Dynamic Markets for Lemons: Performance, Liquidity, and Policy Intervention

Similar documents
DECENTRALIZED TRADE MITIGATES THE LEMONS PROBLEM

A Centralized or a Decentralized Labor Market?

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Some Notes on Adverse Selection

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Mechanism Design

Endogenous Market Segmentation for Lemons

Solving Extensive Form Games

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Homework #9 - Answer key

Cheap Talk in the Decentralized Market for Lemons

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets

Equilibria in Second Price Auctions with Participation Costs

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Experimentation, Patents, and Innovation

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Internet Appendix for The Labor Market for Directors and Externalities in Corporate Governance

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics"

Search, Adverse Selection, and Market Clearing

Prices and Quality Signals

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

OPTIMAL TWO-PART TARIFF LICENSING CONTRACTS WITH DIFFERENTIATED GOODS AND ENDOGENOUS R&D* Ramón Faulí-Oller and Joel Sandonís**

Screening. Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1

Decentralized Trading with Private Information

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Upstream capacity constraint and the preservation of monopoly power in private bilateral contracting

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

h Edition Money in Search Equilibrium

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline

Optimal taxation with monopolistic competition

Exclusive contracts and market dominance

Banks, depositors and liquidity shocks: long term vs short term interest rates in a model of adverse selection

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis

Simplifying this, we obtain the following set of PE allocations: (x E ; x W ) 2

Decentralized trading with private information

Externalities and PG. MWG- Chapter 11

Incentives and Machine Learning

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Dynamic Merger Review

Veto Constraint in Mechanism Design: Ine ciency with Correlated Types

game. Daniel Cardona Universitat de les Illes Balears and CREB Antoni Rubí-Barceló Universitat de les Illes Balears June 1, 2012 Abstract

All Entrepreneurial Productivity Increases are Not Created Equal

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

THREE ESSAYS ON GAME THEORY. Demet Yilmazkuday. Dissertation. Submitted to the Faculty of the. Graduate School of Vanderbilt University

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Lecture 7. Simple Dynamic Games

On the Threat of Counterfeiting

Arbitrage and global cones: Another counterexample*

Kyoto Project Mechanisms and Technology. Di usion

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Chapter 1. GMM: Basic Concepts

Spatial Competition and Collaboration Networks

Pre-Communication in a Coordination Game with Incomplete Information

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 21: Stochastic Dynamic Programming and Applications

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Endogenous timing in a mixed duopoly

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Not Only What But also When A Theory of Dynamic Voluntary Disclosure

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM

Problem 1 (30 points)

On the Optimality of Financial Repression. V.V. Chari

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Bounded Rationality Lecture 4

Some Benefits of Cyclical Monetary Policy

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Robust Mechanism Design and Robust Implementation

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

Extensive Form Games with Perfect Information

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Lecture Notes on Bargaining

Advanced Microeconomics Fall Lecture Note 1 Choice-Based Approach: Price e ects, Wealth e ects and the WARP

Monetary Mechanisms. Chao Gu. Department of Economics, University of Missouri. Randall Wright

Volume 30, Issue 3. Monotone comparative statics with separable objective functions. Christian Ewerhart University of Zurich

PERISHABLE DURABLE GOODS

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Hotelling Meets Weber

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

Final Exam (Solution) Economics 501b Microeconomic Theory

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Experimentation and Observational Learning in a Market with Exit

National Treatment in International Agreements on. Intellectual Property

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

WORKING PAPER NO SPINOFFS AND THE MARKET FOR IDEAS. Satyajit Chatterjee Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

An E cient Auction. (First version: October 1998) April 2001

Property Rights and the E ciency of Bargaining

Bayesian Nash equilibrium

When Should a Firm Expand Its Business? The Signaling Implications of Business Expansion

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Discussion Paper #1541

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Notes on the Thomas and Worrall paper Econ 8801

Transcription:

Dynamic Markets for Lemons: Performance, Liquidity, and Policy Intervention Diego Moreno y John Wooders z August 2013 Abstract We study non-stationary dynamic decentralized markets with adverse selection in which trade is bilateral and prices are determined by bargaining. Examples include labor markets, housing markets, and markets for nancial assets. We characterize equilibrium, and identify the dynamics of transaction prices, trading patterns, and the average quality in the market. When the horizon is nite, the surplus in the unique equilibrium exceeds the competitive surplus; as frictions vanish the surplus remains above the competitive surplus even though the market becomes completely illiquid at all but the rst and last dates. When the horizon is in nite, the surplus realized equals the static competitive surplus. Subsidizing low quality or taxing high quality raises the surplus. We gratefully acknowledge nancial support from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation, grant ECO2011-29762. y Departamento de Economía, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, dmoreno@eco.uc3m.es. z Department of Economics, University of Technology Sydney, john.wooders@uts.edu.au.

Notation Chart A Market for Lemons : the good s quality, 2 fh; Lg: u : c : q : value to buyers of a unit of -quality. cost to sellers of -quality. fraction of sellers of -quality. t: a date at which the market is open, t 2 f1;... ; T g: : traders discount factor. u(q) = qu H + (1 q)u L : q: = ch u L u H u L, i.e., u(q) = ch. S: = m L (u L c L ). ^q: = ch c L u H c L, i.e., u(^q) ch = (1 ^q)(u L c L ). ~S: = m L + m H (1 ^q) (u L c L ): r t : t : A Decentralized Market for Lemons reservation price at date t of sellers of -quality. probability that a seller of -quality who is matched at date t trades. m t : stock of -quality sellers in the market at date t: q t : fraction of -quality sellers in the market at date t: V t : expected utility of a seller of -quality at date t: V B t : expected utility of a buyer at date t: S DE : surplus in a decentralized market equilibrium see equation (3). t : probability of a price o er of r t at date t:

