Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Similar documents
(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

1 The Basic RBC Model

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Sticky Leverage. João Gomes, Urban Jermann & Lukas Schmid Wharton School and UCLA/Duke. September 28, 2013

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Learning and Global Dynamics

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

The Smets-Wouters Model

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Handling Non-Convexities: Entrepreneurship and Financial Frictions

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

When Inequality Matters for Macro and Macro Matters for Inequality

Analysis of the Government Expenditure Multiplier under Zero Lower Bound: the Role of Public Investment 1

When Inequality Matters for Macro and Macro Matters for Inequality

Problem 1 (30 points)

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

High-dimensional Problems in Finance and Economics. Thomas M. Mertens

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Imperfect Risk-Sharing and the Business Cycle

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

The Real Business Cycle Model

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Accounting for Heterogeneity

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

Bubbles and Credit Constraints

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Macroeconomics Theory II

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Advanced Macroeconomics

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Chapter 4. Applications. 4.1 Arrow-Debreu Markets and Consumption Smoothing The Intertemporal Budget

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

Homework 3 - Partial Answers

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

University of Pittsburgh Department of Economics Econ 1720: Advanced Macroeconomics Handout 3

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Growth Theory: Review

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Optimal Taxation with Capital Accumulation and Wage Bargaining

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

optimal simple nonlinear rules for monetary policy in a new-keynesian model

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

Transcription:

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model. January 8, 2018 1 Introduction This document describes the equilibrium conditions of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) and the computational algorithm used. 2 Equilibrium Conditions: Steady State We start with the steady state equilibrium conditions. To emphasize that the time subscript is removed. 2.1 Household Maximization Households discount time by rate ρ, must decide savings on an illiquid and a liquid asset, a and b, are subject to productivity shocks z with logs following a Markov Process, receive bonuses and commissions given by π(z) and have exogenous probability of dying ζ. Because of perfect annuity markets households receive interest r b (b) + ζ in the liquid asset and r a + ζ in the illiquid asset. Household s value function is given by (ρ + ζ)v (a, b, z) = max c,l,d u(c, l) + V b(a, b, z) [ (1 τ)wzl + (r b (b) + ζ)b + T d χ(d, a) + π(z) c ] (1) + V a (a, b, z)((r a + ζ)a + d) + V y (a, b, z)( βz) + λ s.t. (V (a, b, x) V (a, b, z)) φ(x)dx b b; a 0; 0 l 1; r b (b) = r b + I{b 0}κ The respective state-constraint boundary conditions are then given by The FOC can then be written as V b (a, b, z) u c (c, l) (2) V a (0, b, z) u c (c, l) (3) u c = V b (4) V b (1 + χ d (d, a)) = V a (5) u l = V b (1 τ)wy (6) (7) 1

Note that there are two kinks in the budget constraint. The first one is at b = 0, which imply that 4 will not hold with equality, the second one is due to the fixed cost of adjustment in the illiquid account, which implies that 5 will not hold with equality. Moreover, 6 may not hold because of the boundary condition on l. 1 Using that u(c, l) = c1 γ 1 γ ϕ l1+ν 1+ν one can write in an interior solution Using the functional form for χ d we finally have d = { ([Va V b 1 χ 0 ] 1 χ 1 χ 2 2.2 Kolmogorov Forward Equation c = (V b ) 1/γ (8) V b (1 + χ d (d, a)) = V a (9) ( ) 1/ν Vb (1 τ)wy l = ϕ (10) ) 1/(χ2 1) + { ( [ ] Va a} + 1 + χ 0 V b 1 χ 1 χ 2 ) 1/(χ2 1) a} (11) Let µ(a, b, z) be the stationary distribution of households and g(a, b, z) the corresponding density function. Let s a (a, b, z) = r a a + d and s b (a, b, z) = (1 τ)wzl + r b (b)b + T d χ(d, a) + π(z) c. The Kolmogorov Forward Equation is given by 0 = a (s a (a, b, z)g(a, b, z)) b ( s b (a, b, z)g(a, b, z) ) y ( βyg(a, b, z)) (12) λg(a, b, z) + λφ(y) g(a, b, x)dx ζg(a, b, z) + ζδ(a a 0 )δ(b b 0 )g (y) where δ is the Dirac delta function, (a 0, b 0 ) are starting assets and income and g (y) is the stationary distribution of y. 2.3 Firms 2.3.1 Final Good Producer There is a competitive representative final good producer with aggregating technology given by that solves ( 1 Y = 0 ) ɛ y ɛ 1 ɛ 1 ɛ j dj 1 To determine consumption when b = 0 one must calculate household s optimal solution when ḃ > 0 and she faces rb (b) = r b, when ḃ < 0 and she faces rb (b) = r b + κ and when ḃ = 0. The household pick the solution that renders maximum utility. Moreover, at the state constraint 2 and when ḃ = 0 the consumption-leisure condition determine labor supply u l ((1 τ)wzl + (r b (b) + ζ)b + T + π(z), l) u c((1 τ)wzl + (r b = (1 τ)wy (b) + ζ)b + T + π(z), l) 2

