On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Similar documents
Advanced Microeconomics

Basics of Game Theory

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Static Models of Oligopoly

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Classic Oligopoly Models: Bertrand and Cournot

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

REVEALED PREFERENCE TESTS OF THE COURNOT MODEL. By Andrés Carvajal, Rahul Deb, James Fenske and John K.-H. Quah 1

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Mixed duopolies with advance production

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

October 16, 2018 Notes on Cournot. 1. Teaching Cournot Equilibrium

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

1 Oligopoly: Bertrand Model

Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Product differences and prices

C31: Game Theory, Lecture 1

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

DISCRETE-TIME DYNAMICS OF AN

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Chapter 7 Duopoly. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly.

Oligopoly. Firm s Profit Maximization Firm i s profit maximization problem: Static oligopoly model with n firms producing homogenous product.

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

Barnali Gupta Miami University, Ohio, U.S.A. Abstract

EconS Sequential Competition

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

ONLINE APPENDIX. Upping the Ante: The Equilibrium Effects of Unconditional Grants to Private Schools

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Introduction to Game Theory

A nonparametric analysis of multi-product oligopolies

Maximin and minimax strategies in symmetric oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Equilibrium a la Cournot and Supply Function Equilibrium in Electricity Markets under Linear Price/Demand and Quadratic Costs

Overview. Producer Theory. Consumer Theory. Exchange

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Quantum Bertrand duopoly of incomplete information

The Nonparametric Approach to Evolutionary Oligopoly

Nonlinear dynamics in a duopoly with price competition and vertical differentiation

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

A Dynamic Network Oligopoly Model with Transportation Costs, Product Differentiation, and Quality Competition

Price and Capacity Competition

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

3. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition Competitive Equilibrium

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

Duopoly and Project Uncertainty

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Iterated Strict Dominance in Pure Strategies

EconS Nash Equilibrium in Games with Continuous Action Spaces.

Price-quantity competition with varying toughness

Research Article Complexity Analysis of a Cournot-Bertrand Duopoly Game Model with Limited Information

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

A Network Economic Model of a Service-Oriented Internet with Choices and Quality Competition

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Industrial Organization

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Durable goods monopolist

On Pure-Strategy Nash Equilibria in Price-Quantity Games

Transcription:

University of Manchester, UK November 25, 2010

Introduction Suppose we make a finite set of observations T = {1,..., m}, m 1, of a perfectly homogeneous-good oligopoly market. There is a finite number of firms N = {1,..., n}, n 2, which compete in the market. In each period we observe the price of each firm, P it, their output, Q it, and possibly their costs incurred, C it. The total set of observations can then be summarized as (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T. Given this information how should we go about checking whether these observations are consistent/inconsistent with firms playing a Nash equilibrium in prices?

Related literature Sprumont (2000) considered the case where we observe players choices from all possible subsets of strategy choices, all action spaces were finite, and identified two conditions, expansion and contraction consistency, which are necessary and sufficient to be able to rationalize the observed choices as Nash equilibria. Zhou (2005) considered two-player games where players strategy sets were the unit interval and assumed that we observe a finite subset of choices. Carvajal and Quah (2009) analyzed the Cournot oligopoly model- this was my motivation for studying this problem. Anticipating this work, Sprumont (2000, p.221) noted at the end of his paper that it would be interesting to characterize observable restrictions in games with more economic flesh such as oligopoly games.

Equilibrium concepts First consider a perfectly homogeneous-good market with N = {1,..., n}, n 2, firms. Each firm has a cost function C i : R + R + which is strictly increasing, continuous and satisfies C i (0) = 0. he market demand D : R + R + is continuous and strictly decreasing whenever D > 0. We shall let the function F : R + R + denote the inverse market demand in what follows.

Bertrand equilibrium Each firm simultaneously and independently chooses a P i R +. Firms in the market commit to supplying all the demand forthcoming at any price. If a firm posts the unique minimum price in the market then it obtains all the market demand and its payoff is P i D(P i ) C i (D(P i )). If a firm ties with m 1 firms at the minimum price then they share the demand equally between themselves and the payoff of each firm is given by 1 m P id(p i ) C i ( 1 m D(P i)). If a firm is undercut by any other firm in the market then it obtains zero demand, and given the assumption that the cost function passes through the origin, its payoff is zero.

Bertrand equilibrium These payoffs are summarized below. P i D(P i ) C i (D(P i )) if P i < P j j i; 1 π i (P i, P i ) = m P id(p i ) C i ( 1 m D(P i)) i ties with m 1 firms; 0 if P i > P j for some j. Definition A pure strategy Bertrand equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium of the game with payoffs defined above. That is, a vector of prices (P B i, P B i ) such that π i (P B i, P B i ) π i(p i, P B i ) for all P i R + and i N.

