Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Similar documents
Neoclassical Growth Models: II

Macro I - Practice Problems - Growth Models

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Macroeconomics

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Endogenous Growth Theory

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

1 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

The representative agent model

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

1 The Basic RBC Model

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Introduction to Recursive Methods

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Macro 1: Dynamic Programming 1

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

The Real Business Cycle Model

Heterogeneous Agent Models: I

Homework 3 - Partial Answers

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Problem 1 (30 points)

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

2. What is the fraction of aggregate savings due to the precautionary motive? (These two questions are analyzed in the paper by Ayiagari)

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 5: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

14.06 Lecture Notes Intermediate Macroeconomics. George-Marios Angeletos MIT Department of Economics

14.452: Introduction to Economic Growth Problem Set 4

Equilibrium in a Model with Overlapping Generations

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

Growth Theory: Review

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Growth Theory: Review

Housing with overlapping generations

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Econ 702 Macroeconomic Theory Spring 2016

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Notes for ECON 970 and ECON 973 Loris Rubini University of New Hampshire

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Lecture Notes. Econ 702. Spring 2004

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Equilibrium in the growth model with an endogenous labor-leisure choice

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Discussion Papers in Economics

Advanced Macroeconomics

First Welfare Theorem

Volume 30, Issue 3. Ramsey Fiscal Policy and Endogenous Growth: A Comment. Jenn-hong Tang Department of Economics, National Tsing-Hua University

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

1. Agents maximize 2. Agents actions are compatible with each other.

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Growth: Facts and Theories

Second Welfare Theorem

ECON607 Fall 2010 University of Hawaii Professor Hui He TA: Xiaodong Sun Assignment 2

Transcription:

Neoclassical Growth Model: I Mark Huggett 2 2 Georgetown October, 2017

Growth Model: Introduction Neoclassical Growth Model is the workhorse model in macroeconomics. It comes in two main varieties: infinitely-lived agent and overlapping generations. Some key features: (i) accounts for the NIPA aggregates C, I, G, (ii) accounts for factor shares, (iii) accounts for long-run growth, (iv) framework for analyzing business-cycle fluctuations (impluses and propagation mechanisms) and (v) one can address positive and normative questions within it. Generalization of Solow (1956) to endogenize savings decision.

Infinitely-lived agent Growth Model 1. Preferences: t=0 βt u(c t ) 2. Endowments: k 0 > 0 and 1 unit of time each model period 3. Technology: F (k t, l t ) C.R.S. c t + k t+1 F (k t, l t ) + k t (1 δ) One can rewrite this also as follows: c t + k t+1 k t (1 δ) F (k t, l t )

Equilibrium Def: A competitive equilibrium is {c t, k t+1, l t, w t, R t } t=0 such that 1. {c t, k t+1, l t } t=0 solve P1. 2. w t = F 2 (k t, l t ) and R t = F 1 (k t, l t ) holds t 3. c t + k t+1 = F (k t, l t ) + k t (1 δ) holds t P 1 max β t u(c t ) s.t. t=0 c t + k t+1 w t l t + R t k t + (1 δ)k t c t, k t+1 0, l t [0, 1], given k 0

Equilibrium Comments: 1. We assume a sequential market structure with two factor rental prices per period. 2. There is no direct requirement of profit maximization by a firm or firms. However, this is implicit in the second condition of equilibrium. Macroeconomists often simply impose competitive pricing of factor inputs to shorten the analysis. There is no explicit ownership of shares of the firm and no allocation of profits of the firm in the definition. Since firms will make zero profit in an equilibrium, abstracting from ownership and the allocation of profit shortens the analysis. 3. Sometimes we will impose different market structures: (i) time-0 AD markets and (ii) sequential markets but where the consumer owns the firm and the firm owns the capital.

Planning Problem Planning Problem max β t u(c t ) s.t. t=0 c t + k t+1 F (k t, l t ) + k t (1 δ) and l t [0, 1], given k 0 1. 1st Welfare Theorem: It will be understood that within the growth model comp. equil. allocations are Pareto efficient. Thus, competitive equilibrium allocations will solve the planning problem above. 2. We will not prove the 1st Welfare Theorem. However, we will show how to recast the equilibrium concept into the language of Debreu.