1 Introduction Adverse selection pervades real good markets (e.g., cars, housing, labor) as well as markets for nancial assets (e.g., insurance, stocks). Akerlof s nding that competitive markets for lemons may perform poorly thus has broad welfare implications, and calls for research on fundamental questions that remain open: How do dynamic markets for lemons perform? What is the role of frictions in alleviating adverse selection? What determines market liquidity? Is there a role for government intervention? Our analysis provides answers to these questions. We study the performance of decentralized markets for lemons in which trade is bilateral and time consuming, and buyers and sellers bargain over prices. These features are common in markets for real goods and nancial assets. We characterize the unique decentralized market equilibrium, and we identify the dynamics of transaction prices, trading patterns, and the market composition (i.e., the fractions of units of the di erent qualities in the market). Using our characterization of market equilibrium, we identify policy interventions that are welfare improving. We also study the asymptotic properties of equilibrium as frictions vanish. We consider a market in which sellers are privately informed about the quality of the unit of the good they hold, which may be high or low, and buyers are homogeneous and value each quality more highly than sellers. We assume that the expected value to buyers of a random unit is below the cost of a high quality unit, since in this case only low quality units trade in Akerlof s competitive equilibrium, i.e., the lemons problem arises. The market operates over a number of consecutive dates. All buyers and sellers are present at the market open, and there is no further entry. At each date a fraction of the buyers and sellers remaining in the market are randomly paired. In every pair, the buyer makes a take-it-or-leave-it price o er. If the seller accepts, then the agents trade at that price and exit the market. If the seller rejects the o er, then the agents split and both remain in the market at the next date. There are trading frictions since meeting a partner is time-consuming and traders discount future gains. In this market, equilibrium dynamics are non-stationary and involve a delicate balance: At each date, buyers price o ers must be optimal given the sellers reservation prices, the market composition, and the buyers payo to remaining in the 1

market. While the market composition is determined by past price o ers, the sellers reservation prices are determined by future price o ers. Thus, a market equilibrium cannot be computed recursively. We begin by studying the equilibria of decentralized markets that open over a nite horizon. Perishable goods such as fresh fruit or event tickets, as well as nancial assets such as (put or call) options or thirty-year bonds are noteworthy examples. We show that if frictions are not large, then equilibrium is unique, and we calculate it explicitly. The key features of equilibrium dynamics are as follows: at the rst date, both a low price (accepted only by low quality sellers) and negligible prices (rejected by both types of sellers) are o ered; at the last date, both a high price (accepted by both types of sellers) and a low price are o ered; and at all the intervening dates, all three types of prices high, low and negligible are o ered. Interestingly, as frictions vanish there is trade only at the rst and last dates, and the market is completely illiquid at all intervening dates. In contrast to the competitive equilibrium, some high quality units trade while not all low quality units trade. Nonetheless, low quality trades with delay. The surplus realized in the decentralized market equilibrium, however, exceeds the surplus realized in the competitive equilibrium: the gain realized from trading high quality units more than o sets the loss resulting from trading low quality units with delay. The surplus realized increases as frictions decrease, and thus decentralized markets yield more than the competitive surplus (and traders payo s are not competitive) even in the limit as frictions vanish. We identify the limiting equilibrium of the market as the horizon approaches in nity, and show that it is an equilibrium when the horizon is in nite. Equilibrium trading dynamics are simple: at the rst date buyers make low and negligible price o ers (hence only some low quality sellers trade), and at every date thereafter buyers make only high and negligible price o ers in proportions that do not change over time. All units trade eventually, although the expected delay becomes in nite as frictions vanish. In contrast to prior results in the literature, each trader obtains his competitive payo and the competitive surplus is realized even when frictions are signi cant. An implication of this result is that in a decentralized market the surplus lost due to trading low quality with delay exactly equals the surplus realized from 2

trading high quality units. Our characterization of decentralized market equilibrium yields insights into the e ectiveness of policies designed to increase market e ciency and market liquidity. We take the liquidity of a quality to be the ease with which a unit of that quality is sold, i.e., the probability it trades. In markets that open over a nite horizon, the liquidity of high quality decreases as traders become more patient and, somewhat counter-intuitively, as the probability of meeting a partner increases. Indeed, as frictions vanish trade freezes at all but the rst and the last date. In markets that open over an in nite horizon, the liquidity of each quality decreases as traders become more patient, and is una ected by the probability of meeting a partner. Policy intervention may alleviate or aggravate the adverse selection problem. Subsidizing low quality increases the liquidity of high quality and raises the net surplus (i.e., the surplus net of the present value cost of the subsidy). When the horizon is nite, the subsidy raises net surplus even as frictions vanish. When the horizon is in nite, as frictions vanish the subsidy amounts to a pure transfer to low quality sellers and has no e ect on net surplus. Subsidizing high quality reduces the net surplus when the horizon is nite and frictions are small. Strikingly, when the horizon is in nite taxing high quality raises revenue without a ecting the traders payo s, and hence raises the net surplus. Our work relates to a literature that examines the mini-micro foundations of competitive equilibrium. This literature has established that decentralized trade of homogeneous goods tends to yield competitive outcomes when trading frictions are small see, e.g., Gale (1987, 1996) or Binmore and Herrero (1988) when bargaining is under complete information, and Moreno and Wooders (2002) and Serrano (2002) when bargaining is under incomplete information. More recent work has studied decentralized markets with adverse selection. For markets with stationary entry, Moreno and Wooders (2010) show that payo s are competitive as frictions vanish. Inderst and Muller (2002) show that the lemons problem may be mitigated if sellers can sort themselves into di erent submarkets. Inderst (2004) studies a model where agents bargain over contracts, and shows that separating contracts always emerge in equilibrium. Cho and Matsui (2011) study the impact of the layo probability in a market with long term relationships. 3

For the one time entry case, on which the present paper focuses, Blouin (2003) studies a market that opens over an in nite horizon, in which only one of three exogenously given prices may emerge from bargaining, and nds that equilibrium payo s are not competitive. Camargo and Lester (2011) study a model in which buyers make one of two exogenously set price o ers. They show that all units trade in nite time. An essential feature of our model, which explains the di ering results, is that prices are fully endogenous. 1 Several other recent papers study the role of public information in overcoming the adverse selection problem. Kim (2011) studies a continuous time version of the model of Moreno and Wooders (2010), and shows that if buyers observe the length of time a seller has been in the market, or the number of times a seller has been matched in the past, then market equilibria are more e cient than when this information is absent. Bilancini and Boncinelli (2011) study a market for lemons with nitely many buyers and sellers, and show that if the number of sellers in the market is public information, then in equilibrium all units trade in nite time. Lauermann and Wolinsky (2011) explore the role of trading rules in a search model with adverse selection, and show that information is aggregated more e ectively in auctions than under sequential search by an informed buyer. In our setting, traders only observe their own personal histories. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the market. Section 3 presents our results. Section 4 concludes. Proofs are presented in Appendix A. Appendix B studies dynamic centralized markets. 2 A Decentralized Market for Lemons Consider a market for an indivisible commodity whose quality can be either high (H) or low (L). There is a positive measure of buyers and sellers. The measure of sellers with a unit of quality 2 fh; Lg is m > 0. For simplicity, we assume that the measure of buyers (m B ) is equal to the measure of sellers, i.e., m B = m H + m L. Each 1 Another important di erence between Camargo and Lester (2011) s approach and ours is that in their setting traders have discount rates bounded away from one and randomly drawn at every date, while in ours traders have a xed discount rate not too far from one. 4