Cournot equilibrium Each firm simultaneously and independently chooses a Q i R +. Given the total output chosen by the firms the market demand clears this output and sends back a single market-clearing price. The payoff which any firm receives, given the vector of chosen outputs is (Q i, Q i ), is given below. n π i (Q i, Q i ) = F ( Q j )Q i C i (Q i ) j=1 Definition A pure strategy Cournot equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium of the game with payoffs defined above. That is, a vector of outputs (Q C i, Q C i ) such that π i (Q C i, Q C i ) π i(q i, Q C i ) for all Q i R + and i N.

Revealed Nash equilibria in oligopoly games Now return to the issue of what observable outcomes the equilibrium concepts impose on the set (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T. To organize the observations let P t = min i N P it. Let Qt = i N Q it denote the aggregate output produced in observation t. The set of firms which tie at the minimum price, what we shall informally call the set of active firms, is given by A t = {i N : P it = P t }.

Definition A set of oligopoly observations is a generic homogeneous-good market data set if it satisfies the following conditions: i) P it > 0, Q it 0, C it 0, P it Q it C it and Q it Q it whenever t t. ii) If P it > P jt then Q it = 0. iii) If P it = P jt = P t then Q it = Q jt. iv) A t 2. We observe an oligopoly market where the law of one price holds and tieing firms split the market demand equally. A special type of data set is what we shall term a single-price data set: this is a generic homogeneous-good data set with the additional property that P it = P t for all i N and t T.

Rationalizable observations Definition A set of generic homogeneous-good observations, (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, is Bertrand rationalizable if there exist C 2 functions, C i : R + R + for each i N, D t : R + R + for each t T, such that: i) C i (0) = 0 and C i (x) > 0 for all x > 0. ii) D t (x) 0 and D t(x) 0 with the latter inequality holding strictly whenever D t (x) > 0. iii) C i (Q it ) = C it and D t (P t ) = Q t. iv) The set of observed prices (P 1t,..., P nt ) is a Bertrand equilibrium in pure strategies for each t T.

Definition A single-price data set, (P t, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, is Cournot rationalizable if there exist C 2 functions, C i : R + R + for each i N, F t : R + R + for each t T, such that: i) C i (0) = 0 and C i (x) > 0 for all x > 0. ii) F t (x) 0 and F t (x) 0 with the latter inequality holding strictly whenever F t (x) > 0. iii) C i (Q it ) = C it and F t (Q t ) = P t. iv) The set of observed outputs (Q 1t,..., Q nt ) is a Cournot equilibrium in pure strategies for each t T.

Let R i (t) = {t T : Q it Q t }. That is, R i (t) is the set of observations when the output of firm i is greater than the aggregate output in observation t. Let S i (t) = {t T : Q it < Q it }. The set S i (t) is those observations when the output of firm i is less than its own output in observation t. We shall also want to compare firms outputs with regards to the following quantity ˆQ t = Q t /( A t + 1). Let M i (t) = {t T : Q it ˆQ t } which is the set of observations when the output of firm i is greater than or equal to ˆQ t.

Definition A set of generic homogeneous-good oligopoly observations, (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, satisfy the increasing cost condition (ICC) if, whenever S i (t), then C it C it > 0 for all t S i (t). Definition A set of generic homogeneous-good oligopoly observations, (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, satisfy the monopoly deviation condition (MDC) if, whenever R i (t), then Pt Q it C it Pt Qt C it for all t R i (t) with the inequality holding strictly whenever Q it > Qt.

Definition A set of generic homogeneous-good oligopoly observations, (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, satisfy the tie deviation condition (TDC) if, whenever M i (t), then Pt ˆQ t C it for all t M i (t) and i N\A t with the inequality holding strictly whenever Q it > ˆQ t. Definition A single-price data set, (Pt, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, satisfies the marginal condition (MC) if, whenever S i (t), then Pt Q it C it < Pt Q it C it for all t S i (t).

Results Theorem A set of generic homogeneous-good oligopoly observations, (P it, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, is Bertrand rationalizable if and only if it satisfies ICC, MDC and TDC. Theorem A single-price data set, (P t, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, is Cournot rationalizable if and only if it satisfies ICC and MC (Carvajal and Quah, 2009). Theorem A single-price data set, (P t, Q it, C it ) i N,t T, is Bertrand and Cournot rationalizable if and only if it satisfies ICC, MC and MDC. The result follows from combining the conditions in the first two theorems and noting that a single-price data set trivially satisfies TDC.

Observations of prices and quantities Suppose cost information is not available so that our set of observations reduces to (P it, Q it ) i N,t T. Can any set of generic homogeneous-good market observations be Bertrand or Cournot rationalized? Consider the following example of a symmetric duopoly, n = 2, with two observations, m = 2. (P, Q) t=1 (1, 4) t=2 (2, 2) First observation requires 0 < C(4) 4. Monopoly deviation condition requires that we can choose the cost function so that 4 C(2) 8 C(4) with 0 < C(2) < C(4). Inspection reveals that these observations cannot be simultaneously satisfied. Hence, the observations cannot be Bertrand rationalized.