Language of Debreu Comments: 1. In our application the commodity space is infinite dimensional. Debreu s (1959) analysis handles finite dimensional problems. Debreu (1954) shows how to prove the Welfare Theorems with finite consumers but infinite dimensional commodity space. 2. To invoke standard proofs, one would need to restate competitive equilibria in the language of Debreu. 3. (U i, X i, e i, Y j ) are the elements of an economy in the language of Debreu. In discussing competitive equilibrium there is also share ownership (i.e. θ ij is the fraction of firm j owned by consumer i).

Debreu: Static Warmup Example 1. One agent and one firm in our application: X = {(x 1, x 2 ) : x 1, x 2 0} U(x) = u(x 1 ) + v(x 2 ) e = (0, 1) Y = {(y 1, y 2 ) : 0 y 1 F (y 2 ), y 2 0} 2. A competitive equilibrium is (x, y, p) such that (i) x argmax {U(x) x X, px pe + 1 py}, (ii) y argmax {py y Y } and (iii) x = y + e.

Debreu: Dynamic Growth Model Example 1. One agent and one firm in our application: X = {x = {(x 1t, x 2t )} t=0 : (x 1t, x 2t ) R + [0, 1], t 0} U(x) = t=0 βt u(x 1t, x 2t ) e = {(e 1t, e 2t )} t=0 and (e 1t, e 2t ) = (0, 1), t 0 Y = {y = {(z t, l t )} t=0 : {k t} t=0, k 0 = k s.t. (1) holds} (1) z t + k t+1 F (k t, l t ) + k t (1 δ), l t 0, t 0 2. Prices: px = t=0 (p 1t, p 2t ) (x 1t, x 2t ) 3. A competitive equilibrium is (x, y, p) such that (i) x argmax {U(x) x X, px pe + 1 py}, (ii) y argmax {py y Y } and (iii) x = y + e.

1. We have considered two example economies. Both have one agent and one firm. 2. A competitive equilibrium in both economies is (x, y, p) and the three requirements of equilibria are the same in both economies. 3. What differs across the economies is that the elements (x, y, p) have very different dimensions across the two examples and that the notion of price system in example 2 is perhaps very different from what you are used to thinking about. 4. The equilibrium concepts used in the remainder of these slides and the notation employed will be quite different from the Debreu formalization. One reason for this is that we will be interested in computing equilibria (at least an approximation). Debreu s language is not usually the most natural way to do so. Growth Debreu: Summary

Steady States of the Growth Model A competitive equilibrium {c t, k t+1, l t, w t, R t } t=0 is a steady-state competitive equilibrium provided c t = c, k t = k, l t = l, w t = w, R t = R for all t 0. Analysis: 1. u (c t ) = βu (c t+1 )(1 + R t+1 δ) - FONC 2. u (c t ) = βu (c t+1 )(1 + F 1 (k t+1, l t+1 ) δ) - FONC + equil 3. 1 = β(1 + F 1 ( k, 1) δ) - steady state 4. F 1 (k, 1) > 0 and F 11 (k, 1) < 0 imply that there exists a unique steady state k > 0 5. Golden Rule: k GR argmax F (k, 1) δk Implication: k < k GR

Steady States Generalize to u(c, l) rather than u(c) 1. u 1 ( c, l) = βu 1 ( c, l))(1 + F 1 ( k, l) δ) - FONC 2. u 1 ( c, l)f 2 ( k, l) = u 2 ( c, l) - FONC 3. The following restrictions characterize steady states: 1 = β(1 + F 1 ( k, l) δ) u 1 ( c, l)f 2 ( k, l) = u 2 ( c, l) c + δ k = F ( k, l) 4. An extra assumption (e.g. u additively separable or u is GHH preferences) would lead to a sharper characterization

Steady States Theorem: Assume u(c, l) = u(c) v(l), u > 0, u < 0 and u (0) =, lim c u (c) = 0 and v > 0, v > 0. Then there is a unique interior ss competitive equilibrium allocation ( c, k, l). Proof: sketch 1. Rearrange ss restrictions. (1) 1 = β(1 + F 1 ( k/ l, 1) δ) (2) u ( c)f 2 ( k/ l, 1) = v ( l) (3) c + δ( k/ l) l = F ( k/ l, 1) l 2. Usual assumptions on F imply there exists a unique solution k/ l > 0 to (1)

