in Search Advertising

Similar documents
Price Competition and Endogenous Valuation in Search Advertising

On the strategic use of quality scores in keyword auctions Full extraction of advertisers surplus

Patent Licensing, Entry and the Incentive to Innovate

A Structural Model of Sponsored Search Advertising Auctions

Knapsack Auctions. Sept. 18, 2018

Technical Appendix: When To Fire Customers? Customer Cost Based Pricing

Katz and Shapiro (1985)

Optimal Monopoly Mechanisms with Demand. Uncertainty. 1 Introduction. James Peck and Jeevant Rampal. December 27, 2017

Mechanism Design. Terence Johnson. December 7, University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design December 7, / 44

CS 573: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture date: April 11, 2008

Inducing Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets with. Increasing Returns to Scale

On Random Sampling Auctions for Digital Goods

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

Advanced Microeconomics

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

Supplementary Material for \Collusion with Persistent Cost Shocks"

Welfare Undominated Groves Mechanisms

Redistribution Mechanisms for Assignment of Heterogeneous Objects

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Position Auctions with Interdependent Values

Optimal Objective Function

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

In classical competitive equilibrium, the rms in a market maximize prots taking price as given, each rm produces the quantity at which price equals ma

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Bertrand-Edgeworth competition with substantial product dierentiation

Introduction In many industrialised countries the market for electricity has been liberalised. Until the end of the eighties there was usually no comp

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Undominated Groves Mechanisms

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

The Impact of Advertising on Media Bias. Web Appendix

Pollution Tax and Social Welfare in Oligopoly. Asymmetric Taxation on Identical Polluters

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is.

8. MARKET POWER: STATIC MODELS

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Standards vs. labels with imperfect competition and asymmetric information

EconS Sequential Competition

Merger Policy with Merger Choice

Sequential Search Auctions with a Deadline

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

Competition in Two-Part Taris Between Asymmetric Firms

Environmental R&D with Permits Trading

EconS Oligopoly - Part 2

Mechanism Design II. Terence Johnson. University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design II 1 / 30

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

A Optimal User Search

Relative Profit Maximization and Bertrand Equilibrium with Convex Cost Functions

Ordered Search in Di erentiated Markets

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications

Ralph s Strategic Disclosure 1

Emission Quota versus Emission Tax in a Mixed Duopoly with Foreign Ownership

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

Chapter 5. The Engine of Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Numerical illustration

Basics of Game Theory

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY AND MANAGERIAL DELEGATION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY FANG WEI (UNIVERSITY OF KITAKYUSHU)

Competition in Two-Part Taris Between Asymmetric Firms

Inefficient Equilibria of Second-Price/English Auctions with Resale

Vickrey Auction. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

The commitment eect in belief evolution

Expressive Auctions for Externalities in Online Advertising

Game theory lecture 4. September 24, 2012

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Market Expansion in Duopoly

Self-Enforcing Trade Agreements and Private Information

A three-level MILP model for generation and transmission expansion planning

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

Who should pay for two-way interconnection?

Fossil fuels supplied by oligopolies: On optimal taxation and rent capture

Competition Policy - Spring 2005 Monopolization practices I

Free and Second-best Entry in Oligopolies with Network

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

A Review of Auction Theory: Sequential Auctions and Vickrey Auctions

Protable Double Marginalization

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Virtual Robust Implementation and Strategic Revealed Preference

Fossil fuels supplied by oligopolies: On optimal taxation and rent capture. Abstract

Price vs. Quantity in Oligopoly Games

ON PRICE CAPS UNDER UNCERTAINTY

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Retailer s product line choice with manufacturer s multi-channel marketing

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

Field Exam: Advanced Theory

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Motivation. Game Theory 24. Mechanism Design. Setting. Preference relations contain no information about by how much one candidate is preferred.

Welfare consequence of asymmetric regulation in a mixed Bertrand duopoly

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Lecture 6: Communication Complexity of Auctions

Competitive Equilibrium

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Transcription:

Eects of the Presence of Organic Listing in Search Advertising Lizhen Xu Jianqing Chen Andrew Whinston Web Appendix: The Case of Multiple Competing Firms In this section, we extend the analysis from duopolistic competition to the case with multiple competing rms. Model We now consider n ( 2) rms in the market. One of them sell products catering to the mainstream market, which is termed as M; the other n rms' products are designed for particular niche markets, which are denoted as,..., n. There is a continuum of consumers with mass. Each consumer has a unit demand of the product. Consumers have dierent preferences. Following the main model, we assume θ (0 < θ < 2 ) of them are -type consumers who prefer the niche rms' products to the mainstream rm's, and θ are M-type consumers who prefer the mainstream product. Among the n niche rms, we consider the case in which niche rms develop particular features of the product that are mutually exclusive so that each consumer values one niche product only and derives zero utility for the other niche products. For ease of exposition, we assume all niche rms equally share the market preference. An -type consumer derives utility v from consuming the niche product that she values, and derives discounted utility kv from consuming the mainstream product. An M-type consumer derives utility v from consuming the mainstream product and discounted utility kv from consuming the niche product that she values. k is uniformly distributed between 0 and among all consumers. We normalize v to without loss of generality. We follow a similar way in modeling consumers' click behavior on the search engine results page. The M rm is listed in a top organic position which attracts most attention (i.e., α im can be very

high). Similar as before, we let α im = to emphasize the diminishing promotive incentive when an advertiser's organic rank is high. In other words, consumers click M's link with probability. In contrast, the niche rms' organic ranks are much less satisfactory and the dierences among their organic exposures can be negligible compared to the dierence between the mainstream's and theirs. We thus assume that the niche rms' overall attention levels are determined by their sponsored ) ) ranking, that is, ( α ik ( β j ) γ ik j = α ik ( β j ) ( γ ik j for any k, k {,..., n }. More specically, for a niche rm winning the jth sponsored slot, the combined probability of its link (either organic or sponsored) being clicked is ψ j. There are m ( 2) sponsored slots and we only discuss the case in which m n. Similar analysis can be applied to the case of m < n. Without loss of generality, we let the exposure of sponsored positions monotonically decrease from the rst to the last, that is, 0 < ψ <... < ψ n <. Analysis and Results We can derive the equilibrium pricing similarly as in the main model. The demand function facing the niche rm staying in the jth sponsored position, given M's price p M, can be written as D j (p; p M) = n ( ψ j) S (p, p M ), where S is dened by Eq.(). Maximizing the prot function pd j (p; p M) gives the optimal pricing. otice that the maximization problem is actually independent of ψ j, which implies that all niche rms charge the same price in equilibrium. Given niche rms' price p, the demand function facing M when it stays in the kth sponsored position can be written as D k M(p; p ) = i k n [ψ ia M (p) + ( ψ i ) S M (p, p )] = ψ k A M (p) + ( ψ k ) SM (p, p ),

where ψ k = n i k ψ i. Maximizing the prot functions simultaneously, we can derive the equilibrium prices (when M stays in the kth sponsored position) as follows. p M = min{ 2 θ( ψ k) 3( θ)( ψ k)+4θ ψ, } k p = θ+( θ)p M 2( θ). Therefore, the equilibrium prot functions can be derived accordingly: πm k = ( π M ψ k, θ ) π j(k) = n ( ψ j) f ( ψ k, θ ), where π k M is the equilibrium prot for the M rm if it stays in the kth sponsored position, and πj(k) stands for the equilibrium prot of the rm staying in the jth sponsored position when M gets the kth sponsored slot (j k). Here, πm (ψ, θ) is the same as is dened in Table 2, while f (ψ, θ) is dened as [ θ 2 +θ(3θ )ψ] 2 ψ < ( θ)[3( θ)( ψ)+4θψ] f (ψ, θ) = 2 3 4( θ) ψ 3. Before we derive the bidding equilibrium, we rst summarize a result which will be useful in the analysis of equilibrium bidding. In fact, the following result is a counterpart of Lemma in the oligopolistic case. It shows that the dierence between the mainstream rm's and the niche rms' incentives to improve their sponsored ranks decrease as the competence dierence reduces (i.e., as θ increases). Lemma 2. ψ, θ πm ψ, θ n ( x ) f ψ, θ + n ( x 2) f ψ, θ is decreasing in θ, where > ψ > ψ ψ > 0 and > x 2 x > 0. To derive the bidding equilibrium, we follow Edelman et al. (2007) and consider the locally envy-free equilibrium in the generalized second-price auctions. In a locally envy-free equilibrium, any advertiser does not want to exchange bids with the one ranked one position above it in the sponsored list. We focus on the particular type of locally envy-free equilibrium studied by Edelman et al. (2007), in which each advertiser bids an amount that equals its own payment plus its own value dierence between staying in the current position and moving one position up. In other words, each