buyer wants to purchase a single unit of the good. Each seller owns a single unit of the good. A seller knows the quality of his good, but quality is unobservable to buyers. Preferences are characterized by values and costs: the value to a buyer of a unit of high (low) quality is u H (u L ); the cost to a seller of a unit of high (low) quality is c H (c L ). Thus, if a buyer and a seller trade at price p; the buyer obtains a utility of u p and the seller obtains a utility of p c, where u = u H and c = c H if the unit traded is of high quality, and u = u L and c = c L if it is of low quality. A buyer or seller who does not trade obtains a utility of zero. We assume that both buyers and sellers value high quality more than low quality (i.e., u H > u L and c H > c L ), and that buyers value each quality more highly than sellers (i.e., u H > c H and u L > c L ). Also we restrict attention to markets in which the lemons problem arises; that is, we assume that the fraction of sellers of -quality in the market, denoted by q := m m H + m L ; is such that the expected value to a buyer of a randomly selected unit of the good, given by u(q H ) := q H u H + q L u L, is below the cost of high quality, c H. Equivalently, we may state this assumption as Note that q H < q implies c H > u L. u L q H < q := ch u H u : L Therefore, we assume throughout that u H > c H > u L > c L and q H < q. Under these parameter restrictions only low quality trades in the unique competitive equilibrium, even though there are gains to trade for both qualities see Figure 1. For future reference, we describe this equilibrium in Remark 1 below. Remark 1. The market has a unique competitive equilibrium. In equilibrium all low quality units trade at the price u L, and no high quality unit trades. Thus, the surplus, S = m L (u L c L ); (1) is captured by low quality sellers. 5

u H supply c H u(q H ) u L c L demand 1-q H 1 Figure 1: c H >u(q H )>u L In our model of decentralized trade, the market is open for T consecutive dates. All traders are present at the market open, and there is no further entry. Traders discount utility at a common rate 2 (0; 1), i.e., if a unit of quality trades at date t and price p, then the buyer obtains a utility of t 1 (u p) and the seller obtains a utility of t 1 (p c ). At each date every buyer (seller) in the market meets a randomly selected seller (buyer) with probability 2 (0; 1). In each pair, the buyer o ers a price at which to trade. If the o er is accepted by the seller, then the agents trade and both leave the market. If the o er is rejected by the seller, then the agents split and both remain in the market at the next date. A trader who is unmatched at the current date also remains in the market at the next date. An agent observes only the outcomes of his own matches. In this market, a pure strategy for a buyer is a sequence of price o ers (p 1 ; : : : ; p T ) 2 R T +. A pure strategy for a seller is a sequence of reservation prices r = (r 1 ; : : : ; r T ) 2 R T +; where r t is the smallest price that the seller accepts at date t 2 f1; : : : ; T g. 2 The strategies of buyers may be described by a sequence = ( 1 ; : : : ; T ), where t is a c.d.f. with support on R + specifying the probability distribution over price o ers at date t 2 f1; : : : ; T g. Given, the maximum expected utility of a seller of 2 Ignoring, as we do, that a trader may condition his actions on the history of his prior matches is inconsequential see Osborne and Rubinstein (1990), pages 154-162. 6

quality 2 fh; Lg at date t T is de ned recursively as Z 1 (p t c ) d t (p t ) + 1 V t where V T +1 = max x2r + a price o er p t is p t x Z 1 x d t (p t ) Vt+1 ; = 0. In this expression, the payo to a seller of quality who receives c if p t is at least his reservation price x, and it is V t+1; his continuation utility, otherwise. Since all sellers of quality have the same maximum expected utility, then their equilibrium reservation prices are identical. Therefore we restrict attention to strategy distributions in which all sellers of quality 2 fh; Lg use the same sequence of reservation prices r 2 R T +. Let (; r H ; r L ) be a strategy distribution. For t 2 f1; : : : ; T g; the probability that a matched seller of quality 2 fh; Lg trades, denoted by t, is t = Z 1 r t d t : (2) The stock of sellers of quality in the market at date t + 1; denoted by m t+1, is m t+1 = (1 t ) m t ; where m 1 = m : The fraction of sellers of quality in the market at date t, denoted by q t, is m t qt = : m H t + m L t The maximum expected utility of a buyer at date t T is de ned recursively as 8 0 1 9 < Vt B = max x2r + : X qt I(x; rt )(u x) + @1 X = qt I(x; rt ) A Vt+1 B ; ; 2fH;Lg 2fH;Lg where VT B +1 = 0. Here I(x; y) is the indicator function whose value is 1 if x y; and 0 otherwise. In this expression, the payo to a buyer who o ers the price x is u x when matched to a -quality seller who accepts the o er (i.e., I(x; r t ) = 1), and it is V B t+1, her continuation utility, otherwise. A strategy distribution (; r H ; r L ) is a decentralized market equilibrium (DE) if for each t 2 f1;... ; T g: (DE:) r t c = V t+1 for 2 fh; Lg; and 7

(DE:B) for every p t in the support of t we have 0 X qt I(p t ; rt )(u p t ) + @1 X 2fH;Lg 2fH;Lg 1 qt I(p t ; rt ) A Vt+1 B = V B Condition DE: ensures that each type seller is indi erent between accepting or rejecting an o er of his reservation price. Condition DE:B ensures that price o ers that are made with positive probability are optimal. The surplus realized in a decentralized market equilibrium can be calculated as S DE = m B V B 1 + m H V H 1 + m L V L 1. (3) t : 3 Decentralized Market Equilibrium Proposition 1 establishes basic properties of decentralized market equilibria. intuition for these results is straightforward see Lemma 1 in Appendix A. The Proposition 1. Assume that T < 1; and let (; r H ; r L ) be a DE. Then for all t: (P1.1) r H t = c H > r L t, V H t = 0, and q H t+1 q H t. (P1.2) Only the high price p t = r H t, or the low price p t = r L t ; or negligible prices p t < r L t may be o ered with positive probability. In equilibrium, at each date a buyer may o er a high price p = r H t, which is accepted by both types of sellers, or a low price p = r L t, which is accepted by low quality sellers and rejected by high quality sellers, or a negligible price p < r L t ; which is rejected by both types of sellers. For 2 fh; Lg denote by t the probability of a price o er equal to r t : Since prices greater than r H t then the probability of a high price o er is H t are o ered with probability zero, = H t. (Recall that t is the probability that a matched -quality seller trades at date t see equation (2).) And since prices in the interval (r L t ; r H t ) are o ered with probability zero, then the probability of a low price o er is L t = L t H t : Thus, the probability of a negligible price o er is 1 ( H t + L t ) = 1 L t. Proposition 1 allows a simpler description of a DE. Henceforth we describe a DE by a collection ( H ; L ; r H ; r L ), where = ( 1; : : : ; T ) for 2 fh; Lg, and thus ignore the distribution of negligible price o ers, which is inconsequential. 8