min y j 1 0 s.t. ( 1 Y = p j y j dj That gives the demand for each intermediate good j 0 ) ɛ y ɛ 1 ɛ 1 ɛ j dj y j (p j ) = ( 1 where P is the natural price index given by P = 2.3.2 Intermediate Good Producer ( pj ) ɛ Y P 0 p1 ɛ j ) 1 1 ɛ dj Each intermediate good j is produced by a monopolistic competitive producer with Cobb-Douglas technology and quadratic price adjustment cost. Each intermediate producer choose prices and inputs to maximize discounted present value profits and satisfy the demand y j (p j ) by the final good producer. Given price p j the intermediate good producer chooses k j and n j to solve. Which imply the factor demands min k j,n j wn j + r k k j s.t. y j = kj α n 1 α j ( pj ) ɛ y j = P ( α w k j = y j 1 α r k n j = ( y j ) α α w 1 α r k ) 1 α With operational real profits (Π j ) and marginal cost (m) given by Firms are subject to quadratic adjustment cost given by ( ) 1 α ( ) w r k α m = (13) 1 α α ( pj ) ( Π j = P m pj ) ( y j = P m pj ) ɛ P Θ(π j ) = θ 2 (π j) 2 Y 3

Therefore, firm s dynamic price setting problem is then given by Which implies that in steady state ( r a pj ) ( J(p j ) = max π P m pj ) ɛ θ Y P 2 π2 Y + J p (p j )p j π j m = ɛ 1 ɛ Finally, using this condition and that firms are identical, one can write (14) Where capital letters denote aggregates. 2.4 Government ( ) 1 α α w K = Y 1 α r k (15) Y N = ( ) α α w 1 α r k (16) Y = K α N 1 α (17) Π = (1 m)y (18) The government taxes labor supply, issue debt B g, redistribute amount T to households and expend on exogenous goods G. So the government budget constrain in steady state is 2.5 Distribution of Profits G + T = τwn + r b B g (19) Profits are going to be distributed among share holders and workers. A share 1 ω of total profits Π are given to workers according to their productivity where z is the average productivity. 2.6 Illiquid Asset π(z) = (1 ω)π (20) z z The illiquid asset is allocated efficiently and without costs in capital or equity share: for each household a = k + qs. Normalizing the aggregate amount of equity to one ( sdµ = 1) one can write the following relation between aggregate illiquid assets, A, aggregate capital, K, and equity, q: A = K + q (21) Because resources can be allocated efficiently between the two assets, returns must equalize Πω q = r k δ r a 4

where we have used that q t = 0 on steady state. Which imply that q = Πω r a Using 21, 22 and 14 we have an expression for steady state capital ω(1 m)y = r a (22) K = A ω(1 m)y r a = A ω Y r a ɛ Note that an individual household s illiquid portfolio composition, i.e., the split of a into k and qs, is indeterminate. In contrast, the aggregate illiquid portfolio, the split of A into K and q, is pinned down. 2.7 Liquid Asset The government is the only source of liquid asset. Therefore in equilibrium (23) where B h is the aggregate liquid asset in the hands of households. 2.8 Stationary Equilibrium B h + B g = 0 (24) The set of aggregate equilibrium objects are {K, N, Y, Π, m, w, r k, T, π(z), A, q, B h, r a } that with 13 to 15, 19, 20, 21, 22, 24 and A = N = adµ ldµ provides a system of 13 equations and 13 unknowns. Definition 2.1 (Stationary Equilibrium). An Stationary Equilibrium is defined by a solution to households problem {a, b, c, d, l, V }, a stationary distributions {µ}, a solution to firm s problem {n j, k j, Π j }, prices {w, r k, r b, r a, q}, government fiscal policy {τ, T, G, B g } and aggregate quantities {K, N, Y, Π, A, B h } such that 1. Given prices {w, r b, r a }, profits Π and government fiscal policy {τ, T }, {a, b, c, d, l, V } solves household s problem characterized by 1-11; 2. Given the solution for agent s problem {a, b, c, d, l, V }, {µ} satisfy 12; 3. The aggregate variables {A, B h, N} are compatible with individual households policy functions and stationary distribution; 4. Given prices {w, r b, r a }, {n j, k j } solve firm s problem 13 with profit given by Π j. Moreover 5. The government budget constrain 19 is satisfied; k j = K, n j = N, Π j = Π 6. The illiquid asset markets clears 21 with conditions 23 and 22 satisfied; 7. The liquid asset markets clears 24. 5

