -A: le London Dyers ^CleanefSt * S^d. per Y ard. -P W ..n 1 0, , c t o b e e d n e sd *B A J IllW6fAi>,EB. E D U ^ T IG r?

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Implicit Function Theorem: One Equation

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Durable goods monopolist

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Price setting on a network

Among the available options: horizontal separation (HS) and vertical separation (VS)

Price Discrimination in Quantity Setting Oligopoly

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Successive Monopolies with Endogenous Quality

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Carrot and stick games

1 Games in Normal Form (Strategic Form)

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Internation1al Trade

EconS Cost Structures

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 2, Review of Endogenous Growth: Expanding Variety Models

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

National Treatment in International Agreements on. Intellectual Property

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

A Note of Caution on Using Hotelling Models in Platform Markets

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Microeconomic Theory I Assignment #7 - Answer key

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Transcription:

The Optimal Regulation of Product Quality under Monopoly Hans Zenger University of Munich Abstract This paper characterizes the optimal quality regulation of a monopolist when quality is observable. In contrast to Sheshinski (1976) it is shown that a minimum quality standard may be desirable even if it induces the firm to reduce output. Financial support from the German Research Foundation through grant SFB/TR 15 is gratefully acknowledged. Citation: Zenger, Hans, (26) "The Optimal Regulation of Product Quality under Monopoly." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 12, No. 13 pp. 1-4 Submitted: November 4, 26. Accepted: December 13, 26. URL: http://economicsbulletin.vanderbilt.edu/26/volume12/eb-6l129a.pdf

1 Introduction It has long been known that the provision of product quality under monopoly is distorted away from the social optimum even if quality is observable. In particular, Spence (1975) and Sheshinski s (1976) by now classic papers have shown that a monopolist chooses the level of quality that suits the marginal consumer, while a social planner takes the valuations of all consumers into account. Therefore, to the extent that inframarginal consumers have a higher (lower) valuation for quality than marginal consumers, a monopolist provides too little (too much) quality, given the size of demand. 1 In principle, this market failure can be corrected by imposing the welfare maximizing price and quality on the rm. In practice, however, it is often not feasible or desirable to regulate the price. One prominent reason is that the prospect of pro ts is what gives rms an incentive to provide desired products in the rst place. Hence, Sheshinski (1976) analyzes the optimal quality regulation of a monopoly in the absence of price interventions. 2 Two basic cases are distinguished. When quality and quantity are complements so that p xq >, the optimal regulation can not generally be determined. However, when they are substitutes (p xq < ), there is a clear policy implication (Sheshinski 1976, p. 135): 3 "... when p xq < the regulator, starting from the monopoly equilibrium (^x; ^q), should seek to raise quality levels if m q c xq > but to lower them if m q c xq <..." Alas, this result, which is the central proposition for the quality regulation of a monopolist, is wrong. In fact, the direction of quality regulation does not change with the sign of the e ect of a quality increase on the monopolist s marginal pro t (m q c xq in Sheshinski s model). Rather, the optimal policy can be described as follows: A minimum quality regulation improves welfare by providing a quality level that is closer to consumers wants. However, if the price is unregulated, the monopolist responds to the regulation by increasing prices. If this price increase is so high that demand decreases despite higher quality, there is an additional monopoly distortion that counters the positive e ect of the regulation. As a consequence, if the demand reduction is very strong, the regulator should reduce the level of quality the monopolist provides instead of increasing it. The aim of this note is to demonstrate this claim within Sheshinski s model. 2 The Model I will use Sheshinski s original formulation to derive the optimal regulatory policy. There is a monopolist producing a good of quality q which he sells for price p. Inverse demand is 1 The argument extends to oligopolistic market structures. 2 Sheshinski (1976) focusses on the case where quality is observable and the rm is a single-product monopolist. In alternative settings, di erent results may obtain (see for instance the survey by Sappington, 25). 3 Fortunately, the latter case seems to be more relevant in practice. p xq < means that consumers with a higher valuation for a product also have a higher valuation for quality improvements. This is routinely assumed in models of product di erentiation and price discrimination (e.g., Mussa and Rosen, 1978, and Besanko, Donnenfeld, and White, 1987). 1