Definition A generic homogeneous-good set of prices and outputs, (P it, Q it ) i N,t T, satisfies the revenue condition (RC) if, whenever R i (t), then P t Q it > P t (Q t Q it ) for all t R i (t) and i A t. The revenue condition states that the observed revenue which a firm obtains when it supplies an output at least as large as the observed aggregate output must be strictly greater than the increase in the revenue which a firm would obtain from supplying the entire market at the existing price. Definition A generic homogeneous-good set of prices and outputs, (P it, Q it ) i N,t T, satisfies the tied revenue condition (TRC) if i A t then we do not observe a t T such that i N \ A t and Pt ˆQ t Pt Q it and ˆQ t Q it with at least one of the inequalities holding strictly.

Partial characterizations of rationalizable price-quantity observations Proposition A generic homogeneous-good set of prices and outputs, (P it, Q it ) i N,t T, is Bertrand rationalizable only if it satisfies RC and TRC. Proof. Suppose we have a generic set of observations which violate RC. Then there is an i, t and t R i (t) such that P t Q it P t (Q t Q it ). If the observations are rationalizable we should be able to find a cost function such that C i (Q it ) Pt Q it and C i (Q it ) Pt Q it as firms do not make losses. MDC also requires that C i (Q it ) C i (Q it ) > P t (Q t Q it ). However, if C i (Q it ) Pt Q it we must have that C i (Q it ) C i (Q it ) < Pt (Qt Q it ) and the observations are not Bertrand rationalizable.

Suppose that we have a set of generic observations which violate TRC. Then there is an i, t and t such that i A t, i N \ A t and Pt ˆQ t > Pt Q it and ˆQ t Q it. If the observations are rationalizable we should be able to find a cost function so that C i (Q it ) P t Q it. However, as ˆQ t Q it and P t ˆQ t > P t Q it this implies that P t ˆQ t C i ( ˆQ t ) > 0. Firm i has a profitable deviation by posting the minimum price in observation t. If one returns to the example data set it is clear that the reason that set of observations could not be Bertrand rationalized is because it violates RC: in observation one each firm produces a output equal to the aggregate market output in the second observation and obtains a revenue of 4. The revenue condition then requires that 4 > 2(4 2) which is violated.

Definition A single-price data set of prices and outputs, (P t, Q it ) i N,t T, satisfies the strengthened revenue condition (SRC) if, whenever R i (t), then P t Q it > P t Q t for all t R i (t). The following result shows that this condition alone is sufficient for a single-price set of prices and outputs to be Bertrand rationalizable. Proposition A single-price data set of prices and outputs, (P t, Q it ) i N,t T, is Bertrand rationalizable if it satisfies SRC.

What about Cournot rationalizable observations when cost information is unobservable? Proposition Any single-price data set of prices and outputs, (P t, Q it ) i N,t T, is Cournot rationalizable (Carvajal and Quah, 2009). This represents a significant difference between the two models. One of the advantages of the revealed preference method is that we can write down possible observations and test their compatibility with different equilibrium concepts.

Examples of revealed Nash equilibria in oligopoly games- Example 1 (P, Q, C) t=1 (3, 1, 1) t=2 (4, 2, 7) Consider the example observations given in the table of a symmetric duopoly, n = 2, with two observations, m = 2. First, we can note that S i (2) = {1}. The increasing cost condition requires C i2 C i1 = 7 1 > 0 which is satisfied. Second, note that R i (1) = {2}. The monopoly deviation condition requires P i1 Q i1 C i1 = (3)(1) (1) = 2 (3)(2) 7 = 1 = P 1 Q 1 C i2 which is satisfied. The observations are Bertrand rationalizable. Finally, the marginal condition requires P 2 Q i2 C i2 = (4)(2) 7 = 1 > (4)(1) 1 = 3 = P 2 Q i1 C i1 which is violated. We can conclude that this set of observations cannot be Cournot rationalized.

Example 2 (P, Q, C) t=1 (3, 1, 2) t=2 (4, 2, 4) First, note that S i (2) = {1}. The increasing cost condition requires C i2 C i1 = 4 2 > 0 which is satisfied. Second, note that R i (1) = {2}. The monopoly deviation condition requires that P i1 Q i1 C i1 = (3)(1) 2 = 1 (3)(2) 4 = 2 = P 1 Q 1 C i2 which is violated. Therefore this set of observations cannot be Bertrand rationalized. The marginal condition requires that no firm can benefit by reducing their outputs. The condition requires that P 2 Q i2 C i2 = (4)(2) 4 = 4 > (4)(1) 2 = 2 = P 2 Q i1 C i1. Therefore this set of observations can be Cournot rationalized.

Concluding remarks The aim of this work has been to provide a revealed preference approach to the classical oligopoly games. Established an elegant theoretical framework and intuitive characterizations of the rationalizable observations. What about more applied models? In Vives (1999, Ch. 6) it is assumed that differentiated-good market demand is generated from a representative consumer with utility U(q) p.q so partial equilibrium analysis is valid. A revealed preference analysis of this model would have the advantage of generating applied work- this remains an interesting topic for future research.