advertiser's payment is equal to the negative externality that it imposes on all the other advertisers. The equilibrium analysis is more complex in our setting because any change of M's position will change the values of all niche rms in all positions. We are particularly interested in two types of equilibria, namely, when the mainstream rm wins the rst sponsored position, and when the niche rms win the rst n sponsored positions and the mainstream rm gets the last. Applying the results from Lemma 2, we show that when θ is large, the latter may hold in equilibrium, and the former can be an equilibrium when θ is small, which are similar to Proposition. Proposition 8. Generically, there exist cutos ˆθ (ψ,..., ψ n ) and θ (ψ,..., ψ n ), such that when 0 < θ < ˆθ (ψ,..., ψ n ), M winning the rst sponsored position and all niche rms staying in the second to the nth positions is an equilibrium, and when θ (ψ,..., ψ n ) < θ < 2, all niche rms staying in the rst n positions and M staying in the last is an equilibrium. Proposition 8 reveals a similar pattern in the equilibrium bidding outcomes. With reasonable market preference shares, although still weaker than the leading rm, niche rms have higher bidding incentives and get better sponsored positions. Such outcome, which is not aligned with advertisers' inherent competitive strength, reects the interplay between organic listing and sponsored bidding, and the balance between the promotive and preventive eects. On the other hand, when niche rms are too weak, the leading rm's preventive motivation dominates, making it occupy the top sponsored position. Given the similarity in the equilibrium bidding outcomes, the rest analysis and the main results from the duopoly case can be expected to hold qualitatively when extended to the oligopoly case. The following example illustrates the results. Example 3. We consider the case with n = 3, ψ =.02, ψ 2 =.5, and ψ 3 =.20. As we can show, when θ >.352, the two niche rms bidding higher than the mainstream rm is an equilibrium in the co-listing case, whereas such an equilibrium cannot arise in the benchmark case for any θ. If θ =.4, for example, then b > b2 =.0290 > b3 M =.0045 is an equilibrium in the co-listing case, while b M > b2 =.0366 > b3 =.0098 is an equilibrium in the benchmark case. The colisting case generates higher social welfare, consumer surplus, sales diversity, but lower immediate revenue for search engine than the benchmark case. More specically, W C =.9644 > W B =.9288,

CS C =.308 > CS B =.0, G C =.2288 < G B =.2435, and IR C =.0335 < IR B =.0463. Proofs Proof of Lemma 2. To prove that the objective function is decreasing in θ is to prove θ π M ψ, θ θ π M ψ, θ + n ( x 2) θ f ψ, θ n ( x ) θ f ψ, θ < 0. (25) Recall that Lemma shows that 2 ψθ π M (ψ, θ) < 0. Since ψ > ψ, therefore, θ π M ψ, θ ψ, θ < 0, that is, the rst half of the LHS of Eq.(25) is negative. Also, we can show that θ π M when θ 0.53, 2 ψθ f (ψ, θ) 0. otice that θ f (ψ, θ) > 0. Therefore, ( x 2 ) ) (ψ θ f, θ ( x ) [ θ f ψ, θ ( x ) θ f ψ, θ ( θ f ψ, θ) ] 0. Thus, when θ 0.53, the second half of the LHS of Eq.(25) is also non-positive, which implies that Eq.(25) holds. When θ < 0.53, the second half of the LHS of Eq.(25) could be positive so that we need to compare the magnitudes of the two parts. We discuss the case in which ψ ψ < ψ 3, the other cases can be easily proved. By mean value theorem, we have θ π M ψ, θ θ π M ψ, θ = 2 ( ψθ π M ˆψ, θ ψ ψ ), where ˆψ is some value between ψ and ψ. Similarly, n ( x 2) θ f ψ, θ n ( x ) θ f ψ, θ = [ n ( x ) θ f ψ, θ ] θ f ψ, θ n ( x 2 ( ) ψθ f ψ, θ ψ ψ ), where ψ is some value between ψ and ψ. Since ψ ψ ψ ψ, we can conclude that Eq.(25) holds if we can show 2 ψθ π M ˆψ, θ > 2 ψθ f ψ, θ. As we can verify, both 2 ψθ π M (ψ, θ) and