2.9 Algorithm 1. Guess K, N and r b ; 2. Calculate implied prices: 3. Calculate implied profits and worker s bonus: 4. Find government fiscal policy: If taxes are adjusting set τ to: If transfers are adjusting set T to: Y = K α N 1 α m = ɛ 1 ɛ r k αm = (K/N) 1 α w = (1 α)m(k/n) α r a = r k δ Π = (1 m)y τ = G + T rb B g wn T = τwn + r b B g G If the exogenous expenditure is adjusting set G to If debt is adjusting set B g to G = τwn + r b B g T B g = G + T τwn r b 5. Solve the household problem and find the stationary distribution using the method described by Achdou et al. (2017); 6. Aggregating individual s policy function compute implied illiquid asset holdings, A, labor supply, N, and household liquid asset demand B h ; 7. Using aggregate illiquid asset A, calculate implied equity, q, and capital, K : q = where Y is obtained from the guess of K and N; 8. Calculate the excess demand Λ = K K K (1 m)y r a K = A Y ɛ + N N N + Bh + B g B g 9. If Λ is close enough to zero the equilibrium have been found. Otherwise update the guess and go back to step 2. 6

3 Equilibrium Conditions: Transition 3.1 Household Maximization The household value function is now given by (ρ + ζ)v t (a, b, z) = max c,l,d u(c, l) + V b,t(a, b, z) [ (1 τ t )w t zl + (r b t (b) + ζ)b + T t d χ(d, a) + π t (z) c ] (25) + V a,t (a, b, z)((r a t + ζ)a + d) + V y,t (a, b, z)( βz) + λ s.t. (V t (a, b, x) V t (a, b, z)) φ(x)dx + V t (a, b, y) b b; a 0; 0 l 1; r b t (b) = r b t + I{b 0}κ Which implies an equivalent set of equations as in the steady state case: 2-11. 3.2 Kolmogorov Forward Equation Let µ t (a, b, y) be the distribution of households at time t and g t (a, b, y) the corresponding density function. The Kolmogorov Forward Equation is now given by t g t (a, b, y) = a (s a t (a, b, y)g t (a, b, y)) (26) b ( s b t (a, b, y)g t (a, b, y) ) y ( βyg t (a, b, y)) (27) λg t (a, b, y) + λφ(y) g t (a, b, x)dx ζg t (a, b, y) + ζδ(a a 0 )δ(b b 0 )g t (y) (28) where δ is the Dirac delta function, (a 0, b 0 ) are starting assets and income and g (y) is the stationary distribution of y. 3.3 Firms 3.3.1 Final Good Producer The final good producer has the same problem as before with implied demand for the intermediate good given by: y j (p j,t ) = 3.4 Intermediate goods producers ( pj,t P t ) ɛ Y t Given the price p j,t the intermediate good producer chooses k j,t and n j,t to solve min k j,t,n j,t w t n j,t + r k t k j,t s.t. y j,t = Ξ t kj,tn α 1 α j,t ( ) ɛ pj,t y j,t = Y t P t 7

where Ξ t is TFP shock at t. The solution for firm s problem imply that k j,t = y j,t Ξ t ( α 1 α y j,t Where Π j,t is firm s operational profit. Firm s dynamic price setting problem imply w t rt k ) 1 α (29) n j,t = ( ) α (30) α w Ξ t t 1 α rt k m j,t = 1 ( ) 1 α ( ) wt r k α t (31) Ξ t 1 α α ( ) ( ) ( ) ɛ pj,t pj,t pj,t Π j,t = m j,t y j,t = m j,t (32) P t P t P t (33) Firm s profit is given by ( r a t Ẏt Y t ) m = ɛ 1 ɛ π t = ɛ θ (m t m ) + π t (34) Using again that firms are homogeneous we have Π j,t = Π j,t Θ(π j,t ) ( ) 1 α ( ) wt r k α m t = t (35) 1 α α ( ) 1 α α w t K t = Y t (36) 1 α N t = ( Y t α w 1 α rt k 34 to 39 characterize the solution to firm s problem. 3.5 Government The government budget constraint is given by r k t ) α (37) Y t = Ξ t Kt α Nt 1 α (38) Π t = (1 m t ) Y t Θ(π t ) (39) Ḃ g t + G t + T t = τ t w t N t + r b t B g t (40) 8

