Minimum wage increases can lead to wage reductions by imperfectly competitive firms

Similar documents
Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Advanced Microeconomics

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

T R(y(L)) w L = 0. L so we can write this as p ] (b) Recall that with the perfectly competitive firm, demand for labor was such that

Basics of Game Theory

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

Minimum Wages, Employment and. Monopsonistic Competition

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Volume 29, Issue 3. Strategic delegation and market competitiveness

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

Lecture 9. Matthew Osborne

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Static Models of Oligopoly

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Price and Capacity Competition

Efficient Union Contracts in the Presence of Homogeneous Labor and Differentiated Unions

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

Quantity-setting games with a dominant

Bertrand Model of Price Competition. Advanced Microeconomic Theory 1

Introduction to Game Theory

Manolis Galenianos, Philipp Kircher and Gabor Virag Market power and efficiency in a search model

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Powered by TCPDF (

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Discussion Paper Series No.51. Complexity yields benefits: An example of a heterogeneous duopoly market. Yasuo Nonaka.

No Information Sharing in Oligopoly: The Case of Price Competition with Cost Uncertainty

The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

Continuous Strategy Markov Equilibrium in a Dynamic Duopoly. with Capacity Constraints * Milan Horniaček

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Quantity-setting games with a dominant firm

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

Free Entry Bertrand Competition

Quantum Bertrand duopoly of incomplete information

Maximin and minimax strategies in symmetric oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Subgame Perfect Equilibrium (SPNE)

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Introduction to Game Theory

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

Lecture 4: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

The Impact of Organizer Market Structure on Participant Entry Behavior in a Multi-Tournament Environment

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Endogenous information acquisition

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Answer Key for M. A. Economics Entrance Examination 2017 (Main version)

JOB SEARCH WITH BIDDER MEMORIES*

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Bounded Rationality Lecture 2. Full (Substantive, Economic) Rationality

Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Adverse selection, signaling & screening

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

The ambiguous impact of contracts on competition in the electricity market Yves Smeers

Price-quantity competition with varying toughness

Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

Equilibrium Refinements

CORVINUS ECONOMICS WORKING PAPERS. The Kreps-Scheinkman game in mixed duopolies. by Barna Bakó, Attila Tasnádi CEWP 11/2014

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities

Transcription:

Minimum wage increases can lead to wage reductions by imperfectly competitive firms Ken Clark a,b, *, Leo Kaas c, Paul Madden a a School of Social Sciences, University of Manchester, Oxford Rd, Manchester, M13 9PL, UK b IZA, Bonn, Germany c University of Konstanz, Konstanz, Germany Abstract In a model with imperfect competition and multiple equilibria we show how an increase in the minimum wage can lead firms to reduce wages (and employment). We find some empirical support for this in the Card Krueger minimum wage data. Keywords: Minimum wages; Oligopoly; Oligopsony JEL classification: D43; E24; J48 1. Introduction In a competitive labour market, a minimum wage increase raises wages to the new minimum wage level if they were initially below that level, with no change otherwise; the effect on employment can only be a reduction. Although monopsony can reverse the employment effect (e.g. Manning, 2003), the wage predictions are unchanged. Recently, Bhaskar and To (2003) have shown how oligopsony may also change the wage prediction, with firms who originally set wages above the new minimum wage further * Corresponding author. School of Social Sciences, University of Manchester, Oxford Rd, Manchester, M13 9PL, UK. Tel.: +44 161 275 3679; fax: +44 161 275 4812. E mail address: ken.clark@manchester.ac.uk (K. Clark).