given by p(x; q) where x denotes the quantity sold. It is assumed that p x (x; q) <, p q (x; q) > and p xq <. 4 Total costs are denoted by c(x; q) with c x (x; q) > and c q (x; q) >. Firm and regulatory authority play a two-stage game. In stage one the regulator chooses q to maximize welfare taking into account that the monopolist chooses x to maximize pro t in stage two. The rm s pro t function is (x; q) = p(x; q)x c(x; q). Solving the game by backward induction the second stage outcome is therefore given by the rst order condition x (x; q) = p x (x; q)x + p(x; q) c x (x; q) =. (1) The appropriate second order condition xx (x; q) < will be assumed to hold. In stage one the regulator maximizes the welfare function V (x(q); q) = Z x(q) p(z; q)dz c(x(q); q). (2) This yields the rst order condition dv dq = (p c x) dx dq + Z x p q (z; q)dz c q = (3) where the appropriate second order condition d 2 V=dq 2 < is again assumed to be ful lled. This gives us the (second best) regulatory equilibrium (x ; q ). We will have to compare this with an unregulated situation. Without regulation the producer chooses quality directly to maximize pro ts. The market outcome (^x; ^q) is characterized by (1) and the rst order condition with respect to q, Additional second order conditions are qq < and xx qq hold. q (x; q) = p q (x; q)x c q (x; q) =. (4) 2 xq > which are again assumed to The most convenient way of comparing q and ^q is by representing the two solutions graphically in an (x; q) plane. (^x; ^q) is determined by the intersection of the curves x = and q =, given by equations (1) and (4). From (1) we can infer the slope of the curve x = as dq dx x= = xx xq = p xxx + 2p x c xx p xq x + p q c xq. (5) By the second order condition this has the same sign as xq, the marginal impact of q on (1). Figure 1 (a) displays the case where xq > (with an upward sloping curve x = ) while the case xq < is represented in Figure 1 (b) (with a downward sloping curve x = ). Using (4), the slope of the curve q = is found to be dq dx 4 Subscripts denote partial derivatives. q= = xq qq = p xqx + p q c xq p qq x c qq (6) 2

Figure 1: The regulatory solution which (again by the second order condition) also has the same sign as xq. Simple algebra shows that dq=dxj > dq=dxj x= is equivalent to q= xx qq > 2 xq (when xq > ), respectively xx qq < 2 xq (when xq < ). As we know xx qq > 2 xq to be true from the second order conditions, the curve x = is steeper than the curve q = around (^x; ^q) in both cases. Figure 1 presents the unregulated solution graphically. (x ; q ) are jointly determined by the intersection of the curves x = and dv=dq = given by (1) and (3). Characterizing the latter turns out to be a bit more tedious. What complicates matters is that dv=dq = takes the impact of q on x into account. In order to determine its position, it is helpful to rst derive the curve V q = which leaves aside this indirect e ect. From (2) we nd V q = Z x p q (z; q)dz c q =. (7) Since by assumption p xq <, it follows that p q (z; q) > p q (x; q) for all q and z < x. Therefore, V q = R x p q(z; q)dz c q (x; q) > p q (x; q)x c q (x; q) = q. That is, whenever V q =, we have q <. As qq <, q must be decreased to reach q = given x. In other words, the curve V q = lies everywhere above the curve q =. This is shown in Figure 1 (a) and (b). Next we will determine the position of dv=dq = : Plugging (1) and (7) into (3) we nd that dv=dq = p x x dx=dq + V q =. Using (5) and the fact that p x <, we have sign[ p x x dx=dq] = sign[dx=dq] = sign[ xq ]. Assume rst that xq > (Figure 1 (a)). Then from an arbitrary (x; q) that satis es V q =, q must be increased given x to reach dv=dq = if and only if V qq <. 5 Note that V qq < is a second order condition for the rst best solution (x ; q ) where both quantity and quality are regulated. Hence, it is a mild requirement and I follow Sheshinski (1976) in assuming it. From the previous arguments it can be concluded that dv=dq = lies above V q =. As Figure 1 (a) shows, we therefore have q > ^q and x > ^x at the intersection of dv=dq = and x =. 5 At (x; q) satisfying V q = we must decrease V q to reach dv=dq = as dv=dq > V q =. When V qq < such a decrease implies an increase in q. 3

Next assume xq < (Figure 1 (b)). By a similar argument we nd that dv=dq = lies below V q =. Clearly, how much it lies below depends on the magnitude of xq. Figure 1 (b) presents two possibilities, the curve dv=dq = ( xq small) and the curve dv=dq = ( xq large), demonstrating that we may either have q > ^q and x < ^x or q < ^q and x > ^x, contradicting the mistaken result in Sheshinski (1976) who claims that one can always conclude q < ^q and x > ^x. The di erence is seen most clearly when xq =. In this case a regulatory intervention in q does not alter the monopolist s quantity choice. Hence, an in nitesimal increase in q has the welfare improving impact of increased quality without side-e ects. 6 There is no e ect on welfare regarding the monopoly quantity distortion, so the overall e ect is clearly positive while Sheshinski s result suggests that there is no impact on welfare. When xq >, a minimum quality requirement even has a positive e ect on the monopoly distortion through increased output. Finally, if xq <, then a small quality increase unfortunately triggers a larger monopoly distortion as monopoly prices go up too much to sustain the demand level. As long as the positive welfare e ect of a quality increase is strong enough, however, there is scope for a minimum quality regulation even in this case. References [1] Besanko, D., S. Donnenfeld and L.J. White (1987). "Monopoly and Quality Distortion: E ects and Remedies", Quarterly Journal of Economics 12, 743-768 [2] Mussa, M. and S. Rosen (1978). "Monopoly and Product Quality", Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 31-17 [3] Sappington, D. (25). "Regulating Service Quality: A Survey", Journal of Regulatory Economics 27, 123-154 [4] Sheshinski, E. (1976). "Price, Quality and Quantity Regulation in Monopoly Situations", Economica 43, 127-137 [5] Spence, M. (1975). "Monopoly, Quality, and Regulation", Bell Journal of Economics 6, 417-429 6 As noted earlier, Spence (1975) and Sheshinski (1976) show that a monopolist underprovides quality given output when p xq <. 4