Proposition 2 establishes additional properties of market equilibrium. Proposition 2. Assume that T < 1; and let ( H ; L ; r H ; r L ) be a DE. Then: (P2.1) At every date t 2 f1; : : : ; T g either high or low prices are o ered with positive probability, i.e., H t + L t > 0. (P2.2) At date 1 high prices are o ered with probability zero, i.e., H 1 = 0: (P2.3) At date T negligible prices are o ered with probability zero, i.e., 1 H T L T = 0. Propositions P 2:2 and P 2:3 are intuitive. The intuition for P 2:1 is a bit more involved: Suppose, for example, that all buyers make negligible o ers at date t, i.e., H t = L t = 0: Let t 0 be the rst date following t where a buyer makes a non-negligible price o er. Since there is no trade between t and t 0, then the distribution of qualities is the same at t and t 0 ; i.e., q H t = qt H 0. Thus, an impatient buyer is better o by o ering at date t the price she o ers at t 0 ; which implies that negligible prices are suboptimal at t; i.e., H t + L t = 1: Hence H t > 0 and/or L t > 0: In a market that opens for a single date, i.e., T = 1, the sellers reservation prices are their costs. The fraction of high quality sellers c L ^q := ch u H c ; L makes a buyer indi erent between an o er of c H and an o er of c L. It is easy to see that q < ^q: Since q H < q by assumption, then q H < ^q. Thus, if T = 1 only low price o ers are made (i.e., H 1 propositions P 2:2 and P 2:3. = 0 and L 1 = 1) and only low quality trades, as implied by Proposition 3 below establishes existence and uniqueness of DE when frictions are not large, i.e., whenever and are su ciently near one that the following inequalities hold: (F:1) H := ul c L (c H c L ) < 1; (F:2) (c H u L ) > (1 + ) (1 ) (u L c L ); and (F:3) (1 H )q H (1 H )q H + (1 )(1 q H ) > ^q. The bounds imposed on and by these inequalities depend upon the values and costs of both qualities. Since c H > u L > c L and ^q < 1, it is easy to see that these inequalities are satis ed for and near one. 9

For t 2 f1; : : : ; T g write t = T t (1 ^q)(u L c L ): Clearly t is increasing in and and approaches (1 ^q)(u L c L ) as and approach one. Further, t is decreasing in T and approaches zero as T approaches in nity. Proposition 3. If 1 < T < 1 and frictions are not large, then the unique DE is: (P3.1) High Price O ers: H 1 = 0, H t = 1 c H u L c L u L + t for 1 < t < T, and (P3.2) Low Price O ers: H T = ul c L T 1 : (c H c L ) for 1 < t < T, and L T = 1 H T. (P3.3) r H t = c H for all t. L 1 = ch u L + 2 q H (u H u L ) ; (1 q H )(c H u L + 2 ) L t = (1 H (1 ) t ) t+1 u H u L c H u L + t+1 u H c H t (P3.4) r L t = u L t for all t < T and r L T = cl. The payo to a buyer (low quality seller) is V B 1 = 1 ( V L 1 = u L c L 1 ), which is above (below) his competitive payo, decreases (increases) with T and increases (decreases) with and. The surplus, given by S DE = (u L c L )m L + m H 1, is above the competitive surplus S, decreases with T, and increases with and. It is easy to describe the equilibrium trading patterns: at the rst date only low and negligible prices are o ered, and thus some low quality sellers trade, but no high quality sellers trade (i.e., H 1 = 0 < L 1 < 1). At intermediate dates, high, low and negligible prices are o ered, and thus some sellers of both types trade (i.e., H t ; L t > 0 10

and 1 H t L t > 0). At the last date only high and low prices are o ered, and thus all low quality sellers and some high quality sellers trade. Price dispersion is key feature of equilibrium: At every date but the rst there is trade at more than one price since both c H and rt L < c H are o ered. The comparative statics of buyer payo s are intuitive: In equilibrium negligible price o ers are optimal at every date except the last. Hence only at the last date does a buyer capture any surplus. Consequently, buyer payo s are increasing in and and decreasing in T. Low quality sellers capture surplus whenever high price o ers are made, i.e., at every date except the rst. The probability of a high price o er decreases with both and, and increases with T, and thus the payo to low quality sellers decreases with and, and increases with T. The aggregate e ect on surplus of increasing or or decreasing T is positive since the measure of buyers exceeds that of low quality sellers. Counter-intuitively, shortening the horizon over which the market opens is advantageous since the surplus decreases with T (for T 2); i.e., it is maximal when T = 2. In the DE, units of both qualities trade, although with delay. The surplus generated in the DE is greater than the competitive equilibrium surplus, S: the gain from trading high quality units more than o sets the loss from trading low quality units with delay. In contrast, in markets for a homogenous good, the competitive equilibrium surplus is an upper bound to the surplus that can be realized in a DE. (Moreno and Wooders (2002), e.g., show that this bound is achieved as frictions vanish.) An Example Consider a market in which u H = 1, c H = :6, u L = :4, c L = :2, m H = :2, m L = :8, and T = 10. Figures 2a and 2b show the dynamics of the stocks of sellers of high and low quality in the market, m H t and m L t. Figure 2c shows the dynamics of the market composition, qt H. These gures illustrate several features of equilibrium as frictions become smaller: high quality trades more slowly, low quality trades more quickly at the rst date and at the last date, but trades more slowly at intermediate dates, the fraction qt H increases more quickly, but equals ^q = :5 at the market close regardless of the level of frictions. Even when frictions are very small (e.g., = = :99) a substantial fraction of the high quality units does not trade. 11

m t H 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Figure 2(a): High Quality Stocks Date m t L 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Figure 2(b): Low Quality Stocks Date q t H 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Figure 2(c): Proportion of High Quality in the Market Date 12

Proposition 4 identi es the market equilibrium as frictions vanish. A remarkable feature of equilibrium is that at every intermediate date all price o ers are negligible (i.e., the market freezes as both qualities become completely illiquid), and all trade concentrates at the rst and last date. Since the market is active only at the rst and the last date, then the equilibrium is independent of T so long as 1 < T < 1. Proposition 4. If 1 < T < 1, then as and approach one the DE approaches (~ H ; ~ L ; ~r H ; ~r L ) given by: (P4.1) High Price O ers: ~ H t = 0 for t < T, and (P4.2) Low Price O ers: ~ H T = ul c L u H c L. ~ L 1 = ~ L t = 0 for 1 < t < T, and ~ L T = 1 ~ H T. (P4.3) ~r H t = c H for all t. ^q qh ^q (1 q H ) ; (P4.4) ~r L t = c L + ^q(u L c L ) for all t < T, and ~r L T = cl. The payo to a buyer (low quality seller) remains above (below) his competitive payo and approaches ~ V B 1 = (1 ^q) (u L c L ) ( ~ V L 1 = ^q(u L c L )). The surplus remains above the competitive surplus and approaches ~S = m L + m H (1 ^q) (u L c L ); independently of T. Decentralized Market Equilibria when the Horizon is Infinite We now consider decentralized markets that open over an in nite horizon. In these markets, given a strategy distribution (; r H ; r L ) one calculates the maximum expected utility of each type of trader at each date by solving a dynamic optimization problem. The de nition of DE, however, remains the same. Proposition 5 identi es the limiting DE as T approaches in nity, (^ H ; ^ L ; ^r H ; ^r L ), and establishes that the limiting payo s and surplus are competitive. Moreover, (^ H ; ^ L ; ^r H ; ^r L ) is a DE of the market that opens over an in nite horizon. Although 13