288 increasing their wage. We expand on these possibilities by showing that in a model of oligopsony where the firms are also oligopolists, minimum wage increases can induce a reduction of wages (along with a reduction of employment). We present some evidence of this phenomenon in the Card and Krueger (1995) data on the New Jersey fast-food sector. 2. The model We combine features of Dixon (1992) and Kaas and Madden (2004) in a 2-stage game, with wages and employment determined at stage I and prices and output at stage II. There are two firms, duopsonists in the labour market at stage I and duopolists in the stage II output market. 1 The production function of firm i is y i =l i where y i is output and l i is labour employed. At wage w the upward sloping labour supply is S(w), and the downward sloping inverse output demand is p =P( Y) where p is output price and Y aggregate quantity. The revenue function R( Y)=P( Y)Y is increasing (so demand is elastic) and concave. The unique Walrasian equilibrium wage w WE is defined by w(=p)=p(s(w)). Strategic interaction between firms under laissez-faire is as follows. 2.1. Stage I Firms choose wages w i z0 and labour demands J i.ifw 1 =w 2 =w we assume that initially half of the supply S(w) offer to work at each firm, any unsuccessful offers being diverted to the other firm, implying for i =1,2 and j p i; 2 l i ¼ min J i ; max 1 2 Sw ð Þ; Sw ð Þ J j : ð1þ If w 1 Nw 2 then workers S(w 1 ) offer themselves to firm 1 and those with the lowest reservation wage are hired first, 3 leaving a residual of max[s(w 2 ) min( J 1,S(w 1 )),0] for firm 2, giving l 1 ¼ minðj 1 ; Sw ð 1 ÞÞ; l 2 ¼ min½j 2 ; maxðsw ð 2 Þ l 1 ; 0ÞŠ: ð2þ 2.2. Stage II Firms choose prices p 1, p 2 for the sale of up to the output levels y i =l i. Since demand is elastic, this stage II (bbertrand EdgeworthQ) subgame always has a unique Nash equilibrium, with market-clearing prices p 1 =p 2 =P(l 1 +l 2 ) see Madden (1998). Thus subgame perfect equilibria of the two-stage game reduce to the Nash equilibria of the simultaneous move game where firm i chooses (w i, J i ) and, with l i defined by Eqs. (1) and (2), payoffs 1 For instance, a town in New Jersey has 2 fast food outlets that are the sole employers of the town s teenage labour supply (duopsony) and the only suppliers of fast food to the town (duopoly). Generalizing the results to the oligopoly case is straightforward but tedious. 2 Alternatively phrased, we are assuming here uniform rationing at symmetric wages. 3 This assumption (innocuous here) is the efficient rationing rule of the Bertrand Edgeworth literature.

289 are: p i ðw 1 ; J 1 ; w 2 ; J 2 Þ ¼ ½Pl ð 1 þ l 2 Þ w i Šl i : ð3þ w 1 =w 2 =w WE with J 1, J 2 zs(w WE ) and p 1 =p 2 =0 is an equilibrium of this game; if firm 1 undercuts the Walrasian wage, firm 2 takes the whole market (because of J 2 zs(w WE ) and Eq. (2)), leaving firm 1 with zero profits, and if firm 1 raises the wage, aggregate output can only increase (again because of J 2 zs(w WE ) and Eq. (2)) and its price falls, ensuring a loss for firm 1. The Appendix shows that this equilibrium isunique; Theorem 1. Under laissez-faire the unique equilibrium wage, employment and profit levels are Walrasian w 1 ¼ w 2 ¼ w WE ; l 1 ¼ l 2 ¼ 1 2 SwWE ð Þ; p 1 ¼ p 2 ¼ 0, supported by any labour demands J1, J 2 zs(w WE ). The excess demands for labour ( J i Nl i ) neutralise the output market power of firms. For instance a deviation from equilibrium in only J 1 has no effect on aggregate output (even if J 1 =0 this remains at S(w WE )) and so has no effect on output price (which is always P(S(w WE )) ). With a legally binding minimum wage w MIN N0, the game is the same except for the stage I restriction to w i zw MIN.Ifw MIN =w WE the equilibrium of Theorem 1 remains, but there is another equilibrium. Suppose w 1 =w 2 =w MIN and firms set labour demands which produce unemployment ( J 1 +J 2 bs(w)); profits are p i =[P( J 1 +J 2 ) w MIN ], which is concave in J i. Maximizing with respect to J i produces candidate new equilibrium labour demands J 1 =J 2 =J where Y =2J and, w MIN ¼ wðy Þ ¼ PVðYÞY=2 þ PY ð Þ The marginal revenue curve w( Y) slopes down as in Fig. 1. In fact Y is the Cournot Nash aggregate output level when firms face constant marginal costs w =w 1. The candidate generates the assumed unemployment whenever w Nw shown in Fig. 1, and firms earn positive profits (=( P( Y) w MIN )Y /2= PV( Y)Y 2 /4N0. It turns out that setting the minimum wage and hiring Y /2 workers is indeed equilibrium behaviour provided that the minimum wage exceeds a certain threshold level. Without the minimum wage, firms ð4þ w, p S(w) w WE w w P(Y) ψ (Y) Y Fig. 1. Equilibrium wages and output.

