On Linear Quadratic Approximations

Similar documents
On automatic derivation of first order conditions in dynamic stochastic optimisation problems

Monetary Economics Notes

Eco504, Part II Spring 2010 C. Sims PITFALLS OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION OF STOCHASTIC MODELS

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Optimal Target Criteria for Stabilization Policy

A New Nonlinear Unit Root Test with Fourier Function

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Paretian evaluation of infinite utility streams: an egalitarian criterion

A note on implementing the Durbin and Koopman simulation smoother

1 With state-contingent debt

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. International Finance Discussion Papers Number 1034 November 2011

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Citation Working Paper Series, F-39:

Parameterized Expectations Algorithm and the Moving Bounds

Development Economics (PhD) Intertemporal Utility Maximiza

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Optimization under Commitment and Discretion, the Recursive Saddlepoint Method, and Targeting Rules and Instrument Rules: Lecture Notes

A framework for monetary-policy analysis Overview Basic concepts: Goals, targets, intermediate targets, indicators, operating targets, instruments

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Existence of sparsely supported correlated equilibria

Topic 3. RBCs

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm

Solutions Methods in DSGE (Open) models

Perturbation techniques

The welfare cost of energy insecurity

An Alternative Method to Obtain the Blanchard and Kahn Solutions of Rational Expectations Models

Macroeconomics Theory II

Shipping the Good Apples Out: Another Proof with A Graphical Representation

Maximin and minimax strategies in symmetric oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Is there a flight to quality due to inflation uncertainty?

Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy 1

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Advanced Macroeconomics

1 The Basic RBC Model

Parameterized Expectations Algorithm: How to Solve for Labor Easily

Monetary Policy Design in the Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. October 2015

Comparing Accuracy of Second Order Approximation and Dynamic Programming

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

A Simple Algorithm for Solving Ramsey Optimal Policy with Exogenous Forcing Variables

Equilibrium Determinacy in a Two-Tax System with Utility from Government Expenditure

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

On the International Dimension of Fiscal Policy

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

Inflation Stabilization and Welfare: The Case of a Distorted Steady State

Public Goods, Club Goods and the Measurement of. Crowding. Michael Reiter and Alfons J. Weichenrieder

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model

Adaptive Learning in Macroeconomics: some methodological issues

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Time-Consistent Institutional Design. June 2015

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

News-Shock Subroutine for Prof. Uhlig s Toolkit

A quantifying method of microinvestment optimum

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Marginal and Interaction Effects in Ordered Response Models

Internet Appendix for: Social Risk, Fiscal Risk, and the Portfolio of Government Programs

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Existence of sparsely supported correlated equilibria

Discrete Time or Continuous Time, That is the Question: the Case of Samuelson s Multiplier-Accelerator Model

Optimal Policy with Partial Information in a Forward-Looking Model: Certainty-Equivalence Redux

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

Discussion of. "Indeterminacy with Inflation-Forecast- Based Rules in a Two-Bloc Model" N. Batini, P. Levine and J. Pearlman

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Functions of One Variable

Lecture Notes: Math Refresher 1

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive On Linear Quadratic Approximations Davide Debortoli and Ricardo Nunes July 2006 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/544/ MPRA Paper No. 544, posted 21. October 2006

On Linear-Quadratic Approximations Davide Debortoli Universitat Pompeu Fabra Ricardo Nunes Universitat Pompeu Fabra Submitted: July 2006 Abstract We prove the generality of the methodology proposed in Benigno and Woodford (2006). We show that, even in the presence of a distorted steady state, it is always possible and relatively simple to obtain a purely quadratic approximation to the welfare measure. We also show that, in order to do so, the timeless perspective assumption is crucial. JEL classification: C61, C63 Keywords: Linear-Quadratic Approximation, Distorted Steady State, Timeless Perspective We gratefully acknowledge financial support from Agència de Gestió d Ajuts Universitaris i de Recerca (Debortoli) and Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (Nunes). Any remaining errors are our own. Corresponding author: Ricardo Nunes, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Department of Economics and Business, Ramon Trias Fargas 25-27, 08005 - Barcelona (Spain). Phone: (34) 93 542 1766. Fax: (34) 93 542 1746. e-mail: ricardo.nunes@upf.edu 1

1 Introduction It has been shown that the standard linear-quadratic approach does not usually lead to an accurate approximation of the optimal policy in the presence of a distorted non-stochastic steady state. This happens, for example, whenever the non-stochastic steady state is not efficient, due to the presence of some distortions like market power or distortionary taxes. 1 Benigno and Woodford (2006), among others, show that a correct linear-quadratic approximation to an optimal policy problem is still possible even in the case of a distorted steady state, if the quadratic objective is chosen adequately. In this respect, the crucial step is to eliminate the linear terms in the second order approximation to the welfare measure, to obtain a purely quadratic expression. This is done through an appropriate linear combination of a second order approximation to the model structural equations. Such derivations are usually cumbersome and time consuming. Moreover, it has not been shown that such methodology is general. This paper makes a contribution by proving the generality of the method proposed in Benigno and Woodford (2006). We indeed show that it is always possible to eliminate the linear terms in the second order approximation to the welfare measure. Moreover, we show that this procedure is quite simple, from an analytical point of view, and as tractable as the standard linear-quadratic approach (i.e. the non-distorted case). Finally, with our insight, it is possible to apply this methodology to a broad class of models through the use of standard numerical packages. In an independent work, Altissimo et al. (2005) propose a toolkit to solve linear-quadratic problems of the type proposed in Benigno and Woodford (2006). All the papers that have followed this methodological approach have also made use of the timeless perspective concept. We show that, in the case of a distorted steady state, the timeless perspective assumption is crucial to perform such linearquadratic approximations, since it allows to obtain an approximation to the welfare measure that is purely quadratic. 2 A Purely Quadratic Approximation Consider a general problem with the following form 1 For a discussion on this topic see e.g. Kim and Kim (2003) and Woodford (2003, Chapter 6). 2