there are multiple equilibria when T = 1, only this limiting DE can be approached from a nite T. (Multiplicity of equilibrium is common in these settings when T = 1. The uniqueness of equilibrium when the horizon is nite fully justi es focusing on the limit equilibrium.) Proposition 5. If frictions are not large, then as T approaches in nity the unique DE approaches (^ H ; ^ L ; ^r H ; ^r L ) given by: (P5.1) High Price O ers: ^ H 1 = 0, and ^ H t = 1 u L c H c L u L for t > 1. (P5.2) Low Price O ers: and ^ L t = 0 for t > 1. ^ L 1 = q qh q (1 q H ) ; (P5.3) ^r H t = c H for all t. (P5.4) ^r L t = u L for all t. The traders payo s approach their competitive payo s, i.e., ^V B 1 = ^V H 1 = 0 and ^V L 1 = u L c L, and the surplus approaches the competitive surplus independently of the values of and. Moreover, if T = 1 then (^ H ; ^ L ; ^r H ; ^r L ) is a DE. As the horizon becomes in nite, all units trade eventually. At the rst date, some low quality units trade but no high quality units trade. At subsequent dates, units of both qualities trade with the same constant probability. In the limit, the traders payo s are competitive independently of and, and hence so is the surplus, even if frictions are non-negligible. This result is in contrast to most of the literature (e.g., Gale (1986), Moreno and Wooders (2010)), which has established that payo s are competitive only as frictions vanish. 3 3 Kim (2011) also nds that surplus is competitive even if frictions are non-negligible. 14

Policy Intervention Our results allow an assessment of the impact of programs aimed at improving market e ciency. 4 Remarks 2 through 5 below show the impact of taxes and subsidies on the traders payo s and the surplus. Suppose that the government provides a per unit subsidy of L > 0 to buyers of low quality. Then the instantaneous payo to a buyer who purchases a unit of low quality at price p is u L + L p rather than u L p. The impact of a subsidy may therefore be evaluated as an increase in the value of u L. Such a subsidy is feasible provided that quality is veri able following purchase. A tax is a negative subsidy. When T < 1, subsidizing low quality has a positive e ect on the traders payo s and the surplus: a subsidy increases the net surplus since the marginal increase in (gross) surplus is @S DE @u L = ml + m H T 1 (1 ^q) (see Proposition 3), whereas the marginal cost is at most m L (since at most m L units receive the subsidy). Hence the net surplus, i.e., the surplus minus the present value cost of the subsidy, increases. Remark 2. Assume that 1 < T < 1 and frictions are not large. Then a subsidy on low quality increases the payo s of buyers and low quality sellers, as well as the net surplus. Likewise, the impact of a subsidy on high quality may be evaluated as an increase of the value of u H. Inspecting the formulae of Proposition 3 reveals that u H a ects equilibrium through its impact on ^q. Subsidizing high quality reduces ^q thereby increasing the payo of buyers and decreasing the payo of low quality sellers. Its e ect on the net surplus as and approach one is clear from Proposition 4: The marginal e ect on the surplus is @ ~ S @u H = mh (u L c L ) @ ^q @u H = mh (u L c L ) ch c L (u H c L ) 2 : Since high quality trades only at the last date, the marginal cost of the subsidy 4 An example of such a program is the Public-Private Investment Program for Legacy Assets, by which the U.S. government provided nancial assistance to investors who purchased legacy assets. 15

approaches m H ~ H T. Thus the marginal e ect on the net surplus approaches @ S ~ m H ~ H @u H T = m H ul c L u H c L 1 c H u H c L c L < 0: Remark 3. Assume that 1 < T < 1 and frictions are not large. Then a subsidy on high quality increases the payo of buyers and decreases the payo of low quality sellers. Its impact on the net surplus is ambiguous, but as and approach one the e ect is unambiguously negative. The table below illustrates the e ect of several subsidies and taxes for the market of example above when = = :95 and T = 10. The second row describes the e ect of a subsidy L = :05 on low quality. Relative to the equilibrium without any subsidy or tax ( rst row), the measure of high quality sellers that trades, which is m H m H T +1, increases from :0958 to :1179 (i.e., from 47:92% to 58:96% of all high quality sellers). The measure of low quality sellers that trades increases modestly from :7927 to :7936. The surplus increases to :2150. The present value cost of the subsidy is :0360. Thus, the net surplus increases to :2150 :0360 = :1790. L H m H m H T +1 m L m L T +1 V B 1 V S 1 S DE PV Cost Net Surplus 0 0.0958.7927.0599.1121.1720 0.1720 :05 0.1179.7936.0748.1401.2150.0360.1790 :00 :05.0932.7917.0634.1093.1727.0034.1693 0 :05.0988.7936.0559.1153.1712 :0036.1748 :05.05.1148.7927.0792.1366.2159.0398.1761 E ects of Subsidies and Taxes A subsidy H = :05 on high quality (third row) has a negative e ect on the net surplus: The subsidy increases surplus to :1727. The present value cost of the subsidy is :0034, and therefore the net surplus decreases to :1693. This decrease is the result of a decrease in the measures of trade of both qualities. Naturally, a tax has the opposite e ect, as the fourth row of the table shows. If quality is not veri able after purchase, a subsidy conditional on quality is not feasible. As shown in the last row, an unconditional subsidy increases surplus to 16