290 Table 1 Starting wages: descriptive statistics New Jersey Pennsylvania Before After Before After At minimum 95 (31%) 268 (89%) 22 (32%) 20 (29%) Mean Wage ($) 4.62 5.08 4.65 4.62 (standard dev.) (0.3452) (0.1066) (0.3559) (0.3597) Above $5.05 23 (8%) 33 (11%) 4 (6%) 2 (3%) Reduce wage 19 (6%) 27 (40%) Above $5.05 and reduced to $5.05 18 (6%) Sample size 302 68 would undercut while hiring the same number of workers. The minimum wage removes this option to undercut, thus sustaining the new equilibrium. In the Appendix we prove Theorem 2. There exists a wage w a(w,w WE ) such that (a) For w MIN bw, the unique equilibrium is that of Theorem 1. (b) For w Vw MIN Vw WE there are two equilibria, the equilibrium of Theorem 1 and a minimum wage, positive profits, unemployment equilibrium with w 1 =w 2 =w MIN and J 1 ¼ J 2 ¼ 1 2 Y where wðy Þ ¼ w MIN : (c) For w MIN Nw WE the unique equilibrium is the minimum wage, positive profits, unemployment equilibrium of (b) above. One can argue for the positive profits at the new equilibrium as a selection mechanism the new minimum wage equilibrium Pareto dominates the original. The announcement of the new minimum wage may also make the new equilibrium focal. Thus a minimum wage increase may lead to lower wages and employment at firms that were originally paying wages above the minimum wage. 3. Empirical evidence We analysed Card and Krueger s (1995) bnatural experimentq data on fast food restaurants in Pennsylvania and New Jersey in 1992. In April 1992 the New Jersey minimum wage rose from $4.25 to $5.05 while the minimum wage in Pennsylvania remained at $4.25. Card and Krueger examined the employment impact of the wage hike, however they also collected data on the starting wage for restaurant employees. Table 2 Full time equivalent employment New Jersey Pennsylvania Before After Before After All Restaurants 20.67 21.88 23.70 21.20 Wage Reducers 27.39 22.06

291 Table 1 shows that a relatively small proportion of New Jersey restaurants offered starting wages above the new minimum of $5.05 before the hike. Of the 23 firms in New Jersey that were paying in excess of $5.05, 18 reduced their starting wage to the new minimum when it came into effect. This is prima facie evidence in favour of the theoretical result. Further analysis of the firms that reduced starting wages to $5.05 suggests that this was not a trivial reduction in the majority of cases. The mean reduction was 27 cents while the modal reduction was 45 cents. There is evidence that firms that lowered wages also reduced employment. Table 2 shows the change in full-time equivalent employment for all restaurants in New Jersey and Pennsylvania as well as for those 18 restaurants in New Jersey that reduced their wage to the new minimum. The second row, where we consider only the wage reducers in New Jersey, shows a substantial and statistically significant reduction of around five employees (two-tailed p-value = 0.028). Acknowledgement We are grateful to an anonymous referee for helpful comments on a previous version of this paper. Leo Kaas thanks the Austrian Science Fund (FWF) for financial support. The data we use are available on the World Wide Web. See Chapter 1 of Card and Krueger (1995) for access details. Appendix A. Proof of Theorem 1 To show uniqueness, consider symmetric wages w 1 =w 2 =w. (a) There is no equilibrium with J 1 +J 2 bs(w). If firm 1 reduces w 1 a little it will still be able to hire the same J 1, so aggregate output and price are unchanged and profits higher. (b) There is no equilibrium with J 1 +J 2 zs(w), w Nw WE. Aggregate output would be S(w), its price P(S(w))bP(S(w WE ))=w WE so at least one firm (i say) makes a loss, which J i =0 improves on. (c) There is no equilibrium with J 1 +J 2 zs(w), w bw WE. Here p 1 +p 2 =[P(S(w)) w]s(w). By raising w i and taking the whole market either firm can attain profits close to p 1 +p 2, which must be an improvement for at least one of them. (d) There is no equilibrium with J 1 +J 2 zs(w), w =w WE and J i bs(w) and J i bs(w) some i. Note p 1 =p 2 =0 in any such equilibrium. Suppose J 2 bs(w). If 1 deviates to Ĵ 1 a(0,s(w) J 2 ) then it makes strictly positive profits since P(Ĵ 1 +J 2 )NP(S(w))Nw. The proof of non-existence of asymmetric wage equilibria is available upon request. 5 Appendix B. Proof of Theorem 2 Let p(w)=[p( Y) w]y /2 where w =w( Y), and let pˆ(w)=[p(s(w)) w] S(w) denote bwhole marketq profits. Suppose w( Y)=w MIN zw,sow 1 =w 2 =w MIN, J 1 =J 2 =Y /2 is the candidate new equilibrium with p 1 =p 2 =p(w MIN )N0. Given w i =w MIN, J 1 =Y /2 is a best response to J 2 =Y /2-concavity of [ P( J 1 +J 2 ) w MIN ]J 1 ensures that deviations to J 1 Î[0,S(w MIN ) Y /2] are unprofitable and deviations to J 1 zs(w MIN ) Y/2 leave l 1 unchanged at S(w MIN ) Y /2 (from Eq. (1)). Suppose firm 1 raises its wage from the candidate level. We show that this is beneficial only if there is some wage w 1 =w MIN which, with J 1 =S(w 1 ) is also