2 ψθ f (ψ, θ) are decreasing in ψ for ψ ( 0, 3) when θ < 0.53. Therefore, 2 ψθ π M ˆψ, θ + 2 ψθ f ψ, θ < 2 ψθ π M (0, θ) + 2 f (0, θ) ψθ = 2 ( 2 + 3θ 3θ 2 + θ 3) 27 ( θ) 3 < 0. Altogether, we have shown that Eq.(25) holds for θ ( 0, 2), which means the objective function is decreasing in θ. Proof of Proposition 8. (i) Consider the locally envy-free equilibrium in which the n niche rms' bids (labeled such that b n < bn b n = πn () b i = πi () b 2 = max{π(2) <... < b2 ) are π n() π i() + bi+, i = 3,..., n π2(), 0} + b3 and the mainstream rm bids any amount greater than b 2. As a result, M wins the rst position and niche rms stay in the 2nd through the nth positions. ow we investigate under what conditions the above bidding strategy prole is indeed an equilibrium. It is easy to see that all niche rms have no protable deviations. To ensure no protable deviation of M, πm b2 πk M bk+ has to be satised for all k = 2,..., n (Let b n+ other words, the following conditions have to be satised. ( πm max{π (2), π2() ) ( } πn() πm k π k() ) πn(), k = 2,..., n; = 0). In or equivalently, πm π(2) πm π2() πk M πk() πk M πk() k = 2,..., n, k = 2,..., n

which are further equivalent to that ( ψ, θ ) ( ψ, θ ) ( ψ k, θ ) + n ( ψ k) f ( ψ, θ ) n ( ψ ) f ( ψ 2, θ ) 0 ( ψ k, θ ) + n ( ψ k) f ( ψ, θ ) n ( ψ 2) f ( ψ, θ ) 0 holds for all k = 2,..., n. By Lemma 2, the LHS of the rst inequality is decreasing in θ. Also, it is easy to show that the LHS of the second inequality is decreasing in θ, given that θ f (ψ, θ) > 0. As a result, as long as the values of {ψ i } n i= satisfy ( ψ, 0 ) ( ψ, 0 ) ( ψ k, 0 ) + n ( ψ k) f ( ψ, 0 ) n ( ψ ) f ( ψ 2, 0 ) > 0 ( ψ k, 0 ) + n ( ψ k) f ( ψ, 0 ) n ( ψ 2) f ( ψ, 0 ) > 0 for k = 2,..., n, which is a loose parametric condition that can be satised under most values of {ψ i } n i=, we can conclude that there exists ˆθ (ψ,..., ψ n ) such that when 0 < θ < ˆθ (ψ,..., ψ n ), the described bidding strategy prole is an equilibrium. (ii) Similarly, consider the locally envy-free equilibrium in which the n niche rms' bids (labeled such that b n < bn 2 b n b > b2 <... < b ) are = πn 2(n) b i = πi (n) π n (n) π i(n) + b M + bi+, i = 2,..., n 2 and the mainstream rm bids b M = π n M πn M. As a result, the niche rms stay in the rst n positions and M stays in the last one. To see under what conditions the above bidding strategy prole is indeed an equilibrium, we need to ensure that any niche rm does not have protable deviation, such that π n(n ) π k(n) bk+ = π n (n) ( π n M M) πn (k =,..., n ), as well as that M does not have protable deviation, such that πm k bk πn M for k = 2,..., n. (ote that no deviation to the rst position for M can

easily hold as long as b is high enough.) We can organize these conditions as π n M πm k πn πn M + πn(n ) M + πn (n) π n (n) 0 π k (n) 0, k = 2,..., n ; or equivalently, ( ψ (n ), θ ) πm ( ψ n, θ ) + n ( ψ n) f ( ψ (n ), θ ) n ( ψ n ) f ( ψ n, θ ) 0 ( ψ k, θ ) πm ( ψ (n ), θ ) + n ( ψ n ) f ( ψ n, θ ) n ( ψ k ) f ( ψ n, θ ) 0, where k = 2,..., n. By Lemma 2, the LHS of the rst inequality is decreasing in θ. Also, it is easy to show that the LHS of the second inequality is decreasing in θ, given that θ f (ψ, θ) > 0. As a result, as long as the values of {ψ i } n i= satisfy ( ψ (n ), ) ( 2 π M ψ n, ) 2 + n ( ψ n) f ( ψ (n ), ) 2 n ( ψ n ) f ( ψ n, 2) < 0 ( ψ k, ) ( 2 π M ψ (n ), ) 2 + n ( ψ n ) f ( ψ n, ) 2 n ( ψ k ) f ( ψ n, 2) < 0, for k = 2,..., n, which is not dicult to be satised under most values of {ψ i } n i=, we can conclude that there exists θ (ψ,..., ψ n ) such that when θ (ψ,..., ψ n ) < θ < 2, the described bidding strategy prole is an equilibrium.