CHAOTIC BEHAVIOR IN A TWO-DIMENSIONAL BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL

Similar documents
Routes to Complexity in a Macroeconomic Model Described by a Noninvertible Triangular Map

Spectral and Dynamical Invariants in a Complete Clustered Network

Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot duopoly game with heterogeneous players

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

KLEINIAN GROUPS AND HOLOMORPHIC DYNAMICS

WHAT IS A CHAOTIC ATTRACTOR?

UNIVERSITY of LIMERICK

INVARIANT CURVES AND FOCAL POINTS IN A LYNESS ITERATIVE PROCESS

ELEMENTARY PROOF OF THE CONTINUITY OF THE TOPOLOGICAL ENTROPY AT θ = 1001 IN THE MILNOR THURSTON WORLD

Dynamical Systems. Pierre N.V. Tu. An Introduction with Applications in Economics and Biology Second Revised and Enlarged Edition.

Invariant densities for piecewise linear maps

On Riddled Sets and Bifurcations of Chaotic Attractors

Self Similarity of Sousa Ramos s Trees and Mira s Boxes Within the Boxes

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

Homoclinic tangles associated with closed invariant curves in families of 2D maps

Dynamic IS-LM model with Philips Curve and International Trade

Quaderni di Dipartimento. Double route to chaos in an heterogeneous triopoly game. Ahmad Naimzada (Università di Milano-Bicocca)

Hicks trade cycle revisited: cycles and bifurcations

Artin-Mazur Zeta Function on Trees with Infinite Edges

Entropy production for a class of inverse SRB measures

Center Bifurcation of a point on the Poincaré Equator

Chaos, Solitons and Fractals

INTRICATE ASSET PRICE

A Final Bifurcation in a simple duopoly model

CHAOTIC UNIMODAL AND BIMODAL MAPS

Smooth Ergodic Theory and Nonuniformly Hyperbolic Dynamics

PROGRAM. Sunday, September 7. Monday, September 8

The Sine Map. Jory Griffin. May 1, 2013

DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS. I Clark: Robinson. Stability, Symbolic Dynamics, and Chaos. CRC Press Boca Raton Ann Arbor London Tokyo

Dynamical Systems and Chaos Part I: Theoretical Techniques. Lecture 4: Discrete systems + Chaos. Ilya Potapov Mathematics Department, TUT Room TD325

Chapter 23. Predicting Chaos The Shift Map and Symbolic Dynamics

Multistability and cyclic attractors in duopoly games

Discussion Paper Series No.51. Complexity yields benefits: An example of a heterogeneous duopoly market. Yasuo Nonaka.

Hunting Admissible Kneading pairs of a Real Rational Map

A modification of Kaldor-Kalecki model and its analysis

General stuttering Beta(p, q) Cantor-like random sets

Nonlinear Multiplier-Accelerator Model with Investment and Consumption Delays

Maps with vanishing denominator explained through applications in Economics

Transitions to Chaos in a 3-Dimensional Map

ON THE EXISTENCE OF HOPF BIFURCATION IN AN OPEN ECONOMY MODEL

On the Topological Entropy of Some Skew-Product Maps

Production, Capital Stock and Price Dynamics in A Simple Model of Closed Economy *

ONE DIMENSIONAL CHAOTIC DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS

Spectrum of the Laplacian on hyperbolic surfaces

Synchronization in von Bertalanffy s models

BASINS OF ATTRACTION FOR TRIPLE LOGISTIC MAPS. 1. Introduction

UNIVERSIDADE DE SÃO PAULO

An economic Economical Model with Allee

A MINIMAL 2-D QUADRATIC MAP WITH QUASI-PERIODIC ROUTE TO CHAOS

Delay Kaldor-Kalecki Model Revisited. September 2014

Chaos in the Dynamics of the Family of Mappings f c (x) = x 2 x + c

Detecting Macroeconomic Chaos Juan D. Montoro & Jose V. Paz Department of Applied Economics, Umversidad de Valencia,

Kneading Sequences for Unimodal Expanding Maps of the Interval

SHADOWING PROPERTY FOR INDUCED SET-VALUED DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS OF SOME EXPANSIVE MAPS

Dynamical Behavior of Logistic Equation through Symbiosis Model

EXISTENCE OF CONJUGACIES AND STABLE MANIFOLDS VIA SUSPENSIONS

Invariant manifolds of the Bonhoeffer-van der Pol oscillator

Period-doubling cascades of a Silnikov equation

ZERO-HOPF BIFURCATION FOR A CLASS OF LORENZ-TYPE SYSTEMS

Research Article Local and Global Dynamics in a Discrete Time Growth Model with Nonconcave Production Function