Steady States Proof: sketch (continued) 1. Substitute (3) into (2) to get (*) u ( c)f 2 ( k/ l, 1) = v ( l) ( ) u ( l(f ( k/ l, 1) δ( k/ l))) F 2 ( k/ l, 1) = v ( l) 2. Given unique solution k/ l to (1), LHS of (*) is st decreasing in l and RHS is st increasing in l. 3. LHS( l) RHS( l) is a continuous and st monotone decreasing fn of l. Intermediate-Value Thm delivers a solution l to LHS( l) RHS( l) = 0. It s unique by st. monotonicity. 4. Conclusion: There are unique positive values ( c, k, l) solving (1)-(3)

Steady States with Proportional Tax Rates Perspective: One use of the growth model is to provide insight into fiscal policy. While we know that the growth model implies that government tax and spending plans do not improve upon the market allocation, we will still pursue an analysis of proportional taxes within this model. This establishes a useful benchmark and is an important point of departure in the literature.

Steady States with Proportional Tax Rates Def: A competitive equilibrium is {c t, k t+1, l t, w t, R t, T t } t=0 such that 1. {c t, k t+1, l t } t=0 solve P1. 2. w t = F 2 (k t, l t ) and R t = F 1 (k t, l t ) holds t 3. c t + k t+1 = F (k t, l t ) + k t (1 δ) holds t 4. T t = τ c c t + τ w w t l t + τ k (R t δ)k t holds t P 1 max β t u(c t ) s.t. t=0 c t (1 + τ c ) + k t+1 w t l t (1 τ w ) + (R t δ)(1 τ k )k t + k t + T t c t, k t+1 0, l t [0, 1], given k 0

Steady States with Proportional Tax Rates Analysis: τ k > 0 and τ c, τ w = 0 1. u (c t ) = βu (c t+1 )(1 + (R t+1 δ)(1 τ k )) - FONC 2. 1/β = 1 + (F 1 ( k, 1) δ)(1 τ k ) - steady state 3. F 1 (k, 1) > 0 and F 11 (k, 1) < 0 imply that there exists a unique steady state k > 0 and k decreases as τ k increases. 4. F (k, l) = Ak α l 1 α implies k = ([ 1/β 1 1 τ k + δ] 1 αa )1/(α 1)

Steady States with Proportional Tax Rates How large is the steady state output effect of capital income taxation? 1. F (k, l) = Ak α l 1 α 2. k(τ k ) = ([ 1/β 1 1 τ k + δ] 1 αa )1/(α 1) 3. 4. 5. ȳ(τ k ) ȳ(0) = F ( k(τ k ),1) F ( k(0),1) = ( k(τ k ) k(0) )α ȳ(τ k ) ȳ(0) = ( [ ȳ(τ k ) ȳ(0) 1/β 1 +δ] 1 τ k [1/β 1+δ] ) α α 1 > (1 τk ) α 1 α for δ > 0 > (1 τ k) α 1 α. = (.5).3/.7 =.74 6. When α =.3, then a 50 percent capital tax lowers steady-state output by at most 25 percent.

Steady States with Proportional Tax Rates Analysis: u(c, l) and τ k, τ c, τ w > 0 1. u 1 (c t, l t ) 1 1+τ c = βu 1 (c t+1, l t+1 ) (1+(R t+1 δ)(1 τ k )) 1+τ c - FONC 2. u 1 (c t, l t ) wt(1 τw) 1+τ c = u 2 (c t, l t ) - FONC 3. In steady state the following hold: 1/β = 1 + (F 1 ( k, l) δ)(1 τ k ) u 1 ( c, l)f 2 ( k, l) (1 τ w) 1 + τ c = u 2 ( c, l) c = F ( k, l) δ k 4. First equation pins down the ratio k/ l. l is not pinned down absent further restrictions.