max E 0 {x t} β t u(x t 1, x t, s t ) (1) s.t. : E t g(x t 1, x t, x t+1, s t, s t+1 ) = 0, t 0 where s t is exogenously given and follows a Markov process, u is a standard utility function, g is a vector of constraints and E t denotes rational expectations conditional on information available at time t. For our purposes, there is no need to distinguish among control and state variables. The problem is in a form such that all the first order conditions (FOCs) are taken with respect to the vector of variables x t. Denoting the vector of lagrange multipliers associated with the constraints at time t by λ t the FOCs for t > 0 can be written as u 2,t + βu 1,t+1 + βλ t+1 g 1,t+1 + λ t g 2,t + β 1 λ t 1 g 3,t 1 = 0 (2) E t g(x t 1, x t, x t+1, s t, s t+1 ) = 0 (3) where we are using the short notation u 2,t to denote the first derivative of the function u(x t 1, x t, s t ) with respect to the second argument. Imposing a steady state relationship in the FOCs for t > 0 we obtain u 2 + βu 1 + βλg 1 + λg 2 + β 1 λg 3 = 0 (4) g = 0 (5) where all the functions are evaluated at steady state. In the standard linear-quadratic approach, the original problem is transformed such that the objective function is a local quadratic approximation to the exact objective and the constraints are local linear approximations to the exact constraints. The second order Taylor approximation to utility around the steady state found above is β t u(x t 1, x t, s t ) β t (u 2 (x t x) + βu 1 (x t x)) + s.o.t. + t.i.p. (6) where s.o.t. and t.i.p. denote second order terms and terms independent of policy respectively. 2 Here we do not explicitly derive the s.o.t., as they do not matter for our considerations. 2 The term x 1 is also t.i.p. 3

As it is known, in the case of a distorted steady state, the standard linearquadratic approach would lead to incorrect conclusions. The way proposed by Benigno and Woodford (2006) to overcome this problem is to substitute for the linear terms in (6), thus obtaining a purely quadratic expression. These derivations are sometimes hard to follow and cumbersome. In what follows we show that this procedure can be applied to a broad class of model and that the necessary calculations are relatively inexpensive from an analytical point of view. Consider that the constraint in Eq. (3) is also present at t = 1. After writing a second order Taylor approximation to the constraints and summing over time, we obtain β t g(x t 1, x t, x t+1, s t, s t+1 ) (7) β t (βg 1 (x t x) + g 2 (x t x) + β 1 g 3 (x t x)) + s.o.t. + t.i.p. Now we can multiply Eq. (7) by λ and sum the resulting expression with Eq. (6). 3 It is easy to see that all the linear terms drop out due to the steady state relationship described in Eq. (4). This technique shows that one can always eliminate the linear terms from a second order approximation to the welfare measure. This result holds no matter what is the number of linear terms to eliminate and the number of constraints in the problem. 4 Indeed, it suffices to take a linear combination of the second order approximation to the constraints, using as weights the steady state values of the lagrange multipliers associated with the constraints, and sum the resulting expression to the approximated welfare measure. Such calculations can be performed with relatively low effort. This implies that, from an analytical point of view, the case of a distorted steady state is as tractable as the standard linear-quadratic approximation. Moreover, our result implies that these substitutions can be performed automatically with a mathematical package. The resulting formulation of the problem can then be solved and simulated with any standard toolkit. 3 Eq. (7) equals zero (up to third order terms). Therefore, we can sum this expression to Eq. (6) without altering the approximated welfare measure. 4 In some cases it might seem fortuitous that it is possible to eliminate n linear terms with a linear combination of less than n equations. On the contrary, this is a direct consequence of the optimality conditions at the non-stochastic steady state. 4

We would like to emphasize some key features of this procedure. Note that the FOCs w.r.t. x 0 of the original problem are different. As a consequence, it would not be possible to eliminate the linear terms in x 0. However, this is possible if one considers the problem only for t > 0 or if one assumes that the constraints were present also at t = 1. In other words, it is crucial to impose a proper value of initial commitments. 5 Therefore, we can conclude that the timeless perspective assumption, beside other considerations, is crucial to obtain an approximation to the welfare measure that is purely quadratic. 3 Conclusions We have shown that the linear quadratic approach in the case of a distorted steady state proposed in Benigno and Woodford (2006) can be applied to any model. To do so, it is crucial to consider the policy problem from a timeless perspective. We have shown that the procedure to eliminate the linear terms in the second order approximation to the welfare measure is relatively inexpensive from an analytical point of view. Solving economic models with this methodology can be done through slight extensions to available numerical packages. References Altissimo, F., Curdia, V., Rodríguez-Palenzuela, D., 2005. Linear-quadratic approximation to optimal policy: An algorithm and two applications. Manuscript. Benigno, P., Woodford, M., 2006. Optimal taxation in an RBC model: A linearquadratic approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. Forthcoming. Kim, J., Kim, S. H., 2003. Spurious welfare reversal in international business cycle models. Journal of International Economics 60, 471 500. Marcet, A., Marimon, R., 1998. Recursive contracts. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Working Paper. 5 Marcet and Marimon (1998) describe that past commitments are summarized in the lagrange multipliers associated with forward looking constraints. If one considers the original problem, where at t = 0 no commitments have been made, then the lagrange multipliers should be initialized at the value of zero. 5

Woodford, M., 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press. 6