L Enseignement Mathématique, t. 40 (1994), p AN ERGODIC ADDING MACHINE ON THE CANTOR SET. by Peter COLLAS and David KLEIN

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction

Global Attractivity, Oscillations and Chaos in A Class of Nonlinear, Second Order Difference Equations

A Hicksian multiplier-accelerator model with floor determined by capital stock

A dynamic marketing model with best reply and inertia

Can two chaotic systems make an order?

APPLIED SYMBOLIC DYNAMICS AND CHAOS

Reconstruction Deconstruction:

Stable cycles in a Cournot duopoly model of Kopel

Personal notes on renormalization

Braids of entangled particle trajectories

HOPF BIFURCATION AND HETEROCLINIC CYCLES IN A CLASS OF D 2 EQUIVARIANT SYSTEMS

Mathematical Properties of a Combined Cournot-Stackelberg Model

Economics 2: Growth (Growth in the Solow Model)

Global Bifurcations in a Three-Dimensional Financial Model of Bull and Bear Interactions

Construction of four dimensional chaotic finance model and its applications

Analysis of nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players

Chaotic Dynamics and Synchronization of Cournot Duopoly Game with a Logarithmic Demand Function

THE SET OF RECURRENT POINTS OF A CONTINUOUS SELF-MAP ON AN INTERVAL AND STRONG CHAOS

An Analysis of Nondifferentiable Models of and DPCM Systems From the Perspective of Noninvertible Map Theory

Maximum topological entropy of permutations and cycles. Deborah King. University of Melbourne. Australia

A Note on the Generalized Shift Map

Complete Synchronization, Anti-synchronization and Hybrid Synchronization Between Two Different 4D Nonlinear Dynamical Systems

INVESTIGATION OF CHAOTICITY OF THE GENERALIZED SHIFT MAP UNDER A NEW DEFINITION OF CHAOS AND COMPARE WITH SHIFT MAP

Local Bifurcations and Global Dynamics in a Solow-type Endogenous Business Cycles Model

ESTIMATES OF TOPOLOGICAL ENTROPY OF CONTINUOUS MAPS WITH APPLICATIONS

B5.6 Nonlinear Systems

An Undergraduate s Guide to the Hartman-Grobman and Poincaré-Bendixon Theorems

The Nonlinear Real Interest Rate Growth Model : USA

Acceleration of Levenberg-Marquardt method training of chaotic systems fuzzy modeling

TOPOLOGICAL ENTROPY FOR DIFFERENTIABLE MAPS OF INTERVALS

Research Article Topological Entropy of Cournot-Puu Duopoly

HOMEWORK #1 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, November 3 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Research Article A Dynamic Economic Model with Discrete Time and Consumer Sentiment

1.Introduction: 2. The Model. Key words: Prey, Predator, Seasonality, Stability, Bifurcations, Chaos.

Universidade Técnica de Lisboa, Rua do Quelhas 6, Lisboa, Portugal

Exact Solutions for the Nonlinear (2+1)-Dimensional Davey-Stewartson Equation Using the Generalized ( G. )-Expansion Method

A Metzlerian business cycle model with nonlinear heterogeneous expectations

FAMILIES OF TRANSITIVE MAPS ON R WITH HORIZONTAL ASYMPTOTES

An alternative use of the Verdoorn law at the Portuguese nuts II level

Transcription:

CHAOTIC BEHAVIOR IN A TWO-DIMENSIONAL BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL CRISTINA JANUÁRIO Department of Chemistry, Mathematics Unit, Instituto Superior de Engenharia de Lisboa, Rua Conselheiro Emídio Navarro, 1949-014 Lisboa, Portugal E-mail: cjanuario@deq.isel.ipl.pt CLARA GRÁCIO Department of Mathematics, Universidade de Évora, Rua Romão Ramalho, 59, 00-585 Évora, Portugal E-mail: mgracio@uevora.pt J. SOUSA RAMOS Department of Mathematics, Instituto Superior Técnico, Av. Rovisco Pais 1, 1049-001 Lisboa, Portugal E-mail: sramos@math.ist.utl.pt We consider a discrete-time economic model which is a particular case of the Kaldor-type business cycle model and it is described by a two-dimensional dynamical system. Under certain conditions the map can be reduced to a skew map whose components, the base and the fiber map, both have entropy. Our proposal is to study and measure the complexity of the system using symbolic dynamics techniques and the topological entropy. 1. Introduction The manifestation of nonlinear effects can be easily detected in almost all real world systems. In the particular case of economics, many of its important fluctuations arise out of nonlinear dynamic phenomena. The most interesting theories of business cycles in the Keynesian vein are the ones that utilizes non-linear functions. In this work we present a variation of the model considered by Bischi et al. 2 and Dieci et al. 3. It departs from a discrete time-version of the Kaldor model described by a two-dimensional system. We intend to introduce nonlinearity in a variable of the model in order to study the effect it produces. 1