:2159. However, this subsidy is more costly and has a smaller positive e ect on the net surplus than a subsidy on low quality alone. When T = 1, subsidizing low quality leads to an increase of the net surplus since the surplus m L (u L c L ) increases by a factor equal to m L while the present value cost of the subsidy is less than m L (because not all low quality trades at date 1). We show that as approaches one, the present value marginal cost of the subsidy approaches m L (see Appendix A), and thus the subsidy amounts to a transfer to low quality sellers. These results, stated in remarks 4 and 5, follow by di erentiating the expressions for payo s and surplus provided in Proposition 5. Remark 4. Assume that T = 1 and frictions are not large. Then a subsidy on low quality increases the payo of low quality sellers, as well as the net surplus. As approaches one, the subsidy has no e ect on the net surplus and amounts to a transfer to low quality sellers. Subsidizing high quality leads to a decrease of the probability of a low price o er at date 1, and thereby increases the delay with which low quality trades. Interestingly, a tax on high quality raises revenue without a ecting either the traders payo s or the surplus by increasing the volume of trade of low quality units at date 1, while having no e ect on trade in subsequent dates. (Speci cally, the tax reduces q and increases ^ L 1 ; while leaving ^ L t and ^ H t unchanged for t > 1.) Thus, while the traders payo s and the surplus remains unchanged, the net surplus increases by the tax revenue. Remark 5. Assume that T = 1 and frictions are not large. Then a subsidy on high quality has no e ect on either the traders payo s or the surplus, and is therefore purely wasteful. Remarkably, a tax on high quality raises revenue without a ecting payo s or surplus. Market Liquidity Liquid assets are those that can be easily bought or sold. In our setting, the liquidity of a good is determined by the probability that it trades. At date t high quality trades with probability H t and low quality trades with probability ( H t + L t ). Remark 6 follows from di erentiating the formulae in Propositions 3 and is provided without proof. 17

Remark 6. Assume that 1 < T < 1 and frictions are not large. Then for all t > 1, H t decreases with and, and increases with u L. Recall that in equilibrium H 1 = 0 see Proposition 3. Thus, Remark 6 implies that high quality is less liquid as traders become more patient and, perhaps counterintuitively, as the probability of meeting a partner increases. (Indeed, both qualities become completely illiquid at intermediate dates as both and approach one see Proposition 4.) Further, an increase in the value of low quality increases the liquidity of high quality. Remark 7 establishes results analogous to Remark 6 when the market opens over an in nite horizon. These results follow from di erentiating the formulae in Propositions 5. Remark 7. Assume that T = 1 and frictions are not large. Then for all t > 1, ^ H t is independent of, decreases with, and increases with u L. Further, ^ L 1 is independent of and, and decreases with u L. Recall that in the equilibrium of a market that opens over an in nite horizon we have ^ L t = 0 for all t > 1. Thus, Remark 7 implies that the liquidity of both qualities decreases with. The liquidity of both qualities is independent of : an increase in is exactly o set by a decrease in the probability of a high price o er. An increase in u L reduces the liquidity of low quality units at the rst date but increases the liquidity of both qualities at every subsequent date. 4 Discussion When the horizon is nite and frictions are not large, in the equilibrium of a decentralized market most low quality units as well as some high quality units trade, and the surplus is above the competitive surplus. When the horizon is in nite all units of both qualities trade, although with delay, and payo s and surplus are competitive. Appendix B studies the market described in Section 2 but where trade is centralized. We show that if the horizon is nite and traders are patient (i.e., their discount factor is not too small), in a dynamic competitive equilibrium (CE) all low quality 18

units trade at the rst date and no high quality units ever trade. Hence the surplus realized is the same as in the static competitive equilibrium. We show that subsidies, which are e ective in decentralized markets, are ine ective in centralized markets. Moreover, high (low) quality is more (less) liquid in decentralized markets than in centralized ones. These features hold even as frictions vanish. These results suggest that when the horizon is nite, decentralized markets perform better than centralized markets, in which trade is multilateral and agents are price takers. We also show that if traders are su ciently impatient or the horizon is in nite, there are dynamic competitive equilibria in which all low quality units trade immediately at a low price and all high quality units trade with delay at a high price. These separating CE, in which di erent qualities trade at di erent dates, yield a surplus greater than the static competitive surplus. Consequently, when the horizon is in nite, centralized markets may perform better than decentralized markets. Interestingly, we show that as frictions vanish the surplus at a separating CE equals the surplus in the equilibrium of a decentralized market that opens over a nite horizon. Intuitively this result holds since the same incentive constraints operate in both markets. In a separating CE high quality trades with su ciently long delay that low quality sellers are willing to trade immediately at a low price rather than waiting to trade at a high price. Likewise, in a DE high price o ers are made with a su ciently small probability that low quality sellers are willing to immediately accept a low price, rather than waiting for a high price. 5 Appendix A: Proofs We begin by establishing a number of lemmas. In the proofs, we refer to previous results established in lemmas or propositions by using the letter L and P, respectively, followed by the number. Lemma 1. Assume that 1 < T < 1, and let (; r H ; r L ) be a DE. Then for each t 2 f1; : : : ; T g: (L1:1) t (maxfrt H ; rt L g) = 1: (L1:2) m t > 0 and qt > 0 for 2 fh; Lg: 19

(L1:3) r H t = c H > r L t ; V H t = 0 < Vt B, and Vt L c H c L : (L1:4) q H t+1 q H t : (L1:5) t (c H ) = 1: (L1:6) t (p) = t (r L t ) for all p 2 [r L t ; c H ): (L1:7) If L t = H t ; then q t+1 = q t+1 for 2 fh; Lg: Proof: Let t 2 f1; : : : ; T g. We prove L1:1: Write p = maxfr H t ; r L t g, and suppose that t (p) < 1. Then there is ^p > p in the support of t : Since I(p; r t ) = I(^p; r t ) = 1 for 2 fh; Lg, we have V B t X 2fH;Lg = X 2fH;Lg > X 2fH;Lg = X 2fH;Lg which contradicts DE:B. 2 qt I(p; rt )(u p) + 41 X q t (u p) + (1 ) V B t+1 q t (u ^p) + (1 ) V B t+1 2fH;Lg 2 qt I(^p; rt )(u ^p) + 41 X 2fH;Lg 3 qt I(p; rt ) 5 V B 3 t+1 qt I(^p; rt ) 5 V B We prove L1:2: Clearly m t > 0 implies q t > 0: We prove by induction that m t > 0 for all t and. Let 2 fh; Lg; we have m 1 = m > 0: Assume that m k > 0 for some k 1; then 2 (0; 1) and k 2 [0; 1] imply m k+1 = (1 k)m k > 0. We prove L1:3 by induction. Because V T +1 and DE:L imply t+1; = 0 for 2 fb; H; Lg; then DE:H r H T = c H + V H T +1 = c H > c L = r L T = c L + V L T +1: Hence T (c H ) = 1 by L1:1, and therefore V H T = 0 and V L T ch c L : Moreover, by L1:2 qt L > 0; and therefore 0 < ql T ul c L VT B : Let k T, and assume that L1:3 holds for t 2 fk; : : : ; T g; we show that it holds for k DE:H implies r H k implies r L k 1 = ch + Vk H 1: Since V H k = 0; = c H : Since V L k ch c L and < 1; then DE:L 1 = cl + V L k (1 )c L + c H < c H : Hence k (c H ) = 1 by L1:1, and therefore V H k 1 = 0. Also since t(c H ) = 1 for t k 1; then V L k 1 ch c L. Also Vk B 1 V k B > 0: 20