3.6 Distribution of Profits The distribution of profits follows the same scheme as in the steady state scenario. A share 1 ω of total profits Π t are given to workers as bonuses according to their productivity π t (z) = z z (1 ω)π t (41) where z is the average productivity. The remaining goes to equity holders. 3.7 Illiquid Asset The illiquid asset is invested in capital and equity from the intermediary firms as before. This again imply that A t = K t + q t (42) ωπ t + q t = rt k δ = rt a q t (43) which are the two equations characterizing equilibrium in the illiquid asset market. 3.8 Liquid Asset The liquid asset market clears when government debt is equal to household holdings of liquid bonds B h t + B g t = 0 (44) 3.9 Monetary Authority The Monetary authority follows a Taylor rule affecting the return of the liquid asset therefore r b t = i t π t. i t = r b + φπ t + ɛ t (45) 3.10 Equilibrium The set of aggregate equilibrium objects are {K t, N t, Y t, Π t, m t, w t, r k t, T t, π t (z), A t, q t, B h t, r a t, π t } that with 34 to 39, 40, 41, 42, 43, 44, 45 and the definition of A t and N t form a system with 14 equations and 14 unknowns at each point t in time. Definition 3.1 (Equilibrium). Equilibrium is defined by a solution to households problem {a t, b t, c t, d t, l t, V t }, a path of distributions {µ t }, a solution to firm s problem {n j,t, k j,t, π j,t }, prices {w t, r k t, r b t, r a t, q t }, the inflation rate {π t }, shocks {Ξ t, ɛ t }, government fiscal policy {τ t, T t, G t, B g t } and aggregate quantities {K t, N t, Y t, Π t, A t, B h t } such that 1. Given prices {w t, r b t, r a t } profits Π t and government taxes {τ t, T t }, {a t, b t, c t, d t, l t, V t } solves household s problem characterized by 25; 2. Given the solution for agent s problem {a t, b t, c t, d t, l t, V t }, {µ t } satisfy 26; 3. The aggregate quantities {N t, A t, B h t } are consistent with households maximization and the path for distribution {µ t }; 9

4. Given prices {w t, r b t, r a t }, {n j,t, k j,t } solve firm s problem 13 with profit given by Π t. Moreover and π t satisfy ; 5. The government budget constrain 40 is satisfied; 6. The illiquid asset markets clears 42 and 43; 7. The liquid asset markets clears 44. 8. The Taylor rule 45 is satisfied; 3.11 Algorithm k t = K t, n t = N t Let s say that the economy is initially at the steady state equilibrium and then is hit by a transitory monetary shock ɛ 0 or a transitory TFP shock A 0. The algorithm to calculate the transition dynamics is given by the following: 1. Compute the steady state equilibrium; 2. Guess a path for capital, K t, liquid asset holdings, B h t, labor supply, N t, and illiquid asset returns,r a t ; 3. Calculate the excess demand of liquid assets, B w = B h t + B g t, and use it to derive the implied guess for interest rate in the liquid asset r b t = r + 1 φḃw t + B w t B η where r is the stationary liquid asset return and η, φ and B are parameters; 4. Using this guess compute the implied prices and equilibrium objects Inflation using the Taylor Rule: π t = rb t r b ɛ t φ 1 Marginal cost by solving the Phillips Curve backward in time with the terminal condition m T = m : [( ) ] π t π t Wage: m t = m + θ ɛ r a t Ẏt Y t ( ) α Kt w t = (1 α)ξ t m t N t Profits: Π t = (1 m t ) Y t Θ(π t ) 10

Equity by solving the following equation backward with terminal condition that q T = q : q t = q t r a t ωπ t Because q 0 drops and K 0 is fixed, aggregate illiquid holdings A 0 drop on impact. Similarly, individual households a 0 drops. For simplicity, we assume that in steady state before impact all households have the same share of illiquid assets invested in equity q s /a = q /A and k /a = K /A, where an asterisk denotes variables before impact. Hence each households a 0 drops proportionately to A 0 : a 0 = k + q 0 s = K A a + q 0 1 A a = A 0 A a Use government budget constrain 40 to calculate the implied tax, transfer or debt depending on what is adjusting; 5. Solve household s transition problem and find the path of distributions using the method described by Achdou et al. (2017); 6. Using the path of distributions compute the implied path for liquid assets Bt h, illiquid assets, A t and labor supply, N t; 7. Use equilibrium on the illiquid asset to calculate the implied capital: 8. Calculate the error K t = A t q t Λ = K t K t + B h t B h t 9. If Λ is close to zero, the equilibrium have been found. Otherwise adjust the guess and go back to step 2. 11