2 Firstly, consider the Kaldor-type business cycle model { Yt+1 Y t = α(i t S t ) K t+1 = (1 δ)k t + I t (1) which depends on four variables, Y, K, I and S, representing, respectively, income, capital stock, investment and savings. We have also two parameters, α and δ, verifying the inequalities, α > 0 and 0 < δ < 1. The parameter α represents the speed of reaction to the excess demand and δ is the capital stock depreciation rate. The function describing investment is assumed to take the form of an increasing arc tangent type function of income, like suggested in Bischi et al. 2 and Dieci et al. 3. In order to introduce nonlinearity to the capital stock variable we shall propose it as a decreasing trigonometric function of the sin type (see Fig.1) instead of being just a linear decreasing function. Therefore, let ( σµ ) I t = σµ + γ 1 δ K t + arctan(y t µ) β sin(0.2 K t µ), (2) where the parameters σ and δ are such that 0 < σ, δ < 1 and the parameters β, γ 1, µ, σ are positive (β, γ 1, µ, σ > 0). I K Figure 1. Effect of the nonlinearity in the capital stock variable, K. Concerning the savings function, we also modify the assumption of proportionality to the income assuming, as in many versions of the Kaldor business cycle models, that savings are nonlinear. We consider that it depends also on the capital stock in a decreasing way: ( σµ ) S t = σy t + γ 2 δ K t β sin(0.2 K t µ), (3)

3 with γ 2 a positive parameter. Replacing expressions (2) and (3) in (1) and considering the particularly interesting case when γ 1 = γ 2 = γ we get the following two dimensional system in income and capital stock variables: { Yt+1 = Y t + ασµ + α arctan(y t µ) ασy t K t+1 = (1 δ)k t + σµ + γ ( σµ δ K ) t + arctan(yt µ) β sin(0.2 K t µ). (4) This paper is organized as follows: in Section 2 we present the model and the main results concerning triangular maps and the topological entropy. In Section 3 we explore its complex dynamic behavior. We also illustrate the computation of the topological invariant in an example and finally in Section 4 we make some final considerations. 2. The model and some considerations about triangular maps Let us change the notation in the model (4) to: y := Y and k := K. We consider a family of two-dimensional continuously differentiable maps F : R 2 R 2 given by F : ( y k ) ( = y + ασµ + α arctan(y µ) ασy (1 δ)k + σµ + γ ( σµ δ k) + arctan(y µ) β sin(0.2 k µ) (5) where σ, δ, β, γ, µ, σ are real parameters such that α > 0, 0 < σ < 1, µ > 0, 0 < δ < 1, γ > 0, β > 0. This dynamical system is generated by a skew map (triangular map) since it has the form F (y, k) = (f (y), g (y, k)), that is, the first component doesn t depend on the second variable. So, from the economic point of view, the dynamics of income is only affected by income itself. The map f is called the basis map and g is called the fiber map. Due to this triangular structure it is possible to apply mathematical methods to compute relevant quantities that characterize the system as chaotic or non chaotic. In Fig.2 we present the graphical representation of the map F for some values of the parameters. Let P = {x 0, x 1,..., x p 1 } be a periodic orbit of period p of the map f such that f (x i ) = x i+1 for i = 0,..., p 2 and f (x p 1 ) = x 0. We define the map g p : Y Y as g p (y) = g (x p 1, g (x p 2,...g (x 1, g (x 0, y))...)). (6) If Q = {y 0, y 1,..., y q 1 } is a periodic orbit of period q of the map g p such ),