In order to prove L1:4; note that L1:3 implies H t L t. Hence q H t+1 = m H t+1 m H t+1 + m L t+1 = (1 H t )m H t (1 H t )m H t + (1 L t )m L t As for L1:5; it is a direct implication of L1:1 and L1:3: m H t m H t + m L t = q H t : We prove L1:6: Suppose that t (p) > t (r L t ) for some p 2 (r L t ; r H t ): Then there is ^p in the support of t such that r L t < ^p < r H t : Since I(^p; r L t ) = 1 and I(^p; r H t ) = 0; then V B t X 2fH;Lg 2 qt I(rt L ; rt )(u rt L ) + 41 X = q L t (u L r L t ) + (1 q L t )V B t+1 > qt L (u L ^p) + (1 qt L )Vt+1 B 2 = X qt I(^p; rt )(u ^p) + 41 X 2fH;Lg which contradicts DE:B. 2fH;Lg 2fH;Lg In order to prove L1:7; simply note that L t = H t implies 3 qt I(rt L ; rt ) 5 V B 3 qt I(^p; rt ) 5 V B t+1; t+1 q t+1 = m H t+1 m H t+1 + m L t+1 = (1 t ) m t = 1 H t q H t + 1 L t q L t m H t m t + m L t = q t. Proof of Proposition 1. P 1:1 follows from L1:3 and L1:4, and P 1:2 follows from L1:5 and L1:6. Proof of Proposition 2. H T + L T We prove P 2:3: Suppose by way of contradiction that < 1: Then negligible prices are optimal, and therefore V B T which contradicts L1:3. We prove P 2:1: Suppose contrary to P 2:1 that there is k such that H k +L k = V B T +1 = 0, = 0: By P 2:3, k < T: Let k be the largest such date. Then H k+1 + L k+1 > 0 and q k+1 = q k for 2 fh; Lg. If H k+1 > 0; i.e., o ering rh k+1 is optimal, then V B k+1 = (q H k+1u H + q L k+1u L c H ) + (1 ) V B k+2: Since Vk+1 B V k+2 B B (because the payo to o ering a negligible price is Vk+2 ), then q H k+1u H + q L k+1u L c H V B k+1: 21

And since q k+1 = q k B for 2 fh; Lg; Vk+1 > 0 (by L1:3) and < 1, then q H k u H + q L k u L c H = q H k+1u H + q L k+1u L c H V B k+1 > V B k+1: Therefore a negligible price o er at k is not optimal, which contradicts that H k +L k = 0. Hence H k+1 = 0, and thus L k+1 > 0 and V L k+1 = L k+1(r L k+1 c L ) + (1 L k+1)v L k+2 = V L k+2: Therefore r L k = c L + V L k+1 c L + V L k+1 = c L + V L k+2 = r L k+1: Since L k+1 > 0; i.e., price o ers of rl k+1 are optimal at date k + 1, we have q L k+1(u L r L k+1) + (1 q L k+1)v B k+2 V B k+2: Hence and V B k+2 u L r L k+1 V B k+1 = q L k+1(u L r L k+1) + (1 q L k+1)v B k+2 u L r L k+1: Since H k + L k = 0; then the payo to a negligible o er at date k is greater or equal to the payo to a low price o er at date k, i.e., V B k+1 q L k (u L r L k ) + (1 q L k )V B k+1: Thus u L rk L V k+1 B : Since V k+1 B > 0 (by L1:3) and < 1, then u L r L k V B k+1 < V B k+1 u L r L k+1; i.e., r L k+1 < rl k, which is a contradiction. Hence H k +L k P 2:1. We prove P 2:2: Since q H 1 > 0 for all k, which establishes = q H < q by assumption and V B 2 > 0 by L1:3; then q H 1 u H + q L 1 u L c H < 0 < V B 2 : Hence o ering c H at date 1 is not optimal; i.e., H 1 = 0: Therefore L 1 > 0 by P 2:1: Lemmas 2 establishes properties that a DE has when frictions are not large, i.e., when the inequalities F:1; F:2 and F:3 hold. Recall that by assumption q H < q < 22

^q < 1: When H t + L t = 1 at some date t; then the fraction of high quality sellers in the market at date t + 1 is q H t+1 = m H t+1 m H t+1 + (1 ) m L t+1 where the function g; given by g(x; y) := = (1 H t )q H t (1 H t )q H t + (1 )(1 q H t ) = g(qh t ; H t ); (1 y)x (1 y)x + (1 )(1 x) ; is increasing in x and decreasing in y, and satis es g(q H ; H ) > ^q by F:3. Lemma 2. Assume that 1 < T < 1 and frictions are not large, and let ( H ; L ; r H ; r L ) be a DE. Then for all t 2 f1; : : : ; T g: (L2:1) H t < 1. (L2:2) L t < 1. (L2:3) H T > 0; L T > 0; and qh T = ^q. (L2:4) V L t > 0. (L2:5) L t > 0. (L2:6) H t < H = ul c L (c H c L ). (L2:7) If t < T, then L t + H t < 1 and H t+1 > 0. Proof: We prove L2:1: Assume by way of contradiction that the claim does not hold, and let t be the rst date such that H t = 1: By P 2:2, t > 1: We show that H t 1 = 1; which contradicts that t is the rst date for which H t = 1: Since H t = 1 and V L t 0 for all t; we have V L t = (c H c L ) + (1 ) V L t+1 (ch c L ): Since frictions are small, then (c H c L ) > u L c L, and therefore r L t 1 = cl + V L t c L + (c H c L ) > c L + u L c L = u L : Hence o ering r L t 1 at date t 1 is suboptimal, i.e., L t 1 = 0: Moreover, qh t 1 = qh t : Since o ering r H t at date t is optimal we have V B t = (u(q H t ) ch ) + (1 ) V B t+1 ; 23