Application: Corporate Tax Let s analyze how the introduction of a proportional tax τ on corporate income impacts the steady state properties of the one-sector growth model. To do so, we recast the definition of equilibrium. Specifically, now the firm s problem is dynamic and we model the value of the firm when the firm owns its capital. Definition: A steady-state equilibrium is (c, l, b, s, k, d, w, r, p, T ) such that 1. (c t, l t, b t, s t ) = (c, l, b, s), t solves P1. 2. (k t, l t ) = (k, l), t solves P2 3. c + δk = F (k, l) and s = 1 and b = 0 4. T = τ[f (k, l) wl δk] 5. d = (1 τ)[f (k, l) wl δk]

Application: Corporate Tax P 1 max β t u(c t ) s.t. t=0 c t + s t+1 p + b t+1 wl t + s t (p + d) + b t (1 + r) + T c t, s t+1, b t+1 0, l t [0, 1], given (s 0, b 0 ) = (1, 0) P 2 max 1 ( 1 + r )t d t, given k 0 = k t=0 d t [F (k t, l t ) wl t (k t+1 k t (1 δ))] τ[f (k t, l t ) wl t δk t ]

Application: Corporate Tax Necessary Conditions for interior optimization are for all t 0 1. u (c t ) = βu (c t+1 )(1 + r) 2. u (c t )p = βu (c t+1 )(p + d) 3. F 2 (k t, l t ) = w 4. 1 = ( 1 1+r )[(1 τ)(f 1(k t+1, l t+1 ) δ) + 1] Steady State: l = 1 (1 + r) = 1/β via 1. k = F 1 (, 1) 1 ([ 1 β 1]/(1 τ) + δ) via 1 and 4 w = F 2 (k, 1) via 3 p = β 1 β d = β 1 β (1 τ)[f (k, 1) w δk] via 2 p = β 1 β (1 τ)[k(f 1(k, 1) δ)] = T = τ[f (k, 1) w δk] β 1 β ( 1 β 1)k = k

Application: Corporate Tax Theorem: In a steady state in the growth model with a proportional tax τ on corporate income, 1. capital k(τ) decreases as the tax rate τ increases. 2. wage w(τ) = F 2 (k(τ), 1) decreases as the tax rate τ increases. 3. interest rate r(τ) = 1/β 1 is constant as the tax rate τ increases. 4. value p(τ) = k(τ) of the firm decreases as the tax rate τ increases. Proof: see analysis on the previous slide. [Could generalize this Theorem to handle a labor-leisure decision.]

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Motivation It will be useful to develop the notion of a recursive competiitive equilibrium and a recursive formulation of the planning problem for the growth model. One reason for this is that to analyze these models it will often be easier to computationally approximate functions rather than infinite sequences. The recursive notions we employ in growth theory will be closely connected to the recursive methods employed in the analysis of asset pricing models in exchange economies (e.g. Lucas (1978)).

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Def: A recursive competitive equilibrium is (c(x), g(x), w(k), R(K), G(K)) such that 1. optimization: (c(x), g(x)) solve BE. 2. factor prices: w(k) = F 2 (K, 1) and R(K) = 1 + F 1 (K, 1) δ 3. feasibility: c(k, K) + g(k, K) = F (K, 1) + K(1 δ) 4. law of motion: G(K) = g(k, K) State: x = (k, K) (BE) v(k, K) = max u(c) + βv(k, K ) s.t. c + k w(k) + R(K)k and c, k 0 and K = G(K)

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Standard big K little k trick 1. We employ the state variable x = (k, K). Little k is the agent s capital. Big K is economy wide capital. 2. Big K determines factor prices and helps the agent forecast the future economy wide capital. The agent knows factor prices via knowing the functions (w, R) and the level K. 3. We acknowledge that in equilibrium big K and little k are equal. Thus, for the purpose of computing equilibria the distinction will not be important. However, for the purpose of defining equilibria and clarifying the analysis the distiction is useful. 4. Absent the distinction, the agent would view future factor prices as being influenced by curent capital choices. Since we want to capture competitive behavior, the distinction is useful.

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Recursive Planning Problem 1. v(k) = max u(c) + βv(k ) s.t. c + k F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) 2. Solution: Decision rule k = G(k) 3. 1st Welfare Thm. implies that Law of motion in competitive equilibrium G(k) coincides with the optimal decision rule G(k) solving the Planning Problem. 4. Implication: can analyze competitive equilibrium by solving the planning problem. 5. All the properties of the growth model reduce to properties of G(k).

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Recursive Planning Problem 1. v(k) = max u(c) + βv(k ) s.t. c + k F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) 2. Properties: Decision rule G(k) is (i) continuous, (ii) increasing, (iii) there is a unique positive k such that k = G(k ), and (vi) monotone convergence of capital to k induced by recursively applying k t+1 = G(k t ) from k 0 > 0. 3. Properties (i)-(ii) follow standard lines from early in the semester, but (iii)-(iv) need to be developed.