4 k 68.5 68 67.5 67 a 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 y 90 88 86 k 84 82 80 b 94 96 98 100 102 104 106 y Figure 2. Graphical representation of the map F for some values of the parameters. In plot a) α = 10, µ = 100, σ = 0.3, δ = 0.4, β = 9.5, γ = 1.0 and in plot b) α = 10, µ = 100, σ = 0.32, δ = 0.4, β = 9.5, γ = 0.8. that g p (y i ) = y i+1 for i = 0,..., q 2 and g p (y p 1 ) = y 0, we can define the product P.Q as the set containing the p.q pairs: (x 0, y 0 ) (x 1, g (x 0, y 0 ))... (x p 1, g (x p 2,...g (x 1, g (x 0, y 0 ))...)) (x 0, y 1 ) (x 1, g (x 0, y 1 ))... (x p 1, g (x p 2,...g (x 1, g (x 0, y 1 ))...))...... (x 0, y q 1 ) (x 1, g (x 0, y q 1 ))... (x p 1, g (x p 2,...g (x 1, g (x 0, y q 1 ))...)). The orbits of the one-dimensional maps f and g p determine the orbits of the triangular map T, as we show in the following Lemma: Lemma 2.1. Let T = (f, g) : X Y X Y be a continuous triangular map. Then the following hold: (1) If f has a periodic orbit P and g p has a periodic orbit Q, then P.Q is a periodic orbit of T. (2) Conversely, each periodic orbit of T can be obtained as a product of a periodic orbit P of f by a periodic orbit of g p. Proof. See Alsedà-Llibre 1. The topological entropy is a measure of complexity of a dynamical system. Let T be a triangular map like defined in the earlier Lemma. The Bowen s formula for the inferior and superior values of the topological en-

5 tropy of T, h top (T ), is valid, that is, max {h top (f), h top (g p )} h top (T ) h top (f) + h top (g p ), (7) where h top (f) and h top (g p ) represent, respectively, the topological entropy of the basis map, f, and the topological entropy of the fiber map associated to the orbit P, g p. 3. Chaotic behavior in the map F It is possible to prove the existence of chaotic behavior in the map F if there are parameter values that correspond to a positive value of the topological entropy. Let us consider first the basis map f. It is an one-dimensional map and it can be easily proved that f is a bimodal map when ασ 1 > 0. In this case there are two turning points, whose expressions are: c 1 = µ α ασ 1 1 and c 2 = µ + α ασ 1 1. The first one corresponds to the relative minimum and the second corresponds to the relative maximum. Fixing the parameters µ = 100 and σ = 0.3, f depends only on α which is the most interesting parameter from the economics point of view. In Fig.3 we present the long term behavior of the map f when α changes between 7 and 14. 107.5 105 102.5 y 100 97.5 95 92.5 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Α Figure 3. Bifurcation diagram of the basis map f as a function of α, with initial conditions c 1 and c 2. For α = 11.1726, f has an orbit, P = {y 0, y 1, y 2, y 3 }, of period 4, such that f (f (c 1 )) = c 2, described in Fig.4. The corresponding kneading data

6 f y 115 110 105 100 95 95 100 105 y Figure 4. Period-4 orbit of the map f, when α = 11.1726, µ = 100 and σ = 0.3. (ALBR, BRAL) generates a three interval Markov partition of the line y, which corresponds to the transition matrix: 1 1 0 M(f) = 1 1 1 0 1 1 The maximum eigenvalue is λ y = 2.41421 and the value of the topological entropy of the basis map is h top (f) = log (λ y ) = 0.881374... Let us consider now the points of the orbit P ordered like: y 0 = 92,...; y 1 = 101,...; y 3 = 107,...; y 4 = 98,... Consider also the function g p0 (k), depending on the variable k and defined, according to (6), by g p0 (k) = g (y 3, g (y 2, g (y 1, g (y 0, k)))). If we fix β = 9.5 and δ = 0.52, the bifurcation diagram of g p0 as a function of γ, the free parameter, is presented in Fig.5. The study of this function can give us significant information about the long term behavior of the original map F. Let s consider, for example, the case γ = 0.8518. The function g p0 (k), whose graphical representation is showed in Fig.6 is continuous, limited and has many critical points but its dynamics reduces to the values where there is an intersection with the diagonal line. If we iterate all the critical points of g p0 (k) it is all reduced to an orbit of period 4 or to a fix point (see Fig.7).