and u(q H t ) yields ch V B t+1 > 0 (by L1:3): Thus, o ering rh t 1 = ch (L1:3) at date t 1 (u(q H t 1 ) ch ) + (1 ) V B t = (u(q H t ) ch ) (1 + (1 )) + (1 ) 2 2 V B t+1 : Then we have (u(q H t 1 ) ch ) + (1 ) V B t V B t = (u(q H t ) ch ) (1 ) (1 ) 2 V B t+1 (u(q H t ) ch ) (1 ) (1 + (1 )) > 0: Hence o ering a negligible price at date t 1 is suboptimal, i.e., 1 L t 1 H t 1 = 0: Since L t 1 = 0; then H t 1 = 1: We prove L2:2: We rst show that L t < 1 for t < T: Assume by way of contradiction that L t = 1 for some t < T: Then L1:4 and the inequality F:3 imply q H T q H t+1 = g(q H t ; 0) > g(q H ; H ) > ^q: Hence q H T u H + q L T u L c H > ^qu H + (1 ^q) u L c H = (1 ^q) (u L c L ) > q L T (u L c L ); i.e., o ering r L T = cl at date T is suboptimal, and therefore L T = 0: Thus, H T P 2:3, which contradicts L2:1: of r L T and We show that L T < 1: Assume that L T = 1. Then qh T L is suboptimal); VT = 1 by ^q (since otherwise an o er = 0 and V B T = ql T (ul c L ): Hence r L T 1 = cl by DE:L, qt L 1(u L rt L 1) + qt H 1VT B = qt L 1(u L c L ) + (1 qt L 1)VT B > qt L 1VT B + (1 qt L 1)VT B = V B T ; i.e., the payo to o ering rt L 1 at date T 1 is greater than that of o ering a negligible price. Therefore L T 1 + H T 1 = 1. Since qh T 1 qh T by L1:4 and qh T ^q; then the 24

payo to o ering r H T 1 = ch at T 1 is q H T 1u H + q L T 1u L c H q H T u H + q L T u L c H q L T (u L c L ) q L T 1(u L c L ) < q L T 1(u L c L ) + q H T 1V B T ; where the last term is the payo to o ering r L T 1 = cl at T 1. Hence H T 1 = 0; and therefore L T 1 = 1, which contradicts that L t < 1 for all t < T as shown above. Hence L T < 1. We prove L2:3: By P 2:3, L2:1 and L2:2, we have H T > 0 and L T > 0: Since both high price o ers and low price o ers are optimal at date T; and reservation prices are r H T = ch and r L T = cl ; we have q H T u H + q L T u L c H = q L T (u L c L ): Thus, using q L T = 1 qh T and solving for qh T yields q H T = ch c L u H c L = ^q: We prove L2:4 by induction. By L2:3; VT L = H T c H c L > 0: Since Vt L Vt+1 L for all t T; then V L t T t V L T > 0: We prove L2:5: Suppose by way of contradiction that L t = 0 for some t: Since L T > 0 by L2:3; then t < T: Also L t = 0 implies H t > 0 by P 2:1. Since H t < 1 by L2:1; then buyers are indi erent at date t between o ering c H or a negligible price, i.e., q H t u H + q L t u L c H = V B t+1: We show that H t+1 = 0: Suppose that H t+1 > 0; then V B t+1 = (q H t+1u H + q L t+1u L c H ) + (1 )V B t+2: Hence < 1 and V B t+1 > 0 by L1:3 imply q H t u H + q L t u L c H = V B t+1 < V B t+1 = (q H t+1u H + q L t+1u L c H ) + (1 )V B t+2; But L t = 0 implies that q H t+1 = q H t ; and therefore q H t+1u H + q L t+1u L c H < V B t+2; 25

i.e., o ering c H at date t + 1 yields a payo smaller than o ering a negligible price, which contradicts that H t+1 > 0: Since H t+1 = 0; then DE:L implies V L t+1 = L t+1(r L t+1 c L ) + (1 L t+1)v L t+2 = V L t+2: Since V L t+1 > 0 by L2:4; then V L t+2 > 0; and therefore DE:L and < 1 imply r L t = c L + V L t+1 = c L + 2 V L t+2 < c L + V L t+2 = r L t+1: i.e., r L t < r L t+1: We show that this inequality cannot hold, which leads to a contradiction. Since H t < 1 by L2:1; then L t = 0 implies 1 H t L t > 0; i.e., negligible price o ers are optimal at date t: Hence at date t the payo to o ering r L t than or equal to the payo to o ering a negligible price, i.e., q H t V B t+1 + q L t (u L r L t ) V B t+1: Using q H t = 1 q L t we may write this inequality as u L r L t V B t+1: must be less Likewise, H t+1 = 0 implies 0 < L t+1 < 1 by P 2:1 and L2:2; and therefore 1 H t+1 L t+1 > 0: Hence low and negligible price o ers are both optimal at date t + 1, and therefore V B t+1 = q L t+1(u L r L t+1) + (1 q L t+1)v B t+2 = V B t+2: Hence V B t+1 = u L r L t+1: Thus, < 1 and V B t+1 > 0 by L1:3 imply u L r L t V B t+1 < V B t+1 = u L r L t+1: Therefore r L t > r L t+1, which contradicts r L t < r L t+1. We prove L2:6: For t 2 f1; : : : ; T g, since V L t 0, and r L t c L = V L t+1 by DE:L; we have V L t = H t (c H c L ) + L t (r L t c L ) + 1 ( H t + L t ) V L t+1 H t (c H c L ): 26

By P 2:2, we have H 1 = 0 < H : For 1 < t T; since L t 1 > 0 by L2:5 (i.e., low price o ers are optimal at date t and therefore 1) and V B t 1 > 0 by L1:3, then u L > r L t 1. Hence u L c L > r L t 1 c L = V L t H t c H c L ; H t < ul c L (c H c L ) = H : Finally, we prove (L2:7): Let t 2 f1; : : : ; T 1g: We proceed by showing that (i) H t > 0 implies H t + L t < 1, and (ii) H t + L t < 1 implies H t+1 > 0: Then L2:7 follows by induction: Since H 1 = 0 by P 2:2 and L 1 < 1 by L2:2; then H 1 + L 1 < 1; and therefore H 2 > 0 by (ii). Assume that H k + L k < 1 and H k+1 1 k < T 1; we show that H k+1 + L k+1 < 1 and H k+2 > 0: Since H k+1 H k+1 + L k+1 < 1 by (i), and therefore H k+2 > 0 by (ii). > 0 holds for some > 0; then We establish (i), i.e., H t > 0 implies H t + L t < 1. Suppose not; let t < T be the rst date such that H t > 0 and H t + L t = 1. Since q H t q H 1 = q H by L1:4, and H t < H by L2:6, then the inequality F:3 and L2:3 imply which contradicts L1:4: q H t+1 = g(q H t ; H t ) > g(q H ; H ) > ^q = q H T ; Next we prove (ii), i.e., H t + L t < 1 implies H t+1 > 0. Suppose by way of contradiction that H t + L t < 1 and H t+1 = 0 for some t < T. Since L t > 0 by L2:5, then low and negligible o ers are optimal at date t. Hence u L r L t = V B t+1: Since H t+1 = 0, then V L t+1 = V L t+2: Since V L t+1 > 0 by L2:4 and < 1, we have r L t+1 = c L + V L t+2 = c L + V L t+1 > c L + V L t+1 = r L t : Since 0 < L t+1 < 1 by L2:2 and L2:5 and H t+1 = 0, then 1 H t+1 L t+1 > 0; i.e., low and negligible o ers are optimal at t + 1: Therefore u L r L t+1 = V B t+2: 27