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium Monotone Convergence: LS (1989, Ch 6) v(k) = max u(c) + βv(k ) s.t. c + k F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) 1. u (F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) G(k)) = βv (G(k)) - nec condition 2. v (k) = u (F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) G(k))(1 + F 1 (k, 1) δ) - BS 3. v st. concave implies [v (k) v (G(k))][k G(k)] 0, = iff G(k) = k 4. [(1 + F 1 (k, 1) δ) 1 β ][k G(k)] 0 5. Let k solve β(1 + F 1 (k, 1) δ) = 1. Consider k > 0. 6. Case 1: k < k implies [+][k G(k)] < 0. Thus, G(k) > k 7. Case 2: k > k implies [ ][k G(k)] < 0. Thus, G(k) < k

Recursive Competitive Equilibrium How fast does capital converge to steady state? v(k) = max u(c) + βv(k ) s.t. c + k F (k, 1) + k(1 δ) 1. k t+1 = G(k t ). = G(k ) + G (k )(k t k ) 2. k t+1 k. = G (k )(k t k ) 3. 1 α k t+1 k k t k = G (k ) 4. Upshot: If G (k ) is close to 1 then convergence is slow. Fraction α of gap closed is then small. 5. Note: Solow model with Cobb-Douglas production and capital s share near.3 implies rapid convergence. Calculations for the optimal growth model suggest similar results.

Sunspot Equilibria and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis Rational Sunspot Equilibria Idea: Contemplate an economy for which sunspot realizations are independent of shocks to preferences, endowments or technology. See if sunspot realizations impact allocations under these circumstances. We will do so within the growth model where the ONLY shocks are sunspot shocks. Notation: s t (s 0,..., s t ) S t = S S history of realizations of s t s t S finite set P (s t ) probability of sunspot history

Sunspot Equilibria and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis A { competitive ( equilibrium is ct s t ) (, k t+1 s t ) (, l t s t ) (, w t s t ) (, R t s t )} such that: t=0 1. { ( c t s t ) (, k t+1 s t ) (, l t s t )} solve P1. t=0 ( 2. w t s t ) ( = F 2 (k t s t 1 ) (, l t s t ) ( ), R t s t ) ( = 1 + F 2 (k t s t 1 ) (, l t s t ) ) δ 3. Feasibility: t, s t c t ( s t ) + k t+1 ( s t ) F ( k t ( s t 1 ), l t ( s t )) + (1 δ) k t ( s t 1 ) and l t ( s t ) [0, 1] Decision Problem P1: max E [ t=1 βt 1 u ( ( c t s t ))] ( subject to c t s t ) ( + k t+1 s t ) ( w t s t ) ( l t s t ) + R t (s t ( )k t s t 1 ) (, l t s t ) [0, 1] t, s t

Sunspot Equilibria and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis Theorem: Assume u(c) is st. increasing and st. concave and F is concave and CRS. Then there is no comp equilibrium in which c(s t ) c(ŝ t ) for some t 0 and two histories s t and ŝ t S t. Sketch of Proof: 1. SBWOC that there is an equilibrium w/ c(s t ) c(ŝ t ). 2. Define c t = E [ ( c t s t )], k t+1 = E [ ( k t+1 s t )], l t = E [ ( l t s t )] 3. Claim: { c t, k t+1, l } t satisfies Feasibility. First line below t=0 takes expectations of the feasibility condition. Second line applies ( Jensen s inequality and uses l(s t ) = 1. E[c t s t ) ( + k t+1 s t ) ] E[F ( ( k t s t 1 ) (, l t s t )) ( + (1 δ) k t s t 1 ) ] c t + k t+1 E[F ( ( k t s t 1 ) (, l t s t )) ] + (1 δ) k t F ( k t, l t ) + (1 δ) k t 4. E [ t=1 βt 1 u (c t ) ] > E [ t=1 βt 1 u ( ( c t s t ))] by Jensen s Inequality. 5. This contradicts 1st Welfare theorem.

Sunspot Equilibria and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis Comments: (1) While rational sunspot equilibria exist in some model economies, they don t matter in basic growth models. (2) Even if they were to matter in growth models, it is not so easy to produce procyclical labor productivity, as observed in US data, with constant returns technology. (3) Proof of Theorem used l(s t ) = 1. It remains to be seen if one can extend the proof to handle endogenous labor-leisure decision.