292 beneficial. First suppose w 1 Nw MIN is coupled with J 1 a[0,s(w MIN ) Y /2]. This cannot be beneficial since the resulting employment J 1 can also be attained choosing w MIN and the same J 1 with the same aggregate output and price, and higher profit. Second, if w 1 Nw MIN is coupled with J 1 a[s(w MIN ) Y /2, S(w MIN )] then p 1 =[P(S(w MIN )) w 1 ]J 1. This cannot be beneficial if w MIN zw WE (non-positive p 1 ); if w MIN bw WE then J 1 =S(w MIN ) is the best for 1 in this J 1 range, allowing profits arbitrarily close to pˆ(w MIN ), by choosing a small enough wage increase. Third w 1 Nw MIN and J 1 as(w MIN ), S(w 1 )) is dominated for 1 by the same J 1 and ŵ 1 =s 1 ( J 1 )a(w MIN,w 1 ), pˆ1(ŵ 1 ). Finally, w 1 Nw MIN and J 1 zs(w 1 ) implies p 1 =pˆ1(w 1 ). Thus the best that firm 1 can achieve with w 1 Nw MIN is pˆ (w 1 ). Hence the candidate is an equilibrium iff p(w MIN )zpˆ(w 1 ) for all w zw MIN. Now pˆ (w)=2 p(w)n0, so pˆ (w)np(w); also pˆ(w WE )=0bp(w WE )and pˆ (w) V0 for w zw WE. In the interval [w, w WE ] we have the following with Y =w 1( 1) (w); pˆv(w)=a s(w), pv(w)=b Y /2 where A sv(w)[ PV(s(w)) s(w)+p(s(w)) P( Y) PV( Y)Y /2] B PV( Y)Y[wV( Y)] 1 /4 Since P( Y) is downward sloping and R( Y) is increasing and concave, A b0, and since w( Y) is downward sloping B N0. Since S(w)NY(2) it follows that pˆ V(w)bpˆV(w) on[w,w WE ]. Hence there is an unique w a(w,w WE ) where pˆ(w )=pˆ(w ) and p(w MIN )zpˆ(w), for all w zw MIN zw. Thus the candidate is an equilibrium if and only if w MIN z w. The uniqueness arguments in Theorem 1 ensure that this is the only new candidate, completing Theorem 2. 5 References Bhaskar, V., To, T., 2003. Oligopsony and the distribution of wages. European Economic Review 47, 371 399. Card, D., Krueger, A.B., 1995. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Dixon, H., 1992. The competitive outcome as the equilibrium in an Edgeworthian price quantity model. Economic Journal 102, 301 309. Kaas, L., Madden, P., 2004. A new model of equilibrium involuntary unemployment. Economic Theory 23, 507 527. Madden, P., 1998. Elastic demand, sunk costs and the Kreps Scheinkman extension of the Cournot model. Economic Theory 12, 199 212. Manning, A., 2003. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton University Press, Princeton.