7 k 40 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 Γ Figure 5. Bifurcation diagram of the map g p0 (k) as a function of γ. g p0 k 20 40 80 100 120 140 k Figure 6. Graphical representation of the map g p0 (k) for γ = 0.8518. It is very interesting to notice what happens if we change the order of appearance of the points y 0, y 1, y 2, y 3, of the orbit P, in the construction of the function g p (k). We have three more possibilities. We can also define g p1 (k), g p2 (k) and g p3 (k) in the following way: g p1 (k) = g (y 0, g (y 3, g (y 2, g (y 1, k)))), g p2 (k) = g (y 1, g (y 0, g (y 3, g (y 2, k)))), and g p3 (k) = g (y 2, g (y 1, g (y 0, g (y 3, k)))). We obtain functions, all very different from each other, but the dynamic behavior of all these maps asymptotically goes to a period 4 orbit or to a fix point. In Fig.10 are shown the stable orbits for the considered parameter

8 g p0 k k Figure 7. A magnification of the graphical representation of the map g p0 (k) for γ = 0.8518. gp1 k a g p2 k b k k Figure 8. Graphical representation of the functions g p1 and g p2. values. The periods of the orbits are in agreement with the considerations made in Section 2: the period of the orbit of F is equal to 16 or to 4 depending on the initial conditions. In each fiber we can see the orbit of period 4, in black, and the fix point, in grey. The first fiber corresponds to the stable orbits of the function g p0 (k) and the others respectively to the

9 g p3 k a g pi k b k k Figure 9. In plot a) graphical representation of the function g p3 and in plot b) graphical representation of the functions g pi, i = 0, 1, 2, 3 in the same plot. k 94 96 98 100 102 104 106 108 y Figure 10. The stable orbits of the triangular map F for α = 11.1726, µ = 100, σ = 0.3, β = 9.5, δ = 0.52 and γ = 0.8515. stable orbits of functions g p3 (k), g p1 (k) and g p2 (k). The transition matrix is: 0 1 0 M(f) = 0 0 1 1 1 1 which corresponds to a topological entropy given by: h top (g p0 ) = log (1.83929...) = 0.9378...

10 The earlier value doesn t depend on the function g pi, that is, doesn t depend on the fiber. So we can conclude that the topological entropy of the original triangular map F is such that: 0.881374... h top (F ) 1.5721... The map F certainly has a value of the topological entropy that is positive, and therefore, the system is chaotic for these parameter values. 4. Final conclusions In this paper we presented a Kaldor-type business cycle model described by a two-dimensional map. The model is a modification of the one proposed in Bischi et al. 2 and Dieci et al. 3 and can be reduced to a map of triangular type with income and capital stock as variables. Due to its triangular structure it is possible to compute the topological entropy, for certain values of the parameters, as a measure of complexity of the system. The introduction of nonlinearity in the capital stock variable, into the investment and savings functions allows us to have chaotic basis map and chaotic fiber map, since we found a positive value for the topological entropy in both cases. References 1. L. Alsedà; J. Llibre; Periods for triangular maps, Bull. Austral. Math. Soc. (1993), no. 47, 41 53. 2. GI. Bischi; R. Dieci; R. Rodano; S. Saltari; Multiple attractors and global bifurcations in a Kaldor-type business cycle model, J. Evol Econ (2001), no. 11, 527 4. 3. R. Dieci; GI. Bischi; L. Gardini; From bi-stability to chaotic oscillations in a macroeconomic model, Chaos Solitons Fractals 21 (2004), no. 2, 403 412. 4. D. Mendes; J. Sousa Ramos; Kneading theory for triangular maps, Int. J. Pure Appl. Math. 10 (2) (2004) 421-0. 5. C. Mira; L. Gardini; A. Barugola; J.-C. Cathala; Chaotic dynamics in twodimensional noninvertible maps. World Scientific Series on Nonlinear Science. Series A: Monographs and Treatises, 20. World Scientific Publishing Co., Inc., River Edge, NJ, 1996. xiv+7 pp. 6. T. Puu; Attractors, bifurcations, and chaos. Nonlinear phenomena in economics. Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 2000. xii+7 pp. 7. J. P. Lampreia; J. Sousa Ramos; Symbolic dynamics of bimodal maps, Portugal. Math. 54 (1997), no. 1, 1 18. 8. J. Milnor; W. Thurston; On iterated maps of the interval. Dynamical systems (College Park, MD, 1986 87), 4 563, Lecture Notes in Math., 1342, Springer, Berlin, 1988.